Vogt-Schilb, AdrienHallegatte, Stephane2012-03-192012-03-192011-09-01https://hdl.handle.net/10986/3567This article investigates the use of expert-based Marginal Abatement Cost Curves (MACC) to design abatement strategies. It shows that introducing inertia, in the form of the "cost in time" of available options, changes significantly the message from MACCs. With an abatement objective in cumulative emissions (e.g., emitting less than 200 GtCO2 in the 2000-2050 period), it makes sense to implement some of the more expensive options before the potential of the cheapest ones has been exhausted. With abatement targets expressed in terms of emissions at one point in time (e.g., reducing emissions by 20 percent in 2020), it can even be preferable to start with the implementation of the most expensive options if their potential is high and their inertia significant. Also, the best strategy to reach a short-term target is different depending on whether this target is the ultimate objective or there is a longer-term target. The best way to achieve Europe's goal of 20 percent reduction in emissions by 2020 is different if this objective is the ultimate objective or if it is only a milestone in a trajectory toward a 75 percent reduction in 2050. The cheapest options may be sufficient to reach the 2020 target but could create a carbon-intensive lock-in and preclude deeper emission reductions by 2050. These results show that in a world without perfect foresight and perfect credibility of the long-term carbon-price signal, a unique carbon price in all sectors is not the most efficient approach. Sectoral objectives, such as Europe's 20 percent renewable energy target in Europe, fuel-economy standards in the auto industry, or changes in urban planning, building norms and infrastructure design are a critical part of an efficient mitigation policy.CC BY 3.0 IGOABATEMENT ACTIVITIESABATEMENT COSTSABATEMENT LEVELABATEMENT MEASURESABATEMENT OPTIONABATEMENT POTENTIALABATEMENT STRATEGIESABATING CLIMATE CHANGEAGGREGATE EMISSIONSAIRAIR POLLUTIONAIR POLLUTION REDUCTIONAMOUNT OF ABATEMENTANNUAL EMISSIONANNUAL EMISSIONSATMOSPHERIC CONCENTRATIONAUTO INDUSTRYBASELINE EMISSIONSCAPITAL STOCKSCAPITAL TURNOVERCARBONCARBON BUDGETCARBON EMISSIONSCARBON PRICECARBON PRICESCLEAN TRANSPORTATIONCLIMATECLIMATE CHANGECLIMATE DAMAGESCLIMATE OBJECTIVESCLIMATE POLICIESCLIMATE POLICYCLIMATE RESPONSECLIMATIC CHANGECOCO2COMBUSTIONCONCENTRATIONSCUMULATIVE EMISSIONSDEMAND CURVEDISTRIBUTIONAL IMPACTSECOLOGICAL ECONOMICSECONOMIC SECTORSELECTRIC POWERELECTRIC POWER SYSTEMSELECTRIC VEHICLESELECTRICITYEMISSIONEMISSION ABATEMENTEMISSION BASELINEEMISSION CONSTRAINTEMISSION REDUCTIONSEMISSION TARGETEMISSION TARGETSEMISSIONSEMISSIONS ABATEMENTEMISSIONS PATHWAYSEMISSIONS TARGETSENERGY ECONOMICSENERGY INFRASTRUCTUREENERGY POLICYENERGY PRICESENERGY SECURITYENERGY SOURCESENGINESENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICSENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENTENVIRONMENTAL POLICIESENVIRONMENTAL POLICYEXOGENOUS CONSTRAINTFUELFUEL ECONOMYGAS EMISSIONGHGGLOBAL WARMINGGREENHOUSEGREENHOUSE GASGREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONSGREENHOUSE GASESGREENHOUSE-GASINVESTMENT DECISIONSLOW-CARBONMARGINAL ABATEMENTMARGINAL ABATEMENT COSTMARGINAL COSTMARGINAL COST OF ABATEMENTMARKET FAILURESPOLICY ANALYSISPOLICY IMPLICATIONSPOLLUTION ABATEMENTPOWER GENERATIONPOWER PLANTSPPPRESENT COSTPRESENT VALUEPRICE SIGNALREDUCTION IN EMISSIONSRENEWABLE ENERGIESRENEWABLE ENERGYRESTRICTIONSSHADOW PRICESUM OF EMISSIONSSUPPLY CURVESUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENTSUSTAINABLE ENERGYTRADABLE EMISSIONSTRANSACTION COSTSVEHICLEWASTEWASTE RECYCLINGWORLD ENERGYWhen Starting with the Most Expensive Option Makes Sense : Use and Misuse of Marginal Abatement Cost CurvesWorld Bank10.1596/1813-9450-5803