@ D IR EC TI O NS I N DE VE L O P M E N T |A * ~~~~~~~~- j,;,gi,j,/iilea''G1..MNX * !Lmj 0 0 .s .. * _ X,,j:EUjAi l~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~44 DIRECTIONS IN DEVELOPMENT Development Finance Institutions Measuring Their Subsidy DIRECTIONS IN DEVELOPMENT Development Finance Institutions Measuring Their Subsidy Mark Schreiner Jacob Yaron THE WORLD BANK WASHINGTON, D.C. Copyright © 2001 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, USA All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing October 2001 1 2 3 4 04 03 02 01 The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this book are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its affil- iated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility for any consequence of their use. The material in this publication is copyrighted. The World Bank encourages dis- semination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly. Permission to photocopy items for internal or personal use, for the internal or per- sonal use of specific clients, or for educational classroom use is granted by the World Bank, provided that the appropriate fee is paid directly to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-750-4470. Please contact the Copyright Clearance Center before photocopying items. For permission to reprint individual articles or chapters, please fax a request with complete information to the Republication Department, Copyright Clearance Center, fax 978-750-4470. All other queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, World Bank, at the address above or faxed to 202-522-2422. Cover photo credit: Curt Carnemark, 1994; Morocco Cover background: Tomas Sennett, undated; Brazil Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Schreiner, Mark, 1969- Development finance institutions: measuring their subsidy / Mark Schreiner, Jacob Yaron. p. , cm. - (Directions in development) Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 0-8213-4984-8 1. Development credit corporations. 2. Development banks. 3. Subsidies. 4. Externalities (Economics) 1. Yaron, Jacob. II. Title. 111. Series. HG3726 .S34 2001 332.2'8-dc2l 2001045424 Contents Abstract ............................................... viii Acknowledgments ................................................x Glossary of Acronyms ................................................ xi Glossary of Notation ................................................ xii Introduction ................................................1 What Is the Subsidy Dependence Index? ................................................2 What Is Net Present Cost to Society? ................................................ 6 Is the Subsidy Dependence Index Redundant? .......................................8 What Does the Rest of the Monograph Cover? ........................................9 1. Why Measure the Social Cost of Public Development Finance Institutions? ............................................... 10 What Is a Public Development Finance Institution? ............................. 10 Who Bears the Costs and Who Reaps the Benefits of Public Development Finance Institutions? ......................................... 11 How Do Public Development Finance Institutions Differ from Other Public Projects? ............................................. 12 Why Does Society Subsidize Public Development Finance Institutions? ............................................. 12 How Can Society Measure the Benefits of Public Development Finance Institutions? ............................................. 14 What Is the Opportunity Cost to Society of Public Funds Used by Development Finance Institutions? ...................................... 16 Why Does the Measurement of Costs Boost Performance? ................. 21 v vi DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS 2. What Is a Measure of the Social Cost of a Public Development Finance Institution in the Short Term? ............................................... 22 How Does a Development Finance Institution Get Subsidies? .......... 22 What Forms of Subsidized Funds Does a Development Finance Institution Get? ..................................................... 23 Numerical Examples of the Subsidy Dependence Index .................... 32 Is Subsidy in the Subsidy Dependence Index Related to a Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity? .................................................. 43 How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as Its Parts Change? .................................................... 46 3. What Is a Measure of the Social Cost of a Public Development Finance Institution in the Long Term? ................................................. 53 How Does the Net Present Cost to Society Discount Flows? ............. 53 What Questions Does the Net Present Cost to Society Inform? ......... 55 What Are the Net Present Cost to Society and the Subsidy Dependence Index in the Long Term for the Example Development Finance Institution? ...................................... 58 4. What Are the Pitfalls When Calculating the Subsidy Dependence Index or Net Present Cost to Society? ........................... 62 What Is the Social Opportunity Cost? .................................................... 62 What Can Be Done to Cope with Accounting Data? ........................... 62 What Are Other Pitfalls and Caveats? .................................................... 68 What Are the Key Caveats? ..................................................... 73 5. Recent Proposed Changes to the Subsidy Dependence Index ....... 74 The Subsidy Dependence Ratio of Khandker ........................................ 74 The Profitability Gap of Sacay .................................................... 79 The Average Subsidy Dependence Index of Hulme and Mosley ....... 81 Appendix: A Framework to Approximate the Opportunity Costs of Private Entities .................................................... 84 What Is the Price of Private Debt? .................................................... 84 What Is the Price of Private Equity? .................................................... 86 References .................................................... 90 CONTENTS vii Tables 2.1. Types of Subsidized Funds ............................................... 23 2.2. Balance Sheet ............................................... 34 2.3. Income Statement ............................................... 35 2.4. Calculation of the Subsidy Dependence Index ................................ 36 2.5. Alternative Calculation of the Subsidy Dependence Index ............................................... 38 2.6. ROE, SAROE, ROA, and SAROA ............................................... 47 3.1. Net Present Cost to Society ............................................... 59 4.1. Balance Sheet with Loan Losses ............................................... 65 4.2. Income Statement with Loan Losses ............................................... 66 4.3. Summary with Loan Losses ............................................... 67 A.1. Private Opportunity Costs ............................................... 85 A.2. Subsidy Dependence Index with Private Opportunity Costs ............................................... 88 Figures 1.1. Five Possible Proxies of the Social Opportunity Cost ..................... 18 2.1. Profit Grants and ROE ............................................... 25 2.2. Grameen: Inflation and Nominal and Real Yields ........................... 31 2.3. BancoSol: Inflation and Nominal and Real Yields ........................... 31 2.4. ROE versus SAROE for the Example DFI ......................................... 46 2.5. ROA versus SAROA for the Example DFI ........................................ 46 2.6. The SDI and the Yield on Loans, i ............................................... 49 2.7. The SDI and the Rate Paid for Public Debt, c ................................... 49 2.8. The SDI and the Social Opportunity Cost, m ................................... 50 2.9. The SDI and Administrative Expenses .............................................. 51 2.10. The SDI and the Ratio of Deposits to Public Debt .......................... 52 Boxes 1.1. Social Cost Is the Road Not Taken ................................................ 3 1.2. Economic Value Added, Subsidy for For-Profit Firms ......................4 1.3. Social Worthwhileness, Subsidy Independence, Private Profitability, and Self-Sustainability ................................................7 2.1. How Profit Grants Affect Profit and Return on Equity .................. 25 2.2. Real Yields at Grameen and BancoSol ............................................... 31 2.3. The Subsidy Dependence Index and Average Equity at Bank Rakyat Indonesia ............................................... 42 2.4. The Subsidy Dependence Index and Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity for an African DFI .............................................. 48 Abstract Measures of the social cost of development finance institutions (DFIs) that receive public funds help to check whether DFIs are good uses of public funds. Public funds are well-spent-and social welfare is improved-if the social benefit of a DFI exceeds the social cost. The term development finance institution encompasses not only government devel- opment banks but also thousands of nongovernmental microfinance organizations worldwide that use matching grants to attempt to promote community development, decentralization of power, and local empower- ment. This monograph describes the measurement of costs but not of benefits, but even without precise knowledge of benefits, knowledge of costs can help to spend funds well. It is less expensive to measure costs than benefits, and "cost calculations can provide a useful 'reality check' on proposed interventions. Whatever the true [unknown] size of external benefits, the government must judge that at a minimum the external ben- efit exceeds this cost for the intervention to be worth undertaking" (Devarajan, Squire, and Suthiwart-Narueput 1997, p. 40). This monograph presents two measures of social cost. The first is the Subsidy Dependence Index (SDI). The SDI does not discount flows, so it works best in short time frames or when the rate of time preference is low. The SDI is the ratio of subsidy received to revenue from loans. Subsidy is defined as the social cost of the public funds used to run a DFI. The mea- sure of subsidy can also be used to adjust common measures of financial performance such as Return on Equity (ROE) or Return on Assets (ROA). The second measure is the Net Present Cost to Society (NPCS). Like standard present-value measures, the NPC5 discounts cash flows and works in any time frame. The SDI and the NPCS are useful because common financial ratios- such as ROE-may hide the true performance of DFIs because their mea- sures of cost may not reflect social opportunity costs. The SDI and the NPCS shift the paradigm from reported (accounting) costs-much of which are routinely subsidized-to opportunity (economic) costs. The two measures proposed here use standard tools of project analysis to viii ABSTRACT ix answer questions from the point of view of society. The questions and answers also matter to governments and donors who care about sustain- ability. A sustainable DFI can meet its goals now and in the long term. Sustainability improves social welfare if the consequent long-term increase in the length, breadth, scope, and quality of outreach compen- sate for the short-term increases in costs shifted to the target group. By definition, a subsidy-independent DFI has no social cost in financial terms. The SDI and the NPC5 are simple tools, and their results are only as good as their data and assumptions. Like other yardsticks, they help to establish benchmarks, chart trends, and compare a DFI with peers with identical clients and services. The measurement of the social cost of public DFIs matters because funds earmarked for development are scarce. Subsidies for DFIs are not bad unless they could improve social welfare more somewhere else. The measurement of social cost as described in this monograph is a first step toward wiser use of public funds. Acknowledgments We are thankful for comments from Stephanie Charitonenko, Carlos Cuevas, Douglas Graham, Michael Lyne, Jonathan Morduch, Sergio Navajas, Glenn Pederson, Richard Rosenberg, Michael Sherraden, and participants in seminars at The Ohio State University. The opinions expressed are not necessarily those of Washington University in St. Louis nor of the World Bank. x Glossary of Acronyms BancoSol Banco Solidario, S.A. BRI Bank Rakyat Indonesia CBA Cost-benefit analysis CEA Cost-effectiveness analysis CGAP Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest CNCA Caisse Nationale de Credit Agricole EVA Economic Value Added DFI Development finance institution GAAP Generally accepted accounting principles IADB Inter-American Development Bank IAS International accounting standard NGO Nongovernmental organization NPCS Net Present Cost to Society PG Profitability Gap ROA Return on Assets ROE Return on Equity SAROA Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Assets SAROE Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity SDI Subsidy Dependence Index in a short time frame SDIL Subsidy Dependence Index in a long time frame SDR Subsidy Dependence Ratio xi Glossary of Notation c Rate paid for public debt by a DFI A Average public debt A (i(m - c) Discount on public debt 8 Social discount rate d Deposit interest rate Dep Average deposit liabilities DG Direct grants DX Discount on expenses E Average equity EG Equity grant Yield on loans I Average investments j Yield on investments IC Yield received by DFI on required reserves k Reserve requirement L Leverage LP Average loan portfolio (net) LP- i Revenue from loans m Opportunity cost of public funds in nominal terms to society or the opportunity cost of public debt to a private entity M Opportunity cost of public equity to a private entity n Age of a DFI in years P Accounting profit Q Quantity of public funds It Inflation rate PC Paid-in capital R Nominal rate of interest r Real rate of interest RG Revenue grant S Subsidy t Index of years since the start of a time frame T Years in a time frame TP True profit xii Introduction Why measure the social cost of public development finance institutions? Governments and donors for decades have tried to improve social welfare through public support for development finance institutions (DFIs). Public DFIs, as with all projects that use public funds, are worthwhile in principle only if their social benefits exceed their social costs. In practice, it is so expensive to measure social benefits that a full-blown social cost- benefit analysis (CBA) cannot be done each time a choice must be made to spend public funds on a DFI. A less-expensive alternative to CBA is a sim- ple measure of social cost. Social cost is defined as the opportunity cost of public resources used by a DFI. It is the opportunity cost to society of the public funds used by a DFI less what the DFI could pay for those funds and still show a profit. A DFI with no social cost is subsidy-independent. This monograph presents two measures of social cost. The first is the Subsidy Dependence Index (SDI) proposed by Yaron (1992a, 1992b). The second is the Net Present Cost to Society (NPCS) proposed by Schreiner (1997) for the flows of public funds between society and a DFI. The SDI works in short time frames such as a year. Like all other standard present- value measures, the NPCS works in all time frames because it discounts resource flows according to when they take place in time. Common financial measures such as accounting profit or Return on Equity (ROE) are based on prices paid as recorded in the accounts of the DFI, and these prices may reflect market failures or nonmarket rules of governments or donors. In contrast, the SDI and the NPCS are based on social opportunity costs, the social return those funds would earn in their best use outside of DFIs. This paradigm shift matters because the prices of public funds entrusted to a DFI as loans or equity are almost always set far below the social opportunity cost. Likewise, DFIs often record grants in cash as revenues and/or fail to record grants in kind as expenses. This practice lards profits but does not change business performance. Such accounting window dressing can hide the truth about the use of public funds by a DFI and its economic subsidy dependence. Generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) take the opportunity cost of equity as zero 1 2 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS and ignore both low levels of inflation and the time value of money. Thus, a DFI can boast of an accounting profit even as inflation shrinks its net worth in real terms. A positive ROE does not always mean that a DFI can compensate society for the opportunity cost of public funds. The SDI and the NPC5 resolve the problems of accounting-based mea- sures because they value funds at their opportunity costs. They help to check whether a DFI uses public funds to increase or to decrease social welfare. A DFI increases social welfare only if the net benefits from its use of public funds exceed the net benefits from their use elsewhere. Measurement of the social cost of public support for DFIs matters because public funds are scarce. New measures-such as the SDI and the NPCS-are needed because the old ones fail to measure social costs well because they were designed for private firms, not for public DFIs. The goal of the measurement of social cost is not to end subsidies for DFIs; rather, the goal is to put a price tag on DFIs to make sure that subsidies for DFIs are the best way to improve social welfare. Appropriate measurements of performance matter because DFIs use a big chunk of the development budget. For example, the World Bank had loaned more than $30 billion (all dollar amounts are U.S. dollars unless specified) for credit projects by 1989 (Von Pischke 1991). Even if donor lending for DFIs dwindles-which seems unlikely given the myriad spe- cialized-credit programs worldwide-the SDI and NPCS are still useful as measures of the social cost of the explosion of public support for micro- finance DFIs during the past decade. Microfinance DFIs outnumber tra- ditional public-sector DFIs; a 1996 survey of more than 200 microfinance DFIs found 13 million loans worth $7 billion and 45 million deposit accounts worth $19 billion (Paxton 1996). Some microfinance advocates hope to attract more than $21.6 billion to extend microfinance to 100 mil- lion families in the next 10 years (RESULTS International 1996). It behooves society to check whether the crusade for microfinance siphons funds away from better ways to improve welfare (box 1.1; Mosley and Hulme 1998; Buckley 1997; Rogaly 1996). What Is the Subsidy Dependence Index? Yaron (1992a, 1992b) proposed a two-part framework of outreach and sustainability that has become the most common tool to measure the per- formance of DFIs (e.g., Gonzalez-Vega and others 1997; Khandker 1996; Chaves and Gonzalez-Vega 1996; Christen and others 1995; Benjamin 1994; Yaron 1994; Hossain 1988). The SDI is a summary measure of sustainability. It is the ratio of sub- sidy received by a DFI to revenue from loans to the target group and indicates whether a DFI could compensate society for the opportunity INTRODUCTION 3 Box I.1. Social Cost Is the Road Not Taken The social cost of public resources used in a DFI is the benefit lost because those resources were not used in another project. For example, the social cost as measured by the SDI of the Caisse Nationale de Credit Agricole (CNCA), a rural development bank in Morocco, was about $85 million a year. According to Devarajan, Squire, and Suthiwart-Narueput (1997, p. 40), these subsidies "could conceivably be justified on the grounds that the bank operated in an underserved rural credit market and reached poor people. Although these benefits are hard to quantify, assessing the cost of the subsidy is one way to ask whether this subsidy is a good use of scarce public resources and to think about alternative uses. In this case, CNCA's annual subsidy amounted to about 20 percent of the recurrent budget for primary education and 160 percent of the recurrent budget for basic health care. And this in a country where social indicators were quite unsatisfacto- ry-primary enrollment is around 70 percent, and under-five mortality is about 80 deaths per thousand live births." Even without a full-blown CBA, the SDI can help to guide the best mix of public investments among, as in this example, agricultural credit, education, and preventative health care. cost of public funds used in a short time frame and still show a profit. Such a DFI is called subsidy-independent. The SDI looks at social cost. The second half of the framework-out- reach-looks at social benefit. Outreach has six aspects (Schreiner 1999a): worth to users, cost to users, breadth, length, depth, and scope of the out- put of a DFI. The SDI relates to subsidy in two ways. First, the SDI provides a frame- work to measure subsidy as the social opportunity cost of the public funds held by the DFI in a short time frame such as one year, minus the price the DFI paid, minus (plus) accounting profit (loss). Thus, subsidy is the implicit "rental cost" of public resources, minus the rented funds that were lost and thus cannot be returned. Subsidy is positive for a subsidy- dependent DFI and negative for a subsidy-independent DFI. Second, the SDI is a ratio that uses the measurement of subsidy as its numerator and revenue from loans as its denominator. The ratio can be seen as the percentage change in the yield on loans that, all else constant, would make the DFI subsidy-independent. It may also be seen as the matching grant (subsidy in the numerator) awarded to the DFI by society for each dollar of interest and fees paid by borrowers (revenue from loans in the denominator). The subsidy measure in the SDI can also be transformed into a Subsidy-Adjusted ROE (SAROE). As will be shown later, the two mea- 4 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS sures are equivalent in that the SDI is negative if and only if an SAROE would exceed the social opportunity cost. The measure of subsidy in the SDI has features like those of Economic Value Added (EVA), a popular new measure of the financial performance of for-profit firms (box 1.2). Box I.2. Economic Value Added, Subsidy for For-Profit Firms The concept of the measurement of performance as opportunity cost less profit is not unique to DFIs, having long been a staple in the analysis of not- for-profit hospitals (Jennings 1993; Wheeler and Clement 1990; Silvers and Kauer 1986; Pauly 1986; Conrad 1984, 1986). Nor is the concept unique to not-for-profits. For-profit firms-'lost in ever darker muddles of account- ing" (Tully 1993)-have turned to measures based on opportunity cost because measures such as accounting profit and ROE do not tell owners whether a firm increases private wealth, just as they do not tell policymak- ers whether a DFI increases social welfare. Subsidy in the SDI is analogous to the concept of Economic Value Added (EVA), a new performance measure used by for-profit firms (The Economist 1997). EVA is after-tax profit minus the economic cost of funds used. If EVA is positive, then the firm created financial value for its owners; likewise, if subsidy is negative, then the DFI created financial value for society. EVA is useful to stockholders because "stock prices track EVA far more closely than they track such popular measures as earnings per share or operating margins or ROE. That is because EVA shows what investors real- ly care about-the net cash return on their capital-rather than some other type of performance viewed through the often distorting lens of accounting rules" (Tully 1993). Wal-Mart, Coca-Cola, AT&T, and Proctor & Gamble use EVA because, unlike standard accounting measures, EVA accounts for the total cost of capital. One analyst said, "Capital looks free to a lot of managers. It doesn't look free to investors who hand them the money" (Tully 1993). Just as EVA reminds managers of for-profit firms of opportunity costs to investors, the SDI reminds managers of DFIs of opportunity costs to society. Like the SDI, a strength of EVA is its ease of use. Better measures-such as Net Present Value for stockholders and the Net Present Cost to Society- use discounting, but they are used less because they are more complex. Measurement with the SDI or EVA boosts performance and ratchets standards up a notch. One CFO said, "The effect is staggering. 'Good' is no longer positive operating earnings. It's only when you beat the cost of cap- ital" (Tully 1993). Like the SDI, EVA "is powerful and widely applicable because in the end it doesn't prescribe doing anything.... Instead, it is a way to see and under- stand what is really happening" (Tully 1993). INTRODUCTION 5 What Are the Strengths of the Subsidy Dependence Index? The SDI has at least 12 strengths. * The SDI quantifies subsidy and shows the extent of subsidy depen- dence. Often governments and donors do not know just how much their support for DFIs costs society because much of the subsidy is not in terms of explicit cash flows from the public purse to the DFI. Knowledge of subsidies is needed to compare support for DFIs with other uses of public funds. * The SDI compares subsidy with revenue from loans. This ratio can be seen as a matching grant; that is, the amount of subsidy awarded to the DFI by society for each dollar of interest paid by borrowers. * The SDI is a measure of subsidy dependence through time. Whether or not a DFI can declare complete subsidy independence, it can always strive to improve. * A negative SDI implies an SAROE higher than the social opportunity cost. This patches the weaknesses in the common framework based on unadjusted ROE. * The SDI shifts the paradigm from accounting costs to opportunity costs because accounting costs are often distorted by subsidies. • The SDI highlights the possibility of covering costs with revenue from loans. * Although the SDI does not measure benefits, which is expensive, it does measure costs, which is less expensive. * The SDI is simple-if the financial data of the DFI conform with GAAP-and well known. * The use of the SDI can induce a disciplined approach to the judgment of the social costs of public support for DFIs. * Because the data needed for the SDI should be easy to extract, the use of the SDI can highlight specific improvements that should be intro- duced in the accounting systems. * The SDI can help in the analysis of the sources and uses of subsidy (Yaron 1992b, p. 24). * The SDI-unlike the SAROE-worsens if DFIs keep profit constant but shift resources away from loans to the target group and toward other investments such as government bonds. What Are the Limitations of the Subsidy Dependence Index? The SDI has at least two limitations. Analysts should know them so that they use the SDI only to answer the question to which it applies. The SDI answers an important question-whether a DFI could compensate soci- 6 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS ety for the opportunity cost of its funds and still show a profit-but it does not answer all the important questions. First, the SDI does not discount flows of funds. This is not a difficulty in short time frames (such as one year) with low inflation. But not all time frames are short, and inflation can be high. For example, suppose gov- ernments or donors need to choose whether to start a new DFI from scratch. To inform this choice, they might ask whether an existing DFI would have been judged as subsidy-independent from its birth had its eventual performance been known at its birth. Or they might want to plan their support so that projected performance in a long time frame meets a goal (Helms 1997). After all, newborn DFIs, just like all newborn firms, lose money until time and growth spread start-up costs and hone technology. Like private investors who judge firms by their Net Present Value, governments and donors must judge DFIs not only in their first year, not only in the most recent year, and not only in the next year, but rather all through their whole lifetimes. Of course, pro forma data may have a wide margin of error, but society should follow the lead of private investors, who find that explicit present-value analysis is useful even if based on data of doubtful quality. Second, the SDI indicates subsidy independence but not self-sustain- ability (box I.3). A subsidy-independent DFI could pay the social opportu- nity cost of its funds and still show a profit, and a self-sustainable DFI can meet its goals now and in the long term. Subsidy independence may not guarantee self-sustainability. For example, private opportunity costs may exceed social opportunity costs, so a subsidy-independent DFI might not be able to pay market prices for private funds and still show a profit should sources of public funds dry up. Also, for example, a subsidy-inde- pendent DFI may fail to meet its goals in the long term if it drifts from its development mission. Of course, the SDI-like all performance mea- sures-indicates subsidy independence in the past and not in the future. Past performance is not a guarantee of future results. What Is Net Present Cost to Society? The NPCs answers the question: What benefits did society lose because it entrusted public funds to a DFI rather than to some other project? Like the SDI, the NPC5 uses the social opportunity cost. Unlike the SDI, the NPCs discounts flows. Discounting matters more and more as a time frame lengthens. The NPCs complements the SDI. To match the practice of the SDI, the NPCs adds financial flows from society to the DFI and subtracts financial flows from the DFI to society, so the NPCs is the negative of Net Present Value, a basic yardstick in finance and economics. INTRODUCTION 7 Box 1.3. Social Worthwhileness, Subsidy Independence, Private Profitability, and Self-Sustainability The four concepts of social worthwhileness, subsidy independence, private profitability, and self-sustainability are distinct (Schreiner 1997). A socially worthwhile DFI has social benefits that exceed costs in present-value terms. A subsidy-independent DFI could pay the social opportunity cost of public funds and still show a profit. A privately profitable DFI could pay the private opportunity cost of all funds and still show a profit. A self-sustainable DFI could meet its goals now and in the long term. Social worthwhileness matters because public support for DFIs aims to improve social welfare. Subsidy independence matters because, if cus- tomers benefit from a DFI and if there are no external social costs, then zero social cost implies social worthwhileness. Private profitability matters because if public funds are limited then DFIs will be few and small unless private investors use their own funds to buy DFIs or to start new ones from scratch. Finally, self-sustainability matters because society cares about improved welfare both now and in the future. Subsidy independence is necessary and sufficient for private profitabili- ty only if the social opportunity cost equals or exceeds the private oppor- tunity cost. Private profitability is needed, however, for self-sustainability. Privately profitable DFIs may also improve social welfare more than sub- sidy-dependent DFIs (Schreiner 1999a; Mosley and Hulme 1998; Chaves and Gonzalez-Vega 1996; Rosenberg 1996; Yaron 1994). Privately profitable DFIs may also attract private funds and thus produce more development finance at less cost to the public purse (Rosenberg 1994). While private profitability is needed for self-sustainability, it does not guarantee it. Self-sustainability also requires a host of other nonfinancial qualities such as organizational strength, efficient technology, a consistent structure of incentives to give stakeholders reasons to act in the interests of the mission of the DFI, and rules that build in flexibility to adjust through time (Schmidt 1997; Schreiner 1995). An investor-whether public or pri- vate-that contemplates the purchase of a DFI should check more than just past financial performance because future success depends greatly on intangible, nonfinancial assets. Both Net Present Value and the NPCS answer the same questions and are derived from standard benefit-cost theory (Gittinger 1982). The two measures have the same magnitude and opposite signs. If customers get more benefits than costs and if noncustomers do not bear any costs, then a DFI started from scratch that is equivalent to a DFI with a negative NPCS would be expected to be a good social investment. Likewise, a DFI with a negative NPCS seen from now on is a good social investment from now on. 8 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Wise use of the NPCS recognizes three facts. First, the NPCs is not just the sum of SDIs through a span of years. Second, a negative NPC5 as seen from now on does not necessarily imply a negative NPCS as seen from birth. Because past costs are sunk, public support for a DFI from now on may make sense even though it would not have made sense had future performance been known at the time of birth. Third, the NPCs ignores benefits and costs to noncustomers. If these benefits exceed these costs, then a DFI with a positive NPCS (or a positive SDI) could still be a good use of public funds. Is the Subsidy Dependence Index Redundant? Unlike the SDI, the NPCS discounts flows. Thus, the NPCS measures social cost better than the SDI, especially in long time frames or when the social rate of time preference is high. All else constant, society would be better off if it judged DFIs not only with the SDI but also with the NPCS, especially in long time frames. Still, the SDI is far from redundant for three reasons. First, the SDI is slightly easier to compute than the one- year case of the NPCS. Second, the extra accuracy caused by discounting in the one-year case of the NPCs may be dwarfed by the inaccuracies of the basic data and by the coarse assumptions used by both the SDI and the NPCS in the attempt to fit data based on GAAP accounting into a economic framework. Third and most important, many people already are familiar with ROE, so the SDI is useful in its guise as a Subsidy- Adjusted ROE. Because the NPCS discounts cash flows and the SDI does not, the two measures do not answer the same question. Society might ask about social cost (or the Subsidy-Adjusted ROE) of a DFI in a short time frame, and the answer is contained in the SDI. Society might also ask about social cost in long time frames, and the answer is the NPCs. Both ques- tions and answers matter, and both the SDI and the NPCS are the right tools for their own distinct purposes. Neither the SDI nor the NPCs answers all questions about the perfor- mance of a DFI. The two measures inform some questions, but they do not inform all questions, nor do they fully inform any single question. Like all financial ratios, the SDI and the NPCS do not tell directly why performance is good or bad, nor do they tell directly how to improve. Other quantitative indicators and qualitative analysis still have a role in the full assessment of the performance of public DFIs. In particular, fur- ther analysis and even full-blown benefit-cost analysis might be desirable in some circumstances despite its high cost. INTRODUCTION 9 What Does the Rest of the Monograph Cover? Chapter 1 discusses why DFIs exist and why society would want to mea- sure their performance. Chapter 2 presents the formula of the SDI in terms of the basic accounts of a set of financial statements for an example DFI. It also has numerical examples and discusses what the SDI means and shows how the measure of subsidy in the SDI can also be transformed into a Subsidy- Adjusted ROE. Chapter 3 derives the NPCS and gives numerical examples. It also shows that the one-year case of the NPCS is not the same as the SDI. Chapter 4 emphasizes that the SDI and the NPCs are only as good as their data and assumptions. It notes pitfalls in their calculation, especial- ly the need to adjust financial statements to reflect the repayment risk of outstanding loans and to purge the effects of inflation. Chapter 5 reviews three recent attempts to modify the SDI or to use other standards to judge the performance of public DFIs. It makes explicit the questions answered by these new proposals and argues that their use does not lead to a better understanding of the social cost of public DFIs. 1 Why Measure the Social Cost of Public Development Finance Institutions? The measurement of the social cost of public DFIs matters because pub- lic funds budgeted for development are scarce. The poor can use loans and deposits, but they can also use more and/or better food, water, air, health, clothes, houses, schools, roads, fuels, skills, tools, laws, markets, and/or safety. The SDI and the NPCS are two measures of social cost. Neither the SDI nor the NPCS is equivalent to social CBA, but both mea- sures are linked to self-sustainability and to social welfare. Oversight of public DFIs is needed because the people who work for governments and donors and who choose to support DFIs with public funds do not bear most of the costs and benefits of that choice. Instead, costs and benefits accrue to taxpayers (because they provide public funds), customers of the DFI (from the use of services), and noncustomers (from displacement by customers and from the loss of benefits from pro- jects left unfunded). Oversight is also needed because DFIs tempt gov- ernments and donors more than most development projects because they involve self-help not with gifts but with loans (Mosley and Hulme 1998). Measurement of the social cost of public DFIs aims to help to align pri- vate incentives with the public good. What Is a Public Development Finance Institution? A public DFI is a financial intermediary that aims to improve social wel- fare and that gets some resources from governments or donors. A public DFI may be owned by the state and thus receive public resources as equi- ty, but it may also have private owners (or no owners) and receive public resources as gifts or loans. Public funds entrusted to a DFI are subsidized because the unfettered market would charge more. If not, then the DFI would refuse public funds and go straight to the market on its own. By the same logic, a DFI subsidizes its clients. If services from a public DFI were costlier than identical services from the market, then clients would eschew the DFI. 10 WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIs? 11 Who Bears the Costs and Who Reaps the Benefits of Public Development Finance Institutions? Society-all the people in the world or all the people in a country-bears the cost of public DFIs. Subsidies to one person are taxes to another. Furthermore, funds spent on a DFI are funds not spent to improve wel- fare in some other way. The direct or primary benefits of a public DFI accrue to its clients. Although indirect or secondary costs and benefits to nonclients and to the employees of the DFI, governments, and donors may be large, they are also very difficult to measure, so this monograph ignores them. If there are no externalities, then there is no need to measure social costs and benefits when private people transfer their own funds to a DFI. It is safe to assume that private people look out for their own good and thus weigh benefits and costs as they see them. In contrast, there is a need to measure social costs and benefits when governments and donors transfer funds to DFIs. Public servants do not always look out for the public good (Stiglitz 1998; Tollison 1984). Analysis is warranted because the group that bears the costs is not the group that gets the benefits (Brent 1996). Worse, the choice to subsidize DFIs may be in the hands of the very same employees who stand to gain from the subsidies because more funds for DFIs maintain their jobs, foster promotion, and expand their influence. This group is small, organized, and vocal. Each member may have a lot to gain from channeling more subsidies to DFIs. Furthermore, the subsidies linked to loans from DFIs may attract rich people. If loans are big so that subsidies are big, then rich people may find it worthwhile to press for more public funds for DFIs. For exam- ple, rich farmers and their lobbies sought and received big subsidies from agricultural DFIs all over the world (Adams, Graham, and Von Pischke 1984). In contrast, the groups who bear the brunt of the costs of public DFIs are taxpayers and nonclients left unhelped by projects left unfunded. These groups are big, dispersed, and silent. The small cost to each mem- ber of the group means that it is not worth their effort to press for cuts in public support for DFIs. Because changes in personal welfare caused by public support for DFIs are not perfectly aligned with changes in social welfare, industry lobbies and employees of governments, donors, and DFIs may be tempt- ed to crusade for DFIs even if DFIs are not the best way to improve social welfare. Alternatively, policymakers may lack the tools or the data to check whether a DFI improves social welfare. The decision makers must be watched because they may get benefits without bearing the costs. The 12 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS measurement of costs can help to remind them of the worth of public funds in DFIs versus in alternative uses. How Do Public Development Finance Institutions Differ from Other Public Projects? Public DFIs resemble most other projects that get public funds. The peo- ple who bear the costs are not the same people who get the benefits, and there are small groups whose jobs and rents depend on more funds. DFIs also hold an uncommonly tempting promise of development potential because they work with financial capital, a factor often seen as a con- straint on development. DFIs transfer control over assets, and the poor are poor because they lack the assets that produce income (Sherraden 1991). DFIs are also politically correct. They do not give money away; rather, they lend it at interest. Few dare oppose helping others help them- selves. DFIs differ from other public development projects in their unusual susceptibility to abuse. The benefits of DFIs for clients are easy to see, but costs are often obscure. No one can argue with the worth of a loan that helps an orphan married at 12 and abandoned at 13 to buy land and to send her child to school (RESULTS International 1996). In contrast, even skilled financial analysts often overlook the opportunity costs of a public DFI or the erosion of the real value of its equity. Measures of cost can help decision makers to remember not only the faces of a few recipients but also the faceless millions who do not get projects because funds go to DFIs. The choice is not between a public DFI or nothing at all; rather, the choice is between a public DFI or some other project to improve welfare. DFIs are also susceptible to abuse because, on the surface, making loans requires only money. Compared with other development projects, DFIs are easy to start and to run because anyone with money-regardless of technical expertise-can make loans (Ladman and Tinnermeier 1981). DFIs may also attract-from a social point of view-too much donor funds because they can absorb and disburse funds fast. It can be easier to lend than to spend, especially if repayment is not a concern (Von Pischke 1991). Public support for DFIs may also offer politicians a convenient way to hide transfers of wealth (Ladman and Tinnermeier 1981). To sum up, the potential for the abuse of a DFI is high. Why Does Society Subsidize Public Development Finance Institutions? Society subsidizes DFIs to improve social welfare (Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek 1997). The social benefit is the extra utility of clients with the DFI WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIS? 13 versus without it. The social cost is the benefit lost because the DFI was funded instead of something else. In principle, a market failure is required for public DFIs to improve social welfare. A marketfailure is when competition fails to lead to a social- ly efficient outcome (Besley 1994). This happens when a movement from the status quo would improve social welfare, but no private entity can capture enough of the gains to recoup its costs. The market fails because the best private choice is not also the best social choice. In principle, someone could be made better off and no one would be worse off. In practice, market failures plague financial markets (Stiglitz 1993). But market failure, though needed to justify public intervention, is not enough. DFIs can be justified only if they mitigate a market failure so well that the benefits due to the intervention exceed the costs due to the inter- vention. Even in the absence of market failure, a public DFI might be the best way to reach a social goal, for example, if no other tool addresses an important social concern as efficiently (Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek 1997). DFIs venture where the market failed, and to find good borrowers shunned by private lenders is a difficult task. Through adjustments to the ways in which they judge and control risk, some DFIs have found prof- itable ways to make loans and to get repaid without traditional collater- al. Often, the most successful DFIs are those most concerned about the measurement of their costs. In the past, DFIs have often backfired, and they may even have hurt those they meant to help (Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek 1997; Hulme and Mosley 1996; Krahnen and Schmidt 1994; Adams, Graham, and Von Pischke 1984). "In practice, DFIs found it difficult to finance projects with high economic but low financial rates of return and to remain financially viable at the same time" (World Bank 1989, p. 106). Subsidies grew, strained budgets, and failed to strengthen the DFIs so that they could sur- vive without subsidies. For example, Mexico put more than $23 billion in 1992 dollars in agricultural DFIs from 1983 to 1992 before budget cuts forced a decrease (World Bank 1994). Of course, some DFIs are good and do mitigate market failures. But some other DFIs may waste scarce funds or exacerbate market failures. The theory is clear; if there is a market failure, then a DFI might have scope to improve social welfare. In practice, however, market failure alone is not enough to justify a DFI because DFIs themselves have costs and can disrupt markets. Government failure may wreck attempts to fix market failure, or a DFI might be inefficient. To choose well, society must measure costs, and perhaps also benefits (Devarajan, Squire, and Suthiwart-Narueput 1997). A DFI is only one of a number of possibly complementary ways to improve welfare through reduced poverty and increased incomes. 14 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS According to Lipton and Ravaillon (1995, p. 2630), "Chronic poverty does not appear to be due mainly to 'market failure' in credit or other markets, but rather to low factor productivity and low endowments-per-person of nonlabor factors." How Can Society Measure the Benefits of Public Development Finance Institutions? The benefits of DFIs are the extra welfare of clients with a DFI versus without. The comparison is not before-and-after but rather with-and- without. A before-and-after comparison does not control for the changes in welfare that would have happened regardless of access to the DFI (Gittinger 1982). The problem is to know what would have happened without the DFI, the standard counter-factual problem. This requires a control group: people who cannot choose to use the DFI but who are just like the people who can choose to use it in all ways. Getting a control group usually requires random assignment of access to a DFI (or random assignment of qualified applicants), but such social experiments consume large amounts of funds, time, and expertise and are still subject to poten- tially debilitating critiques (Heckman and Smith 1995). The only social experiment with random assignment ever in development finance tests the effects of access to Individual Development Accounts and is current- ly taking place in Tulsa, Oklahoma (Schreiner 2000a; Sherraden and oth- ers 2000). Without a control group, there is no inexpensive way to measure the impact of a DFI. For example, a dollar from a DFI is the same as a dollar from any other source. This fungibility of money means that, without a control group, the analyst cannot know if the loan caused an observed outcome or if the outcome would have happened anyway (Adams 1988; Adams and Von Pischke 1992; David and Meyer 1983; Von Pischke and Adams 1980). Once the difficulties caused by fungibility became clear and widely accepted, serious work to measure the benefits of DFIs went dormant. While fungibility does indeed wreck before-and-after comparisons, it does not affect with-and-without comparisons between randomly assigned treatment and control groups because random assignment con- trols for all other factors that might affect outcomes. While good mea- surements cost a lot and while wrong measurements could be worse than no measurements, it does not follow that no one should try to make good measurements. In the absence of random assignment, the measurement of the benefits of a DFI is similar to program evaluation with nonexperimental data. Econometricians have grappled with this problem for at least 30 years WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIs? 15 (Moffitt 1991). Their research has concluded that the analyst must control for the systematic differences-whether observed or unobserved- between clients and nonclients. Rigorous attempts to do this for DFIs include, among others, Montgomery, Johnson, and Faisal (2000); Amin, Rai, and Topa (1999); Coleman (1999); McKnelly and Dunford (1998); Morduch (1998); Mosley and Hulme (1998); Pitt and Khandker (1998); Smith and Jain (1998); Carter and Olinto (1996); McKeman (1996); Sial and Carter (1996); Lapar (1995); Bolnick and Nelson (1990); Feder and others (1990); and Carter (1989). Without random assignment, a good control group is hard to find. Among the people who have access to a DFI, the people who choose to use the DFI are not the same as the people who choose not to use the DFI; the users are more likely to do well regardless of the DFI, perhaps because they work more or accept higher risks. In contrast, the nonusers likely would not do so well regardless of the DFI. Thus, simple compar- isons of users to nonusers may overestimate the impact of the DFI. Although the measurement of benefits is improving all the time, cred- ible measures are still incomplete and require a long time, a lot of skill, and a big budget. Thus, it is too expensive to measure the benefits of all public DFIs (Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek 1997). Also, while a study may estimate the impact of a DFI on one outcome, it is much more difficult to estimate the impact of a DFI on all outcomes of interest. In contrast, it is less expensive to measure costs. In most cases, the measurement of costs but not benefits is a better use of resources than the measurement of both costs and benefits. This is the basic premise behind cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) (Garber and Phelps 1997; Weinstein and Stason 1977). Whereas CBA compares costs with expensive-to-measure benefits, CEA compares costs with inexpensive-to-measure outputs. Of course, CEA is not as useful as full-blown CBA. For example, CEA cannot rank projects that do not produce the same outputs for the same cus- tomers. Also, CEA cannot tell whether benefits exceed costs. Examples of CEA for development finance are Morduch (1999), Schreiner (1997), Binswanger and Khandker (1995), and Gale (1991). CEA is the essence of the measurement of the cost of public provision, suggested by Devarajan, Squire, and Suthiwart-Narueput (1997) as one of two keys for better pro- ject appraisal. Of course, the fact that the measurement of costs is less expensive than the measurement of benefits does not mean that only costs matter to the exclusion of benefits. It just means that in discussions of the social worth of DFIs, analysts will often be able to be more explicit about costs than about benefits. Choices about what public projects to fund ultimately must rely on informed judgments of both costs and benefits, even if knowledge of costs is better than knowledge of benefits. 16 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS What Is the Opportunity Cost to Society of Public Funds Used by Development Finance Institutions? The social cost of a public DFI is the return its public funds could get in their best other use. This return is called the opportunity cost, the efficiency price, or the shadow price. A dollar used on one thing cannot be used on something else. The most important parameter in the measurement of the social cost of public DFIs is the opportunity cost to society of public funds. The choice of an appropriate opportunity cost will often drive the main results of the analysis. This parameter is so expensive to measure that the analyst must choose a proxy or simply make an assumption. While there are no foolproof rules, this section provides some criteria and guidelines for the choice. Are Social and Private Opportunity Costs the Same? Social and private opportunity costs are not the same. For both society and for private entities, the opportunity cost is the return that funds could earn in a use of similar risk. But social and private opportunity costs may diverge for two reasons. First, public and private investors do not in general have the same opportunities, budgets, or constraints. For example, public funds earmarked for development must be spent on development projects. Private investors have no such constraint. Second, private and social costs and benefits may diverge due to mar- ket failures caused by externalities, public goods, transaction costs, prin- cipal-agent problems, and/or information asymmetries. Private investors count only their own costs and benefits. As a result, they may ignore some projects with low private returns but high social returns. In con- trast, public entities should count all costs and benefits to all people in society. Of course, the existence of market failure does not necessarily jus- tify public intervention (Besley 1994). In general, the social opportunity cost is at least as high as the private opportunity cost, because society accounts for benefits to all people while private people only account for their own benefits. Furthermore, if a pri- vate project has higher returns than a public one, then society can always invest in it as if it were a private owner (ennings 1993). Are Social or Private Opportunity Costs the Same as the Price Paid by a Development Finance Institutionfor Public Funds? Neither social nor private opportunity costs are necessarily equal to the price paid by a DFI for public funds. The prices of public funds are set WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIs? 17 most often not by market feedback but by administrative fiat. For exam- ple, one multi-lateral donor has made loans to DFIs with grace periods of 5 years, terms of 40 years, and interest rates of 1 percent. The price of this public debt did not depend on its social opportunity cost, on the expect- ed risk of the DFI, or on the rates and terms of a like loan in the market. Because the price of public funds does not reflect opportunity costs, mea- sures such as accounting profit and ROE do not reflect the performance of a public DFI from a social nor private point of view. Do Public Funds as Equity Have the Same Opportunity Cost as Public Funds as Debt? Public funds labeled as equity in a DFI do not necessarily have the same opportunity cost as public funds labeled as debt because equity does not have a fixed repayment obligation. In general, equity is riskier than debt, so the opportunity cost of equity exceeds that of debt. The appendix reviews a simple method developed by Benjamin (1994) to approximate the private opportunity costs of debt and equity. For society, debt and equity are the same for DFIs that are completely state-owned or that have explicit or implicit state guarantees for all of their debt. The examples here assume that the DFI is completely state- owned, although most microfinance DFIs are not state-owned and do not enjoy state guarantees on their debt. If a DFI can take deposits, then it might replace public debt with deposits instead of with private debt. In this case, the private opportuni- ty cost of public debt would be the interest rate paid on deposits plus a markup for the expected increases in the cost of administration and reserve requirements. Still, loans from banks would often replace public debt. In general, deposits will cost more and the DFI will be more likely to use debt rather than deposits as the DFI is newer and smaller, has less experience with deposits, is seen as risky by potential depositors, has more debt compared with equity, has more competition, and has more public funds to replace. Many DFIs-and certainly most microfinance DFIs-cannot replace public funds with private deposits because they are not licensed to take deposits. What Are Proxiesfor the Social Opportunity Cost of Public Funds? In practice, it is so expensive to measure the social opportunity cost of public funds that less-expensive proxies are used. In some cases, govern- ments or donors will have estimates of the return to some unfunded pro- ject. But because project analysis itself is costly and is subject to dimin- ishing returns, returns for all funded and unfunded projects will not be 18 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS known. Furthermore, in practice, some projects are funded for reasons other than their high net social benefits. If governments, donors, and their employees are risk averse, then safe but low-return projects may get funded before risky but high-return projects. With a budget constraint, the best projects should be chosen until funds run out. The goal of the choice of a social opportunity cost is to measure costs well so as to help to spend public funds better. The choice has four cri- teria. First, the number should be meaningful, that is, credibly close to the true opportunity cost. Second, all public-sector analyses should use the same opportunity cost because all public projects compete for pub- lic funds and because comparisons across projects require the use of a uniform opportunity cost. Third, higher rates are preferred to lower rates, all else constant. This protects society from those who would use low rates to give a false sense of rigor to support their pet projects. Fourth, the rate chosen must be credible. Disagreements about the social opportunity cost sidetrack project analyses more than any other issue. Figure 1.1 illustrates five possible proxies of the social opportunity cost. The horizontal axis is the amount of funds Q. The vertical axis is the nominal social opportunity cost m. As the amount Q increases, the mar- Figure 1.1. Five Possible Proxies of the Social Opportunity Cost Nominal social opp. cost, m arginal return on public project m Private opp. cost M|* 10 percent real = 0.1 + ic Deposit interest rate Inflation : Ma a cost of public fun s M4 Amount offunds,Q Q Amount of funds, Q WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIS? 19 ginal cost of public funds m increases, and the marginal return on pub- lic projects decreases. Except for the signs of their slopes, the curves are drawn arbitrarily and are assumed to include all factors that matter for social costs and benefits, for example, the monopoly of the govemment in the sale of riskless bonds due to its monopoly on the creation of legal tender. ZERO. Analyses that ignore opportunity costs implicitly assume a zero nominal social opportunity cost. With positive inflation, this implies a negative real social opportunity cost because real rates r are linked to inflation xt and to nominal rates R through r - (R - rt)/(1 + it). Negative opportunity costs are not credible because the net benefits of the mar- ginal project are positive. THE RATE OF INFLATION. A second possible proxy for the nominal social opportunity cost is inflation 7t. Given positive inflation, then the real social opportunity cost is zero. This is too low (Mishan 1988; Dasgupta and Pearce 1978), in part because it implies that benefits in the present are not preferred to benefits in the future. Some frameworks, however, do use inflation as the nominal social opportunity cost (Rosenberg, Christen, and Helms 1997; Holtmann and Mommartz 1996). THE RATE OF INTEREST ON DEPOSITS. A third possible proxy is the interest rate for treasury bills or, equivalently, the rate paid for time deposits by state-owned DFIs plus a markup for the expected cost of administration and reserve requirements, commonly assumed to be about two to three percentage points but adjustable to the specific case (Yaron 1992b). Most examples of the SDI use the deposit rate (e.g., Sacay, Randhawa, and Agabin 1996; Khandker, Khalily, and Khan 1995; Yaron 1994). This assumes that the social benefit of the marginal public project equals the marginal cost of funds to the state. If public funds were raised and spent to the point where marginal cost equals marginal benefit (Q', m' in figure 1.1) and if all other markets were perfectly competitive, frictionless, and without information or transac- tion costs, then the deposit interest rate would equal both social and pri- vate opportunity costs. In this equilibrium case, the social opportunity cost is also a market rate, hence the symbol m. In practice, all markets are not perfect. Instead, govemments and donors have limited budgets and more potentially high-retum projects than they can fund. In this disequilibrium, the cost of funds raised and spent at Q is not the same as the return on the marginal project m. The deposit rate is often less than the social opportunity cost. Thus, measures of subsidy that use the deposit rate are lower bounds (Yaron 1992b). 20 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS TEN PERCENT IN REAL TERMS. A fourth possible proxy for the social oppor- tunity cost is 10 percent per year in real terms. This somewhat arbitrary rate is used by most governments and by the World Bank as a uniform rule of thumb (Belli 1996a; Katz and Welch 1993; Gittinger 1982). Like all of the proxies described here, it may be adjusted for risk, although that is not the best way to analyze risk (Norgaard and Howarth 1992; Markandya and Pearce 1991). If the real rate is r, then the nominal rate is r + 7i + r . i. Thus, the nom- inal rate could be above or below the equilibrium rate m in figure 1.1. Usually, funds will run out before projects with returns above 10 percent. Although no one claims that 10 percent is particularly close to the true real rate of return on the marginal public investment, the rate has been favored in practice for at least three reasons. First, the true return on the marginal public investment is unknown, and guesses as to its value inevitably lead to endless debates. Second, compared with the known rates already discussed, 10 percent is a higher lower bound on the true marginal social return. Quirk and Terasawa (1991) find that the marginal return to public investment is probably much higher than 10 percent, and the estimates of Ballard, Shoven, and Whalley (1985) imply a minimum social opportunity cost of 17 percent. Third, 10 percent is the number most widely used. This not only defuses quibbles about its use, but it also allows cost comparisons across projects. This view treats opportunity costs less as marginal returns and more as tools to allocate scarce funds from a budget (Belli 1996a). Ten percent per year in real terms is a lower bound for the social opportunity cost. According to Belli (1996a, p. 148), "A discount rate lower than 10 percent might be difficult to justify." In particular, Gittinger (1982, p. 315) says that "financial rates of interest, such as government borrowing rates or the prime lending rate, are generally too low to justi- fy their use in economic [from the point of view of society] analysis of projects. Indeed, when inflation is high, these rates may even be negative in real terms." The burden of proof for another opportunity cost rests on the analyst (Gittinger 1982). The examples in this monograph use 10 per- cent because it is the highest credible lower bound and because it helps to make analyses comparable across projects and countries. THE OPPORTUNrrY COST OF FuNDs TO PRIVATE ENTMES. A fifth possible proxy for the social opportunity cost is the opportunity cost of private entities. This is the risk-adjusted price to replace public funds with simi- lar funds from private sources. For example, the private opportunity cost of equity is the return required to attract and to retain private investors in the long term. Likewise, the private opportunity cost of public debt is what a DFI would pay for similar debt from private lenders. Of course, WHY MEASURE THE SOCIAL COST OF PUBLIC DFIs? 21 private opportunity costs vary through time and among DFIs due to dif- ferences in risk, leverage, and the local cost of funds. The market price of funds in figure 1.1 is drawn below the marginal return on public projects because the state can always invest in private projects, should private projects have a higher return than public projects (Conrad 1984, 1986; Jennings 1993; Silvers and Kauer 1986). Why Does the Measurement of Costs Boost Performance? The measurement of costs sparks strong performance, casts light on bad performance, and helps to reward good stewards in five ways (Schreiner 1997). * Measurement forces DFIs and their sponsors to discuss their goals. Foggy goals wither under attempts at measurement. Buzzwords lose punch unless grounded in the nuts-and-bolts problems of measure- ment (IADB 1994). * Measurement changes goals. Those who measure costs worry about costs and vice versa (Von Pischke 1996). * Measurement highlights goals. A DFI that measures costs signals a willingness to reduce costs. Success is more than only disbursement. If donors measure only disbursements, then a DFI will learn to disburse at any cost (Von Pischke 1998). • Measurement helps to meet goals. Technical feedback helps managers detect trends, set targets, benchmark progress, and compare to peers (Richardson 1994; Koch 1992; Barltrop and McNaughton 1992). * Measurement proves what is possible for DFIs. Governments and donors want to demand better performance. But without measurement, they are pestered by the fear that they ask for too much too fast. Unsure donors expect less, and they get less (Schmidt and Zeitinger 1996). 2 What Is a Measure of the Social Cost of a Public Development Finance Institution in the Short Term? A measure of the social cost of a public DFI in the short term is the SDI (Yaron 1992b). The SDI is the dollar value of subsidy divided by revenue from interest and fees on loans. It answers the question: Howfar is the DFI from being able to compensate society for the opportunity cost of its funds and still show a profit? If a DFI could compensate for subsidy, then it is sub- sidy-independent. Its SDI would be less than zero, and its Subsidy- Adjusted ROE would exceed the social opportunity cost. The SDI measures the cost of a public DFI and compares it with its activity level. The SDI is a simple tool that shifts the paradigm from reported (accounting) costs to opportunity (economic) costs. Accounting profit and ROE often disguise the performance of public DFIs because some expenses do not reflect social opportunity costs. The SDI helps to measure progress toward "the phasing out of credit subsidies, the assumption by the fiscal budget of funding responsibility for any remaining subsidies, and the reduction and/or rationalization of directed credit lines" as required by "World Bank Policies Guiding Financial Sector Operations" (paragraph 17). The SDI can help link cur- rent public support to progress toward future independence from public support (Women's World Banking 1995). How Does a Development Finance Institution Get Subsidies? A DFI gets subsidies from subsidized funds. Subsidizedfunds are public funds. If a DFI accepts public funds, then it must be that they cost less than private funds. Subsidy is the social opportunity cost minus the price the DFI actually pays. By definition, only public funds can be subsidized, and private funds, regardless of their price, are not subsidized, unless a contribution is tax- exempt or unless the market price is affected by an explicit or implicit state 22 SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 23 guarantee of the liabilities of a DFI. The distinction is particularly impor- tant for microfinance DFIs that receive some private donations. Unlike public donors, private donors spend their own money. The fact that the owner of the funds agrees to entrust them to a DFI reveals that the benefits of the transaction exceed the costs, at least from the point of view of the pri- vate donor. For example, shares in a credit union held by members of their own free will are not subsidized even if the credit union never pays divi- dends or buys the shares back. The members choose to buy shares because they judge that the benefits of membership are worth it. Likewise, com- pensating balances that pay low rates are not subsidized. The lost earnings are part of the price borrowers accept when they choose to borrow. Even outright gifts are not subsidized, as long as they are private. The fact that private funds are not subsidized does not necessarily mean that the DFI is efficient, nor that it is privately profitable. It may still be useful to compute private costs and/or benefits with common measures such as ROE or EVA (box 1.2) that take the private point of view. But no public analysis is need- ed. Still, the measurement of social cost for DFIs with some public funds must be careful to exclude funds from private sources. What Forms of Subsidized Funds Does a Development Finance Institution Get? Subsidized funds come in six forms (table 2.1). Three forms are equity grants. Equity grants increase net worth directly but do not directly change accounting profit reported in the year received. The other three forms are profit grants. Profit grants increase accounting profit directly because they inflate revenues and/or deflate expenses. This increases net worth at year-end indirectly through retained earnings. Compared with the case without the grant, all six forms increase net worth one-for-one and have a social opportunity cost equal to m. As in Yaron (1992b), this monograph ignores dividends and taxes on profits in the interest of simplicity. Table 2.1. Types of Subsidized Funds Type of subsidizedfunds Notation Type of grant Direct grant DG Equity grant (EG) Paid-in capital PC Equity grant (EG) Revenue grant RG Profit grant (PG) Discount on public debt A . (m - c) Profit grant (PG) Discount on expenses DX Profit grant (PG) True profit TP Equity grant (EG) Source: Authors. 24 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Equity Grants The first two forms of subsidized funds are equity grants EG. These cash gifts increase net worth but do not change the accounting profit reported in a period directly. Equity grants are the sum of direct grants DG and paid-in capital PC: equity grants = direct grants + paid-in capital (2.1) EG = DG + PC. Direct grants DG are cash gifts. Direct grants increase net worth, but they do not pass through the income statement, and so they do not inflate accounting profit. Direct grants include both gifts in cash and gifts in kind such as computers or trucks. Paid-in capital PC comes from sales of shares to governments or donors. Such a sale is like a direct grant because public funds pay for the shares. Furthermore, most donors do not wield control like private own- ers. This monograph assumes that all paid-in capital comes from public sources. Profit Grants Profit grants are the third through fifth forms of subsidized funds (table 2.1). Like all equity grants, all forms of profit grants PG increase net worth because they inflate accounting profit or reduce accounting loss and thus increase retained earnings. Profit grants are the sum of revenue grants RG, discounts on public debt A. (m - c), and discounts on expenses DX: profit grants = revenue grants + discount on public debt + discount on expenses (2.2) PG = RG + A - (m - c) + DX. Profit grants distort accounting profit P and thus ROE because they depend not on business performance but on arbitrary choices by admin- istrators and accountants. Donors can use profit grants to nudge account- ing profit and ROE as high or as low as they like. In contrast to account- ing profit and ROE, the SDI and the NPCS recognize that a dollar treated as a profit grant has the same effect on business performance as a dollar treated as an equity grant (box 2.1; figure 2.1). Revenue grants RG are cash gifts. They are just like equity grants except for the accounting choice to record them as revenue instead of as direct injections to equity. Revenue grants increase net worth, but only SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 25 Box 2.1. How Profit Grants Affect Profit and Return on Equity Governments and donors can give a DFI a dollar through equity grants or profit grants. The choice affects nothing of substance because all grants increase equity one-for-one and have the same opportunity cost. Unlike equity grants, however, profit grants boost accounting profit and thus ROE. Profit grants are equity injections, but they enter the accounts as if they were operating revenue. Classifying a dollar as a profit grant instead of as an equity grant increases accounting profit but does not change business performance. For example, suppose a donor injects $100 in a DFI at a smooth pace through a year. The DFI starts with equity of $100. In the first case, the donor gives all $100 as equity grants and none as profit grants. Equity grants do not affect revenues or expenses, and the DFI posts an accounting loss of $50. End equity is the sum of start equity, equity grants, and profit, so average equity is (100 + 100 + 100 - 50)/2 = 125. ROE is -50/125 = -0.40. In this first case, ROE correctly states that the DFI destroyed 40 cents for each dollar of equity used (see figure 2.1). Now suppose all $100 shifts from equity grants to profit grants. Revenues increase and/or expenses decrease, so now profit is $50 even though business performance is unchanged. Average equity is still 125, but ROE is now 50/125 = 0.40. In this second case, ROE incorrectly states that the DFI created 40 cents for each dollar of equity used (see figure 2.1). Accounting profit and ROE depend on the arbi- Figure 2.1. Profit Grants and ROE trary choice to record subsi- dized funds as equity 4' grants or profit grants. These measures may hide / the true performance of a DFI because they depend ; 0 on the arbitrary form of subsidized funds. Many DFIs do not adhere to GAAP and thus may record -40 grants or reimbursements of expenses not as equity /o grants as profit grants injections but as revenue. The distinction matters for meaningful measures of financial performance. Other common financial ratios have the same weaknesses. In contrast, the SDI and the NPCS do not change as profit grants change. Christen (1997) also proposes an elegant approach that adjusts the financial state- ments themselves so that common ratios answer the questions they are meant to answer for public DFIs. 26 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS after they pass through the income statement and inflate accounting prof- it. Because revenue grants are not the product of the business operations of the DFI, they should not be in reported profit. Discounts on public debt A - (m - c) and discounts on expenses DX are the fourth and fifth forms of subsidized funds. They are noncash gifts, expenses paid on behalf of the DFI by someone else. Discounts increase the profit reported by the DFI because they decrease expenses. The discount on public debt A. (m - c) is the opportunity cost of pub- lic debt less what the DFI paid, where A is average public debt, c is the rate the DFI paid for public debt, and m is the social opportunity cost of public debt: discount public debt = average public debt - (opportunity cost public debt - rate paid) (2.3) =A. (m c). Like all discounts, discounts on public debt are subsidized funds that inflate profit and boost net worth because they cut expenses. Public debt is like private debt linked to a grant of A - (m - c) (IADB 1994). Unlike the discount on public debt, public debt itself does not increase net worth. The average rate paid on public debt c is the expense for interest paid on public debt, divided by the average public debt A: c _ expense for interest for public debt (2.4) average public debt The best way to estimate average public debt A is to track the dates and the amounts of each inflow and outflow and then to find the average daily balance. Usually, such detailed data are unavailable to external ana- lysts. A common practice is to estimate A as half the sum of the public debt at the start of the year Ao and at the end of the year A1, although quarterly or monthly averages would be more accurate: A = (Ao + A1)/2. (2.5) Discounts on expenses DX are costs absorbed by governments or donors that the DFI does not record as expenses. Classic examples are technical help, free deposit insurance, coverage of organization costs or feasibility studies, debt guarantees, fees for consultants, classes for loan officers, and travel for employees. Although discounts on expenses often leave no trace in the financial statements and are difficult to track, they are common and may represent large resource transfers (Schreiner 2000b). SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 27 True Profit True profit TP, the sixth form of subsidized funds (table 2.1), is like an equity grant. True profit is accounting profit P less profit grants (equa- tion 2.2): true profit = accounting profit - profit grants (2.6) TP=P-[RG+A. (m -c)+ DX]. All else constant, true profit is the change in retained earnings that would obtain in the absence of profit grants. Positive true profits are a social benefit because governments or donors could withdraw them from the DFI for use in other development projects. By the same logic, negative true profits (true losses) are social costs. Although easily confused, the concept of true profit is distinct from the concept of profit grants. Profit grants are cash gifts from government or donors recorded as revenue. Profit grants inflate accounting profit. True profit is accounting profit after the removal of profit grants and discounts on expenses. True profit is what accounting profit would be in the absence of distortions due to access to public funds. What Is the Formula of the Subsidy Dependence Index? Yaron (1992a) defines the SDI as subsidy S divided by revenue from loans LP * i, where LP is the average loan portfolio and i is the yield on loans: SDI subsidy revenue from lending (2.7) S LP . i The SDI is the percentage change in the yield on loans (or, equivalent- ly, in revenue from loans) that, all else constant, would make subsidy zero. For example, an SDI of 1.00 means that an increase in the yield of 100 per- cent would wipe out subsidy and make the SDI equal zero. An SDI of zero or less means the DFI could compensate society for its opportunity cost and still show a profit. It also means that the Subsidy-Adjusted ROE would exceed the social opportunity cost. What Is the Denominator of the Subsidy Dependence Index? The denominator of the SDI is revenue from loans. This is the product of the average loan portfolio outstanding LP and the yield on loans i: 28 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS revenue from loans = average loan portfolio * yield on loans (2.8) = LP i. The yield i is interest and fee revenue from loans, divided by the aver- age loan portfolio: interest and fees from loans (2.9) average loan portfolio What Is the Numerator of the Subsidy Dependence Index? Yaron (1992a) defines the numerator of the SDI as subsidy S: S=m E+A (m-c)+K-P (2.10) where S is subsidy, m is the social opportunity cost, E is average equity, A is average public debt, c is the rate paid for public debt, K is revenue grants and discounts on expenses, and P is accounting profit. Subsidy is the sum of the opportunity cost of the funds lodged in the net worth of a DFI and of the three types of profit grants, less the accounting profits the DFI could use to compensate for opportunity costs while still showing a profit. This monograph assumes that all net worth in average equity E comes from public sources. K is "the sum of all other annual subsidies received by the DFI (such as partial or complete coverage of the DFI's operational costs by the state) . . . [and] all other miscellaneous subsidies that a DFI might receive. These include subsidization of training costs, free use of govern- ment facilities and vehicles, free computer facilities, full or partial exemp- tion from the deposit reserve requirement, and full or partial guarantee by the state of loan repayment by subborrowers in default" (Yaron 1992b, pp. 6, 12). In other words, K is revenue grants plus discounts on expenses: K=RG+DX. (2.11) Clarity about K matters because if K does not include revenue grants, then the SDI will depend on the arbitrary form of subsidized funds. Worse, the SDI would underestimate subsidy. Two recent attempts to adjust the SDI (chapter 5) botch K. Given K (equation 2.11), the level of subsidy S (equation 2.10) is: S = m E +A (m-c) +RG + DX-P. (2.12) Given year-end financial statements and assuming that stocks grow and flows occur at a constant pace through the year, average stocks are SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 29 half the sum of the start and end stocks. The end stock of equity is the start stock plus the change in the stock: E = (Eo + Ej)/2 = (Eo + Eo + AE)/2 (2.13) = Eo + (1/2) AE. The change in equity AE is the sum of flows of the six forms of subsi- dized funds: AE = equity grants + profit grants (2.14) =DG+PC+RG+A -(m-c)+DX+ TP. We rewrite the formula for subsidy (equation 2.10) with the formula for true profits (equation 2.6), K (equation 2.11), average equity E (equa- tion 2.13), and the change in equity AE (equation 2.14): S =m E + A- (m - c) + K - P =m [Eo + (1/2) - (DG + PC + RG + A * (m - c) + DX + TP)] (2.15) + RG + A - (m - c) + DX - [TP + RG + A- (m - c) + DX] =m-Eo + (m/2) - [DG + PC + RG + A - (m - c) + DX + TP] - TP. This breaks the SDI into three terms. The first term, m EO, is the oppor- tunity cost of the subsidized funds that the DFI used through the whole year. The second term, (m/2). [DG + PC + RG + A . (m - c) + DX + TP], is the opportunity cost of the fresh subsidized funds that the DFI got in the course of the year. On average-or in the absence of knowledge of the times when flows of public funds were received-the DFI had the use of half the change in the stock of these new funds. The third term, TP, is the true profit that the DFI would record without subsidies, what the DFI could use to compensate society if it had no profit grants. Subsidy S is then equal to the unpaid social opportunity cost less profit generated from operations. The formula also shows that the SDI does not depend on the form of subsidized funds. Total subsidized funds from past years (in EO) have a marginal and average cost of m. Total fresh subsidized funds have an average cost of (m/2). Why Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Compare Subsidy to Revenuefrom Loans? The key of the SDI is the measurement of subsidy. The comparison of sub- sidy to revenue from loans is important, but secondary. Many things affect 30 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS subsidy, and subsidy could be compared with any item from the financial statements. Yaron (1994) focuses not only on revenue from loans but also on loan recuperation, deposit mobilization, and administrative costs. The choice to focus first on revenue from loans makes sense for four reasons. First, DFIs often set interest rates by decree or have rates set for them by governments or donors. Within a range, the DFI can often change them with a stroke of a pen. In theory, interest rate hikes can dampen demand and prompt loan losses (Morduch 2000; Stiglitz and Weiss 1981). In practice, few DFIs have doused demand or spawned a rash of default with higher interest rates because demand outstrips supply (Rosenberg 1996) (box 2.2; figures 2.2, 2.3). An efficient DFI does not gouge when it charges enough to cover its costs in the long term. lqbal (1986) found that interest rates mattered much less to small farm- ers than to big farmers. According to Singh, Squire, and Strauss (1986, p. 175): It follows that the elimination or reduction of subsidies to programs providing agricultural credit may serve the dual purpose of increas- ing efficiency in the capital market and simultaneously improving equity, since the reduction in borrowing by "large" farmers will exceed that by "small" ones. Second, if public funds will be cut in the long term, then the chances of survival increase as a DFI can cover more of the cost of private funds with revenues from loans. Third, revenue from loans is the biggest item in the income statement and usually exceeds all other operational sources of income combined. Most DFIs cannot reduce expenses or increase nonloan income enough to compensate for subsidies, so higher prices for loans may be the best option, at least in the short term. Fourth, the comparison of subsidy with revenue from loans places subsidy in the context of the size of the DFI. Measures of effective pro- tection or of domestic resource cost do the same thing (Tweeten 1992; Gittinger 1982). The comparison also allows the SDI to be seen as the matching grant society provides the DFI (subsidy in the numerator of the SDI) for each dollar of revenue from interest and fees earned from loans to clients in the target group (the denominator of the SDI). Could Subsidy Be Compared to Anything Else? Subsidy can be compared with anything in units of dollars per unit of time. Good candidates are average equity or average assets. Such com- SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 31 Box 2.2. Real Yields at Grameen and BancoSol Along with the unit-desa system of Bank Rakyat Indonesia, the most famous DFIs in the world are the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh (Hashemi 1997; Khandker 1996) and BancoSol of Bolivia (Gonzalez-Vega and others 1997; Mosley 1996). The real yield on loans at Grameen and BancoSol varied widely, but the loan portfolios grew consistently and default stayed low. Thus, there may be room to increase interest rates and/or fees in the pur- suit of subsidy independence. From 1984 to 1994, Grameen earned a nominal yield that varied from 12 to 19 percent (figure 2.2). Inflation varied from 1 to 22 percent, and the real yield varied from -1 to 14 percent. More than 99 percent of taka disbursed were recovered (Schreiner 1999b), and the loan portfolio grew from $9 mil- lion to $275 million. The portfolio grew and default was low despite big changes in the real yield. From 1987 to 1996, the nominal yield at BancoSol varied from 36 to 63 percent (figure 2.3). Inflation varied from 8 to 23 percent, and the real yield varied from 11 to 49 percent. More than 99 percent of dollars disbursed were recovered, and the loan portfolio grew from 0 to $47 million (Schreiner 1997). Again, huge swings in the real yield went side-by-side with huge portfolio growth and low default. Figure 2.2. Grameen: Figure 2.3. BancoSol: Inflation and Nominal Inflation and Nominal and Real Yields and Real Yields 0.22 -0.7- 0.122Nominal yield 0.6 Nominal yield 0.5 0.14 0.4- 0.10 - lation 0.06 Real ~~~~yield 0.3 Ra il 0.02 0.1 0.1 Inflation -0.02 84 8 8 '9 99 92 9394 0 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 Year Year Sources: Schreiner (1997); Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek (1997); Khandker, Khalily, and Khan (1995); Hashemi (1997); and IMF (various years). 32 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS parisons result in a Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity (SAROE) or a Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Assets (SAROA). If subsidy is less than zero, then the SAROE will exceed its hurdle rate, the social opportunity cost. A DFI might respond to the loss of subsidy or might decrease its sub- sidy dependence in many ways (Yaron 1992b). For example, it could slash administrative costs, dun borrowers more, grow the loan portfolio, or boost productivity. All these strategies require care and analysis. Also, the DFI is a price- taker in its investment portfolio, and so it cannot increase those revenues much without an increase in risk. Comparisons with the average loan portfolio LP require care because the DFI cannot increase LP with the same ease as interest rates. Rapid growth in loan volume seems more likely to provoke a rash of default than would a rapid price increase because rapid growth in the short term can only be achieved by accept- ing lower-quality clients. Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Prescribe Interest Rate Hikes? The SDI does not prescribe interest rate hikes; rather, the SDI describes social cost and how much yields would have to increase-all else con- stant-to eliminate subsidy. The SDI does not condemn subsidies nor public DFIs; after all, they may be the best way to improve social welfare. But society should pursue knowledge of the cost of DFIs to check whether they are good stewards of public funds. Governments and donors should not buy DFIs sight unseen nor measure their performance with inappropriate tools. Of course, they also need some estimate of benefits to check the social worth of DFIs. Numerical Examples of the Subsidy Dependence Index The following describes the financial results of an example DFI and then walks through the calculation of the SDI. The DFI was born on January 1 of Year 01, and the averages for Year 01 use the figures (all zero) for the end of Year 00. Description of Financial Results for Year 01 In the balance sheet of the first year of the example DFI (table 2.2), most assets (more than two-thirds) are loans (lines Ad and Ag), and invest- ments and fixed assets are modest. Cash is 20 percent of all assets. Half of all liabilities are public debt, and half are deposits and private debt (lines SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 33 Ah, Ai, and Aj). While governments or donors own some shares (line Al), most net worth comes from direct grants (line Am). The example DFI is highly subsidized. The first-year income statement (table 2.3) shows that the DFI paid 25 in interest for its liabilities (line Bg), spent 600 in operating costs (line Bj), and did not provide for loan losses (line Bi). Revenues from loans and investments were 420 + 5 = 425 (lines Ba, Bb, and Bc). Operating revenue less operating costs and financial costs produced an operating margin of 425 - (25 + 600) = -200 (line Bk). This would have been even more nega- tive in the absence of the discount on expenses of 100 (line Bn). As it was, this and a revenue grant of 400 (line BI) let the example DFI boast an accounting profit of 200 (line Bm). If gifts from discounts on expenses and revenue grants of 100 + 400 = 500 were called equity grants rather than profit grants, then accounting profits would be negative. Thus, measures that use accounting profit can obscure the true performance of a public DFI. The accounting treatment of a gift should not change measures of business performance. Rates of interest are ratios of revenues and expenses from the income statement to average stocks from the balance sheet. The yield on loans i for the example DFI in Year 01 is (420)/[(0 + 2,100)/2] = 0.40 (line Cv of table 2.4). This result uses the formula for the yield on loans (equation 2.9), the revenue from loans (line Ba in table 2.3), and the start and end stocks of the net loan portfolio (line Ad in table 2.2). The interest rate on public debt is (10)/[(0 + 400)/2] = 0.05. This uses the formula for c (equation 2.4), the interest expense on public debt (line Bf in table 2.3), and the start and end stocks of public debt (line Aj of table 2.2). With an assumed opportunity cost to society of public debt m of 10 percent per year in real terms (line Ck of table 2.4), the DFI would pay (0.10) - [(0 + 400)/2] = 20 for equivalent private debt. The discount on public debt is the social opportunity cost less what was actually paid, 20 - 10 = 10 (line Cl). The example DFI paid an interest rate on deposits of (5)/[(0 + 200)/2] = 0.05 (line He of table A.1). The interest rate paid on private debt was (10)/[(0 + 200)/2] = 0.10. The DFI also earned a yield on investments j of (5)/[(0 + 200)/2] = 0.05. What Is the Subsidy Dependence Index of the Example Development Finance Institutionfor Year 01? The SDI of the example DFI for Year 01 was 100 percent (line Cx of table 2.4). Table 2.4 uses the received formula for subsidy (equation 2.10), but the alternative formula (equation 2.15) gives the same result (line Dq of table 2.5). An SDI of 100 percent means that, all else constant, an Table 2.2. Balance Sheet Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Assets Aa Cash Data 600 700 800 Ab Loan portfolio (gross) Data 2,100 3,300 5,200 Ac Reserve for loan losses Data 0 0 0 Ad Loan portfolio (net), LP Ab + Ac 2,100 3,300 5,200 Ae Investments, I Data 200 400 600 Af Fixed assets (net) Data 100 200 200 Ag Total assets Aa + Ad +Ae + Af 3,000 4,600 6,800 Liabilities Ah Deposit liabilities Data 200 400 600 Ai Private debt Data 200 300 400 Aj Public debt, A Data 400 800 1,200 Ak Total liabilities Ah + Ai + Aj 800 1,500 2,200 Equity Al Paid-in capital, PC Data 300 645 910 Am Direct grants, DG Data 1,700 2,000 2,300 An Retained earnings Ant - 1 + Bm 200 455 1,390 Ao Total equity Al + Am + An 2,200 3,100 4,600 Ap Total equity and liabilities Ak +Ao 3,000 4,600 6,800 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Source: Example of authors. Table 2.3. Income Statement Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ba Revenue from loans, LP . i Data 420 1,080 1,700 Bb Revenue from investments, I j Data 5 15 25 Bc Total revenue operations Ba + Bb 425 1,095 1,725 Bd Exp. int. deposit liabilities Data 5 15 25 Be Exp. int. private debt Data 10 25 35 Bf Interest expense on public debt, A cData 10 30 50 Bg Total int. exp. Bd + Be + Bf 25 70 110 Bh Financial margin Bc - Bg 400 1,025 1,615 Bi Exp. prov. reserve for loan losses Data 0 0 0 Bj Exp. admin. Data 600 1,170 1,080 Bk Operating margin Bh - (Bi + Bj) (200) (145) 535 Bl Rev. grants, RG Data 400 400 400 Bm Accounting profit, P Bk + Bl 200 255 935 Memo item: Bn Discounts on expenses, DX Data 100 100 100 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Source: Example of authors. Table 2.4. Calculation of the Subsidy Dependence Index Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ca Start equity Alt -1 + Am, -l + An 0 2,200 3,100 Cb End equity Al + Am + An 2,200 3,100 4,600 Cc Average equity, E (Ca + Cb)/2 1,100 2,650 3,850 Cd Opportunity cost of society, m Data 0.10 0.10 0.10 Ce Subsidy on equity, E - m Cc Cd 110 265 385 Cf Start public debt Ajt 1 0 400 800 Cg End public debt Aj 400 800 1,200 Ch Average public debt, A (Cf + Cg)/2 200 600 1,000 Ci Exp. int. public debt, A c Bf 10 30 50 Cj Rate paid for public debt, c Ci/Ch 0.05 0.05 0.05 Ck Opportunity cost public debt, m Data 0.10 0.10 0.10 Cl Discount on public debt, A. (m - c) Ch (Ck - Cj) 10 30 50 Cm Revenue grants, RG Bl 400 400 400 Cn Discounts on expenses, DX Bn 100 100 100 Co Revenue grants and discounts on expenses, K Cm + Cn 500 500 500 Cp Accounting profit, P Bm 200 255 935 Cq Subsidy, S Ce + Cl + Co-Cp 420 540 0 Cr Start loan portfolio (net) Adt_1 0 2,100 3,300 Cs End loan portfolio (net) Ad 2,100 3,300 5,200 Ct Average loan portfolio (net), LP (Cr + Cs)/2 1,050 2,700 4,250 Cu Revenue from loans, LP. i Ba 420 1,080 1,700 Cv Yield on lending, i Cu/Ct 0.40 0.40 0.40 Cw Revenue from lending, LP. i Ct Cv 420 1,080 1,700 Cx Subsidy Dependence Index, S/(LP i) Cq/Cw 1.00 0.50 0.00 Cy Yield on lending, i Cv 0.40 0.40 0.40 Cz Change in yield Cy . Cx 0.40 0.20 0.00 Caa Subsidy-free yield Cy + Cz 0.80 0.60 0.40 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit. Source: Example of authors. Table 2.5. Alternative Calculation of the Subsidy Dependence Index Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Da Opportunity cost of society, m Cd 0.10 0.10 0.10 Db Start equity, Eo Ca 0 2,200 3,100 Dc EO m Da Db 0 220 310 Dd End direct grants Am 1,700 2,000 2,300 De Start direct grants Am, - 0 1,700 2,000 Df Change direct grants, DG Dd - De 1,700 300 300 Dg End paid-in capital Al 300 645 910 Dh Start paid-in capital Alt-1 0 300 645 Di Change paid-in capital, PC Dg - Dh 300 345 265 Dj Discount public debt, A. (m -c) Cl 10 30 50 Dk Rev. grants, RG Bl 400 400 400 Dl Discounts on expenses, DX Bn 100 100 100 Dm Accounting profit, P Bm 200 255 935 Dn True profit, TP Dm - (Dj + Dk + Dl) (310) (275) 385 Do Subsidy, S Dc + (Da/2) - (Df + Di + Dj + Dk-Dl + Dn) -Dn 420 540 0 Dp Rev. from loans, LP * i Ba 420 1,080 1,700 Dq Subsidy Dependence Index, S/(LP i) Do/Dp 1.00 0.50 0.00 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit. Source: Example of authors. SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 39 increase of 100 percent in the yield on loans would allow the DFI to show a profit and still compensate for the social opportunity cost of its funds. The subsidy on equity is 1,100 0.10 = 110 (line Ce of table 2.4). This is the product of an average equity E of [(0 + 0 + 0) + (300 + 1,700 + 200)]/2 = 1,100 (line Cc) and of a social opportunity cost of equity m of 10 percent (line Cd). The discount on public debt (line Cl) is [(0 + 400)/2] * (0.10 - 0.05) = 10. This is the product of average public debt A (line Ch) and of the opportu- nity cost to society of public debt m (line Ck) less the rate paid c (line Cj). The amount K (equation 2.11) is 400 + 100 = 500 (line Co). This is the sum of revenue grants RG (line Cm) and discounts on expenses DX (line Cn). Accounting profit P is 200 (line Cp). Finally, revenue from loans LP - i is [(0 + 2,100)/2] - 0.40 = 420 (line Cw). This is the product of the aver- age loan portfolio LP (line Ct) and the yield on loans i (line Cv). Thus, the SDI for Year 01 is (equation 2.7): S SDI01 = LPSt m . E + A - (m - c) + K-P LP . i 0.10 * 1,100 + 200. (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - 200 (2.16) 1,050 - 0.40 = (110 + 10 + 500 - 200)/420 = 420/420 = 1.00. What Does the Subsidy Dependence Indexfor Year 01 Mean? All else constant, the SDI for Year 01 of 100 percent means the DFI could compensate for the social opportunity cost of its funds and still show a profit if revenue from loans increased by 100 percent. If the size of the loan portfolio does not change, then this would mean doubling the yield. In general, Subsidy-free yield = actual yield- (1 + SDI) (2.17) = actual yield + implied change in yield. The SDI is a relative measure; it measures the implied change in the yield that would compensate for subsidies, relative to the actual yield. The actual yield varies from year to year and from DFI to DFI. Also, the nominal yield varies with inflation even if the real yield does not. Thus, good analysis will consider, in both real and nominal terms, the absolute level of subsidy S (a dollar amount), the ratio of subsidy to revenue from loans (the SDI, a percentage), the actual yield i (a percentage), the implied 40 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS change in the yield (a percentage), and the subsidy-free yield (a percent- age). In this example, the actual yield is 40 percent (line Cy in table 2.4). The subsidy-free yield is 0.40 + 0.40 * 1.00 = 0.80 (line Caa). The implied change is 0.80 - 0.40 = 0.40 (line Cz). Because inflation is assumed to be zero, the real yield equals the nominal yield. Does the Subsidy Dependence Index De end on How Average Equity Is DefinedT Like ROE, the SDI depends on how average equity is defined. Accountants do not agree on the best way to define average equity. All agree that average equity should include start equity Eo and fresh injec- tions to equity such as equity grants and paid-in capital in the year, weighted for the time of injection. Average equity should also include revenue grants RG, the discount on public debt A * (m - c), and the dis- count on expenses DX because these profit grants are equity grants in disguise. Opinion differs, however, whether average equity should also include true profit in the current year. When average equity excludes true profit in the current year, then the measure of subsidy in the SDI more closely resembles a present-value measure. For this reason, it is preferable to exclude true profit in the current year from measures of average equity. As in Yaron (1992a, 1992b), the formulae in this monograph include true profit TP in average equity (e.g., equation 2.15). This recognizes that owners could, in principle, withdraw true profit as it accrues. If they choose not to, then it is as if they withdrew true profit but injected it back as paid-in capital. If average equity includes true profit, then the measure does not depend on this arbitrary choice made by owners. Also, the use of average equity can be seen as a practical solution to imperfect data without knowledge of the timing of injections to equity, accrual of profit, and dividend pay-outs. The use of start equity would be more consistent with economic paradigms based on net present cost, but this approach would require more accurate data than are normally available to external analysts. The use of average equity rather than start equity is a compro- mise necessitated by the available data. Unfortunately, this definition of average equity is inconsistent with the way some other rates are measured. For example, suppose that a DFI has a constant balance through a year of 100 of debt and 100 of paid-in capi- tal. Suppose that in a year the DFI pays 10 in interest for the debt and that it accrues a true profit of 10. The common way to measure the rate of interest on the debt is as 10/ [(100 + 100)/2] = 0.10. At the same time, the rate of Return on Equity with true profit included in average equity is 10/[(100 + 100 + 10)/21 = 0.095. These two measures are inconsistent. SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 41 This can be reconciled in two ways. The first recognizes that the inter- est on the debt was paid throughout the year and not just at the end, so the DFI had to finance the interest with 10 of debt. Then the measure of the interest rate on debt is 10/ [(100 + 100 + 10)/2] = 0.095, the same as the common way to measure rates of Retum on Equity. The second way to reconcile the measures is to assume that owners measure their returns not on average funds used but rather on start funds invested. This is similar to the practice of measuring the effective annual interest rate on a loan as if its balance did not change in the course of a year. In this case, the measure of the rate of Return on Equity is 10/[(100 + 100)/2] = 0.10, the same as the common way to measure rates of inter- est on debt. The method used to measure average equity affects the SDI (Schreiner 1997; Yaron 1992b). The choice of method matters more as the absolute value of true profit grows relative to start equity (box 2.3). For the exam- ple DFI in Year 01, suppose that average equity does not include true profit. Thus, average equity does not change when the yield on loans doubles and when true profit increases by 420. The new SDI is: SDI'01 = 0.10 . 1,100 + 200 . (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 420) SDI'oi = 1,050 . [0.40 . (1 + 1.00)] 110 + 10 + 500 - 620 (2.18) 840 = 0/840 = 0. If the change in true profit does affect average equity, then the new SDI is: SDI"01 - 0.10. (1,100 + 200) + 200 (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 420) SDI"oi = 1,050 [0.40 (1 + 1.00)] 130 + 10 + 500 - 620 (2.19) 840 = 20/840- 0.02. What Are the Subsidy Dependence Indexes for Year 02 and Year 03? The example DFI cut its SDI in Years 02 and 03. It did not increase its yield on loans in Year 02; rather, it increased the average loan portfolio by 157 percent (line Ct of table 2.4) while administrative costs increased only 95 percent (line Bj of table 2.3). In short, the DFI got more efficient. Perhaps costs were high in the first year because the DFI was born with all it would ever need. It bought office space, hired a full complement of administrators, set up a computer system, and hired 42 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Box 2.3. The Subsidy Dependence Index and Average Equity at Bank Rakyat Indonesia The case of the unit-desa system of Bank Rakyat Indonesia illustrates the sensitivity of the SDI and ROE to the inclusion of current-year profit in the measure of average equity E (Charitonenko, Patten, and Yaron 1998). The stock of equity in the unit-desa system at the start of 1995 Eo was about 72 billion rupiah ($1 was worth about 2,200 rupiah). Accounting prof- its P in 1995 were about 393 billion rupiah. Thus, ROE computed in terms of start equity Eo was 393/72 -5.45, or about 545 percent. With profits in the year included in the measure of average equity, ROE was 393/[(72 + 393) /2] - 1.69, or about 169 percent. Thus, the inclusion of current-year profits in equity had a large effect on the estimate of ROE. To compute the SDI, note that the value of K-including discounts due to exemption from reserve requirements-was -43 billion. The unit-desa system used no subsidized debt, so the discount on public debt A * (m - c) was zero. The social opportunity cost m used in Charitonenko, Patten, and Yaron (1998) was 17.9 percent, and revenue from loans LP i was 861 billion rupiah. With the inclusion of current-year profits in average equity E, the SDI was: l[(E0 + El)/2] m + A * (m - c) + K - P)/LP i = ([(72+72+393)/2] - 0.179 + 0 + (-43)-393]/861 - -388/861 _-0.45. That is, the unit-desa system could have reduced the yield on loans by 45 percent (from about 32 percent to about 17 percent), compensated for the social opportunity cost of its public funds, and still shown a profit. This extremely high level of subsidy independence is one reason why Charitonenko, Patten, and Yaron (1997, p. 5) conclude that "no other suc- cessful, sustainable micro or rural finance institution shows the extent of outreach or the degree of financial self-sustainability that the BRI Unit Desa system has achieved." What if the measurement of average equity E excludes current profits? The SDI is then: ([(72 + 72)/2] * 0.179 + 0 + (-43) - 3931/861 - -423/861 - -0.49. Subsidy independence increases, although the change is only about four percentage points. Given the extremely high leverage of the unit-desa sys- tem (equity in 1995 was only 1.4 percent of assets) and its extremely high profitability (ROA in 1995 was 6.1 percent), the SDI does not seem very sen- sitive to the inclusion or exclusion of current-year profits in the measure- ment of average equity. SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 43 several loan officers. It took time for the loan officers to get up to speed with a full portfolio. In the meantime, costs per unit of output were high because the costs of the infrastructure were spread over a small portfolio. Discounts on expenses DX did not change (line Bn of table 2.3), and discounts on public debt tripled (line Cl of table 2.4). Average equity increased by 140 percent (line Cc of table 2.4). The SDI was cut in half: SDI02 = m E + A. (mr-c) + K-P SDI02 LP . 0.10 * 2,650 + 600 * (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - 255 (2.20) 2,700 0.40 = (265 + 30 + 500 - 255)/1,080 = 540/1,080 = 0.50. Subsidy S rose from 420 to 540, but the SDI fell (lines Cq and Cx of table 2.4). The subsidy-free yield was 0.40 * (1 + 0.50) = 0.60 (line Caa), and the implied change was 0.20 (line Cz). In the third year, the average portfolio grew by more than 50 percent (line Ct of table 2.4). Administrative expenses fell by about 8 percent (line Bj of table 2.3). Discounts on expenses DX did not change. Discounts on public debt grew by 20 (line Cl of table 2.4). The example DFI still got fresh flows of all six forms of subsidized funds, but increased profits drove the SDI to zero: SDIo3 = m . E + A. (m - c) + K - P SD03 LP . i 0.10 * 3,850 + 1,000 - (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - 935 (2.21) 4,250 - 0.40 (385 + 50 + 500 - 935)/1,700 0/1,700 = 0.00. Of course, similar examples could be presented in which the measure of equity E does not include profit in the current period. Is Subsidy in the Subsidy Dependence Index Related to a Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity? The measure of subsidy in the SDI is closely related to a Subsidy- Adjusted ROE. This is useful because ROE is the most common measure of the financial performance of a private firm. Most users of financial information know and understand ROE. ROE compares accounting prof- it (after tax) with average equity: 44 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS ROE = accounting profit (after tax) (2.22) average equity ROA resembles ROE except it compares accounting profit with aver- age assets: ROA = accounting profit (after tax) (2.23) average assets ROA is a useful tool for comparisons between peers in the same macroeconomic environments because it removes the effects of financial leverage. Barltrop and McNaughton (1992) and Mould (1987) explain the use of ROE, ROA, and other common financial ratios in the analysis of DFIs. ROE and ROA use accounting profits, and accounting profits depend on whether a gift is called an equity grant or a profit grant. A Subsidy- Adjusted ROE (SAROE) (or a Subsidy-Adjusted ROA [SAROA]) would replace accounting profit with true profit. An SAROE compares true prof- its with average equity: SAROE = true profit (2.24) average equity Likewise, an SAROA compares true profit with average assets. The SAROE and the SAROA are useful to compare public DFIs with peers (Christen 1997). Peer comparisons are the standard way to benchmark the performance of banks (Barltrop and McNaughton 1992; Koch 1992). The SDI and the SAROE are closely related. Yaron (1992b, p. 5) hints at this when he says that subsidy is less than zero when "the Return on Equity, net of any subsidy received, equals or exceeds the opportunity cost of funds." The SDI is negative if and only if the SAROE exceeds the social opportunity cost. The proof that a negative SDI implies an SAROE higher than the hur- dle rate-that is, the opportunity cost of funds-uses the alternative for- mula for subsidy (equation 2.15), the formula for the change in equity (equation 2.14), and the formula for average equity (equation 2.13): S = m Eo + (m/2) - [DG + PC + RG + A (m - c) + DX + TPI - TP = m * Eo + m .(1/2)- AE - TP (2.25) = m [Eo + (1/2) . AE] - TP = m E- TP. SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 45 This simple formula shows that subsidy S is the opportunity cost of the equity used in a year less what the DFI could have paid for that equi- ty and still shown a true profit. A negative SDI implies an SAROE above the social hurdle rate: S < O m . E - TPO 0 m ES TP (2.26) m S TP/E opportunity cost of capital S Subsidy-Adjusted ROE. A strength of the SDI is that it answers the same question as an SAROE. Figure 2.4 compares ROE and SAROE for the example DFI (table 2.6). In the three years, ROE goes from 0.18 to 0.10 to 0.24. ROE seems to show that performance improved in the second year and worsened in the third. In contrast, SAROE goes from -0.28 to -0.10 to 0.10, showing that improvement was constant. This shows that ROE is not a good measure of the financial performance of subsidized DFIs. By the third year (when the SDI was zero), the DFI could have compensated society for its oppor- tunity cost and still have shown a profit. ROA and SAROA follow the same pattern as ROE and SAROE (figure 2.5). If the measure of subsidy in the SDI and the SAROE gives the same answer for one question, then why use the SDI? After all, the process of adjusting the financial statements as required to compute the SAROE helps to ensure that all standard, widely understood financial ratios are meaningful. The SDI, however, is more than just the measure of subsidy in its numerator, and thus the SDI has at least three features that the SAROE does not. First, subsidy independence is zero with the SDI but m with the SAROE. Given human psychology, naive users may celebrate a positive SAROE even if it is still less than m. The chances that the SAROE is positive and yet less than m increase in low-income countries where inflation may be high and where real interest rates tend to be high due to the underdevelopment of the financial sector. Second, the SDI is a measure of the matching grant provided by society (the numerator) for each dollar of interest paid by the clients of a DFI (the denominator). For example, if the SDI of a DFI is 1.00, then the SDI contrasts the dollar pro- vided by society with the dollar provided by the client in a way that the SAROE does not. Thus, the SDI allows analysts to compare the matching grant provided to the target group through a DFI with matching grants (potential or actual) provided through other channels. Third, the SDI worsens if a DFI abandons its mission and puts resources in investments other than loans to the target group, all else constant, because revenue from loans LP . i in the denominator decreases. The SAROE, however, 46 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Figure 2.4. ROE versus Figure 2.5. ROA versus SAROE for the Example DFI SAROA for the Example DFI 0.3 - 0.3 ROE 0.2 ROE E 0.21 ROA 0. ROAA 0 OSAROE 0 -0.1 -0.1 SAROA -0.2- -0.2 -SAROA -0.3 .3 - 1 2 3 1 2 3 Year Year stays the same, and may even improve, if the other investments are more profitable than loans to the target group (box 2.4). How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as Its Parts Change? The SDI has many parts, among them the yield on loans i. Knowledge of how changes in these parts drive changes in the SDI may help to map concrete plans to reduce subsidy dependence. Of course, increased subsidy independence may not always be possi- ble or even preferred. For example, the DFI controls some parts of the SDI but not all. Still, knowledge of how social cost might be reduced is always useful to society. The figures that follow show how the SDI for Year 01 of the example DFI changes as one of its parts changes, all else constant. The figures show the direction of change better than the level of change. The level depends on the units and on the levels of the part being changed as well as the units and levels of all other parts of the SDI. How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as the Yield on Loans Changes? As the yield on loans i increases, the SDI decreases at a decreasing rate (figure 2.6). All else constant, an increase in i increases the denominator of the SDI because it increases revenue from loans. This decreases the Table 2.6. ROE, SAROE, ROA, and SAROA Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ea Accounting profit, P Bm 200 255 935 Eb Revenue grants, RG BI 400 400 400 Ec Discount on public debt, A (m - c) Cl 10 30 50 Ed Discounts on expenses, DX Bn 100 100 100 Ee True profit, TP Ea - (Eb + Ec + Ed) (310) (275) 385 Ef Start equity Aot 1 0 2,200 3,100 Eg End equity Ao 2,200 3,100 4,600 Eh Average equity, E (Ef + Eg)/2 1,100 2,650 3,850 Ei Start assets Agt_l1 0 3,000 4,600 Ej End assets Ag 3,000 4,600 6,800 Ek Average assets (Ei + Ej)/2 1,500 3,800 5,700 El ROA Ea/Ek 0.13 0.07 0.16 Em Subsidy-Adjusted ROA Ee/Ek (0.21) (0.07) 0.07 En ROE Ea/Eh 0.18 0.10 0.24 Eo Subsidy-Adjusted ROE Ee/Eh (0.28) (0.10) 0.10 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit. Source: Example of authors. 48 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Box 2.4. The Subsidy Dependence Index and Subsidy-Adjusted Return on Equity for an African DFI A large African DFI illustrates how the SDI improves when funds shift away from other investments to loans to the target group, all else constant, even though the SAROE stays unchanged. In 1998, the DFI had an average public debt A of 9.91, an opportunity cost m of 15.5 percent, and an actual rate paid c of 3.9 percent. Average equi- ty E was 1.5, and K was zero. Of the 9.91 + 1.5 = 11.41 resources in use at the DFI, 2.47 were in the average loan portfolio LP, and 8.94 were invested in treasury bills. The yield on loans i was 23 percent, so LP. i was 0.57. Finally, accounting profit P was -1.42. Thus, the SDI was [1.5 * 0.155 + 9.91 * (0.155 - 0.039) + 0 - (-1.42)1/0.57 - 2.8/0.57 = 492 percent. The SAROE was -2.8/1.5 --187 percent, far from the hurdle rate. With profit held constant, a shift of 1 unit from treasury bills to the loan portfolio would not affect the SAROE. The SDI, however, would improve from 492 percent to 2.8/ (3.47 - 0.23) - 350 percent. The SDI is more sensitive than the SAROE to the allocation of funds between loans to the target group and other investments. Source: Authors. SDI. The increase in i also increases true profit and so decreases subsidy in the numerator (as long as m < 200 percent). Thus, the effects of an increase in i in both the numerator and the denominator serve to decrease the SDI. How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as the Rate Paid on Public Debt Changes? If the measure of equity E in the SDI includes profits in the current period, then an increase in the rate paid on public debt c decreases the SDI (figure 2.7; equation 2.15). This happens because a higher rate paid for debt decreases the equity injected by the discount on public debt A * (m - c). In turn, this decreases the social cost of the public funds in the net worth of the DFI and so decreases the SDI. If the mea- sure of equity E does not include profit in the current period, then a change in c does not affect the SDI, because the decrease in the dis- count on public debt A * (m - c) is exactly balanced by an increase in accounting profit P. SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 49 Figure 2.6. The SDI and the Yield on Loans, i SDI 3.00 2.50 - 2.00 - 1.50 - 1.00 Base case 0.50 0.00- -0.50 - l l l l 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Yield on lending, i Figure 2.7. The SDI and the Rate Paid for Public Debt, c SDI 1.002 1.001 1.000 Base case 0.999 0.998 0.997 0.996 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 Rate paid on public debt, c How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as the Social Opportunity Cost Changes? The SDI increases as the social opportunity cost m increases (figure 2.8). This happens in two ways. First, the increase in m increases social cost through the discount on public debt A - (m - c) (because the spread 50 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS between m and c widens) and decreases the ability to compensate for social cost through true profit (due to the increase in A - m). Second, the increase in m increases the social cost of the public funds in the net worth of the DFI. This is often the bulk of the social cost of a DFI. Small changes in m can lead to big changes in the SDI (figure 2.8). This is one reason why the choice of m matters so much. At the same time, the fact that the SDI depends on m has no policy implication for a DFI. The opportunity cost of the public funds in the DFI depends on the perfor- mance not of the DFI but of the marginal public project. (Subsidy-and the SDI-can be positive even if m is zero because subsidy is the social opportunity cost of public funds used, less the ability to compensate for that cost out of true profits. If true profits are negative, then subsidy is positive even if the use of public funds has no opportunity cost.) How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as Administrative Expenses Change? Increases in administrative expenses decrease true profit and so increase the SDI (figure 2.9). In the first year of the example DFI, decreases in administrative expenses could make the subsidy zero. This is not always the case-social cost could be positive even if administra- tive costs are zero, for example, if social cost exceeds the level of admin- istrative costs. Figure 2.8. The SDI and the Social Opportunity Cost, m SDI 1.25 1.20 1.15 1.10 1.05 1.00 Base case 0.95 0.90 0.851 0.05 0.075 0.1 0.125 0.15 Social opportunity cost, m SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE SHORT TERM 51 Figure 2.9. The SDI and Administrative Expenses SDI 1.50 Base case/ 1.00 0.50 0.00 -0.50 0 300 600 900 Administrative expenses All else constant, the slope of the graph of figure 2.9 does not depend on the type of expense that changes. For example, the effect on the SDI of a $1 change in provision for loan losses is the same as the effect of a $1 change in administrative expenses. Provision for loan losses is discussed in chapter 4. How Does the Subsidy Dependence Index Change as Liabilities Shiftfrom Public Debt to Deposits? The SDI decreases as deposits replace public debt (figure 2.10). If d is the cost (both financial and administrative) of deposits, then a shift of one dollar from public debt to deposits affects subsidy S in three ways. First, the shift changes the discount on public debt injected in equity by -(m/2) - (m - c). Because m > c, the discount is negative and so decreas- es subsidy. Second, the shift changes the true profit injected in equity by (m/2) . (m - d). True profit increases by m because that is the opportuni- ty cost of a unit of public debt, but it decreases by d because that is the unit expense on deposits. Third, the switch changes the true profit avail- able to compensate for subsidies by (m - d). Because m > d, the change in true profit is positive. Because in most cases (m/2) < 1, the net effect of the increase in true profit on subsidy is negative. Because the effect on subsidy of the decrease in the discount on public debt is also negative, a shift of one dollar from public debt to deposits decreases subsidy and thus the SDI. 52 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Figure 2.10. The SDI and the Ratio of Deposits to Public Debt SDI 1.02 1.01\ \.01 Base case 1.00 0.99 0.98 0.97 0.00 0.33 0.67 1.00 Deposits/(public debt + deposits) 3 What Is a Measure of the Social Cost of a Public Development Finance Institution in the Long Term? The NPCS is a measure of the social cost of flows of resources between society and a public DFI in any time frame. Because the SDI does not dis- count, it does not properly measure social cost in long time frames. Just like private investors, society should look at the present value of projects in the long term. Even if society plans to own equity for only a short time, the present value of the equity at the end of the time frame depends on expected performance after that point. The NPCS complements short-term measures of social cost. Just like dams, DFIs should not be judged only by output in their tenth year but rather by discounted costs and benefits in their whole lifetimes. How Does the Net Present Cost to Society Discount Flows? What Is the Discount Rate? The NPCs discounts flows by when they take place in time. The discount rate is the price of gains and costs in the present in terms of gains and costs in the future. The social discount rate 6, for a flow one year past the start of the time frame is one divided by one plus the social opportunity cost in the first year, m1 (Gittinger 1982). This assumes that all flows take place at the end of the year. Often the analyst has year-end financial statements and assumes that flows and changes in stocks take place at a constant pace in the course of the year. In this case, flows are discounted as if they took place halfway through the year. For year t in time frames that last more than one year, the dis- count rate for a flow or a change in a stock would be: t-0.5 1 )1-0.5 t-l 1 53 54 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS The subscript t is a time index. Likewise, the superscript t - 0.5 is not an exponent but a label. The opportunity cost m may change through time. What Is the Formula of the Net Present Cost to Society? Outflows from society to a DFI are social costs, and inflows back to soci- ety from a DFI are social gains. As a cost measure, the NPC5 adds dis- counted outflows and subtracts discounted inflows. Like all discounted measures, the NPC5 ignores flows sunk before the start of the time frame. As presented here, the NPCS assumes all equity injections come from society, but this assumption can be relaxed (Schreiner 1997). The stock of equity at the start of the time frame E. is not a sunk flow. At time 0, society chooses to keep this net worth in a DFI rather than withdraw it for use elsewhere. Thus, society counts Eo as an out- flow: NPCS start net worth = 5 * Eo = Eo. (3.2) After the start of the time frame, the DFI builds net worth from fresh flows of funds FFt from grants, paid-in capital, and discounts. The dis- counted cost of these outflows from society to the DFI is: T t 0.5 NPC5 fresh flows of funds = X 8 * [DGt + PCt + RGt t=1 + At * (mt - c1) + DXtJ (3.3) T t -0.5 t=1 t True profit accrues through each year. Society could withdraw true profit as it accrues, but, in the absence of precise knowledge of the tim- ing of flows, it is assumed that society lets the DFI keep true profit. Hence, true profit is like an inflow back-to-back with an outflow, and the two flows cancel out of the NPCS. The treatment here ignores taxes and dividends, but Schreiner (1997) adjusts the framework to handle them. At the end of the time frame, it is assumed that society gets an inflow equal to the net worth then present in the DFI. Net worth at the end includes all outflows from society to the DFI up to time T plus true prof- it. The flow is discounted by Tr: SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIc DFI IN THE LONG TERM 55 T NPC5 end net worth = 6T ' {EO + I [DGt + PCt + RGt + At (mt - ct) + DXt + TPt]J (3.4) rT - [E + j (FFt + TPt)] t=l The NPCs adds the discounted outflows (equations 3.2 and 3.3) and subtracts the discounted inflows (equation 3.4): NPCS = discounted outflows - discounted inflows T T = E0 + I t * F1 -T [EO + t (FFt + TPd)] (3.5) 1=1 t1 T T T + X (8t 0.5 -T .F 8 =(1 -AT )* Eo + T -AT) *FF- * TPt. The NPCS of the flows of funds between society and a DFI from time 0 to time T has three terms. The first term is the cost of funds put in at the start. For society at time 0, start equity is worth Eo when entrusted to the DFI at time 0 but only 6 - Eo when it comes back at time T. The cost is the present value of funds when they are put in less their present value when they come back. The second term is the cost of fresh funds FFt injected after the start of the time frame. Seen from time 0, these funds are worth 8t - 0.5 when entrusted to the DFI but only 5r when the DFI gives them back. The cost is the difference. The third term is the cost (or the gain) of the true profit built up by the DFI. Society gets this inflow at the end of the time frame, so the discount factor is T . For most DFIs, the sum of true profit since birth is negative, and this decreases the inflow back to society. This means that-in real, nominal, and present-value terms-society gets back fewer dollars than it put in. Of course, the NPC5-like the SDI-cannot account for social benefits or costs not reflected in the financial statements of the DFI. What Questions Does the Net Present Cost to Society Inform? The NPC5 informs two important social questions that involve long time frames. In the first, the NPCS informs the question of whether it improves social welfare to use public funds to start a new DFI from scratch, ignor- ing all costs and benefits borne by members of the target group. In the 56 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS second, the NPC5 informs the question of whether it improves social wel- fare to maintain public support for a DFI from now on, again ignoring all costs and benefits borne by members of the target group. The NPC5 is negative if the worth of the inflows to society exceeds the worth of the outflows. Thus, the concept of net present cost mirrors the concept of present value. If a DFI imposes no costs on nonclients, then a negative NPC5 indicates that a DFI would be a good social investment because its return exceeds that of the marginal public project. This requires true profits so large that, even when discounted from the end of the time frame back to the start, they exceed the cost of the funds used by the DFI. Is There a Long-Term Analog to the Subsidy Dependence Index? A long-term SDI (SDIL) tells the percentage change in revenue from loans that would make the NPC5 zero (Schreiner 1997). To derive this, first write true profit TPt as revenue from loans LPt- it plus OROE1, all other revenues less other expenses: TPt = LPt* it + OROEt* (3.6) Now set the NPCS (equation 3.5) equal to zero and solve for the SDIL, the percentage change in revenue from loans that would make the NPCs zero: O ( ti ) o +tLl(6tO5 - t ) UF-T * 1 LPt *it *(1 + SDIL) + ORoEt] T T ( 0DIL = T T t r t = = t T t1 With data since birth, the SDIL tells how far a public DFI has been from subsidy independence since birth. With projected data from now on, the SDIL predicts how far a DFI is expected to be from subsidy independence. Is Subsidy in the Subsidy Dependence Index Just the One-Year Case of Net Present Cost to Society? If average equity includes true profit, then subsidy in the SDI (equation 2.15) is not just the one-year case of the NPCS (equation 3.5). If true prof- SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE LONG TERM 57 it is positive (negative), then subsidy in the SDI is less (more) than in the NPCS because the SDI does not discount the flow of true profit, implying less (more) subsidy (Schreiner 1997). The NPCS assumes that true profit comes at the end of the year, but the SDI assumes that true profit comes in the middle of the year. For example, suppose a DFI starts a year with equity of 100. It posts a true profit of 10 by the end of the year, and it gets no more fresh funds in the year. In a one-year time frame and with m set at 10 percent, the NPCS is 0 because true profit is just enough to compensate for the opportunity cost of public funds in net worth: T T NPC = (1-)Eo + X (6 - T ) FFt-TP t=1 t ~~~~~~t=1 1 = (1 - 81) *E0 + ( 1 - 81) * FF1 - 81 TP1 38 = (1 - 0.9091). 100 + (0.9535 - 0.9091) 0 - 0.9091 - 10 = 9.09 - 9.09 = 0 . The measure of subsidy in the framework of the SDI is 0.5: S =m . E + A . (m - c) + K - P =0.10 [(100 + 100 + 10)/2] + 0 + 0 - 10 (3.9) 10.5 - 10 = 0.5. If the measure of average equity excludes true profit, then the SDI does equal zero, because equity remains unchanged during the year. In this case, the SDI is the same as the one-year NPCs: S m . E + A . (m - c) + K - P, 0.10- [(100 + 100)/2] + 0 + 0 - 10 (3.10) 10 - 10 = 0. Is the Net Present Cost to Society Better Than the Subsidy Dependence Index? Both the SDI and the NPCS work well in short time frames. In practice, many people understand ROE, and the measure of subsidy in the SDI can be transformed into a Subsidy-Adjusted ROE. The SDI is useful if the user wants a quick, crude estimate, if the time frame is short, if inflation is low, and if the user understands ROE but not the NPCS. Both the SDI and the SDIL (which uses the NPCs) can be seen as measures of matching grants provided to members of a target group through a DFI. 58 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Unlike the SDI, the NPCS works in long time frames and is recognized as the best tool to judge projects (Brigham and Gapenski 1993). Choices may be sub-optimal investments if based on the SDI instead of on the NPC,, especially in long time frames and in particular when an SDI that indicates subsidy independence takes place only after years of SDIs that indicate subsidy dependence. What Are the Net Present Cost to Society and the Subsidy Dependence Index in the Long Term for the Example Development Finance Institution? For the example DFI, the NPC5 and SDIL for three time frames that start at birth (the start of Year 00) are in table 3.1. The first time frame ends at the end of Year 01, the second at the end of Year 02, and the third at the end of Year 03. Table 3.1 also shows the one-year NPCS and the SDI based on the one-year NPCs. Time Framefrom Birth to the End of Year 01 With the opportunity cost of public funds to society ml set at 10 percent, the discount rate S1 from the point of view of the birth of the DFI for a flow at the end of Year 01 is 1/(1 + 0.1) - 0.9091 (line Fc). The discount rate S1 -05 for flows in the middle of the year is [1/(1 + 0.1)]05- 0.9535 (line Fd). Start equity Eo for the example DFI is 0 (line Fo). Direct grants DG, were 1,700 and paid-in capital PC1 was 300. Revenue grants RG, were 400. The discount on public debt Al - (ml - cl) was 10. Discounts on expenses DX, were 100. Total fresh hmds FF, were 1,700 + 300 + 400 + 10 + 100 = 2,510 (line Fj). True profit TP, was -310 (ine Fn). The NPCS0-1 from the start to the end of Year 01 was: NPC°-= (1- 8) Eo+ (60 - ) . FF, - S TPi -(1 - 0.9091) * 0 + (0.9535 - 0.9091) * 2,510 - 0.909 - (-310) (3.11) -111.44 + 281.82 - 393.28. Subsidy in the SDI for Year 01 is 420 (line Cq of table 2.4). Because aver- age equity includes true profit and because true profit is negative (the most common case), the SDI is more than the NPCs. Revenue from loans LP1, i1 is 420. The SDI for the example DFI in Year 01 is 1.00 (line Cx of table 2.4), but the SDI( - 'is (line Fv of table 3.1): NPCO - 393.27 SDL-==- 1.03. (3.12) S1 - LP1 * il 0.9091 * 420 Table 3.1 Net Present Cost to Society Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 For one-year time frames Fa Disc. flow at end of year 1/(1+Cd) 0.9091 0.9091 0.9091 Fb Disc. flow middle of year [1/(1+Cd)]05 0.9535 0.9535 0.9535 For time frames that start at birth Fc Disc. flow at end of year Fct _ 1/ (1+Cd) 0.9091 0.8264 0.7513 Fd Disc. flow middle of year Fct _ I [1/(1 + Cd)105 0.9535 0.8668 0.7880 Fe Change direct grants, DG Df 1,700 300 300 Ff Change paid-in capital, PC Di 300 345 265 Fg Revenue grants, RG BI 400 400 400 Fh Discount public debt, A. (m - c) Cl 10 30 50 Fi Discounts on expenses, DX Bn 100 100 100 Ul Fj Fresh funds in year, FF Fe + Ff + Fg + Fh + Fi 2,510 1,175 1,115 Fk Accum. discounted fresh funds Fkt -1 + Fd . Fj 2,393 3,412 4,290 Fl Accum. fresh funds Flt 1 + Fj 2,510 3,685 4,800 Fm True profits, TP Dn (310) (275) 385 Fn Accum. true profit Fnt1 - + Fm (310) (585) (200) Fo Start equity at birth, Eo Aoo 0 0 0 Fp Start equity this year, Eo Ao° 1 0 2,200 3,100 Fq One-year NPCS (1 - Fa) Fp +Fj * (Fb - Fa) - Fm Fa 393 502 (19) Fr NPC5 from birth (1 - Fc) Fo + Fk - Fc . Fl - Fn Fc 393 850 834 Fs Revenue from lending, LP.i Ba 420 1,080 1,700 Ft Accum. rev. from lending Ftt -1 + Fs 420 1,500 3,200 Fu One-year SDI with NPCS Fq/(Fa. Fs) 1.03 0.51 (0.01) Fv Long-run SDI Fr/(Fc. Ft) 1.03 0.69 0.35 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Source: Example of authors. 60 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS The DFI could have been privately profitable with 103 percent more revenue from loans. With the size of the loan portfolio held constant and with the actual yield at 0.40, this implies a change in yield of 0.40- 1.03 0.41 and a subsidy-free yield of 0.40 + 0.41 = 0.81. Time Framefrom Birth to the End of Year 02 With m2 at 10 percent, the discount rate52 from birth to the end of Year 02 is [1/(1 + 0.1)12 0.8264 (line Fc of table 3.1). The discount rate 82 - 0.5 for flows in the middle of the year is [1/(1 + 0.1)1'5 - 0.8668 (line Fd). Direct grants DG2 are 300, paid-in capital PC2 is 345, revenue grants RG2 are 400, the discount on public debt A2 - (m2 - c2) is 30, and discounts on expenses DX2 are 100. Total fresh funds FF2 are 300 + 345 + 400 + 30 + 100 = 1,175 (line Fj). True profit TP2 was -275. Thus, the NPCO -2 for the first two years of the example DFI was: 2 T NPC°-2 = (1 - 62). * + (Et-+ _E+ 2 )* FF - 5 2 * TP = (1 - 0.8264) * 0 + (0.9535 - 0.8264) * 2,510 + (0.8668 - 0.8264) (3.13) - 1,175 - 0.8264 * (-310 - 275) - 319.02 + 47.47 + 483.44 = 849.93. Revenue from loans LP2* i2 is 1,080. The SDI°-2 is: NPCO°-2 849.93 DIO-2= - 224 0.69. (3.14) E I LPt* it 0.8264 .(420 + 1,080) t=l Time Frame from Birth to the End of Year 03 With m3 at 10 percent, the discount rate 833 from birth to the end of Year 03 is [1/(1 + 0.1)]3 - 0.7513 (line Fc of table 3.1). The discount rate d3 - 05 for constant flows is [1/(1 + 0.1)12.5 0.7880. Direct grants DG3 are 300, paid- in capital PC3 is 265, revenue grants RG3 are 400, the discount on public debt A3- (M3 - C3) is 50, and discounts on expenses DX3 are 100. Total fresh funds FF3 are 300 + 265 + 400 + 50 + 100 = 1,115. True profit TP3 is 385. The NPCO-3 is: SOCIAL COST OF A PUBLIC DFI IN THE LONG TERM 61 3 3 (t - .5 _8) F8 NPCO-3 = (1 - 63). Eo + ( -3 t- 3 1 TPt = (1 - 0.7513) . 0 + (0.9535 - 0.7513) . 2,510 + (0.8668 - 0.7513) * 1,175 + (0.7880 - 0.7513) (3.15) * 1,115 - 0.7513. (-310 - 275 + 385) - 507.52 + 135.71 + 40.92 + 150.26 = 834.41. Revenue from loans LP3. i3 is 1,700. The SDIO- 3 is: NPCO-3 834.41 SDIL-3= 3 - 0.35. (3.16) 63 LPt it 0.7513- (420 + 1,080 + 1,700) The example DFI had an actual yield i over the three-year time frame of 0.40. All else constant, an increase in the yield in each year of 0.40 . 0.35 = 0.14 would have led to subsidy independence. The subsidy-free yield for the lifetime of the DFI would be 0.40 + 0.14 = 0.54. If the yield on loans i had been 54 percent in all three years instead of 40 percent, then the NPCS for the three-year time frame would have been zero. The example DFI was subsidy-independent in Year 03 (SDI of 0.00) even though it was not subsidy-independent from birth through Year 03 (SDIL of 0.35). Thus, measurement of the social cost of public DFIs should include both the short-term SDI and the long-term SDI. The two mea- sures cannot be compared directly because the SDI uses undiscounted values and the SDIL uses discounted values. 4 What Are the Pitfalls When Calculating the Subsidy Dependence Index or Net Present Cost to Society? The use of the SDI and the NPC5 in practice presents two key challenges. The first is the need to pick a meaningful social opportunity cost. The second is the need to cope with the constraints of accounting data within an economic framework. What Is the Social Opportunity Cost? The social opportunity cost is defined as the return to public funds in the marginal public project. Because it is difficult to measure and a wide range of reasonably defensible estimates of social opportunity costs appear in the literature, chapter 1 discussed five proxies. Regardless of the proxy, the SDI and the NPCS are useful inasmuch as they show orders of magnitude and trends. When the proxy is lower than the true social opportunity cost, then the SDI and NPCS also are lower bounds on true social costs. Results in Schreiner (1997) suggest that long-term measures such as the SDIL are not very sensitive to the social opportunity cost because the vast bulk of cash flows take place long after the start of the time frame. Two other important points about social opportunity costs from chap- ter 1 are repeated here. First, the social opportunity cost is not necessari- ly the cost to the DFI of public funds. Second, the social opportunity cost is not necessarily the opportunity cost of a private entity, that is, the cost to replace public funds with private funds. It is not uncommon to confuse social and private opportunity costs. What Can Be Done to Cope with Accounting Data? The most important caveat for the SDI and NPC5 is that they use account- ing data that were not designed for economic (present-value) analysis. For example, accrued revenue in the income statement may never be col- lected. Even if the DFI eventually collects all accrued revenue or if it pro- 62 PITFALLS WHEN CALCULATING THE SDI OR THE NPCS 63 vides for all expected losses from unpaid accrued revenue, the financial statements still overstate the present value of accrued revenue. In gener- al, items in the balance sheet are not recorded in terms of their present values; for example, debt and fixed assets are recorded at their cost to the DFI. The income statement of the DFI often does not distinguish between cash items and accrued items, nor does it distinguish between flows at different times within a reported period. Of course, the SDI and the NPCS are limited by the data and assump- tions fed to them. As in all financial analysis, good outputs require good inputs. This is not a weakness of the measures described here but rather a standard caveat of all analysis, especially when accounting data are stretched to fit economic purposes. Like any disciplined attempt to measure performance, the SDI and the NPCS are like canaries in a coal mine that serve to unearth deviations from GAAP and International Accounting Standards. In this case, any financial indicator based on these weak data would probably be of low quality. Measurement helps to discover these weaknesses so that they can be addressed. By far the two most important problems with the accounting data of DFIs are the failure to provide properly for loan losses and the failure to adjust for inflation. Either failure can result in financial statements that do not accurately reflect financial performance. When failures are sub- stantial, any financial analysis is either meaningless or misleading. Why Should a Development Finance Institution Provide for Loan Losses? Financial statements should reflect business performance. The business of DFIs is to produce financial services such as deposits and loans, and, in general, defaults and loan losses are a normal part of doing business. A loan may not turn sour for a long time, but a DFI should record the expect- ed expense of the loss at disbursement. This conservatively reflects that some loans will go bad, even though, at disbursement, the DFI does not know which ones (Christen 1997). Ex post write-offs of bad loans under- state profit in the year of the write-offs and overstate profits in past years. Thus, a DFI should incur expenses for provision for loan losses con- stantly as it makes loans. These expenses build the reserve for loan loss- es, a contra-asset account. The net loan portfolio is the value of loans out- standing that the DFI expects to recover. It is the gross loan portfolio-which includes all loans outstanding, some of which will not be repaid-minus the reserve for loan losses. If the DFI does not provide enough for loan losses, then it deflates expenses and inflates profits and net worth. The reserve for loan losses is 64 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS too small, and the net portfolio is too big. Other authors discuss how to estimate the amount of provision for loan losses (Christen 1997; Von Pischke and others 1988; Bolnick 1988). Often DFIs do not provide enough for loan losses. This distorts all financial ratios, including the SDI and the NPCS. An important part of the business of a DFI is to make loans and to collect them, so any measure of performance must be based on financial statements that reflect the true risk of loans in the portfolio. The example DFI did not provide for loan losses at all (line Bi of table 2.3). Most DFIs, however, cannot recover all their loans. Suppose that in each of the three years the DFI made 100 in loans that later turned bad. Thus, in each year the DFI should have incurred expenses of 100 as pro- vision for loan losses. It is assumed that the DFI did not accrue revenue from interest. If it had, then the recognition of the bad loans would also require an adjustment to decrease accrued revenue from loans. In the adjusted balance sheet, the reserve for loan losses changes by -100 each year (line Jc of table 4.1). The net portfolio (line Jd) and total assets (line Jg) shrink in step. Retained earnings (line Jn) fall because accounting profit falls. The ripple effects of provision for loan losses are shaded in the adjust- ed income statement (table 4.2). The expense for loan-loss provisions increases from zero to 100 in each year (line Ki), and this changes the operating margin (line Kk) and accounting profit (line Km). Adequate provision for loan losses also changes the SDI. Without ade- quate provision, the SDI was 1.00, 0.50, and 0.00 (line Cx of table 2.4). With adequate provision, the SDI is 1.18, 0.52, and -0.01 (line Gb of table 4.3). These are small differences, but the effects of proper provisions would be much larger for many DFIs. Inadequate provision for loan losses leads to an inaccurate SDI and to inadequate financial ratios in general. Without provisions, ROE is 0.18, 0.10, and 0.24 (line En of table 2.6). With provisions, ROE falls to 0.10, 0.06, and 0.23 (line Ge of table 4.3). Provisions cause the SAROE to change from -0.28, -0.10, and 0.10 (line Eo of table 2.6) to -0.37, -0.13, and 0.11 (line Gf of table 4.3). ROA and SAROA follow the same pattern. Table 4.3 shows the SDI, the NPCS, and the SDIL with provisions for loan losses. Yaron (1992b) provides more discussion of provisions for loan losses. Why Should a Development Finance Institution Adjustfor the Effects of Inflation? Inflation wreaks havoc with financial statements prepared under the assumption that monetary figures keep a constant value (Goldschmidt, Shashua, and Hillman 1986). Adjustments help to ensure that the data Table 4.1. Balance Sheet with Loan Losses Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Assets Ja Cash Data 600 700 800 Jb Loan portfolio (gross) Data 2,100 3,300 5,200 Jc Reserve for loan losses Data (1(X) (100) (100) Jd Loan portfolio (net), LP I' + Jc 2,000 3,200 5,100 Je Investments, I Data 200 400 600 Jf Fixed assets (net) Data 100 200 200 Jg Total assets Ja + Jd + Je + Jf 2,900 4,500 6,700 Liabilities Jh Deposit liabilities Data 200 400 600 Ji Private debt Data 200 300 400 Jj Public debt, A Data 400 800 1,200 Jk Total liabilities Jh + Ji + Jj 800 1,500 2,200 Equity JI Paid-in capital, PC Data 300 645 910 Jm Direct grants, DG Data 1,700 2,000 2,300 Jn Retained earnings Jnt1 + Km 100 255 1,090 Jo Total equity Jl + Jm + Jn 2,100 2,900 4,300 jp Total equity and labilities Jk + Jo 2,900 4,400 6,500 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Source: Example of authors. Table 4.2. Income Statement with Loan Losses Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ka Revenue from loans, LP i Data 420 1,080 1,700 Kb Revenue investments, I j Data 5 15 25 Kc Total revenue from operations Ka + Kb 425 1,095 1,725 Kd Expenses int. deposit liabilities Data 5 15 25 Ke Expenses int. private debt Data 10 25 35 Kf Expenses int. public debt, A c Data 10 30 50 Kg Total int. exp. Kd + Ke + Kf 25 70 110 Kh Financial margin Kc - Kg 400 1,025 1,615 Ki Exp. admin. Data 600 1,170 1,080 Kl Revenue from grants, RG Data 400 400 400 t " ''(mit' 3',P A~zcowt". t';"0S00ing prof00N PM Kk , KI^O 100 155 835 Memo item: Kn Discounts on expenses, DX Data 100 100 100 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Source: Example of authors. Table 4.3. Summary with Loan Losses Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ga Subsidy, S Not shown 495 565 (25) Gb Subsidy Dependence Index, SDI Not shown 1.18 0.52 (0.01) Gc ROA Not shown 0.07 0.04 0.15 Gd Subsidy-Adjusted ROA Not shown (0.27) (0.09) 0.07 Ge ROE Not shown 0.10 0.06 0.23 Gf Subsidy-Adjusted ROE Not shown (0.37) (0.13) 0.11 Gg One-year NPC5 Not shown 465 527 (41) Gh NPCS from birth Not shown 465 944 910 Gi One-year SDI with NPCS Not shown 1.22 0.54 (0.03) Gj Long-run SDI Not shown 1.22 0.76 0.38 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit in current period. Source: Example of authors. 68 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS measure what they intend to measure. Just as with provisions for loan losses, the problem is with the meaningfulness of the data, not with the measures that use the data. IAS 29 suggests a few simple adjustments to use if the effects of infla- tion might affect the results of the analysis. The goal is a set of adjusted financial statements with the same meaning as unadjusted statements when prices are stable. Yaron (1992b) also discusses the need to adjust for inflation. Goldschmidt (1992) discusses IAS 29, and Goldschmidt and Yaron (1991) outline shortcut methods with numerical examples. Christen (1997) adjusts for inflation (and for the effects of subsidized funds) directly and elegantly in the financial statements of an example DFI. Once adjusted, common financial measures such as ROE are mean- ingful. The NPCS requires inflation-adjusted data unless inflation is zero for the whole time frame. Otherwise, monetary figures from different times are in different units and cannot be added together. Even if annual infla- tion is low, inflation adjustments are important in long time frames. If the SDI and NPCS are applied to inflation-adjusted figures, then opportunity costs should be in real terms because nominal rates with inflation-adjust- ed data would count costs twice (Yaron 1992b). The example DFI is assumed to be in an economy without inflation. What Are Other Pitfalls and Caveats? How Can Average Stocks Be Computed? Given only year-end balance sheets, average stocks are half the sum of the start and end stocks. This monograph uses this method, but such two- point averages can mislead if actual cash flows are seasonal, lumpy, or otherwise nonuniform. This is a data problem. Balance sheets are snapshots at a moment, and income statements sum revenues and expenses regardless of when they took place. A better average requires more frequent data from monthly or quarterly financial statements. Is Exemptionfrom Reserve Requirements a Subsidy? A deposit-taking DFI that is exempt from reserve requirements gets a subsidy (Benjamin 1994; Yaron 1992b). Reserve requirements are funds left on deposit with the central bank. They tax financial intermediation by reducing the return on deposits. Exemption from reserve requirements lowers the cost to the DFI not only of deposits but also of equity and liabilities. Let k be the reserve PITFALLS WHEN CALCULATING THE SDI OR THE NPCS 69 requirement, K the interest rate eamed on required reserves (often zero), and Dep the average deposit liability. The subsidy for a DFI exempt from reserve requirements is (Benjamin 1994; Yaron 1992b): S = m . E + A. (m - c) + RG + DX - P k. [E (m - a) + (A + Dep) (m - ic)] (4.1) 1 -k Without a reserve requirement, k is zero, and the last term vanishes. Suppose that the example DFI is exempt from a reserve requirement k of 20 percent and that required reserves earn no interest (K = 0). Subsidy in Year 01 is then: S = 0.1 * 1,100 + 200- (0.1 - 0.05) + 400 + 100 - 200 + 0.2 [1,100. (0.1 - 0) + (200 + 100) . (0.01 - 0)] (4.2) 1 - 0.2 = 110 + 10 + 300 + 0.2- (110 + 30)/0.8 = 420 + 35 = 455. The SDI without the adjustment for the exemption from reserve requirements is 420/420 = 1.00 (line Cx of table 2.4). With the exemption, the SDI is 455 /420 - 1.08. How Can Exemption from Taxes on Profits Be Handled? Most DFIs do not pay taxes on profits. This is a subsidy because a tax cut is like a cash gift. For simplicity, this monograph ignores taxes, but the frameworks of the SDI and the NPCs can be adjusted to handle taxes (Schreiner 1997). How Can Protection from Foreign Exchange Risk Be Handled? Some DFIs hold debt denominated in foreign currencies but do not bear the risk that the exchange rate will change before payment is due. If a public entity absorbs the risk, then there is a subsidy defined as the dif- ference in the payment with versus without protection, minus any pre- mium paid by the DFI for insurance for exchange rate risk. One way to compute this-analogous to the discount on public debt as A. (m - c)-is to assume that the DFI would replace foreign exchange with domestic currency (A) and then compute the subsidy per unit of foreign exchange as the price of equivalent domestic funds (m) minus the actual cost of for- eign exchange (c). 70 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS How Can Guarantees of Debt Be Handled? Some DFIs have private debt backed by public guarantees. This debt is subsidized because the DFI would have to pay more for an equivalent unguaranteed loan. The subsidy is determined by the difference between the interest rate with and without the guarantee. Benjamin (1994, see appendix) provides a framework to estimate the cost of debt in the absence of guarantees. How Can Nonfinancial Services Be Handled? DFIs often produce both financial and nonfinancial services (e.g., busi- ness training or agricultural extension). In most cases, each line of busi- ness should be analyzed by itself. Most of the work for the analyst is to divide the accounts, unless the DFI does it itself. Helms (1998), Christen (1997), and Yaron (1992b) discuss the issue and give example formats to help make the division. The fact that public funds are often earmarked for one line of business may help to simplify the division. How Can Apex Development Finance Institutions and Their First-Tier Customers Be Handled? Apex DFIs make loans to first-tier DFIs that then re-lend to final borrowers (Gonzalez-Vega 1998). Care is required to make sure that all subsidies in the chain are counted once and only once. There are three basic guidelines. First, although apex DFIs often charge the prime rate or some other "market" rate to DFIs, this rate is subsidized because it is still below the cost of funds from private sources. If public debt from the apex costs more than private debt, then the retail DFI would borrow on the market and skip the hassle of the apex DFI. The market price for a loan to a DFI is not the prime rate charged to blue-chip private firms but rather the price that covers all expected costs-including the cost of risk-of a loan to the DFI. Second, the analyst must not double-count costs by adding social cost as seen at the level of the apex to social cost as seen at the level of the first- tier DFI. To see why not, suppose an apex DFI lends two dollars, one to each of two first-tier DFIs, and that the first-tier DFIs get no other funds from anywhere else in the year. If both first-tier DFIs go broke in one year, then society loses two dollars. The sum of the social cost of two dollars for the apex and the social cost of two dollars for the first-tier DFIs is four dollars, and society cannot lose more than it had loaned in the first place. Third, it does not make sense to analyze only the apex or only the first- tier DFI. The whole system matters because the price charged by the apex PITFALLS WHEN CALCULATING THE SDI OR THE NPCS 71 is like an arbitrary transfer price between two subsidiaries with the same owner (society). The apex can set' its price high or low to shuffle the rev- enues and expenses-and the measure of social cost-between the two tiers. Because public funds are used in both tiers, pricing policy should not affect the measure of social cost. As an example, suppose an apex DFI has two identical first-tier cus- tomers, no debt, and 100 of paid-in capital from public sources through the year. The apex earns 6 per year on two loans of 50 to the first-tier DFIs at 6 percent interest. Because revenues are 6 and expenses are assumed to be zero, profit for the apex is 6. Given K = 0, m = 0.1, and A = 0, subsidy is 0.1 * 1(100 + 100 + 6)/2] + 0. (0.1 - 0) + 0 - 6 = 4.3 (equation 2.10). The SDI is 4.3/6 - 0.72 (equation 2.7). Now suppose that each of the first-tier DFIs has no expenses except for the 3 paid for their apex debt. Each first-tier DFI has 100 of paid-in capi- tal from public sources through the year. With 50 of debt and 100 of net worth, each DFI gets revenue of 1 by lending 150 at an interest rate of two-thirds percent. Each posts a net return of 1 - 3 = -2. Given that K = 0, m = 0.1, and A = 50, subsidy for each first-tier DFI is 0.1 * [(100 + 100 - 2)/2] + 50- (0.1 - 0.03) + 0 - (-2) = 9.9 + 3.5 + 2 = 15.4. The SDI is 15.4/1 = 15.4. The sum of the three measures of subsidy is 4.3 + 15.4 . 2 = 35.1. Because the revenue from loans to final borrowers is 2, the SDI for the system would be 35.1/2 = 17.55. But this subsidy is not the social cost of the system, nor is this SDI the change in revenue from loans needed to make social cost equal to zero. To see why, suppose that nothing changes except that the apex decreases its interest rate to 1 percent. Its profit falls to 1, and subsidy is 0.1 [(100 + 100 + 1)/2] + 0- (0.1 - 0) + 0 - 1 = 9.05. For the first-tier DFIs, profit increases to 1 - 0.5 = 0.5, and subsidy S is 0.1 * [(100 + 100 + 0.5)/2] + 50- (0.1 - 0.01) + 0 - 0.5 = 10.025 + 4.5 - 0.5 = 14.025. The sum of the three measures of subsidy has changed to 9.05 + 14.025 * 2 = 37.1, and the SDI is now 37.1/2 = 18.55. By now the problem is clear. In both cases, all the DFIs were owned by society, 150 * 2 = 300 was lent to final borrowers, and revenue from loans to final borrowers was 2. Nothing changed except the transfer price between the DFIs, yet the supposed measure of social cost changed from 35.1 to 37.1. The correct approach is to consolidate the financial statements of all DFIs in the system and then to compute subsidy. This removes the depen- dence on the transfer price (Stickney and Weil 1994). In this example, con- solidated net worth is 300, the sum of net worth in each DFI. The debt lia- bilities of the first-tier DFIs cancel with the loan assets of the apex. This leaves 300 in consolidated assets as loans to final borrowers. Expenses are 72 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS zero, revenues from loans are 2, and profit is 2 - 0 = 2. Subsidy is 0.1 - [(300 + 300 + 2)/2] + 0 . (0.1 - 0.01) + 0 - 2 = 28.1, and the system SDI is 28.1/2 = 14.05. How Can Compensating Balances Be Handled? Some loan contracts require borrowers to maintain a minimum deposit with the DFI until the loan is repaid. This decreases the effective loan portfolio LP. For example, a DFI with 100 in loans as assets and 10 in com- pensating balances as liabilities would have an effective loan portfolio not of 100 but of 90. Compensating balances are not subsidies because the (private) borrower accepts them as part of the price of the loan (IADB 1994). No public funds flow. All else constant, the smaller effective loan portfolio LP due to com- pensating balances does not affect the SDI nor the NPCs because it does not affect the revenues, expenses, or net worth of the DFI. It does, how- ever, increase the yield on loans and thus increase the subsidy-free yield; revenue from loans LP * i is unchanged, but the effective loan portfolio LP decreases, so the yield on loans i must increase. Suppose that all the deposit liabilities of the example DFI (line Ah in table 2.2) are compensating balances. The average loan portfolio LP decreases from (0 + 2,100)/2 = 1,050 (line Ct of table 2.4) to (0 + 2,100 - 200)/2 = 950. Revenue from loans stays at 420 (line Ba of table 2.3). The yield on loans i, however, increases from 420/1,050 = 0.40 to 420/950 - 0.4421 (equation 2.9). The SDI stays at 1.00 because neither LP nor i appear in it except through revenue from loans LP - i, unchanged at 950 . 0.4421 - 420. The increase in i, however, increases the subsidy-free yield from 0.80 (line Caa of table 2.4) to 0.44 (1 + 1.00) = 0.88 (equation 2.17). Does It Make Sense to Regress the Subsidy Dependence Index on Itemsfrom the Financial Statements? It does not make sense to regress the SDI against items from the financial statements. Regressions assume a stochastic relationship between depen- dent and independent variables, but the SDI has an exact, known relation- ship to all items in the financial statements. This requires not statistics but algebra. In contrast, it may make sense to regress the SDI on factors not in its formula. For example, Benjamin (1994) regressed the SDI on the age of a nonrandom sample of microfinance DFIs. He found that the SDI decreased with age. PITFALLS WHEN CALCULATING THE SDI OR THE NPCS 73 What Are the Key Caveats? The SDI and the NPCs are subject to six often-misunderstood caveats. * The SDI does not say that all DFIs should raise interest rates until sub- sidy is zero. * Neither the SDI nor the NPCS pretends to answer all questions asked about financial performance from all points of view. Standard financial analysis is still useful as long as it uses meaningful data. * Comprehensive analyses should consider not only the SDI itself but also the level of subsidy, the actual yield, the subsidy-free yield, and the absolute change in the yield that would make subsidy zero. * Neither the SDI nor the NPC5 pretends to measure benefits. * The SDI and the NPCS require the analyst to find meaningful data and opportunity costs and to use the results to suggest ways to improve performance. • The SDI measures subsidy dependence as seen by society, not private profitability as seen by a private entity The SDI and the NPCS are useful as measures of the social cost of DFIs and thus as part of the process that allots public funds. They are useful even in the absence of measures of benefits, although the existence of measures of cost should not be used to advocate for the irrelevance of benefits. An example is the issue of agricultural extension, often provid- ed free to clients by agricultural DFIs. It is expensive to measure the ben- efits of extension. In contrast, it is inexpensive to measure the costs. Once costs are known, the pursuit of efficiency and improved social welfare can focus on down-to-earth questions. Is there a new technology that needs extension to speed its spread? Could farmers pay for it? Should only rich farmers be asked to pay for it? Should fees be phased in? Would subcontractors cost less and provide better service than the employees of the DFI? 5 Recent Proposed Changes to the Subsidy Dependence Index The importance of the social cost of DFIs has prompted several attempts to refine the SDI or to use other standards to judge performance. This chapter presents critiques of three recent proposals. They fix what is not broken, or they tweak the SDI to answer unimportant questions. This chapter is based on Schreiner and Yaron (1999). The Subsidy Dependence Ratio of Khandker In several papers on DFIs in Bangladesh, Khandker proposes the Subsidy Dependence Ratio (SDR) as an alternative to the SDI (Khandker and Khalily 1996; Khandker, Khalily, and Khan 1995). Similar measures have also been proposed by Holtmann and Mommartz (1996), SEEP (1995), and the IADB (1994). These authors are concerned that the SDI compares subsidy only with revenue from loans even though DFIs also get revenue from investments in nonloan assets such as treasury bills. In principle, a DFI could decrease its subsidy dependence through increased revenues either from loans or from investments. The SDR compares subsidy with revenue both from loans and from investments. Fixing the fact that the SDR of Khandker, Khalily, and Khan omits K, if j is the yield on investments and if I is the average investment so I j is revenue from investments, then the SDR is: S SDR = - + I j (5.1) Both the SDR and the SDI have subsidy S in the numerator. Like the SDI, the SDR is negative if and only if an SAROE exceeds the social opportunity cost. Thus, the SDR and the SDI do not differ in their most important aspect, the measurement of subsidy. They differ only in what they compare with subsidy. 74 RECENT PROPOSED CHANGES TO THE SDI 75 What Question Does the Subsidy Dependence Ratio Answer? The SDR tells how much more revenue from loans and investments would be needed to reach subsidy independence. This is not a very use- ful question. While most DFIs have some degree of local monopoly and some freedom to set the price of their loans, DFIs are probably price tak- ers in the investment market. If a DFI could get a higher rate of return on investments without more risk, then presumably it would have already done so (IADB 1994). More importantly, the mission of a DFI is not to invest in nonloan assets but to make loans to members of a target group. In general, it is true that a DFI can decrease social cost via any increased revenue or decreased expense, so it is indeed useful to compare subsidy not only with revenue from loans but also with other revenue and expense items. But the biggest, most malleable item is revenue from loans, and lending is the main purpose of a DFI. DFIs do invest in order to maintain liquidity and to meet demand from clients for loans and withdrawals of deposits, but investment is not their main line of busi- ness. The numerator of both the SDR and the SDI is subsidy. The denomi- nator of the SDI is revenue from loans, while the denominator of the SDR is revenue from loans and from investments. Thus, the SDR is always less than or equal to the SDI. In almost all cases, the need to maintain liquid- ity means that investments are nonzero, and so the SDR makes a DFI look less subsidy-dependent than the SDI. If investments are large compared with loans-as is the case in some years for some of the DFIs studied by Khandker-then the SDR is much smaller than the SDI. This misleads because a DFI cannot increase the rate of return on its investments at will unless it also assumes more risk and because the purpose of DFIs is to make loans to the target group. (An SDR of 100 percent implies that a DFI could become subsidy-independent by doubling the yield on both loans and investments. Even if the DFI could double the yield on loans, how- ever, it could not double the yield on investments without incurring much more risk. Thus, the elimination of subsidy would imply more than a doubling of the yield on loans, suggesting that the SDR understates subsidy and overstates subsidy independence.) For example, the SDR gives an unfair assessment of Grameen Bank, the best-known DFI in the world (Yaron, Benjamin, and Piprek 1997, p. 146): [The SDRI results in an understatement of Grameen's dependence on subsidies, particularly during its initial years of operation, when a larger share of its financial resources was invested in the capital 76 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS market. The measure therefore also underestimates the subsequent progress Grameen made in reducing its dependence on subsidies as the share of funds invested in the capital market declined relative to the share of funds loaned to clients. Following [the logic of the SDR], a microfinance institution could appear increasingly inde- pendent of subsidies simply by reducing its loans outstanding. How Is the Subsidy Dependence Ratio Motivated? Khandker, Khalily, and Khan justify the SDR as follows (1995, p. 46): As part of a prudent risk-reducing policy, a financial institution may diversify its financial resources to maximize expected return and profit. This needs to be taken into account while calculating the SDI. Otherwise, even if everything else remains the same, a portfolio mix can yield a higher profit for a program that diversifies resources compared to a program that only lends, and consequently, [the] SDI differs by program. WNhile more loans may indeed mean more losses if the rush to make more loans leads to more default, the above claim is weak on two counts. First, the variance of the SDI across DFIs is not a weakness but a strength. A measure that did not vary would be useless. Second, the SDI does account for the diversification of assets because the measure of subsidy in the numerator includes profit and thus, by definition, all revenue from all sources, including investments. Khandker, Khalily, and Khan also offer a second motivation of the SDR (1995, p. 47): To the extent that a program always minimizes its income risk through portfolio diversification, the SDR appears more consistent than the SDI with such a practice, and consequently is subject to less variation over time and across programs. We disagree with this claim on two counts. First, few DFIs minimize income risk. Indeed, Khandker, Khalily, and Khan (1995) suggest that DFIs "maximize expected return and profit" (p. 46), which would require anything but to minimize risk. Second, variation in how funds are split between investment and lending over time and across programs has the same effect on the numerator of both the SDR and the SDI. The fact that the denominator of the SDR is always greater than or equal to the denom- inator of the SDI means that the SDR will be less than or equal to the SDI. RECENT PROPOSED CHANGES TO THE SDI 77 While this does indeed imply that the SDR has less variation than the SDI, the reduced sensitivity also means that the SDR dampens differences and so is less useful as a tool to assess performance. Finally, Khandker, Khalily, and Khan (1995) claim that the SDI pre- scribes higher yields on loans as the only way to reduce subsidy depen- dence. This is not true (Yaron 1992a, 1992b). Increased yields on loans may indeed often be the easiest, quickest, and most practical way to decrease subsidy dependence, but a DFI that pursues efficiency will also use economies of scale, high recuperation, decreases in operating costs, and increases in deposit mobilization. For the example DFI and for the sample of DFIs in Benjamin (1994), subsidy independence resulted not so much from increased interest rates as from improved efficiency with age and growth. What Is the Subsidy Dependence Ratio for the Example Development Finance Institution? The SDR has the same numerator as the SDI but a bigger denominator: SDR =m.E+A .(m-c)+K-P 01 LP. i+lj 0.10 - 1,100 + 200. (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - 200 (5.2) 1,050 . 0.40 + 100. 0.05 = 420/425 0.988. The SDI was 420/420 = 1.00 (line Cx of table 2.4), saying that the example DFI could be subsidy-independent if the yield on loans increased by 100 percent. In contrast, the SDR says that the example DFI could be subsidy-independent if the yields both on loans and on invest- ments increased by 99 percent. Most DFIs are price makers for their loans to their specific target groups and price takers for their investments. Thus, a DFI could probably increase the yield on loans but not the yield on investments. To see the weakness of the SDR, suppose that the example DFI got an extra direct grant DG of 1,000 at the start of Year 01 and invested it at a yield j of 5 percent. If the new direct grant does not increase expenses, then accounting profits grow by 1,000 .0.05 = 50. Average equity grows by 1,025, the 1,000 granted at the start of the year plus half of 50, the extra profit from the investment in the year. The DFI used more public funds but did not produce any more loans to the target group. The SDI reflects this downturn in performance because it increases by 0.13, from 1.00 to 1.13: 78 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS SD', m -E + A (m -c) +K -P LP i 0.10. (1,100 + 1,025) + 200 (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 50) (53) 1,050 0.40 = 472.5/420 -1.13. The SDR, in contrast, increases only 0.007, from 0.988 to 0.995: SDI~j = m E + A (m -c) + K -P LP i + I . j 0.10- (1,100 + 1,025) + 200 * (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 50) (54) 1,050 * 0.40 + (100 + 1,000) * 0.05 = 472.5/475 - 0.995. Social cost increased from 420 to 472.5, and the DFI produced the same loans to the target group. How did the performance of the DFI change? The SDI suggests that it worsened a lot. In contrast, the SDR suggests that it barely changed. If (m - j)/j < SDR, then investments of extra direct grants will decrease the SDR even though the SDI increases. In the example above, m = 0.10, j = 0.05, and investment of extra direct grants increased the SDR slightly because (0.10 - 0.05)/0.05 = 1 > SDR - 0.988. Usually, however, (m - j)/Ij < SDR. For example, if the return on investments j increased from 0.05 to 0.06, then (0.10 - 0.06)/0.06 - 0.667 < SDR - .988. Investment of extra direct grants still increases the SDI, from 1.00 to 1.10: ,, m-E+A-(m-c)+K-P SDI0l = LP * i 0.10- (1,100 + 1,030) + 200 . (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 60) (55) 1,050 . 0.40 = 463/420 -1.10. The SDR, however, decreases, from 0.988 to 0.953: SDI", m mE +A.(m-c) +K-P LP * i + I j 0.10 * (1,100 + 1,030) + 200 . (0.10 - 0.05) + 500 - (200 + 60) (5.6) 1,050. 0.40 + (100 + 1,000) . 0.06 = 463/486 -0.953. RECENT PROPOSED CHANGES TO THE SDI 79 Investment of extra public funds increased social cost from 420 to 463. The SDI increased to reflect this, but the SDR decreased, suggesting that subsidy dependence decreased even though more public resources were used to produce the same output for the target group. Hence, the SDR is not a useful measure of subsidy dependence. The Profitability Gap of Sacay Three concerns prompted Sacay (1996) to propose the Profitability Gap (PG) as an alternative to the SDI. First, Sacay wanted to compare subsidy with equity. Second, Sacay wanted to account for the subsi- dies implicit when a government allows a DFI to fall below minimum legal standards for capital adequacy. Third, Sacay said that the SDI assumes that subsidy can be decreased only by increases in the yield on loans. These concerns are unfounded (Belli 1996b). First, a function of the measure of subsidy in the SDI is already equivalent to an SAROE. Second, most DFIs meet legal capital requirements. For those DFIs that do not, the PG proposed by Sacay counts some subsidies twice. Third, the SDI does not claim that the only way to remove subsidy is to increase the yield on loans. What Question Does the Profitability Gap of Sacay Answer? The PG tells how far from a target SAROE is a DFI that gets subsidies from an exemption from legal capital standards, but this is not a very use- ful question. Given a target SAROE of m, the PG of Sacay is: P - A (m - c) - max (0, Emin E) (5.7) PG = m - ' (5.7)___ __ __ E + max (0, Emin - E) where E min is the minimum equity required by law and r 0 if 0Ž Emin - E max (0, Emin_E) = E) Emir - E if Ermm - E > 0. Sacay calls max (0, E min E) the capital deficiency. If capital exceeds the legal minimum, then the deficiency is zero. Otherwise, it is the minimum less actual equity. With no capital deficiency, Emin - E < 0 and so max (0, Emin - E) = 0. The PG is then: 80 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS PG =rn- P- A. (rn-c)-O0 PGno deficiency E m 0 E m+A*(m-c)-P (5.8) E The numerator of the PG with no capital deficiency, except for the lack of K, is the same as subsidy in the SDI. Without K, donors could force the PG as low as they like with profit grants. We adjust the PG to prevent this: G'E = m Er+A- (m-c)+K-P S PGno deficiency E E9) With no capital deficiency, the PG compares subsidy with equity rather than with revenue from loans. Like the SDI, the PG is negative if and only if a Subsidy-Adjusted ROE exceeds the opportunity cost m: PGO¢rn . F - TP TP E E For a capital-deficient DFI, the PG proposed by Sacay (with K added) is: PG' m - P - A . (m - c) - K - (Emin - E) deficiency Sacay E + (Emin - E) F + (Emm - ~~~~~(5.11) Emn-m + A.- (mn - c) + K - [P - (Emir - E) Emin The PG proposed by Sacay would adjust capital up to its legal mini- mum, taking the needed capital from profit and making it unavailable to compensate for subsidies. While it does make sense to charge an oppor- tunity cost m against the full minimum capital requirement Emin, it does not make sense to take Emin - E from profit P. This would impute a social cost of 1 + m for each dollar of capital deficiency, m for the use of the dol- lar for the year, and 1 because the dollar was used up. But the dollar was not used up, so the correct PG with capital deficiency should replace E with Emin but not take the difference from profit: PG ~Ernin.rn+A.(rn-c)+K-P (12) PG deficiency = K (5.12) Emim RECENT PROPOSED CHANGES TO THE SDI 81 None of the six example DFIs in Sacay (1996) had capital deficiencies. Whether the level of capital is adequate or deficient, the social opportu- nity cost of funds used by a DFI should be adjusted to reflect the risk due to its leverage (Benjamin 1994). Decreased Subsidy Dependence through an Increased Yield on Loans The SDI does not assume that an increased yield on loans is the only way to decrease subsidy dependence. Among a host of factors, the SDI depends on loan recuperation, deposit mobilization, and administrative costs. The classic statement of the SDI repeatedly insists that a DFI can decrease its subsidy dependence in many ways (Yaron 1992b, pp. 5, 7, 23). The Average Subsidy Dependence Index of Hulme and Mosley Two important works compute four-year averages of SDIs for 10 DFIs around the world (Mosley and Hulme 1998; Hulme and Mosley 1996, p. 44). The broad conclusions of these works depend on the average SDIs because they help to determine which DFIs are analyzed as ones with a focus on growth and sustainability. The average SDI of Hulme and Mosley has two problems. First, it can- not be interpreted as the percentage increase in revenue on loans that would make subsidy zero. Second, its formula in the one-year case does not seem meaningful. The Ratio of Averages and the Average of Ratios The ratio of averages is not the same as the average of ratios: ( 2a ) c +d) (5.13) c + d 2 2 The SDI is a ratio. Huhne and Mosley computed the average SDI as the average of ratios, the right-hand side of equation 5.13. But only the ratio of averages-the left-hand side of equation 5.13-keeps the meaning of the SDI as the percentage increase in lending that, all else constant, would make the sum of subsidy through the years zero. 82 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS For the first two years of the example DFI, the average SDI computed as the average of ratios (right-hand side of equation 5.13) is: a b~~~ S, s ~420 540 (+2 ) LPI. +i LP2 i2 420 1,080 = 0.75. (5.14) 2 2 2 A 75 percent increase in the yield on loans would increase profit in the first year by 0.75 * 420 = 315. Using start equity Eo and not average equi- ty E, this leaves a subsidy of 420 - 315 = 105. In the second year, profits would increase by 0.75 . 1,080 = 810. This leaves a subsidy of 540 - 810 = -270. The sum of subsidy in the two years is not zero but 105 - 270 = -165. In contrast, the ratio of averages (left-hand side of equation 5.13) is: a 2 b 240 4 (2Sb) 420 + 540 = 0.64. (5.15) (c + d) LP1 i1 + LP2 i2 420 + 1,080 \ 2 / A 64 percent increase in the yield on loans would increase profit in the first year by 0.64 * 420 = 268.8. Using start equity Eo and not average equi- ty E, this leaves a subsidy of 420 - 268.8 = 151.2. In the second year, prof- its would increase by 0.64 * 1,080 = 691.2. This leaves a subsidy of 540 - 691.2 = -151.2. The sum of subsidy in the two years is now zero. In any case, the SDI should not be averaged across years because it is meaningful only in short time frames. In long time frames, a full picture of subsidy dependence requires a measure that discounts flows by when they take place (Schreiner 1997). If, as in Hulme and Mosley, the SDI is averaged through a long time frame anyway, then the analyst should divide the sum of subsidy in all years by the sum of revenue from loans in all years. This would preserve the interpretation of the SDI. The Loan Portfolio LP as a Proxyfor Average Public Debt A Public debt A is a liability of a DFI, and the loan portfolio LP is an asset. In general, the two are not equal. In fact, they differ markedly when the DFI mobilizes savings or when the DFI has a high ratio of equity to assets. Hulme and Mosley (1996, p. 92), however, replace A with LP in their mea- sure of subsidy dependence. They also change the expression (m - c) in the discount on public debt to (c - m): RECENT PROPOSED CHANGES TO THE SDI 83 Subsidy in Hulme and Mosley = m E + LP- (c - m) + K - P. (5.16) LP i The formula in Hulme and Mosley (1996) follows neither the spirit nor the letter of the SDI. In private correspondence, Hulme and Mosley state that they deliberately replaced A with LP, but they do not say whether the switch of c and m (which makes the discount on public debt negative) is a typographical error. The replacement of A with LP does not make sense because the social opportunity cost applies to the public funds used by a DFI, not to the funds loaned to the target group. Otherwise, a DFI that did not lend would have less subsidy than one that did. In later work (1998, p. 789), Hulme and Mosley write out the standard SDI formula, although they do not elaborate on the shift in the tool used to measure subsidy in DFIs. Appendix A Framework to Approximate the Opportunity Costs of Private Entities This appendix presents a framework to approximate the opportunity costs of debt and equity for private entities. It is based on Benjamin (1994). What Is the Price of Private Debt? The price of private debt depends on what kind of debt it is. The two options are deposits and market debt. When Will Deposits Replace Public Debt? If a DFI takes deposits, it is assumed that deposits will replace public debt. The base cost is taken as the rate the DFI pays on deposits plus a mark-up of three percentage points (Benjamin 1994; Yaron 1992b). This assumes that a DFI could attract more deposits at the same rate it pays now. In practice, the assumed mark-up for administrative costs would be based on actual expected costs. The example DFI paid 5 percent on deposits (line He of table A.1). With the mark-up, private deposits would cost 8 percent (line Hg). When Will Market Debt Replace Public Debt? If a DFI does not take deposits, then it is assumed that private debt replaces public debt. The cost of private debt is taken as the local prime rate plus a premium for risk. Most DFIs are far riskier than blue-chip, prime-rate borrowers. In the example, the prime rate is 9 percent (line Hh of table A.1). In some cases, a DFI that lost public support might replace some equi- ty with private debt. But most DFIs are too weak to borrow on the mar- ket even with equity propped up by subsidized funds. Furthermore, lenders are unlikely to adjust interest rates more than a few percentage points to compensate for extra risk. Thus, most DFIs would not replace public equity with private debt. 84 Table A.1. Private Opportunity Costs Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ha Start deposit liabilities Aht 0 200 400 Hb End deposit liabilities Ah 200 400 600 Hc Average deposit liabilities, Dep (Ha + Hb)/2 100 300 500 Hd Exp. int. deposit liabilities Bd 5 15 25 He Rate paid deposit liabilities, d Hd/Hc 0.05 0.05 0.05 Hf Adj. for extra administrative costs Data 0.03 0.03 0.03 Hg Opportunity cost public debt for deposits, M He + Hf 0.08 0.08 0.08 Hh Prime rate Data 0.09 0.09 0.09 Hi Age of DFI in years Data 1 2 3 Hj Premium for age 2/100/Hi 0.02 0.010 0.007 Hk ROE En 0.18 0.10 0.24 HI Premium for profitability See text 0.00 0.01 0.00 Hm Opportunity cost, debt for debt, m Hh + Hj + Hl 0.11 0.11 0.10 Hn Start total liabilities Akt_1 0 800 1,500 Ho End total liabilities Ak 800 1,500 2,200 Hp Average total liabilities (Hn + Ho)/2 400 1,150 1,850 Hq Average equity, E Cc 1,100 2,650 3,850 Hr Leverage, L Hp/Hq 0.36 0.43 0.48 Hs Opportunity cost of equity, M Hm (1.1 + 0.1 Hr) 0.13 0.13 0.11 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit in current period. Source: Example of the authors based on Benjamin (1994). 86 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS How DOES EXPERIENCE AFFECT THE PRICE OF PRIvATE DEBT? Less-experienced DFIs pay more for private debt. Benjamin (1994) assumes that the experi- ence premium to be added to the prime rate is 2/100/n, where n is the age of the DFI in years. All else constant, young DFIs are riskier than old DFIs because lenders do not know them as well and because they are more like- ly to go bankrupt. The example DFI adds 0.02 in the first year, 0.01 in the second year, and about 0.007 in the third year (line Hj of table A.1). As with the mark-up for administrative costs to handle extra deposits, this crude assumption is meant to capture the spirit of risk premia for experience. In most cases, these numbers will provide a consistent base for comparison. In some cases, however, the analyst can pick risk premia matched to a specific DFI. How DOES PROFITABILITY AFFECT THE PRICE OF PRIVATE DEBT? Profitable DFIs pay less for private debt because they are less risky. Benjamin (1994) illustrates this with a rule: If the DFI has an ROE of less than zero, then add 0.03 to the prime rate. If ROE is more than zero but less than the prime rate, then add 0.02. If ROE is more than the prime rate but less than twice the prime rate, then add 0.01. Otherwise, add nothing. For the example DFI, the adjustment for profitability is zero in Years 01 and 03 (line Hl of table A.1). In Year 02, the adjustment is 0.01. The sum of the prime rate, the adjustment for profitability, and the adjustment for experience is m, the assumed private opportunity cost of public debt replaced with private debt. In the example, m is 11 percent in the first two years and 10 percent in the third year (line Hm of table A.1). What Is the Price of Private Equity? Equity costs more than debt because equity is riskier. Benjamin (1994) estimates the price of private equity M by adding a premium for risk to the price of private debt m. Leverage L is the ratio of liabilities to equity. As a DFI has more lever- age, owners demand a higher Return on Equity (Modigliani and Miller 1958). More debt with a constant amount of equity means more fixed obligations and thus a higher risk to equity if revenues fall short. A bank- rupt firm pays creditors before shareholders, so shareholders bear more risk as a DFI uses more debt. The example DFI does not have much lever- age, ranging from 0.36 to 0.48 (line Hr of table A.1). Based on historical data on leverage and ROE in the United States, Benjamin (1994) related M, the private opportunity cost of equity, to m, the private opportunity cost of public debt, and to L, leverage: M = m * (1.1 + 0.1 L). (A.1) APPENDIX 87 For example, a DFI without debt would need to pay 1.1 m to attract private capital. A DFI with a debt: equity ratio of 9: 1 would need to pay 2 . m to attract private capital. For the example DFI, M in its first three years is 13 percent, 13 percent, and 11 percent (line Hs of table A.1). This is about two percentage points higher than m. This framework provides general guidelines and does not substitute for the judgment and knowledge of the analyst. For most public DFIs, the risk of the loss of public support and the pure business risk of its untest- ed financial and organizational technology may swamp the risk due to its financial leverage. For the example DFI, table A.2 computes an SDI using the private opportunity cost. Thus, it measures costs not to society but to private investors. This private SDI is a measure of the increase in the yield on loans that, all else constant, would allow a DFI to show a profit and to compensate for the private opportunity cost of funds, assuming that all public funds were replaced by private funds. For society, the SDI was 1.00, 0.50, and 0.00 (line Cx of table 2.4). For a private entity, the SDI is 1.07, 0.57, and 0.02 (line Ix of table A.2). Table A.2. Subsidy Dependence Index with Private Opportunity Costs Line 12/31/01 12/31/02 12/31/03 Ia Start equity Alt 1 + Amt - 1 + Ant 1 0 2,200 3,100 lb End equity Al + Am + An 2,200 3,100 4,600 co Ic Average equity, E (la + lb)/2 1,100 2,650 3,850 Id Opportunity costs of private entities, M Hs 0.13 0.13 0.11 le Subsidy on equity, E - M Ic* Id 138 333 427 If Start public debt Ajt _ 1 0 400 800 Ig End public debt Aj 400 800 1,200 Ih Average public debt, A (If + Ig)/2 200 600 1,000 Ii Exp. int. public debt, A, c Bf 10 30 50 Ij Rate paid for public debt, c Ii/Ih 0.05 0.05 0.05 Ik Opportunity cost public debt, m Hm 0.11 0.11 0.10 Il Discount public debt, A (m - c) Ih * (lk - Ij) 12 36 47 Im Revenue grants, RG BI 400 400 400 In Discounts on expenses, DX Bn 100 100 100 lo K Im + In 500 500 500 Ip Accounting profit, P Bm 200 255 935 Iq Subsidy, S Ie + Il + Jo - Ip 450 614 39 Ir Start loan portfolio (net) Adt 1 0 2,100 3,300 Is End loan portfolio (net) Ad 2,100 3,300 5,200 It Average loan portfolio (net), LP (Ir + Is)/2 1,050 2,700 4,250 Iu Revenue from loans, LP . i Ba 420 1,080 1,700 Iv Yield on lending, i Iu/It 0.40 0.40 0.40 Iw Revenue from lending, LP . i It Iv 420 1,080 1,700 Ix Subsidy Dependence Index, SDI Iq/Iw 1.07 0.57 0.02 ly Yield on lending, i Iv 0.40 0.40 0.40 Iz Change in yield ly * Ix 0.43 0.23 0.01 Iaa Subsidy-free yield ly + Iz 0.83 0.63 0.41 Note: Monetary figures in constant units. Average equity includes profit in current period. Source: Example of authors. References Adams, Dale W. 1988. "The Conundrum of Successful Credit Projects in Floundering Rural Financial Markets." Economic Development and Cultural Change 36 (2): 355-68. Adams, Dale W, and J. D. Von Pischke. 1992. "Microenterprise Credit Programs: Deja Vu." World Development 20 (10): 1463-70. Adams, Dale W, Douglas H. Graham, and J. D. Von Pischke. 1984. Undermining Rural Development with Cheap Credit. Boulder, Colo.: Westview. Amin, Sajeda, Ashok S. Rai, and Giorgio Topa. 1999. "Does Microcredit Reach the Poor and Vulnerable? Evidence from Northern Bangladesh." Center for International Development Working Paper 28. Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass. Ballard, Charles, John Shoven, and John Whalley. 1985. "General Equilibrium Computations of the Marginal Welfare Cost of Taxes in the United States." American Economic Review 75 (1): 128-38. Barltrop, Chris J., and Diana McNaughton. 1992. Banking Institutions in Developing Markets. Vol. 2: Interpreting Financial Statements. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Belli, Pedro. 1996a. Handbook on Economic Analysis of Investment Operations. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. .1996b. "Measurement of Sustainability." Memorandum to Orlando Sacay, October 9, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Benjamin, McDonald P., Jr. 1994. "Credit Schemes for Microenterprises: Motivation, Design, and Viability." Ph.D. diss. Georgetown University, Washington, D.C. Besley, Timothy. 1994. "How Do Market Failures Justify Intervention in Rural Credit Markets?" World Bank Research Observer 9 (1): 27-47. 90 REFERENCES 91 Binswanger, Hans P., and Shahidur R. Khandker. 1995. "The Impact of Formal Finance on the Rural Economy of India." Journal of Development Studies 32 (2): 234-62. Bolnick, Bruce R. 1988. "Evaluating Loan Collection Performance: An Indonesian Example." World Development 16 (4): 501-10. Bolnick, Bruce R., and Eric R. Nelson. 1990. "Evaluating the Economic Impact of a Special Credit Programme: KIK/KMKP in Indonesia." Journal of Development Studies 26 (2) : 299-312. Brent, Robert J. 1996. Applied Cost-Benefit Analysis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Brigham, Eugene F., and Louis C. Gapenski. 1993. Intermediate Financial Management. Fort Worth: Dryden. Buckley, Graeme. 1997. "Microfinance in Africa: Is It Either the Problem or the Solution?" World Development 25 (7): 1081-93. Carter, Michael R. 1989. "The Impact of Credit on Peasant Productivity and Differentiation in Nicaragua." Journal of Development Economics 31: 13-36. Carter, Michael R., and Pedro Olinto. 1996. "Getting Institutions Right for Whom? The Wealth-Differentiated Impact of Property Rights Reform on Investment and Income in Rural Paraguay." University of Wisconsin-Madison. Processed. Chaves, Rodrigo A., and Claudio Gonzalez-Vega. 1996. "The Design of Successful Rural Financial Intermediaries: Evidence from Indonesia." World Development 24 (1): 65-78. Christen, Robert Peck. 1997. Banking Services for the Poor: Managing for Financial Success: An Expanded and Revised Guidebook for Development Finance Institutions. Boston: Acci6n International. Christen, Robert Peck, Elisabeth Rhyne, Robert C. Vogel, and Cressida McKean. 1995. "Maximizing the Outreach of Microenterprise Finance: An Analysis of Successful Microfinance Programs." Program and Operations Assessment Report 10. United States Agency for International Development, Washington, D.C. Coleman, Brett E. 1999. "The Impact of Group Lending in Northeast Thailand." Journal of Development Economics 60: 105-41. 92 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Conrad, Douglas A. 1984. "Returns on Equity to Not-for-Profit Hospitals: Theory and Implementation." Health Services Research 19 (1): 42-63. . 1986. "Returns on Equity for Not-for-Profit Hospitals: A Commentary and Elaboration." Health Services Research 21 (1): 17-20. Dasgupta, Ajit K., and D. W. Pearce. 1978. Cost-Benefit Analysis: The Theory and Practice. London: Macmillan. David, Cristina C., and Richard L. Meyer. 1983. "Measuring the Farm Level Impact of Agricultural Loans." In J. D. Von Pischke, Dale W Adams, and Gordon Donald, eds., Rural Financial Markets in Developing Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Devarajan, Shantayanan, Lyn Squire, and Sethaput Suthiwart-Narueput. 1997. "Beyond Rate of Return: Reorienting Project Appraisal." World Bank Research Observer 12 (1): 35-46. The Economist. 1997. "Valuing Companies: a Star to Sail By?" August 1 53-55. Feder, Gershon, Laurence J. Lau, Justin Y. Lin, and Xiapeng Luo. 1990. "The Relationship between Credit and Productivity in Chinese Agriculture: A Microeconomic Model of Disequilibrium." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72 (5): 1152-57. Gale, William G. 1991. "Economic Effects of Federal Credit Programs." American Economic Review 81 (1): 33-52. Garber, Alan M., and Charles E. Phelps. 1997. "Economic Foundations of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis." Journal of Health Economics 16: 1-31. Gittinger, J. Price. 1982. Economic Analysis of Agricultural Projects. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Goldschmidt, Yaaqov. 1992. "International Accounting Standard 29: Formulation and Clarification of Income Measurement in Hyperinflationary Economies." International Journal of Accounting 27: 137-50. Goldschmidt, Yaaqov, and Jacob Yaron. 1991. "Inflation Adjustment of Financial Statements: Application of International Accounting Standard 29." Working Paper 670. World Bank, Washington, D.C. REFERENCES 93 Goldschmidt, Yaaqov, Leon Shashua, and Jimmye S. Hillman. 1986. The Impact of Inflation on Financial Activity in Business with Applications to the U.S. Farming Sector. Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield. Gonzalez-Vega, Claudio. 1998. "Microfinance Apex Mechanisms: Concepts, Synthesis of Lessons, and Recommendations." Report to the Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest. Ohio State University, Columbus. Gonzalez-Vega, Claudio, Mark Schreiner, Richard L. Meyer, Jorge Rodriguez-Meza, and Sergio Navajas. 1997. "BancoSol: The Challenge of Growth for Microfinance Organizations." In Hartmut Schneider, ed., Microfinancefor the Poor? Paris: OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). Hashemi, Syed M. 1997. "Building up Capacity for Banking with the Poor: The Grameen Bank of Bangladesh." In Hartmut Schneider, ed., Microfinancefor the Poor? Paris: OECD. Heckman, James J., and Jeffrey A. Smith. 1995. "Assessing the Case for Social Experiments." Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (2) : 85-110. Helms, Brigit S. 1997. "Anatomy of a Micro-Finance Deal: The New Approach to Investing in Micro-Finance Institutions." Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest Focus Note 9. World Bank, Washington, D.C. _ 1998. "Cost Allocation for Multi-Service Microfinance Institutions." Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest Occasional Paper 2. World Bank, Washington, D.C. Holtmann, Martin, and Rochus Mommartz. 1996. Technical Guide for Analyzing the Efficiency of Credit-Granting Non-Government Organizations (NGOs). Saarbrucken: Breitenbach. Hossain, Mahabub. 1988. "Credit for Alleviation of Rural Poverty: The Grameen Bank in Bangladesh." Research Report 65. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C. Hulme, David, and Paul Mosley. 1996. Finance Against Poverty, Vols. I and II. London: Routledge. IADB (Inter-American Development Bank). 1994. Technical Guide for the Analysis of Microenterprise Finance Institutions. Washington, D.C. 94 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS IMF (International Monetary Fund). Various years. International Financial Statistics. Washington, D.C. Iqbal, Farrukh. 1986. "The Demand and Supply of Funds among Agricultural Households in India." In Inderjit Singh, Lyn Squire, and John Strauss, eds., Agricultural Household Models. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Jennings, Edward H. 1993. "Financial Management in Not-for-Profit Businesses." In Eugene F. Brigham and Louis C. Gapenski, eds., Intermediate Financial Management. Fort Worth: Dryden. Katz, David A., and H. Gilbert Welch. 1993. "Discounting in Cost- Effectiveness Analysis of Healthcare Programmes." PharmacoEconomics 3 (4): 276-285. Khandker, Shahidur R. 1996. "Grameen Bank: Impact, Costs, and Program Sustainability." Asian Development Review 14 (1): 97-130. Khandker, Shahidur R., and Baqui Khalily. 1996. "The Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee's Credit Programs: Performance and Sustainability." World Bank Discussion Paper 324. Washington, D.C. Khandker, Shahidur R., Baqui Khalily, and Zahed Khan. 1995. "Grameen Bank: Performance and Sustainability." World Bank Discussion Paper 306. Washington, D.C. Khandker, Shahidur R., Zahed Khan, and Baqui Khalily. 1995. "Sustainability of a Government Targeted Credit Program: Evidence from Bangladesh." World Bank Discussion Paper 316. Washington, D.C. Koch, Timothy W. 1992. Bank Management. Fort Worth: Dryden. Krahnen, Jan Pieter, and Reinhard H. Schmidt. 1994. Development Finance as Institution Building. Boulder, Colo.: Westview. Ladman, Jerry R., and Ronald L. Tinnermeier. 1981. "The Political Economy of Agricultural Credit: The Case of Bolivia." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62: 66-72. Lapar, Ma. Lucila A., Douglas H. Graham, Richard L. Meyer, and David S. Kraybill. 1995. "Selectivity Bias in Estimating the Effect of Credit on REFERENCES 95 Output: The Case of Rural Nonfarm Enterprises in the Philippines." Economics and Sociology Occasional Paper 2231. Ohio State University, Columbus. Lipton, Michael, and Martin Ravallion. 1995. "Poverty and Policy." In Jere Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics. Vol. IIIB. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Markandya, Anil, and David W. Pearce. 1991. "Development, the Environment, and, the Social Rate of Discount." World Bank Research Observer 6 (2): 137-52. McKeman, Signe-Mary. 1996. "The Impact of Micro-Credit Programs on Self-Employment Profits: Do Non-Credit Program Aspects Matter? Essays on Micro-Credit Programs: The Grameen Bank Experience." Ph.D. diss. Brown University, Providence, R.I. McKnelly, Barbara, and Christopher Dunford. 1998. Impact of Credit with Education on Mothers' and Their Young Children's Nutrition: Lower Pra Rural Bank Credit with Education Program in Ghana. Davis, Calif.: Freedom from Hunger. Mishan, E. J. 1988. Cost-Benefit Analysis. New York: Praeger. Modigliani, F., and M. Miller. 1958. "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment." American Economic Review 49 (2): 261-97. Moffitt, Robert. 1991. "Program Evaluation with Nonexperimental Data." Evaluation Review 15 (3) : 291-314. Montgomery, Mark, Terry Johnson, and Syed Faisal. 2000. "Who Succeeds at Starting a Business? Evidence from the Washington Self-Employment Demonstration." Grinnell College, Grinnell, Iowa. Processed. Morduch, Jonathan.1998. "Does Microfinance Really Help the Poor? New Evidence from Flagship Programs in Bangladesh." Princeton University, Princeton, N.J. Processed. . 1999. "The Role of Subsidies in Microfinance: Evidence from the Grameen Bank." Journal of Development Economics 60: 229-48. . 2000. "The Microfinance Schism." World Development 28 (4) 617-29. 96 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Mosley, Paul. 1996. "Metamorphosis from NGO to Commercial Bank: The Case of BancoSol in Bolivia." In David Hulme and Paul Mosley, eds., Finance Against Poverty. Vol. II. London: Routledge. Mosley, Paul, and David Hulme. 1998. "Microenterprise Finance: Is There a Conflict between Growth and Poverty Alleviation?" World Development 26 (5): 783-90. Mould, Maurice C. 1987. Financial Information for Management of a Development Finance Institution. World Bank Technical Paper 63, Industry and Finance Series. Washington, D.C. Norgaard, Richard B., and Richard B. Howarth. 1992. "Sustainability and Intergenerational Environmental Rights: Implications for Benefit-Cost Analysis." In John M. Reilly and Margot Anderson, eds., Economic Issues in Global Climate Change: Agriculture, Forestry, and Natural Resources. Boulder, Colo.: Westview. Pauly, Mark V. 1986. "Returns on Equity for Not-for-Profit Hospitals." Health Services Research 21 (1): 1-16. Paxton, Julia. 1996. A Worldwide Inventory of Microfinance Institutions. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Pitt, Mark M., and Shahidur R. Khandker. 1998. "The Impact of Group- Based Credit Programs on Poor Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender of the Participants Matter?" Journal of Political Economy 106 (5): 958-96. Quirk, James, and Katsuaki Terasawa. 1991. "Choosing a Government Discount Rate: An Alternative Approach." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 20: 16-28. RESULTS International. 1996. "The Microcredit Summit Declaration and Plan of Action." Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship 1 (2): 131-76. Richardson, David C. 1994. "PEARLS: Financial Stabilization, Monitoring, and Evaluation." Research Monograph Series 4. World Council of Credit Unions, Madison, Wis. Rogaly, Ben. 1996. "Micro-Finance Evangelism, 'Destitute Women,' and the Hard Selling of a New Anti-Poverty Formula." Development in Practice 6 (2): 100-12. REFERENCES 97 Rosenberg, Richard. 1994. "Beyond Self-Sufficiency: Licensed Leverage and Microfinance Strategy." USAID (U. S. Agency for International Development) Microenterprise Development Brief 17, Washington, D.C. Processed. .1996. "Microcredit Interest Rates." Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest Occasional Paper 1. World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Rosenberg, Richard, Robert Peck Christen, and Brigit Helms. 1997. "Format for Appraisal of Micro-Finance Institutions." Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest Technical Tools Series 4. World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Sacay, Orlando. 1996. "Measuring Subsidy and Sustainability of Microfinance Institutions." World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Sacay, O., B. Randhawa, and M. Agabin. 1996. "The BAAC Success Story: A Specialized Agriculture Bank under Government Ownership." World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Schmidt, Reinhard H. 1997. "Corporate Governance: The Role of Other Constituencies." In Alice Pezard and Jean-Marie Thiveaud, eds., Corporate Governance: Les Perspectives Internationales. Paris: Association d'Economie Financiere. Schmidt, Reinhard, and Claus-Peter Zeitinger. 1996. "The Efficiency of Credit- Granting NGOs in Latin America." Savings and Development 20 (3): 353-84. Schreiner, Mark. 1995. "Meta-rules." Economics and Sociology Occasional Paper 2268. Ohio State University, Columbus. . 1997. "A Framework for the Analysis of the Performance and Sustainability of Subsidized Microfinance Organizations with Application to BancoSol of Bolivia and Grameen Bank of Bangladesh." Ph.D. diss. Ohio State University, Columbus. . 1999a. Aspects of Outreach: A Framework for the Discussion of the Social Benefits of Microfinance. Center for Social Development Working Paper 99-3. Washington University in St. Louis. . 1999b. "A Cost-Effectiveness Analysis of the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh." Center for Social Development Working Paper 99-5. Washington University in St. Louis. 98 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS . 2000a. "A Framework for Financial Benefit-Cost Analysis of Individual Development Accounts at the Experimental Site of the American Dream Demonstration." Center for Social Development, Washington University in St. Louis. Processed. ____. 2000b. "Resources Used in 1998 and 1999 to Produce Individual Development Accounts in the Experimental Program of the American Dream Demonstration at the Community Action Project of Tulsa County." Center for Social Development, Washington University in St. Louis. Processed. SEEP. 1995. Financial Ratio Analysis of Micro-Finance Institutions. New York: Pact. Sherraden, Michael. 1991. Assets and the Poor: A New American Welfare Policy. Armonk, N.Y: M. E. Sharpe. Sherraden, Michael, Lissa Johnson, Margaret Clancy, Sondra Beverly, Mark Schreiner, Min Zhan, and Jami Curley. 2000. "Savings Patterns in IDA Programs-Downpayments on the American Dream Policy Demonstration, a National Demonstration of Individual Development Accounts." Center for Social Development, Washington University in St. Louis. Sial, Maqbool H., and Michael R. Carter. 1996. "Financial Market Efficiency in an Agrarian Economy: Microeconometric Analysis of the Pakistani Punjab." Journal of Development Studies 32 (5): 771-98. Silvers, J. B., and Robert T. Kauer. 1986. "Returns on Equity for Not-for- Profit Hospitals: Some Comments." Health Services Research 21 (1) 21-28. Singh, Inderjit, Lyn Squire, and John Strauss. 1986. "A Survey of Agricultural Household Models: Recent Findings and Policy Implications." World Bank Economic Review 1 (1) : 149-79. Smith, Stephen C., and Sanjay Jain. 1998. "Village Banking and Maternal and Child Health: Theory and Preliminary Evidence from Honduras and Ecuador." George Washington University, Washington, D.C. Processed. Stickney, Clyde P., and Roman L. Weil. 1994. Financial Accounting: An Introduction to Concepts, Methods, and Uses. Fort Worth: Dryden. REFERENCES 99 Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1993. "The Role of the State in Financial Markets." In Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1993. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. - 1998. "The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions." Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (2) : 3-22. Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Andrew Weiss. 1981. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information." American Economic Review 71 : 393-410. Tollison, R. 1984. "Politics without Romance: A Sketch of Positive Public Choice Theory and Its Normative Implications." In R. Tollison and J. Buchanan, eds., The Theory of Public Choice-Il. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Tully, Shawn. 1993. "The Real Key to Creating Wealth." Fortune, September 20, pp. 143, 160-2. - 1994. "America's Best Wealth Creators." Fortune, November 28, pp. 38-50. Tweeten, Luther. 1992. Agricultural Trade: Principles and Policies. Boulder, Colo.: Westview. Von Pischke, J. D. 1991. Finance at the Frontier: Debt Capacity and the Role of Credit in the Private Economy. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. - 1996. "Measuring the Trade-Off between Outreach and Sustainability of Microenterprise Lenders." Journal of International Development 8 (2) : 225-39. . 1998. "Measuring the Performance of Small Enterprise Lenders." In Mwangi S. Kimeny, Robert C. Wieland, and J. D. Von Pischke, eds., Strategic Issues in Microfinance. Brookfield: Avebury. Von Pischke, J. D. and Dale W Adams. 1980. "Fungibility and the Design and Evaluation of Agricultural Credit Projects." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62: 719-24 Von Pischke, J. D., Robert C. Vogel, Peter Flath, and Maurice C. Mould. 1988. "Measurement of Loan Repayment Performance." Economic Development Institute Course Note 030/086. World Bank, Washington, D.C. 100 DEVELOPMENT FINANCE INSTITUTIONS Weinstein, Milton C., and William B. Stason. 1977. "Foundations of Cost- Effectiveness Analysis for Health and Medical Practices." New England Journal of Medicine 296 (13): 716-21. Wheeler, John R. C., and Jan P. Clement. 1990. "Capital Expenditure Decisions and the Role of the Not-for-Profit Hospital: An Application of a Social Goods Model." Medical Care Review 47 (4): 467-86. Women's World Banking. 1995. "The Missing Links: Financial Systems that Work for the Majority." New York. Processed. World Bank. 1989. World Development Report 1989: Financial Systems and Development. New York: Oxford University Press. . 1994. "Mexico: Agricultural Sector Memorandum." World Bank, Natural Resources and Poverty Division and Latin America and Caribbean Regional Office, Country Department II, Washington, D.C. Yaron, Jacob. 1992a. Successful Rural Finance Institutions. World Bank Discussion Paper 150. Washington, D.C. . 1992b. Assessing Development Finance Institutions: A Public Interest Analysis. World Bank Discussion Paper 174. Washington, D.C. . 1994. "What Makes Rural Finance Institutions Successful?" World Bank Research Observer 9 (9) : 49-70. Yaron, Jacob, McDonald Benjamin, and Gerda Piprek. 1997. Rural Finance: Issues, Design, and Best Practices. Environmentally Sustainable Development Studies and Monographs Series 14. World Bank, Washington, D.C. The term developmentJfinance institutions, or DFIs, refers to public or private financial intermediaries that use resources from government or donors to improve social welfare. As funds for development become increasingly scarce, measuring the social cost of public DFIs becomes more important. If the social benefit of a DFI exceeds its social cost, then it can be said that the public funds are well spent. Developmnent Finance Institutions: Measurin7g Their Subsidy presents two means for measuring social cost: the Subsidy Dependence Index and the Net Present Cost to Society. Both measures advance on common financial ratios because they shift the paradigm from reported (accounting) costs-many of which are routinely subsidized-to opportunity (economic) costs, leading to a more efficient determination of the sustainability of a DFI. Sustainability improves social welfare if the consequent long-term increase in the length, breadth, scope, and quality of outreach compensates for the short-term increase in costs shifted to the target group. As presented in this book, use of the Subsidy Dependence Index and the Net Present Cost to Society to measure social cost constitutes a first step toward the better informed use of public funds. THE WORLD BANK 1818 [H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433 LU.S.A. Telephone: 202-47-1234 H Facsimile: 202-47-6391 Internet: www.worldbank.org E-mail: feedback(@worldbank.org ISBN 0-8213-4984-8