Journal Issue: World Bank Economic Review, Volume 20, Issue 2

No Thumbnail Available
Volume
20
Number
2
Issue Date
Journal Title
Journal ISSN
1564-698X
Journal
Journal
World Bank Economic Review
1564-698X
Journal Volume
Articles
Publication
Doha Merchandise Trade Reform : What is at Stake for Developing Countries?
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-01) van der Mensbrugghe, Dominique; Anderson, Kym; Martin, Will
This article: a) summarizes the costs of current merchandise trade distortions to developing and other economies; b) examines some scenarios that might emerge as part of an eventual Doha agreement consistent with the 2005 Hong Kong Ministerial declaration, particularly with respect to agriculture; and c) draws implications for the strategies developing countries might adopt in the World Trade Organization's (WTO's) Doha round of multilateral trade negotiations. This article estimates what the world economy might look like in 2015 without and with a successful conclusion to the Doha round, how far Doha could take the world toward an outcome with no distortions in merchandise trade, and what contribution various elements of a Doha package could make.
Publication
Price Effects of Preferential Market Access : Caribbean Basin Initiative and the Apparel Sector
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-01) Sharma, Gunjan; Özden, Çaglar
Preferential trade arrangements should be evaluated by their effect on prices rather than by their effect on the total value of trade. This point is emphasized in the theoretical literature but rarely implemented empirically. This article analyzes the U.S. Caribbean Basin Initiative's (CBI's) impact on the prices received by eligible apparel exporters. The CBI's apparel preferences are the most important and heavily used unilateral preferences because of high trade barriers imposed on exports from the rest of the world. A fixed effect generalized least squares (GLS) estimation is used to isolate the effects of other factors (such as quality, exchange rates, and transaction costs) and to identify the effects of tariff preferences. CBI exporters capture only about two-thirds of their preference margin despite the high degree of competition among importers. This translates into a 9 percent increase in the relative prices they receive, with some variance across countries and years. Countries specializing in higher value items capture more of the preference margin, and the implementation of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has a negative effect. Removing multifibre arrangement quotas significantly lowers the benefits of CBI preferences.
Publication
Preference Erosion and Multilateral Trade Liberalization
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-22) Francois, Joseph; Hoekman, Bernard; Manchin, Miriam
Because of concern that tariff reductions in Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries will translate into worsening export performance for the least developed countries, the erosion of trade preferences may become a stumbling block for multilateral trade liberalization. An econometric analysis of actual preference use shows that preferences are underused because of administrative burdens-estimated to be equivalent to an average of four percent of the value of goods traded. To quantify the maximum scope for preference erosion, the compliance cost estimates are used in a model-based assessment of the impact of full elimination of OECD tariffs. Taking into account administrative costs eliminates erosion costs in the aggregate and greatly reduces the losses for countries most affected by preference erosion.
Publication
Development : A Study of the Indian Manufacturing Industry
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-04) Hulten, Charles; Bennathan, Esra; Srinivasan, Sylaja
If infrastructure tends to generate spillover externalities, as has been the assumption in much of the development literature, one may reasonably look for evidence of such indirect effects in the accounts of manufacturing industries. Empirical support for this assumption has so far been ambiguous. This analysis of Indian data, however, reveals substantial externality effects from the states' infrastructure to manufacturing productivity. The analysis separates the direct effects of roads and electricity, as mediated by the infrastructure services purchased by manufacturing industries along with other intermediate inputs, from the indirect effects, as measured by the impact of infrastructure capacity on the Solow productivity residual. In the 20 years from 1972 to 1992, growth of road and electricity-generating capacity seems to have accounted for nearly half the growth of the productivity residual of India's registered manufacturing.
Publication
Trade Preferences to Small Developing Countries and the Welfare Costs of Lost Multilateral Liberalization
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-17) Limão, Nuno; Olarreaga, Marcelo
The proliferation of preferential trade liberalization over the last 20 years has raised the question of whether it slows multilateral trade liberalization. Recent theoretical and empirical evidence indicates that this is the case even for unilateral preferences that developed countries provide to small and poor countries, but there is no estimate of the resulting welfare costs. This stumbling block effect can be avoided by replacing the unilateral preferences with a fixed import subsidy, which generates a Pareto improvement. More importantly, this paper presents the first estimates of the welfare cost of preferential liberalization as a stumbling block to multilateral liberalization. Recent estimates of the stumbling block effect of preferences with data for 170 countries and more than 5,000 products are used to calculate the welfare effects of the European Union, Japan, and the United States switching from unilateral preferences for least developed countries to an import subsidy scheme. In a model with no dynamic gains to trade, the switch produces an annual net welfare gain for the 170 countries that adds about 10 percent to the estimated trade liberalization gains in the Doha Round. It also generates gains for each group: the European Union, Japan, and the United States ($2,934 million), least developed countries ($520 million), and the rest of the world ($900 million).
Publication
Aid and the Supply Side : Public Investment, Export Performance, and Dutch Disease in Low-Income Countries
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-17) Adam, Christopher S.; Bevan, David L.
Contemporary policy debates on the macroeconomics of aid often concentrate on short-run Dutch disease effects, ignoring the possible supply-side impact of aid financed public expenditure. In the simple model of aid and public expenditure presented here, public infrastructure generates an inter-temporal productivity spillover, which may exhibit a sector-specific bias. The model also provides for a learning-by-doing externality, through which total factor productivity in the tradable sector is an increasing function of past export volumes. An extended computable version of this model is used to simulate the effect of a step increase in net aid flows. The simulations show that beyond the short run, when conventional demand-side Dutch disease effects are present, the relationship between enhanced aid flows and real exchange rates, output growth, and welfare is less straightforward than simple models of aid suggest. Public infrastructure investment that generates a productivity bias in favor of non-tradable production delivers the largest aggregate return to aid, but at the cost of deterioration in the income distribution. Income gains accrue predominantly to skilled and unskilled urban households, leaving the rural poor relatively worse off. Under plausible parameterizations of the model, the rural poor may also be worse off in absolute terms.
Publication
The Doha Round and Preference Erosion : A Symposium
(Oxford University Press on behalf of the World Bank, 2006-05-12) Hoekman, Bernard
The trade and welfare impacts of multilateral liberalization on individual countries and groups within countries depend on many factors-including the depth of liberalization by trading partners, the extent of countries' own reforms, the responsiveness of investors to changes in relative prices and market opportunities, and actions by governments to reduce real trade costs. The magnitude of erosion will depend on a variety of factors, including the product and country coverage of preferential schemes, the level of most favored nation restrictions in the markets granting preferential access, the administrative costs associated with using preference programs, the incidence of any preference rents, the depth of liberalization realized in Doha, and the existence of and changes in reciprocal trade agreements. Moreover, the value of preferences is better measured by income earned-what matters is the impact on the price actually received by the exporters because the pass-through of preferential access is likely to be incomplete.
Description
Keywords