Report No. 36573-ZM Zambia Smallholder Agricultural Commercialization Strategy January 9, 2007 Sustainable Development, AFTS1 Country Department 2, Zambia Africa Region Document of the World Bank Zambia SmallholderAgriculturalCommercializationStrategy(SACS) CONTENTS Page ACNOWLEDGMENT i EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 11 .. Chapter 1: Framework for Zambia Smallholder Agricultural Commercialization Strategy 1 Chapter 2: Current State of Smallholder Agriculture 4 Chapter 3: Key Issues for Smallholder Commercialization 19 Chapter 4: Agribusiness Support to Smallholders: Analysis of Outgrower Schemes 29 Chapter 5: Development Potential and Opportunities for Smallholder Commercialization inZambia 52 REFERENCES: 63 ANNEXES Annex 1: Description o fMajor Smallholder Commodity Sub-sectorsinZambia 68 Annex 2: Recommendations for Best Practice Outgrower Models 76 Annex 3: Major On-going Donor SupportedSmallholder Commercialization Projects inZambia 79 BOXES Box 1: Comparison of centralized and distributor Outgrower Models 31 Box 2: Kaleya Smallholder Company Ltd 32 Box 3: C R M Farm: Successful smallholder credit by commercial farmer 40 Box 4: Reducing rural poverty by linking farmer organizations with public- Private partnerships inChina 48 Box 5: Mali: "Silicon Mali" 49 Box 6: Colombia: Buildingproductive agribusiness-farmer partnerships 49 Box 7: Madagascar: Giventhe right incentives, Africa smallholders in Supply chains can compete andprosper 51 MAPS: Map 1: Agro-ecological ones (regions) inZambia 10 Acknowledgements This report focuses on the potential and opportunities for smallholder commercialization in Zambia. The report was prepared under the guidance o f Frank K. Byamugisha (Acting Sector Manager AFTS1, World Bank), Richard G. Scobey (Sector Manager, AFTS1, World Bank), and Tijan Sallah (Lead Specialist, AFTS1, World Bank). Michael Baxter (Country Director, World Bank) and Hartwig Schafer (Director o f Operations, Africa Region, World Bank) also provided overall direction and guidance for the analysis. This report has been preparedby Paavo Eliste (AFTS1, World Bank) with a support from Alex Mwanakasale (AFTS1, World Bank). Other authors who have contributed to various chapters o f the report include: Timothy Purcell, Rudyvan Gent, Paul Siegel, andJens Nielsen (Consultants). Excellent and extensive advice was received from Sari Soderstrom, Eija Pehu (World Bank), and Jan Joost Nijhoff(USAID-Lusaka), who were the peer reviewers for this report. The report also benefited from invaluable comments from Jos Verbeek and Marie W. Sheppard (World Bank), as well as from participants inthe Participatory Learning Workshop held inZambia on July 7-8. 2005, which included members o f the Government, development partners, and private sector in Zambia. Much o f the background analysis was supported by funding from the World Bank and from a multi-donor trust fund (the Bank Netherlands Partnership Program, BNPP), which i s funded by Netherlands. Fundingwas also received from the Danish Consultant Trust Fund. Meseret Kebede provided excellent assistance in various aspects o f the management and administration o f the project, andthe preparation of the final document. i .. 11 EXECUTIVESUMMARY Role of SmallholdersinZambianAgriculture Agriculture remains an important sector for the national economy in Zambia. The agricultural sector provides employment to some 67 percent o f the labour force and supplies raw materials to agro-related industries, which account for some 84 percent o f manufacturing value- added in the country. Agriculture and agro-processing account for more than 40 percent o f Zambia's GDP and contribute about 12percent o f export earnings. The rural economy is dominatedby smallholder agriculture. The overwhelming majority o f rural households are smallholders who depend on agriculture for their livelihoods. There is a very small number o fmedium and large scale agricultural producers. Smallholder agriculture in Zambia is characterized by low productivity levels. Most smallholders use simple technologies and cultivation practices to produce rain-fed staple foods (e.g., maize, groundnuts, roots and tubers), mostly for own consumption. At the other extreme are large scale commercial farms using modem inputs and having access to domestic and global input and output marketing chains. They are sometimes vertically integrated with agro- processing enterprises. Smallholder commercializationis key to rural growth and poverty reduction. Most of Zambia's smallholders produce primarily for home-consumption. Surpluses are sold in the community or marketed outside the community. Also, to get cash quickly, many smallholders sell their produce after harvest and then buy food staples in small quantities over the year. Commercial productionby smallholders is agricultural production primarilyproduced to be sold in markets outside the community. Thus, an external market is needed, along with logistical support to make the accompanying transactions. For smallholders to use agriculture as a poverty reducing strategy, they must increase returns to land by intensifying use o f labor and/or capital (including multiple cropping). Lacking capital and having labor, labor-intensive high-value (Le., highreturnsto land) agricultural enterprises are needed for smallholders.' Past Government efforts to support smallholder commercialization have not achieved expectedresults. Before introductiono fpolicyreforms inthe 1 9 9 0the~ Government attempted ~ to support smallholder commercialization through provision o f subsidized inputs and credit, price interventions for outputs, and by operating agricultural parastatals. However, these measures were less successfd, partly because o f the desire to provide cheap staple food for the urban population. The uniform pricing o f inputs and outputs throughout the country (Le., pan- 1Note: This does not mean that commercializing smallholders should abandon production o f food staples, it means that they need to expand production o f cash crops and/or livestock. Increasing productivity o f food staples is an important means to provide incentives to smallholders to expand cash crop production (since less land and labor needto be devoted to staples). ... 111 territorial pricing), biased production incentives in favor o f maize as opposed to other food staples or higher-value crops produced according to comparative advantage. Followingthe economic reforms of the early 1990s, the Government reduced its role and budget for agriculture, which led to significant changes in Zambia's agriculture sector. With reduced Government role, the private sector has been spearheading the changes in production patterns, technology adoption, enterprise mixes, farm profitability and market orientation o f smallholder farmers. Maize i s still the major, albeit diminishing, crop in smallholder production systems. The major shift in crop production by smallholders has been the significant increase inlandplantedto cotton, the largest export crop inZambia, followed by other smallholder cash crops, such as burley tobacco, paprika, sugar, coffee, etc. Differentforms of contractfarming(e.g., outgrowerschemes) havebecomethe main means for smallholder commercializationin Zambia. Inthese outgrower schemes, an entrepreneur (e.g., commercial farm or an agribusiness entity) contracts smallholders to produce commodities o f high value to be marketed, in turn, by the entrepreneur. The entrepreneur provides the smallholder the necessary technical advice and inputs to produce the agreed product and also provides a guaranteed market outlet for the produce. Many o f the outgrower scheme arrangements are thus similar to past relationships with the Government which provided support services like extension, credit andmarket outlets. Currently about one-third of the 800,000 Zambia's smallholders participatein some form of outgrower scheme arrangements. Most o f these farmers (some 85 percent) are engaged in cotton production. Smallholders produce the majority o f cotton lint in Zambia (some 98 percent). Burleytobacco i s another cash crop which is produced mainly by smallholders. Other cash crops which are produced largely by smallholders through outgrower schemes include paprikdchili and honey. Smallholders also produce about 40 percent o f the country's sugar and 5 percent o f the coffee. Furthermore, smallholders make up a small, but steadily increasing share o f dairy production. However, Zambian smallholders are a heterogeneous group of farmers with various degrees of commercial potential. There are distinct differences in smallholders households' asset composition, human and social capital, and spatial characteristics, such as agro-ecological zones, access to roadrail infrastructure and markets, and proximity to population centers, which determine the commercial potential o f smallholders. Given these characteristics, some smallholders are better positioned to become market oriented than others. Zambian smallholder farmers can be classified into three broad categories according to their commercialization potential. The first group is very poorest and most vulnerable households who suffer chronic food insecurity and require long-term social protection ("sub- subsistence smallholders", about quarter o f smallholders). A second group includes very poor households that have potential to achieve a sustainable livelihoods, marketing a small surpluses during the years o f a reasonable amount o f rain, with the eventual possibility o f joining some outgrower arrangements ("marginal smallholders", about one-third o f households). Finally, the third group o f smallholders includes the poor households with potential to become, or which have already become commercially oriented small-scale farmers, either through joining various iv outgrowing arrangements or marketing their surplus inthe domestic market. They are generally better educated, possessmore labor and landon a per capita basis (of which they allocate a larger share to cash crop production), live in general in the most favorable agro-ecological zone along the main road and railway infrastructure and near larger urban population centers ("viable smallholders", about one thirdo fhouseholds). Despitethe relativesuccess, outgrower schemes in Zambia are facing increasingchallenges to sustain their competitiveness. The main challenges relate to low and declining productivity levels o f smallholder production systems, high rates o f loan delinquency and non-payment and widespread side-sellinghuying leading outgrower companies to reduce their investments in extension services and provision o f inputs. This has led to the strategy o f horizontal development o f outgrower schemes as a risk minimization strategy to cover the costs o f inputs. The strategy is to increase volumes o f raw material by increasing the number o f smallholder farmers or land area, rather than investing in increased productivity o f a smaller number o f smallholders. Key Issuesand Constraintsfor Smallholder Commercialization Constraints related to the development of small and mediumscale agriculturalproduction in Zambia are complex and multi-dimensionalin nature. Some o f the issues are specific to smallholders, while others affect all stakeholders inthe private sector value chains. Because o f the close linkages between smaller and larger farms and agribusinesses inthe commercialization o f smallholders, it is difficult to separate smallholder specific constraints from broader sectoral issues. Furthermore, many o f the constraints are multi-sectoral innature, which are beyond the domain o fthe agricultural sector. Issues Related to Low Farm-level Productivity of Smallholders Productivitylevels of smallholder productionsystems in Zambia are below their potential. This is the case both for staple crops and the cash crops. Low productivity and low returns to labor and land lead to chronically low levels o f farm incomes for smallholders. For smallholders to commercialize, they must break the cycle o f low productivity and returns to labor and land. Furthermore, low and declining smallholder yields o f commodity crops lead to inadequate raw material supply for other actors in the value chain, which reduces the overall profitability and competitiveness o f value chains. The main constraints affecting the low levels of productivity of smallholder production systems are: (i) business orientation o f Zambian smallholders; (ii) weak lack o f public market infrastructure and support mechanisms which hampers private sector provision o f goods and services to smallholders; (iii) incomplete implementation o f public policies which leads to under-provision o f public goods and services, such as extension and research, and (iv) weak capacity to manage risks (e.g., climatic, market, and health). V IssuesRelated toProfitability of Value Chains Related to the issue of low productivity of smallholder production systems is low profitabilityof commoditysub-sectors where smallholdersparticipate. Parto fthe reason for low profitability i s increasing competition in international markets and declining (andor fluctuating) international commodity prices. However, besides low levels o f farm productivity, issues what affect the profitability o f value chains, other key issues include: (i) weak regulatory environment, especially as it relates to contract enforcement and code o f conduct for outgrower schemes, and policy uncertainty; (ii) highfinancing costs and limitedaccess to credit, especially for term financing; (iii)exchange rate instability; and (iv) poor state o f transport infrastructure. Potentialfor SmallholderCommercialization Smallholder agriculture has demonstratedsome potential in Zambia. Availability o f land and low production costs (especially in labor-intensive activities) makes smallholders attractive partners for agribusinesses who require access to raw materials for processing and exports. Smallholders produce the majority o f cotton, tobacco, honey, andpaprika exports and contribute to the increasing share o f sugar exports. Smallholder producers have also started to make inroads into the domestic dairy sector and there i s evidence o f attempts to link with domestic supermarket chains (for some horticultural products). Increased competition in world markets implies that the comparative advantage of Zambian agriculturalexports will continue to rely on low productioncosts of smallholder productionsystems. Withits relatively hightransport (and associated logistical) costs, Zambian smallholders will need to be competitive with respect to production costs. With the largely unrealized potential to increase productivity o f these smallholder production systems, this means that the importance o f improved support services for smallholders i s critical. However, the majority of smallholders will not be able to independently access increasingly sophisticatedglobal value chains without the support of agribusinesses. The success o f smallholder commercialization in Zambia i s closely associated with the ability and willingnesso fprivate sector enterprises to continue investing inthe sector andwork directly with smallholders. Contract farming (e.g., outgrower schemes) will continue to be the major approach for many agribusinesses. Addressing constraints for smallholder commercialization will require interventionsthat benefit both smallholder and the large scale commercial agriculture sector, as well as agriculturalhon-agricultural enterprises in rural areas. The greatest potential for smallholder commercialization lies not so much inaddressing smallholder or commodity specific constraints, but in overall increases in the efficiency o f value chains through the removal o f economy and sector-wide constraints, and strengthening o f institutional mechanisms through which the key stakeholders and their service providers can effectively link to each other by forming partnerships and alliances. vi Smallholder commercialization can have important poverty reduction impacts in rural Zambia. However, inthe short-term these impacts will be most likely limitedto the portion of the smallholder population living in higher agricultural production areas and who possess necessary complementary productive and social assets, such as land and labor, humanand social capital, and access to physical and financial assets, and who already participate in ougrower schemes. Most o f these higher potential households are still poor, albeit not the "poorest". A significant portion o f poor and very poor rural households who are engaged in subsistence agriculture and live inmore remote areas, and/or do not possess necessary resources, should not be expected to become commercial smallholders (especially not inthe short-term). There is, however, longer-term potential to expand smallholder commercialization into areas off main road and rail network. Inthe longer-term, with new investments in transport and communicationinfrastructure, and inirrigation, some poor rural households inwhat are now considered remote and/or drought-prone areas might also be candidates for smallholder commercialization. Addressing the issues of rural poverty and household risks and vulnerabilities requires holisticsolutions which go beyondagriculturalsector. The sustained andbroad-based efforts o f rural poverty reduction in the long-run will probably depend also on the development o f off- farm labor opportunities and rural enterprises. However, smallholder agricultural production systems will remain important from a household food security perspective, especially for those smallholders that do not have commercial potential. Opportunitiesfor SmallholderCommercialization Given the multi-sectoralnature of issues affecting smallholder agriculture in Zambia the opportunitiesfor effective Governmentand donor support are largely limitedto upstream (Le. market neutral) interventions. The opportunities for the Government and donor support for smallholder commercialization can be organized around the following three overall strategies: Strategy 1:StrengthenExistingMarket Mechanisms. First, there i s a need to continue supporting efforts to strengthen the social and human capital o f commercializing smallholders. The development o f appropriate farmer organizations and improving smallholders' business orientation and farm management skills, should make smallholders more attractive business partners for agri-businesses and better candidates for input-credit provision. Secondly, there i s a need to continue support for improved service deliveryo f existing andnew outgrower schemes. Resources should be made available to address the production and organizational constraints facing the functioning outgrower schemes that are constraining the positive momentum o f the more dynamic sub-sectors. Third, there i s a needto continue supporting efforts to increase farm level productivity by encouraging adoption o f innovative farming technologies which have proven to work in Zambia smallholder farming systems. Fourth, there i s a need to strengthen risk management practices by smallholders, especially dealing with weather related risks that directly affect household livelihood strategies andwell-being. vii Strategy 2: Reformand Strengthen Implementationof Sectoral, Multi-sectoraland Macro Policies There i s a needto focus attention on key sectoral, multi-sectoral, and macro policy interventions that are relatively low cost, and have potentially significant impacts, and highreturns. Many o f the issuesthat needto be dealt with to promote smallholder commercialization are really part and parcel o f broader "investment climate" issues inthe country, which should be addressed through coordinated policy dialogue. A constraint to rapidly achieving these reforms is the broader political economy situation in Zambia. Furthermore, there i s a need for a broader and more holistic multi-sectoral approach to agricultural and rural development, which includes differentiated strategies for different household types and areas o f the country based on economic potential. Sectoral policies for agriculture need to reflect a strong growth orientation, with attention also devoted to food security and safety net issues for the poorest households. It is important to identifyreforms for agricultural sector that are beneficial to larger farmers and agribusiness and their efforts to engage smallholders in some form o f contract farming or outgrower scheme. First, there is a need to reduce the uncertainty o f Government policy making processes, which has a negative effect on developing the private sector led markets and appropriate market institutions. Second, there is a need to speed-up policy reforms which improve the business environment. Inparticular, it i s important to deal with weaknesses inlegal andjudiciary systems in Zambia, which affect the feasibility and sustainability of contract farming (Le., outgrower schemes) arrangements. Third, there is a need to continue to address issues which affect macro- economic stability, including managingthe risks related to the exchange rate volatility. Strategy3: InvestmentsinPublicInfrastructure Focus on investments o f public good nature that have potential to generate new economic opportunities, improve accessibility and facilitate forward andbackward linkages to other sectors inthe economy. There is little public sector presence inthe agricultural input or output markets or in rural sector in Zambia in general, except for the distortions created by fertilizer subsidies and maize market interventions. There i s a need to support the development o f new approaches and public-private sector and civil society partnerships for the delivery of productive infrastructure assets (i.e. irrigation infrastructure, storage and post-harvesting facilities, etc.) in order to intensify smallholder farming and to improve the competitiveness o f value chains. Secondly, Zambia is a large country with a long list o f infrastructure needs. However, resources for infrastructure development are extremely limited. There i s therefore a need for strategic geographically targeted approaches for transport, energy and communication infrastructure investments. The short-term focus for infrastructure development should be on those rural areas which have the highest potential for agricultural growth and linked activities (e.g., development o f infrastructure growth poles). Inthe longer-term, infrastructure development could expand to other areas o f the country which would broaden the scope for smallholder commercialization. ... V l l l Chapter 1 Frameworkfor Zambia SmallholderAgriculturalCommercializationStrategy Background After years o f declining real GDP and increasing poverty rates the Zambian economy is experiencing a period o f robust growth. Real GDP has been growing at an average annual rate of over 4 percent during 1999-2005 - the first period o f uninterrupted positive real GDP growth since 1965. However, poverty levels have remained persistently high - during 1998-2004 period, the poverty headcount experienced only a modest decline from 73 to 68 percent. Much higher growth rates are neededfor Zambia to reach its poverty related Millennium Development Goal (MDG), which aims to reduce the proportion o f Zambians whose income i s less than one dollar a day by 50 percent between 1990 and2015. It is clear that without robust andbroad-based economic growth - over sectors and space - there will be few opportunities for Zambia to reduce poverty. The Government o f the Republic o f Zambia (GRZ) has recognized the importance o f smallholder agriculture in its long-term development strategy and has documented its vision for the agricultural sector's growth and development in various policy papers. For example, the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP, 2002-2004) sees an important role for commercial farming and agribusinesses, through the use o f outgrower schemes, to advance smallholder commercialization. The Agricultural Commercialization Program (ACP, 2002-2005), which was put inplace to drive implementation o f the agricultural component of the PRSP, underscores the focus on developing commercial agriculture, while at the same time ensuring food security and increasing incomes of smallholders, thereby contributing to poverty reduction. In addition, the vision set out in the National Agricultural Policy (NAP, 2003-2015) is "to promote the development o f an efficient, competitive and sustainable agricultural sector, which ensures food security and increased income". The issues related to broad-based rural development and poverty reduction in Zambia are complex. At a minimum it would require a comprehensive analysis o f issues related to food security and livelihood strategies; rural labor markets, including rural - urban migration; natural resource management and sustainable farming practices; and commercialization o f smallholder farming systems and other market-oriented activities. Covering o f all these issues through in- depth analytical work is beyond the scope o f this report. As such, the focus o f the Zambia Smallholder Agricultural Commercialization Strategy (SACS) i s to provide a new analytical knowledge and lessons learned on smallholder commercialization, as it relates to the issues related to the development o f outgrower schemes for cash crops inZambia Objectives of the Study Smallholder commercialization has been progressing at different rates in different parts o f the country, but the process generally remains at a relatively early stage. The most notable 1 characteristic o f smallholder commercialization in Zambia i s the involvement o f private sector led outgrower schemes and other forms o f contract farming that link smallholders to larger commercial enterprises which provide access to markets. The objective o f the study i s to analyze issues and constraints to smallholder commercialization and make recommendations for addressing them, including the discussion o f different opportunities. In particular, the study focuses attention on outgrower schemes that have proliferated inseveral sub-sectors. Approach Zambia i s a well studied country and a substantive stock o f knowledge has been generated through various analytical work and technical assistance programs. The SACS builds therefore on the existing knowledge by synthesizing the work done by others, draw upon information generated by background papers prepared for the study, and provides new analyses to fill identified knowledge gaps. The validity of the key findings was checked through extensive consultantions with key stakeholders duringthe field work. The SACS focuses on the smallholder commercialization process through six case studies o f outgrower schemes (cotton, paprika, export vegetables, coffee, dairy and sugar)2. The case studies were based on surveys with various stakeholders in the commodity chains (i.e. agribusinesses, service providers, smallholder farmers, etc.). The field surveys were carried out inLusaka, Central, Eastern and Southern Provinces. The main areas o f survey research included the analysis o f (i)upstream and downstream activities o f the outgrower schemes; (ii) existing market infrastructure facilities relevant to the outgrower schemes; (iii) regulatory environment, taxation policies and trade policy regime; (iv) extension, farmer training and capacity building; (v) financing and marketing arrangements; (vi) benefits for smallholders in participation in outgrower schemes; (vii) role o f farmer organizations; and (viii) identification o f the priority areas for public investments. In addition, the report uses the quantitative data from the survey of outgrower schemes, which was carried out by the Agricultural Consultative Forum (ACF) in 2005 inparallel to qualitative SACS outgrower case studies. The ACF study was based on the survey o f 20 outgrower schemes (i.e. cotton, tobacco, coffee, paprika, fresh vegetables, sugar, honey, maize and soyabeans). The survey questionnaires were sent to outgrower scheme promoters and were later followed up to ensure sufficient response rate. The survey instrument included information about the outgrower schemes, characteristics o f outgrower farmers; production and marketing arrangements o f the scheme; financing and management; and general aspects o f the development o f out-grower schemes. The latter included views andopinions o f the respondents on the general economic environment created by government and recommendations for the development o f the sector. The study benefited greatly from the comments and feedback received during the SACS Participatory Learning Workshop held in Zambia on July 7-8, 2005, which discussed the preliminary findings o f the background studies. The workshop was facilitated by the Bank Multi Sector Learning (MSL)team. Otherbackgroundstudiescarriedout under the SACS includethe analysisofsmallholderproducergroups and profileofZambiansmallholders. 2 Rather than focusing on comparative advantages o f particular crops or sub-sectors, the SACS aims at identifying the characteristics o f smallholders who have the highest potential for commercialization and geographical areas which have the highest economic potential to spearhead sectoral growth (Chapter 2). Related to this, i s a survey of the recent dynamics and trends in the development of the major commodity sub-sectors and the key players, which are relevant for smallholder livelihoods in Zambia (Annex 1). The report then identifies key issues that currently constrain effective smallholder commercialization process in Zambia (Chapter 3). This will set the context to the following discussion o f the lessons learned and recent evidence from the development of partnerships between smallholders and agribusiness sector, which forms the core analytical part o f the report (Chapter 4). Finally, the report identifies the potential and opportunities for the smallholder commercialization process inZambia andproposes a set o f actions and approaches, which suggest alternative way forward for future support to the sector (Chapter 5). 3 Chapter 2 CurrentState of SmallholderAgriculture This chapter presents a brief overview o f issues on the state o f smallholder agriculture in Zambia. There are several recent World Bank publications that present in-depthanalyses o f a wide-range o f relevant institutional and policy issues. See the footnote below for a list o f relevant documents3 Given the narrow focus of the SACS on smallholder commercialization, it i s not possible to incorporate all these issues inthis report. As such, this overview focuses on the current state o f smallholder agriculture. Introduction Major policy shifts took place in Zambia during the 1990s, including the dismantling o f state institutions for marketingand distribution (and oftentimes financing) o f agricultural outputs and inputs, the abolition of producer subsidies, the liberalization o f trade in food items, and the introduction o f market-determined input and output prices. Following the economic reforms o f the early 1990s, the Government reduced its role and budget for agriculture, leading to deterioration in public service delivery. Investments in staff development, necessary facilities and equipment have basically ceased, while operating funds are at a minimum. This has hurt most smallholder farmers dependent on public services who were ill-prepared to face the challenges and exploit the emerging market opportunities that come with market liberalization. Implementation o f sectoral policies i s under the responsibility o f the Ministry o f Agriculture and Co-operatives (MACO) `. Inits current form, theroleofMACOisto support differentproducers by facilitating the flow o f modem information on the methods o f production, processing and marketing o f agricultural produce. Another function o f the M A C O i s related to regulating the agricultural sector and providing a suitable legal andpolicy framework to guide the operations o f different stakeholders in the agriculture sector. However, since introduction o f the economic reform program in the 1990s, and the associated budget austerity measures, M A C O has not recovered from the shock inflicted by the significant cuts in staff and budget. It i s currently a relatively weak and fragmented public institution, which limits its ability to provide an enabling Deininger,K.andP. Olinto (2000); Washington, D.C.; World Bank (2004a) "Zambia CountryEconomic Memorandum: Policiesfor GrowthandDiversification." ReportNo. 28069-ZA Washington, D.C.; see Chapter4, Volume IandAnnex A, Volume 11.; World Bank (2004b) "Zambia: An Assessment of the InvestmentClimate." ReportNo. 29741-ZM Washington, D.C.; DelNinno, C. andA. Marini(2005) "Household's Vulnerability in Zambia." SP DiscussionPaperNo. 0535. The WorldBank: Washington, D.C.; Jorgensen, S.L. andZ. Loudjeva (2005) "A Povertyand Social ImpactAnalysis of Three Reforms inZambia: Land, Fertilizer, and Infrastructure." SocialDevelopmentPapers, Paper No. 49. The World Bank: Washington, D.C.; Siegel, P.B. andJ. Alwang (2005) "Poverty ReducingPotentialof Smallholder Agriculture inZambia: Opportunities and Constraints." Afica Region Working Paper Series, Number 85. The World Bank.WorldBank (2005a) "The Republic of Zambia Joint IDA-IMF Staff Advisory Note on the SecondAnnual ProgressReport." Report 31572-ZA. Washington, D.C.; World Bank (2005b) "Zambia: PovertyandVulnerability Assessment."Report No. 32573-ZA.DiscussionDraft. Washington, D.C. June 29, 2005.; World Bank(2005~)"Summary of Zambia Investment ClimateAssessment." Africa Region, Private Sector Group. NoteNumber 5. September.Washington, D.C.; World Bank(2006) "Zambia: Agricultural Development Support Project:ProjectAppraisalDocument." Report 35804-ZA.Washington, D.C. 4 Chapter 1gives a briefoverviewof mainpoliciesrelevantto agriculture sector inZambia. 4 environment for agricultural development and appropriate services to different stakeholders - especially services for smallholders. As a response to the declining role o f the public sector in agriculture, the Government has established several agricultural trusts to enhance cooperation between the public and the private sector, sometimes set up to support specific commodities. Agricultural trusts are public and private sector partnerships which were set up to manage public assets on commercial basis while providing services to farming community. These arrangements allow the Government to transfer physical assets and human resources into more cost-effective arrangements, thus reducing the public sector financial burden, whilst not actually disposing o f public goods, and provide a more politically acceptable method o f privatisation o f former commercially oriented activities o f the MACO. These trusts generally carry out adaptive research and provide advisory services to smallholders. Some also carry out training courses to monitoring and/or extension staff in the employ o f private sector companies and to selected public extension officers. The main trusts would include: (i)Golden Valley Agricultural Research Trust (GART); (ii)Livestock Development Trust (LDT); (iii) Cotton Development Trust (CDT); and (iv) Zambia Export-Crop Growers Association Training Trust (ZEGATT). The trusts are governed by independent board o f trustees inwhich the main stakeholders are represented. Role of Agriculture in Zambian Economy Zambia has 42 million hectares o f arable land(about 55 percent o f total land area), o f which only 1.5 million hectares (about 4 percent) i s cultivated every year. The country's large smallholder population accounts for some four-fifths o f this cultivated area. Out o f a total land area of 75 million hectares, about 42 million hectares are suitable for agricultural production, o f which only 1.5 million hectares are cultivated every year. Thus, from an aggregate national perspective, land resources remain largely unexploited. The country also has abundant water resources, which could be potentially used for irrigation. However, much o f this natural resource endowment has not beenturned into real wealth for rural households. A major reason that much o f the land i s not cultivated i s the non-existent or poor state o f transport infrastructure and the land-locked status o f the country which reduces Zambia's competitiveness on export markets, especially in products with low value to weight ratio. The lack o f public investment in infrastructure and weak public institutions, along with a nascent private sector exacerbate problems relatedto competitiveness for the agricultural sector. Agriculture remains an important sector for the national economy inZambia. Followingdeclines in copper earnings, agriculture has become a more important source of export earnings and economic diversification inZambia. The sector currently employs about 67 percent o f the labor force in Zambia. Its contribution to GDP was 21.4 percent in2004, up from about 15 percent in mid 1990s. Together with agro-processing industry, it accounts for more than 40 percent o f Zambia's GDP. Agro-processing industries account for about 84 percent o f manufacturing output, and it is more than five times larger than the next largest group, textiles and leather products (both ofwhich rely on agricultural raw materials). 5 Agricultural growth rates accelerated as a result o f economic liberalization policies. During the period o f 1990 to 2000, agricultural GDP grew at an average rate o f 3.9 percent per annum. This was faster than the population growth o f 2.5 percent, indicating a positive growth per capita. However, the average growth rate o f agriculture sector has slowed to 1.3 percent between 2000 to 2004, mainly due to series o f droughts, which contributed to negative growth rates o f -2.6 and -1.7 percent in2001 and 2002 respectively. It i s expected that in2005 the agricultural sector will contract by another -2.7 percent due to extended dry spells. This shows the vulnerability o f the food staple crop sector to external shocks. The sector achieved positive growth rates o f 4.5 and 7.5 respectively in2003 and 2004 which had relatively favorable weather conditions. Agricultural exports reached US$201 million in 2004, representing about 2 percent o f the GDP and about 12percent o f total exports. Agricultural exports grew on average about 15 percent a year between 1990 and 2004. The annual growth o f agricultural exports during the 2000s is about 18 percent, surpassing the 12 per cent per annum during the 1990s (FA0 agricultural database, available at http://faostat.fao.or.g). Three main agricultural exports from Zambia are cotton, tobacco and sugar, which make up about two-third o f total agricultural exports. Table 1 shows that both cotton and tobacco have shown steady and impressive growth since 1999, while most o f the increase in value o f sugar exports has taken place between 2004 and 2005. Horticulture exports peaked in 2003 and have declined since then. Incontrast, exports o f coffee have been steadily increasing. Of the lesser products, paprika i s declining quickly whilst honey i s increasing and tea appears to be steady. Annex 1 provides a detailed review o f the recent trends o f the main export crop and livestock sub-sectors in Zambia which have the largest potential for smallholder commercialization and future growth o f the agricultural sector in general. Paprika 2,800 1,800 2,980 1,625 1,500 1,178 232 Honey 202 87 233 355 544 The dataofhoney also includeexports ofbeeswax Source:- Export Boardo f Zambia Role of Smallholders in Zambian Agriculture Typology of Agricultural Producers in Zambia Most o f Zambia's agricultural producers are asset-poor smallholders who use simple technologies (hand hoes and oxen) and cultivation practices (minimal purchased inputs such as hybridseed or fertilizer) to produce rain-fed maize, groundnuts, roots and tubers, mostly for own 6 consumption on five or less hectares (most smallholders cultivate less than 2 hectares). At the other extreme are large scale commercial farms usingmodern inputs and with access to domestic and global input and output marketing chains, and sometimes vertically integrated with agro- processing. The traditional classification o f Zambian agricultural producers estimates that there are about 800,000 smallholder households and about 50,000 emergent farmer households (Table 2). r- Emergent farmers are often assumed to be commercially-oriented smallholders. Approx. Approx Technology, Market Location # of Farm Size Cultivation Orientation Producers Practice 800,000 5ha Handhoe, Staple foods, Entire country Producers h h S (with minimal primarily majority inputs, home cultivating 2 household consumption or less ha of labor rain-fed land) 50,000 hhs 5 - 20 ha Oxen, hybrid Staple foods Mostly line-of-rail Farmers seed and and cash (Central, Lusaka, fertilizer, few crops, Southern Provinces), with irrigation, primarily some Eastern, Western mostly market Provinces household orientation labor Large-Scale 700 farms 50 - 150ha Tractors, Maize and Mostly Central, Lusaka, Commercial hybridseed, cash crops Southern Provinces fertilizer, some irrigation, modem management, hired labor Large 10 farms 1OOO+ ha High Maize, cash Mostly Central, Lusaka, Corporate mechanization, crops, vertical Southern Provinces Operations irrigation, integration modern management, hired labor I Source: Siege1ai Alwang (2005), aptedfrom World ank (2003b) and Francis, et al., (1997). When considering the potential for smallholder commercialization, it i s important to recognize that Zambian smallholders are not homogeneous group o f farmers. Understanding the heterogeneity o f Zambia's rural households and their different potential as agricultural producers 7 i s critical to designing strategies for commercially viable smallholders. There are distinct differences in smallholder households' assets, human capital, income generating potential, and livelihood strategies. Ingeneral, smallholder households can be classified into 3 groups as a way to characterize their commercial potential5: 1) The very poorest andmost vulnerable households who suffer chronic food insecurity and require long-term social protection (about 200,000 "sub-subsistence" smallholders, about one quarter o f households); 2) The very poor households that have potential to achieve a sustainable livelihoods, marketing a small surpluses during years o f a reasonable amount o f rain, with the eventual possibility o f joining an outgrower scheme (about 300,000 "marginal smallholders", about one-third o fhouseholds) 3) The poor households with potential to become, or which have already become commercially oriented small-scale farmers, either joining an outgrower scheme or marketing their surplus in the domestic market (about 300,000 potentially "viable smallholders", about one-third o f households). Instead o f focusing on the precise distribution o f households in each group, it i s important to focus on the characteristics o f the respective households groups realizing that they all represent significant shares o f the smallholder population. Below are some salient characteristics o f each group: Sub-subsistence smallholders: smallholder households that are not commercially viable farmers and are unlikely to ever become so. They represent the most vulnerable social groups. Ultra poor, often female headed households, or elderly or child headed households, the chronically sick and/or disabled - with less than sufficient to feed themselves throughout the year. They usually occupy the least arable land in the community, face labor constraints and they have no resources on which to call in the event o f a "shock" (e.g., drought, death, sickness). The term "farmer" might be a misnomer for this group since they are simply survivingby whatever means they can, sometimes as casual laborers on commercial farms andestates, andoften on food relief. They are likely to continue to need social protectionmeasures inthe foreseeable future. Marginal smallholders: smallholder households who could, potentially become self-sufficient in food and are capable o f producing a small marketable surplus. Many border on being ultra poor, but they have some resources on which to call - e.g., greater physical strength and better health, slightly more andbetter land closer to means o firrigation, some small savings or livestock to use as collateral for informal or micro-loans. Again, they often rely on obtaining causal work on commercial farms and estates and may grow staple crops for subsistence and the local market. Commercially oriented smallholders can be defined as farmers who market their production surpluses indomestic or export markets (via intermediaries). Their level o f commercialization i s be determined by asset holdings including land, ox or mechanical implements and level o f sophistication o f production systems. Many would start as outgrower farmers and progress towards becoming independent owners-operators (emergent farmers). They are differentiated from subsistence farmers who grow occasional surpluses for sale. Ina recent study onthe "incapacitated poor" inZambia, several estimates were presented, butmost were inthe range o f 1520% (Milimo and others, 2004). 8 Some inthis group have failed to participate inan outgrower scheme or failed while participating inanoutgrower scheme, or who do not liveinan areawhere outgrower schemesexist. Viable smallholders: smallholder households who are poor but potentially, or already commercially viable small scale farmers. They often have assets that are used inefficiently because o f conditions such as lack o f access to markets, poor infrastructure, or inability to raise small loans for investment. They have the potential to participate, or may well be participating already in outgrower schemes, or they are functioning as commercially viable independent small-scale farmers selling to the domestic market. Spatial Distribution of Agricultural Potentialfor Smallholders Locational factors such as access to roadrail infrastructure, agro-ecological zones, and proximity to population centers strongly influence the potential for smallholder commercialization7. These spatial factors are important to understand, as they point towards the profound differences in rural areas with respect to economic potential for smallholder commercialization. Most large commercial farms inZambia are located close to a main (trunk) road network, which follows closely the "line o f rail", running from copper mine areas in the Copperbelt through Lusaka and on to Livingstone in Southern Province. The road infrastructure along the "line-of- rail" route and its extension to Eastern Province i s in fairly good condition. Ingeneral, the primaryroadrail network does not cover large areas o f the country. Inaddition, there is a lack o f coverage OTsecondary and tertiary rural roads8 All o f Zambia's urban centers with more than 100,000 inhabitants are located on the "line-of- rail". The urban areas o f Lusaka and the Copperbelt both have about 1.7 million residents. Together these urbancenters account for almost 40% o f Zambia's total population. Zambia can be divided into 3 major agro-ecological zones (see Map 1). (i) Zone Iis a low-rainfall area in the southern portion o f the Southern and Western Provinces, and parts o f Lusaka and Eastern Provinces. Maize, sorghum, groundnuts, sunflowers and cowpeas are cultivated, and the fishing industry (though now in decline) has drawn many to the area. This zone covers about 16 percent o f Zambia's land area; (ii) Zone I1 is a medium-rainfall belt running east-west through the center o f the country on the plateau o f the Central, Lusaka, Southern and Eastern Provinces' It has the most favorable agro-ecological conditions. There is also ample irrigation 7 Roadrail infrastructure and market access can be through direct access or via an intermediary trader or processor. There i s also a railroad line (and road network) that connects Lusaka to Tanzania and runs through Mpika and Kasama inNorthern Province. Inaddition there i s a fairly good road network connecting Lusaka to Chipata in Eastern Province. There are also road networks to Mongu inWestern Province and Solwezi and Mwinilunga in NorthwesternProvince and Manza inLuapula Province. 9The western part o f Zone I1has low-rainfall that corresponds to centraynorthernparts o f Western Province. This area is often considered a part o f Zone 11, but i s differentiated by lower rainfall and sandier soils, poorer road and market infrastructure. Main crops include sorghum and millet as staple crops along with cassava, and some maize. 9 potential. This allows for a diverse mix of crop and livestock enterprises. Because o f its proximity to Lusaka and other urban centers, Zone I1has been the geographic focus o f the development of commercial farms. Maize i s the staple crop, but a wide variety of other crops are grown; including beans, groundnuts, sorghum, cassava, millet, sweet potato, sunflower, cotton, rice, tobacco, paprika along with vegetables and fruits. This zone covers about 42 percent o f Zambia's landarea; and (iii) Zone I11i s a high-rainfall area inthe north o f the country inCopperbelt, Luapula, Northern and Northwestern Provinces. It includes the mines o f the Copperbelt area, which is relatively urbanized. The major crops produced are cassava, maize, groundnuts, millet, sorghum, beans and sweet potatoes; and small-scale fishing and fish-trading i s also a source of income. Because o f the abundance o f water in this area, there is potential for irrigation, and for fishing. This zone covers about 42 percent o f Zambia's landarea. M a p I:Agro-ecological zones (regions) in Zambia Source: FA0 (2005) 10 Ingeneral, yields are higher inZone I1for most crops andconditions for livestockproduction are also more favorable. Higher yields are due to more favorable agro-ecological conditions and the fact that much o f this zone is located along the primary road network which allows for greater access to input and output markets and technical advisory services. Smallholder households in this area tend to have better access to infrastructure, higher use o f inputs, and a higher share o f medium- and large-sized commercial farms using improved technologies. The existence o f medium- and larger-commercial farms in the area is beneficial to smallholders through labor linkages and the existence o f outgrower schemes, and also through demonstration effects. This i s important with respect to Zones Iand 111, which are characterized by a virtual absence o f medium- and larger-commercial farms. It should be noted, however, that for some export commodities such as coffee and niche products like honey; production is focused in Northwestern and Northern provinces. It is estimated that about two-fifth o f smallholders reside in the more favored ago-ecological Zone 11, and about the same share o f smallholders reside in the high rainfall Zone 111, which i s mostly characterized by lack o f access to infrastructure and markets. Also, about one-fifth o f smallholder households reside indrought-prone Zone I.On average, rural households inZambia have access to approximately three hectares o f land. This amount o f land should allow households, inmost areas, to produce enough food staples and other foods to cover consumption needs. Access to land and the quality o f land, however, varies by province (and also within provinces). Table 3 presents the distribution o f smallholders by agro-ecological Zones. Inmost areas virtually all farm labor is provided by householdmembers and labor marketsare thin. Oxen use can help raise average yields and save labor at critical points in the cropping cycle. Such innovations can help smallholders plant more landwithout resorting to hired labor, or be constrained by household labor availability. Increasing land under production by smallholders is one o f the keys for agricultural growth to bepoverty reducing. Province Share of Shareof Shareof Shareof Hectares smallholder smallholder smallholder smallholder per hh hhs in hhs in Zone hhsin Zone hhsinZone Province I I1 I11 Central 8.7% 8.7% 3.23 average Source: Chiwele and Sikananu (2004) shares of smallholders byprovince and Siege1(2005), hectares per household Note: hhs are households 11 Spatial Distribution of Smallholders by Livelihood Strategies The Zambia Vulnerability Assessment Committee (VAC) generated a National Livelihood Zone Map (Zambia VAC, 2004) that divides the country into zones based on common factors influencing rural livelihoods, such as: (i) agronomic potential, (ii) vulnerability to climatic risks such as droughts and floods, (iii) access to roads and markets, (iv) major agricultural production systems and flows o f agricultural inputs and outputs, and (v) household assets. The livelihood zone map highlights the heterogeneity of conditions over space, and provides some insights into the location o f higher and lower potential areas for smallholder commercial agriculture. The livelihood zones associated with a higherprevalence o f commercial smallholder agricultural activities (and large-scale commercial farmers) are livelihood zones (i) Central Maize-Cotton, (ii) ofRailCommercialFarming,(iii) ProvinceCashCrop, (iv)Chongwe-Nyimba Line Eastern Plateau, and (v) Mkushi Commercial Block. Ingeneral, these livelihood zones coincide to agro- ecological Zone I1along the "line-of-rail" and main road infrastructure. Together these zones account for about 3.6 million out o f an estimated 10.5 million Zambians (about one-third o f all rural and urban residents). Another way to identify higher potential areas for smallholder commercialization emerges from the 2005 Crop Forecast Survey data which indicates that smallholder cash crop production i s dominated by a few districts which are concentrated in the Zone I1part of Eastern Province (Lundazi, Chipata, Chadiza, Katete and Petauke districts) and line o f rail districts of Kapiri Mposhi, Chibombo and Mumbwa in Central Province, western parts o f Chongwe in Lusaka province and Mazabuka, Monze and Choma districts in Southern Province. These districts overlap closely to the livelihood zones associated with a higher prevalence o f commercial smallholder agricultural activities as defined by the V A C National Livelihood Zone Map. The combination o f small and large commercial farmers, relatively good agro-ecological and infrastructure conditions, and the proximity to major urban markets make this the most "dynamic" agricultural area inZambia at the present time. Additional Information on Smallholder Assets, Livelihood Strategies and Well-Being" Socio-demographics. Poor rural households are significantly larger than non-poor households. The average household size of top consumption quintile was 5.5 people compared to 7.5 people inbottom quintile (40 percent larger than top quintile). There i s a strong association between education levels o f household heads and household consumption levels. The relationship i s consistent across the distribution. Household heads in top consumption quintile have in average 7 years o f schooling compared to 4.7 years inbottom quintile. The poorest households also had significantly higher dependency ratio compared to better-off households. Access to road infrastructure and social services. There is surprisingly little variation inmedian distances to markets and public transport by consumption quintiles. More than half o f rural households in Zambia are located within five kilometers o f public transportation, but it i s not "The data presentedinthis subsection are based on the 2002-03 LivingConditions Monitoring Survey and the Zambia PVA (2005). It is assumed for the purpose o f this study that rural household inthe top consumption quintiles possess more likely the characteristics of successfil commercializing smallholders 12 possible to evaluate whether available transportation could serve to transport agricultural products to a market. According to the PVA (2005), the mediandistance to a food market i s 10 kilometers, but it i s not known if these markets are integrated with the national economy. Median distances seem large for agricultural input markets (25 km) selling equipment and fertilizer needed for modem agriculture. Access to land- household and per capita resources. Land is generally plentiful in Zambia and quantity o f land i s not likely to be a bindingconstraint on production. Only a negligible fraction o f rural households (4 percent) listed insufficient land as a reason for their poverty. Given the low levels o f farm mechanization, one household can, on average, cultivate up to 2 hectares o f land with handhoe and about 4 hectares using oxen. Differences between the poor and non-poor rural households are better explained by the availability o f labor in these household than by overall access to land. Land usepatterns. Average total landworked varies little by quintile, but better-off households average use more than twice as much non-food cropland as the poorest households. The smaller households in the richest quintile also work twice as much total landper capita as the poorest households. As pointed out previously, labor constraints (and lack o f other assets that increase productivity) are more likely to bebindingthan land constraints (see Table 4). Source: ZambiaPVA (ZOOS) Table 5 presents a breakdown o f household crop and livestock activities. Most households inall quintiles grow at least some maize. Substantial fractions o f households also grow cassava, millet, sweet potatoes, and groundnuts. There is substantial differentiation in crop choices by rich and poor for cassava, which i s grown by half o f the poorest households but just over a quarter o f the richest households, and hybridmaize, grown by 11percent o f the bottom quintile and 28 percent o f the top. Among the relatively few households with non-food crops, cotton and sunflower are dominant. Nine percent o f those in the poorest quintile grow at least some non- food crops, compared to 13 percent overall. There i s little variation incrop diversity by quintile. 13 Quintileof NationalDistribution All Poorest 2 3 4 Richest 20% 20% At leas one food crop 93% 94% 96% 95% 92% 89% At leas one cash crop 13% 9% 14% 16% 15% 13% Cotton 9% 6% 7% 10% 10% 9% Tobacco 1% 0% 2% 2% 1Yo 1% Paprika 4 % 0% 0% 0% 0% 1% Sunflower 5% 3% 6% 5% 5% 4% Source: Zambia PYA (2005) About 71 percent o f rural households reported the ownership o f some livestock. A clear difference by quintile i s seen only for cattle ownership: 19 percent o f households in the top quintile having cattle compared to 11percent o f those in the bottom quintile. Cattle are more likely to be found in Central, Eastern, Lusaka, and Southern Provinces - Ago-Ecological Zone 11,which points to correlation betweenassets, livelihoods andlocation. Sources of livelihoods. Some 80 percent o f rural Zambian households have farming as the principal activity o f household head. However, people at the top o f the distribution are slightly less likely to be engaged in agriculture; 71 percent o f household heads in the richest quintile report farming as their main activity compared to 83 percent in bottom quintile (see Table 6). These results o f the PVA (2005) suggest that wage- and self-employment are perhaps more important determinants of household welfare than ability to farm. Non-farm income sources are likely to remain important determinants for householdwealth inrural areas. 14 Recent Trends in Smallholder Production and Marketing Changes inZambia's agricultural sector duringthe 1990swere driven bypolicy reforms aimed at market and trade liberalization, while others stem from factors such as changing conditions in international commodity markets and recurring droughts. These changes have had different impacts on technology adoption, enterprise mixes, profitability, and market orientation on different types o f farmers". Below we highlight some o f the changes that are relevant to smallholder commercialization. Shifts in Production Patterns and Yields Smallholder agricultural production i s still concentrated ingrains and staple foods. However, the demise of maize marketing arrangements and rising cost o f fertilizers led many smallholders - especially those in more remote areas - to shift to low-input technologies and increased production o f alternative staple crops for home consumption. This shift has been quite pronounced in Northern Province, where agro-ecological conditions do not favor maize production and transport costs are high. Maize continues to dominate agriculture, but its relative importance has declined. It currently makes up about the quarter o f the total value o f crop output, down from two-fifth in mid 1990s. Major shifts in production patterns have taken place into cassava. Cassava requires no purchased inputs and can produce good yields in a wide variety o f soil-water conditions (including drought). Its flexible plantingand harvesting calendar make cassava one o f the easiest crops for labor-constrained households. Land planted to groundnuts (which have a relatively high value per weight), increased by almost 50 percent between 1990 and 2004. Sorghum and millet plantings (mostly produced by smallholders) increased during the mid-1990s but leveled off and even declined since. A major shift in crop production by smallholders has been the significant increase in land planted to cotton, a largest export crop, which almost doubled between 1990 and 2004 period. There was also significant increases in other smallholder cash crops, such as Burley tobacco, paprika, and other crops, although on much smaller scale. World Bank,2003b 15 Emergence of New Production Technologies and Marketing Arrangements Part and parcel o fthe changes inproductionpatterns andyields since the 1990s has beentwo important phenomena: (i) conservation farming and (ii) outgrowers schemes. Both o f private these phenomena are responses to the demise o fpublic sector support for the agricultural sector and the multipleproduction and marketingconstraints facing Zambia's farmingcommunity. Consewation Farming. Conservation farming (CF) in Zambia i s a locally adopted variant o f traditional minimumtillage technologies adopted inmany parts o f Sub-Saharan Africa12. CF has gained popularity in the 1990s in response to market liberalization and the perceived needs to increase fertilizer efficiency, better conserve and manage water resources, increase productivity, and also to spread labor more evenly over the year. CF technologies and implements have been developed for hand-hoe and oxen landpreparation. It i s important to note that minimumtillage i s not synonymous with "low-input" agricultural production. In many cases there i s need for increased labor and outlays on improved seeds and fertilizers. This i s a reason behind the fact that the highest adoption rates o f CF inZambia have actually beenby commercial and emergent farmers. A recent review o fCF inZambia points out that it is hardto estimate the number o f smallholders that have adopted CF, because many adopt some components and not others. It is estimated that between 20,000 and 75,000 Zambian farmers currently benefit from increased yield and incomes under conservation farming. In addition, there is some evidence that smallholders who participate in CF receive extra extension support as well as input packages o f high-yielding variety (HYV) seeds and fertilizers. Private Sector Outgrower Schemes. Since mid-1990s, there has been increased participation o f smallholder farmers in cash crop production as a result o f development o f outgrower schemes. Infact, outgrower schemes have become the main means for Zambian smallholders to become engaged in commercial agriculture. In these schemes, a commercial f d f a r m e r or an agribusiness entity enters into a business partnership with smallholders, to produce commodities o f high value to be marketed by the entrepreneur. The essence o f the agreement is that the entrepreneur provides the smallholder the necessary technical advice and inputs to produce an agreed product and a guaranteed market outlet for the produce. The smallholder, from hisiher side, i s contracted to produce the agreed commodity and sell it to the entrepreneur. These schemes (both rainfed and irrigated) are expanding rapidly in the country, although most outgrower schemes operate in areas with good infrastructure and close to urban centers, given their relatively better accessibility and market proximity, creating a suitable condition for the cooperationbetween smallholders and entrepreneurs. The proliferation o f outgrower schemes in Zambia can be viewed as a response to the collapse o f state-supported agricultural systems (e.g., input supply, guaranteed output markets, credit, technical assistance) and the lack o f well- functioning private market networks to fill the void. 12As applied inZambia, CT involves apackage of several key practices: dry-season landpreparationusing minimumtillage (rather than plowing after the first rains), crop residue retention(instead ofburning), seedand fertilizer application infixed planting stations (rather than spreading), and nitrogen fixing crop rotations and fallows (rather than continuous production o f crops such as maize and cotton). See Bwalya, 1999; Haggblade and Tembo, 2003. 16 The highest concentration o f outgrower schemes is in Lusaka Province, followed by Southern, Central, Eastern and Copperbelt provinces. It is estimated that in 2003/04 about one-third o f smallholders participated in some form o f out-grower scheme arrangements. Most o f these farmers (some 85 percent) are engaged in cotton production. Smallholders produce also the majority of cotton lint inZambia (some 98 percent). Burley tobacco i s another cash crop which i s produced mainly by smallholders. Other cash crops which are produced largely by smallholders include paprikdchili and honey. For other export crops, smallholders produce about 40 percent o f country's sugar and 5 percent o f coffee. Furthermore, smallholders make up a small, but steadily increasing share o f dairy production (about 20 percent). Table 7 provides information about various outgrower schemes inZambia. Number of small-scale Commodity farmers Area (ha) Production Cotton 250,000 254,000 170,000 tons 15,389 11,228 18,800 tons Honev 10.000 47.000 km2 380 tons ~~~ Oilseeds b' 2,500 61,500 tons Dairy 1,000 5,000 milkers 2.5 -98,000 3 million liters Coffee 250 200 500 tons estimated 36 tondweek indry Vegetables 85 100 period Despite the relative success, outgrower schemes in Zambia are facing increasing challenges in sustaining their competitiveness. The main challenges relate to low and declining productivity levels o f smallholder production systems, high rates o f loan delinquency and non-payment and rampant ~ide-selling/buying'~This has ledto agribusiness companies to reduce their investments inextension. As ariskminimization strategy, outgrower promoters resort to increase the supply o f smallholder production to fill their processing capacities through horizontal development o f outgrower schemes, growing raw material volumes through increasing the number of smallholder farmers or land area, rather than investing into increased productivity. Summary Most o f Zambia's smallholders produce primarily for home-consumption. Surpluses are sold in the community or marketed outside the community. Also, to get cash quickly, many smallholders sell their produce after harvest and then buy food staples in small quantities over l3 Side-selling i s when contracted farmers do not sell their outputs to the provider of inputs on credit, as stipulated. 17 the year. Commercial production by smallholders is agricultural production primarilyproduced to be sold in markets outside the community. Thus, an external market i s needed, along with logistical support to make the accompanyingtransactions. For smallholders to use agriculture as a poverty reducing strategy, they must increase returns to landby intensifying use o f labor and/or capital (including multiple cropping). Lacking capital and having labor, labor-intensive high- value (Le., high returns to land) agricultural enterprises are needed for smallholders. This does not meanthat commercializing smallholders should abandon production o f food staples, it means that they need to expand production o f cash crops and/or livestock. Increasing productivity of food staples i s an important means to provide incentives to smallholders to expand cash crop production (since less land and labor need to be devoted to staples). When considering the potential for smallholder commercialization, it i s important to recognize that Zambian smallholders are not homogeneous group o f farmers. Some rural households are located inhigher (or lower) areas o f economic potential, whereas some households have higher (or lower) potential based on their asset portfolio^'^ and livelihood strategies. As such, some smallholders are better positioned to become market oriented, while a significant proportion can not be expected to be transformed into market-oriented production units. At the same time, many rural households will not directly benefit from agricultural commercialization and will require safety nets. These "ultra poor" households should benefit from increased availability (and possibly lower cost and increased quality) o f agricultural products produced by other households. Another group o f smallholders might be able to achieve food security and more diversified incomes over time, with appropriate assistance. However, even smallholders with the most potential to become market-oriented will require significant assistance to make the transformation into commercial farmers. l4Household assets are broadly defined to include natural, physical, human, financial and social capital. 18 Chapter3 KeyIssues andConstraintsfor Smallholder Commercialization There are numerous constraints to the development o f small and medium scale agricultural production inZambia. Some o f these constraints are specific to smallholders, while others affect larger commercial farmers and agribusinesses". Since most value chains where smallholders participate have largely evolved through investments made primarilyby the private sector, issues that affect smallholders are closely related to broader issues faced by private sector in Zambia - inthe agricultural sector and other sectors. Because of the close linkages between smaller and larger farms and agribusinesses inthe commercialization o f smallholders, it is therefore difficult to separate these constraints. Furthermore, many o f the constraints are actually multi-sectoral in their nature and which lie beyond the domain o f the MAC0 and agricultural sector. This could limit effectiveness of some sector or commodity specific interventions to overcome the constraints for smallholder commercialization. Issues Related to Low Farm-level Productivity of Smallholders In most smallholder sub-sectors in Zambia, productivity levels are well below their potential. This is the case for staple crops (e.g., maize, groundnuts) and the cash crops reviewed in the outgrower case studies. Low productivity and low returns to labor and land lead to the chronically low levels o f farm incomes for smallholders. For smallholders to commercialize, they must break this cycle of low productivity and returns to labor and land. Furthermore, low and declining smallholder yields o f cash crops lead to inadequate raw material supply for other actors in the value chain. Lack o f raw material supply to fill industry processing capacities results in higher costs o f managing the value chains. This, in turn, reduces the overall profitability and competitiveness o fthese chains. The causes for low levels o f smallholder productivity are multi-dimensional and inter-related. The main constraints affecting the low levels o f productivity o f smallholder production systems are: (i)weak business orientation o f Zambian smallholders; (ii)lack o f public market infrastructure and support mechanisms which hampers private sector provision o f goods and services to smallholders; (iii)incomplete implementation o f public policies which result in under-provision o f public goods and services, such as extension and research, and (iv) weak capacity to manage risks. Weak Business Orientation of Smallholders One o f the greatest constraints facing Zambian smallholders i s the lack o f business oriented approach to farming. This argument i s applied to all commodity sub-sectors; even in smallholder export vegetables, which demonstrates a significantly higher than average commercial capacity o f smallholder farmers. The roots o f this problem are complex and come l5SeetheSACSoutgrowercasestudiesbackgroundreportsforsub-sectorspecific issuesandconstraints. 19 partly from many `hard to measure' cultural and attitudinal factors associated with farming. The P V A (2005) points out that Zambian smallholders lack a business oriented approach to farming, since most view agriculture as a way o f life and not as a business16. This has not changed much in spite of a significant donor support which has been provided for farmer capacity building. There i s a history o f dependency by smallholders on others to carry out the commercial activities associated with agricultural production and marketing while they focus on the productive activities. Services that smallholders receive from outgrower schemes are similar to those received in the past from government-supported programs that provided inputs, markets for outputs, credit and technical assistance. Thus, although some smallholders might have experience with commercial agriculture, this does not mean they are commercially-oriented. Lack of Public Market Infrastructure and Support Mechanisms With the declining public resources for agriculture inZambia, inmany cases, the private sector has taken over functions o f the public sector, such as provision o f extension services related to both production and marketing (e.g., information on production technologies and markets). However, despite some success, the private sector has not been able to fill the gap left by declining public funding for extension services and agricultural research, largely because o f lack o f public market infrastructure and support mechanisms (e.g., regulatory and legal framework) which hampers private sector provision of goods and services to smallholders. There are two major forms o f private sector extension services. First are the technical advisory services provided by outgrower companies to smallholders with whom they have contractual arrangements. The second are specialized services provided by some public-private "commodity trusts", such as Cotton Development Trust (CDT), Livestock Development Trust (LDT) and Zambia Export Growers Association (ZEGA)Training Trust, andNGOs, which provide advisory services mainly through intermediary arrangements (usually with the support o f donor funding) to smallholder groups who may or may not have production agreements with agri-business enterprises. In Zambia, significant improvements in yields and farm productivity are possible by adopting better farm management practices. That is, there i s scope to greatly increase yields at the,current levels o f input use. A key missing input, however, i s related to human capital - basic farm management skills. For example, in cotton and paprika sector, evidence provided by outgrower operations shows that it i s possible to increase yields by 30 percent and more under the current rain-fed conditions by changing farm management practices o f smallholders without increasing the levels o f current input use and changing seed varieties. Productive assets, such as oxen and irrigation all help to improve farm productivity, but smallholders need to also master basic farm management skills, and become more entrepreneurial with a strong commitment to profit oriented farm management. Providing extension services to a large number o f smallholders who are dispersed over large land areas i s costly. Poor road infrastructure further increases the overhead cost o f extension and l6Authors who have written on this include among others Parker and Mwape (2004); Skonsburg(2003); Franciset. al. (1997); Milimo, Shilito andBrock (2000); and Chiwele and Sikananu(2004). 20 technical advisory services. The provision o f public goods, such as extension, by private agri- business companies has the same high transactions costs as public provision, but private providers also face high risks when trying to capture some o f the associated benefits. High business risks, such as side-selling and side-buying associated with a failure o f smallholders to honour agreements to deliver produce to the company who provided them services, high levels o f crime and weak law enforcement (including contract enforcement) all prevent agribusinesses to recover full cost o f service provided to smallholders, which discourages them to invest into extension services (public goods). As a result, most private outgrower operators, especially those dealing with cotton, tobacco and paprika have focused on horizontal development to meet capacity requirements o f their processing facilities or markets. Instead o f deepening relationships with a small number o f "better farmers", they have attempted to increase the number o f smallholder farmers producing the crop to offset the impact o f low yields and poor quality. Therefore, outgrower schemes have opted on working with smallholders who are located in areas with relatively good infrastructure access, as opposed to working with smallholders who have the highest capacity to become commercially oriented. The exceptions are sugar and coffee outgrower schemes, which for reasons disussed elsewhere in this report, have resorted to working with a small number o f farmers who have a sronger capability to grow these crops on a commercial basisI7. Incomplete Implementation of Public Policies Public good nature o f extension services justifies a role for Government to fill this gap. However, rather than addressing the issues related to the lack o f public market infrastructure and support mechanisms through increased finding for extension, research and other long-term public investments, Government has traditionally opted to make interventions in the supply of inputs and in crop marketing arrangements - which are primarily driven by short-term political interests. Therefore, Government persists with interventions in activities usually associated with private sector provision, and neglected interventions associated with provision o f public goods and services. This cycle needs to be broken and appropriate public and private sector roles identified and strengthened. It is possible to observe how the effectiveness o f public extension services in Zambia is hampered by chronic under-funding due to the crowding-out effect o f largely politically motivated expenditures. The total MACO agricultural budget increased nearly 70 percent between 2004 and 2006 in nominal terms**, however, almost two-thirds o f this budget was allocated to the Fertilizer Support Program (FSP) and the crop marketing arrangements for the FoodReserve Agency (FRA), while investments critical for increasing farm productivity, such as "Preliminaryfindingsoftheon-goingBankESWonthe `SPSManagementandZambia's Ago-FoodTrade', highlightthat, at this point intime, SPS measures of trading partners are not constraining factors for Zambian agricultural exports. The issue related to smallholder commercialization i s low product quality which results from oor management, but this i s not necessarily a SPS issue. 78 The main difference between 2006 budget and previous years i s that it includes additional allocation of ZK210 billion for Agricultural Development Programs which i s essentially projected disbursements from various donor fbnded programs and projects (not shown in the table) and which operate largely outside o f MACO structures. It is not clear how these figures were derived, as it includes several donors funded projects which may not become even effective during the budget year. 21 irrigation infrastructure, received only 5 percent o f the budget. Operating costs under which research and extension fall received only 10percent o f the budget in2006 (see Table 8). Within agriculture budget which was allocated to Poverty Reduction Programs (PW) (about 70 percent o f the total agriculture budget) the FSP and FRA crop marketing expenditures accounted for 93 percent in2006, up from 88 percent in2004, while the share o f expenditures to productive investmentshas declined accordingly. 2004 Share 2005 Share 2006 Share Personal Emoluments 57 24% 74 22% 84 21% Recurrent Departmental Charges 10 4% 39 12% 39 10% Grants and Other Payments 6 3% 4 1% 6 2% Poverty Reduction Programs 162 222 269 Fertilizer Support Program 96 41% 142 42% 199 50% Strategic Foodreserves 47 20% 59 17% 50 13% Y Other PRP Programs 18 8% 21 6% 20 5% Total 236 339 398 Ifthe smallholder productivity is to be improved, there is a need for a larger share of public expendituresfor agriculture to be allocated to the provision ofpublic goods and services, such as extension, agricultural research, and productive investments (e.g., irrigation). The private sector can not be expected to fill the gap which was left by under-fundingo f these goods and services. Subsidies for farm inputs have little impact on the smallholder productivity if they are not supplemented by changes in farming practices. However, it is unlikely Government will withdraw completely from the market for agricultural inputs. Providing subsidized fertilizer and seed i s one o f the few levers the government has to foster the deep rooted patronage system of political favors and to mobilize rural voteslg. The current FSP program was supposed to be phased out by 2005, but the Government has decided to continue it throughout 2006 in light of general elections. Weak Capacity to Manage Risks Zambia's smallholders face several risks that directly affect productivitg'. T he major risks are related to climate (e.g., rainfall), while others stem from markets (e.g., prices, access), and health (illness, death). Inrecent years, weather related risks have had a major impact. There i s a close link betweenrainfall and recorded agricultural GDP growth rates inZambia. Since 1990, about three out o f every 5 years have essentially been drought years in Zambia. Droughts occurred in 1991/2, 1994, 1995, 1997, 1999,2000,2001, and 2002. The occurrence and impact o f droughts is not equally distributed over the country. Southern and Western Provinces have been most severely impacted, but there are even differences within these provinces and also areas in other "See DFID(2003). 2o SeedelNinno and Marini, (2005) 22 provinces that have suffered from droughts inrecent years. Although the volatility o fproduction due to droughts is larger among smallholders, even crops which are grown predominantly by commercial farmers (including wheat, soybeans, and Virginia tobacco) also exhibit significant year-to-year variability. The weather related risks have direct impact on household choice o f productions systems and willingness to participate in commercial agriculture activities. Over 90 percent o f Zambia's smallholder crop production i s rainfed. Thus, rainfall i s a critical factor for selecting crops, their planting time, the timing and intensity o f input and labor use, and subsequent yields. Yield fluctuations from unpredictable rainfall are a major risk to smallholders. For example, paprika production, which is carried out under rain-fed conditions has shown significant vulnerability to prevailing weather conditions in different growing seasons, especially in recent years. Uncertainty with regard to the onset o f the rains and dry spells often result in a rather hazardous planning o f the production cycle. The late onset o f the rains results in a late start in land preparation and planting that, inturn, shortens growing period for the crop (with the smaller and less developed plants achieving lower yields). Dry spells, especially when occurring in crucial stages o f plant development such as flower setting, result in stress o f the plants (with possible shedding o f flowers and consequent lower yields). An early end to the rains can stunt plant growth and result in lower yields. Issues Relatedto Profitability of Value Chains Associated to the low levels o f farm productivity i s the low (and/or fluctuating) profitability o f commodity sub-sectors where smallholders participate. Part o f the reason i s increasing competition in international markets and declining (and/or fluctuating) international commodity prices. As a small country producer, international commodity price trends are well beyond the control o f Zambianfirms and Government. With respect to national level factors, key constraints that affect profitability o f value chains are: uncertainty; (ii) (i)weak regulatoryenvironment, especially as itrelates to contract enforcement andpolic high financing costs and low access to credit, especially for term financing 2?, (iii)macroeconomic instability, inparticular exchange rate instability; and(iv) poor stateof transport infrastructure. It should be noted that these constraints are also beyond the narrow domain o f the agriculture sector (Le. MACO) and require a concerted efforts from all relevant line agencies to solve them (Le. BOZ, MOWS, MOTC). These constraints are discussed below. 21Although relevant to access to finance, security o f landtenure interms o f collateral does not seem to be a binding constraint for smallholder commercialization inZambia. It is, however, a major constraint for the development o f large-scale commercial farming. The Zambia PSIA (Jorgensen and Loudjeva, 2005) indicates that usufruct rights, when well defined and stable, neednot deter investment; nor i s a title a sufficient condition for investment. The PSIA points out, that landi s poor collateral inremote rural areas. It will not solve the issue o f smallholder access to formal banking institutions, hence title, by itself, does little good inthis cases. Most rural households inZambia can receive small loans on informal basis without collateral. 23 WeakRegulatory Environment and Policy Uncertainty In general, private sector enterprises operating in Zambia face an unfavorable business climate characterized by regulatory uncertainty and poor administration; weakly implemented and enforced policies; high regulatory compliance costs; widespread prevalence o f corruption and rent-seeking behavior; weak law enforcement and basic security issues (e.g., high incidence o f crime, theft and disorder); weak judiciary system and law enforcement." These factors increase the costs o f providing services to smallholders and reduce the profitability and competitiveness o f value chains. A major issue facing outgrower operators working with smallholders is the high risk o fcredit default and side selling. This is further compoundedbyweak contract enforcement andjudiciary system, which i s not capable or willing to prosecute violators ina court o f law. The policy environment for agriculture sector in Zambia is generally conducive towards agricultural commercialization interms o f official pronouncements of policy support. However, reality does not always follow the rhetoric. The main issues are related to poor administration and implementation o f existing policies (which i s driven largely by politically motivated decisions), which results inthe continuing uncertainty (and uncertain signals) inthe mind of the Government as to the division o f roles between itselfand the private sector inrelation to markets and the provision o f services. Instability in the sectoral policy environment affects both agribusinesses and commercial farmers and those smallholders who participate in outgrower schemes. As an example, periodic ad hoc interventions inmaize markets and interventions inthe fertilizer markets conflict with the government's stated goals o f market orientation and reduction in distortionary interventions as stated in the ACP and NAP. Furthermore, import duties for agricultural commodities, export bans on maize (Le. under the auspices o f food security concerns) and VAT exceptions for agricultural goods are often applied on ad-hoc basis and are in constant change o f flux. The Government has created a new institutional framework to address the issues related to business environment and has set up PSD reform Steering Committee (March 2005). The Steering Committee has narrowed the priority reforms from a list o f 76 to three, which includes reducing administrative barriers for doing business. However, while the overall institutional framework for PSD has improved more recently, the question reminds about the Government's commitment to the reforms, as demonstrated by continuation o f policy instabilities (both at the macro and (multi) sectoral levels). Furthermore, the political economy surrounding the reform agenda i s increasingly important. The general attitudes toward the private sector are negative in Zambia, and this i s exacerbated by: (i)the negative image o f privatization; and (ii)the widespread belief (amongst citizens, civil servants and politicians) that recent growth is benefiting foreigners whilst Zambians are increasinglypoor. While some might argue that this i s not true, the perception carries a great deal o f weight which could explain the weak political commitment to policy reforms. ''See the World Bank Investment Climate Assessment (World Bank, 2004b) and "Doing Business Indicators" publication. For example, according to the Zambia Investment Climate Assessment, security costs o fZambian firms are inaverage twice as highas inthe region and Zambian enterprises losses due to crime are inaverage three times as high as regional average. 24 Cost of Financing and Access to Finance The cost of financing and access to finance are largely a macroeconomic issues which are closely related to Government's fiscal discipline. Despite evidence o f downward trends in interest rates inrecent years, current levels of nominal and real interest rates inKwacha terms are still very high and a considerable constraint to borrowers in the agricultural sector. According to ACF survey results, about 85 percent o f outgrower operators in Zambia identified the high cost o f capital as one o f the major constraints to expansion o f their schemesz3. Apart from persistently high inflation rates, another reason for high interest rates is continuing (although declining) Government borrowing from commercial banks, which drives up base lending rates o f commercial banks. Since Government financial instruments are risk free, they are considered more secure means o f earning profits by commercial banks than private lending. As a result, there is insufficient and slow re-allocation o f loan resources to the productive sectors (Le. crowding out the private sector). For example, inAugust 2005, Government still accounted for about 50 percent of total commercial bank lending, although this is a decrease from 64 percent in 2003. The private sector's share was only 38 percent in2005, but an increase from 26 percent in 2003. A second issue related to the credit system in Zambia is access to the medium and long term financing. Provision o f medium and long-term credit i s currently limited due to lack o f appropriate sources o f funds in commercial banks. In view o f the short-term nature o f the commercial banks' deposit fbnds, virtually all commercial bank lending to agriculture is directed towards short-term credits. Banks lack sources o f funds, which would enable them to offer appropriately priced and structured credits to the agricultural sector. Some banks which are able to access lines o f credit from international money markets do so at the cost o f LIBOR plus 6 percent country risk, which i s viewed as too expensive by agricultural stakeholders, especially after adding all other banking fees. A third issue is that virtually all commercial banks inZambia require rigorous credit appraisal procedures and satisfactory tangible security to secure the facilities to be granted. Again, this disproportionately affects SMEs and smaller farmers who are often not able to meet these banks' lending criteria. For example, according to the Zambia I C A survey (2003), enterprises in Zambia need in average twice the amount o f collateral to secure the loans from commercial banks than their counterparts inthe region. However, the issue o f credit inZambia needs to be viewed inthe broader context o f the tradition o f borrowers' unwillingness to service debts and repay loans, which i s a historic legacy o f bad credit culture. Small-scale borrowers, including SMEs and smallholders, continue to be among the worst culprits. Banks and other financial institutions have responded by being hesitant to extend credit to these groups as they are regarded as too risky. Furthermore, agriculture i s characterized by relatively low profitability and highrisks (e.g., price and weather fluctuations) associated compared to other sectors. In addition, there are high transactions costs associated with services to small producers. 23This is consistent to the findings ofthe Zambia Investment Climate Assessment (World Bank, 2004b)' which identified high cost of capital as the most important constraint to business operations for enterprises. 25 Exchange Rate Instability Exchange rate instability is the is the single most important macroeconomic issue which will continue to affect the export competitiveness and profitability o f agricultural value chains, as well as the livelihoods o f thousands o f smallholders. The most recent example o f this is the sudden appreciation o f Kwacha against major currencies at the end o f 2005, which undermines the gains in agricultural exports which were made over the last decade. A number o f factors have contributed to this appreciation, including (i)a sizable upswing inworld copper prices and new investments indomestic miningproduction; (ii) debt relief and foreign aid inflows; and (iii) large inflows o f foreign portfolio investment, largelyinto Government bonds. These developments (Le. some 30 percent revaluation) have raised a concern over reduced export competitiveness o f agriculture sector and the possible reemergence o f the country's long- standing "Dutch Disease" issue24. As the profit margins for many agricultural products are already very small due to low levels o f farm productivity, the sudden strengthening o f the Kwacha will inevitably lead to many o f smallholder operations and/or exporters becoming unprofitable. For example, it has been estimated that growth invalue o f agricultural exports may fall by almost seven percent per year, as a result o f current exchange rate appreciation and agricultural export sector i s expected to contract at annual rate o f 2 percent between 2006 and 2010 (IFPRI, 2006). It could have a significant negative impact on smallholder incomes, since almost one third o f smallholder household in Zambia derive some share o f their incomes from the production o fvarious export products25. The effect o f the exchange rate appreciation on the viability o f outgrower operations depends on the extent to which they are dependent upon Kwacha-based expenses. Where these are not reduced in line with Kwacha appreciation, as in the case for example o f labor and locally produced inputs, the effects o f appreciation are more damaging. Where these costs are more foreign exchange based, as with overseas marketing or imported capital equipment, the effects are less damaging. For this reason, exports o f flowers which have little, if any, linkages to smallholders remain relatively insulated from the effects o f a Kwacha appreciation while the profitability o f export honey production where all production costs are local (labor, hives and other equipment) are highly sensitive to exchange rate appreciation, followed by cotton, sugar, and tobacco where the local content o f production cost i s higher then 50 percent (Figure 1). Figure 1: Localinput share in totalcost 24 The term "Dutch disease" was named after events that occurred inthe Netherlands during the 1970s following the discovery o f natural gas under the North Sea. Dutch disease i s an economic phenomenon that can be triggered by sudden large inflows o f foreign currency. Dutch disease i s often associated with exports o f natural resources, but strictly speaking the foreign currency inflows can come from any source, including foreign aid. In a country affected by Dutch disease, the inflows o f foreign currency causes the value o f country's currency to rise, making domestically produced manufactured goods and agricultural commodities less competitive compared to imported goods and commodities. Imports consequently increase, and (non-resource) exports decrease, resulting in reduced domestic economic activity. Dutch disease weakens the economy when the sectors that are crowded out are vital to the country and poverty reduction. For example, it is expected that prices paid by cotton outgrower companies to smallholders have to be reduced by 20 percent inorder for Zambian cotton exports to remaincompetitive at the world markets. This would equal to net income loss o f Kwacha 420 million for Zambian smallholders. 26 In 100% IIn -m s 80% I0 I 60% 5m P? 40% CI 3 -m sQ 20% -00 0% Source: ZNFU (2006) There are limited short-term opportunities for smallholders and outgrower operators to reduce costs and improve productivity in order to compensate for strengthening o f the Zambian Kwacha. Given high transport costs and high administrative costs o f doing business, Zambian exporters have already become very efficient at international markets. Eventually, the only way for agro-businesses to survive inthis environment i s to reduce farm gate prices for smallholders and/or reduce the scale o f operation inmore marginal areas. Poor State of Transport Infrastructure Zambia i s a large landlocked country with relatively unreliable and expensive access to ports; be they inTanzania or Mozambique (or South Africa). Improving transport infrastructure i s critical for improving the provision o f services to smallholders, both private and public, and improving the general competitiveness and profitability o f smallholder supply chains. For example, the ACF survey o f outgrowers in Zambia identified the poor state o f rural roads network as one of the major constraints for outgrower operators to expand their schemes - 75 percent of respondents considered it as important or very important issue. Smallholders in Zambia are dispersed throughout the country, many located far from the main trunk roads. The lack ofdirect port access, the poor state o frural infrastructure, andthe physical dispersion o f smallholders all make the marketing o f agricultural inputs and outputs more expensive. Furthermore, many rural roads are inbad condition and often not passable duringthe rainy season.26 Private traders therefore tend to concentrate their business to the line-of-rail and 26Zambia has about 67,700 kmo f roads, including about 31,000 kmo f feeder roads. The high proportion of feeder roads i s attributed to the large land area o f the country and the corresponding long distances involved in linking main roads and population centers, and circumventing the many geographicalftopographicalobstacles. The feeder road system in Zambia i s rudimentary at best and exacts a heavy toll on collection units that have to retrieve the produce. About 80 percent o f feeder roads inZambia are inpoor or very poor condition. This imposes high costs to private agribusinesses and outgrower scheme operators along value chains, such as provision o f services to smallholders, collection their produce, and processing and marketing. 27 other main trunk roads, leaving farmers in remote areas without reliable service. These factors contribute to high transaction costs and uncertainty about markets, and have had a negative impact on Zambia's competitiveness ininternational commodity markets. Summary This chapter has highlighted issues related to low on-farm productivity and profitability o f private value chains. As noted, because o f the linkages between smaller and larger farms and agribusinesses in the commercialization o f smallholders, it i s difficult to separate issues and constraints which affect these groups. In addition, many of the issues are multi-sectoral intheir nature and lay beyond the narrow domains o f commodity sectors. This could limit the effectiveness o f commodity specific policies and investments to overcome constraints for smallholder commercialization. It also requires much greater long-term strategic planning and cooperation among Government ministries, the public andprivate sectors, and among donors. '28 Chapter 4 AgribusinessSupportto Smallholders: Analysis of Outgrower Schemes Introduction Outgrower arrangements are becoming an increasingly important aspect o f smallholder commercialization inZambia2'. The approach seems to have considerable potential because the sector i s characterized by a large number o f smallholder households and many o f the arrangements under outgrower schemes are similar to past relations with the Government who provided support services like extension, credit and market outlets. With the decline o f public services many o f these smallholders would no longer be able to be engaged in commercial farming activities without access to the services provided by agribusinesses. The oldest formal outgrower schemes in Zambia are those in the cotton and tobacco sectors. More recent entries in the arena o f outgrower schemes are paprika and honey, which have developed initially at the initiative o f and largely with internal finding from the private sector, with, at some later stage, limited government (under PRSP) and donor support for a select number o f outgrower promoters. The third category o f outgrower schemes are those in the coffee and vegetable sectors, which have been largely donor driven. A separate case i s that of the sugar sub-sector, which is example o fnucleus estatemodel. The main motivation for the outgrower promoters for starting outgrower schemes i s twofold. For enterprises without their own production base, outsourcing production to smallholders i s their only opportunity to collect raw material for hrther processing and exports. Others use outgrower arrangements to bulk smallholder production with their own production base. In Zambia, outgrower schemes take a variety o f forms depending on the crop, objectives and resources o f the outgrower scheme promoter, and the experience o f farmers. Inmost cases, the promoter provides support the production of the crop by smallholders, purchases the crop from these farmers, and then processes, packages and markets the product, thereby controlling its quality. The level o f involvement o f the contracting company in production may vary from the provision o f correct type o f seed, seedlings and agrochemicals to support inlandpreparation, and even harvesting services. The following sections provide a more detailed description o f the types and implementation arrangements o f outgrower operations inZambia. Mode of operation There are three basic types o f outgrower arrangements (models) inZambia to organize their field operations and credit delivery activities. In a way they represent the level of evolution that the diverse commodity chains have been able to develop over time. 21See Annex 1 for the detailed account o frecent dynamics o f the mainsmallholder commodity sub-sectors, including the development of outgrower schemes. 29 Model 1: Centralized System This model is based on the company's (promoter's) own field network and staff managing the entire outgrower operation. The model is normally used for crops for which relatively high quality standards apply, and which therefore require good on-farm management practices and high levels o f supervision from outgrower companies to ensure that quality standards and requirements are met. It is being used mainly in paprika sector, but also by some tobacco and cotton outgrowers. Under this model the outgrower operators aim to have a hands-on control over the input delivery and extension services as a means to secure adequate volumes o f high quality raw material. A comprehensive field network for service delivery also makes it possible to deliver specific extension messages to smallholders in order to collect adequate volumes of raw material, according to the desired quality standards. Under this model farmers are organized into informal groups or clubs o f about 20-25 farmers (e.g. paprika sector) as a channel for input distribution, dissemination o f technical support, and marketing arrangements. Farmer groups are mostly `interest groups' and are rarely established formal cooperatives or associations2*. Individual contracts are sometimes put in place, even though they are difficult to enforce incase o f defaults or side-selling. The contracts are expected to provide at least some form o f a legally binding agreement between the parties and allow for bettermonitoring and evaluationo fthe performance o f individual farmers. The centralized service provision system is relatively costly because outgrower promoter, which needs to advance credit for farm inputs to the farmers, carries an additional financial burden of managing a wide extension network and field supervision. Ifpromoter collects sufficient amount o f raw material, the high investment and recurrent costs o f the service delivery can bejustified. Ifthe operator wants to cut costs by decreasing the volume of extension services, it would risk doing so at the cost o f reduced monitoring capacity o f producers, productivity and loan recovery, which could all lead to increased side-selling. The option o f using public extension services or NGOshas not proven viable. Government extension officers often do not possess the up-to-date knowledge required for the specialized crops. The use o f NGOs, if implemented in a supply- driven manner, without a clear exit strategy and without following a joint strategy with the concerned industry,has shown to create distortions inthe value chain. Model 2: Distributor System Inthe second model the promoting company uses local agents (i.e. distributors), which work on the basis o f a commission and are link between the company and smallholders. The system which i s known also as a `distributor' system, i s currently being used by some cotton and tobacco companies. The companies do not have formal contracts with individual farmers due to the vast numbers involved and the highmanagement cost. The agents distribute inputs to farmers and organize the collection o f crops. They do not have a fixed salary but receive a commission on the recovery rate o f loans provided and on the amount of cotton collected. For particularly good output levels the company pays "volume incentives". The systemhas proven quite successful interms of loan recovery and appears to defeat the side- 28This is important becauseofhistory with politically motivated andpoorlymanaged cooperatives. 30 selling issue when compared to centralized system. The advantage for the industry i s that this network o f people i s not employed, but operates on a commission basis, reducing overhead costs o f the operation. The distributor also removes the need for the farmer groups to operate as commercial enterprises, as it i s the distributor that takes charge o fthis function. Farmers are organized into groups, on average o f about 50-60 farmers. Groups are the vehicle for input distribution, dissemination o f technical support, and marketing arrangements. As inthe case of the centralized system, groups are mere `interest groups' and rarely establish formal cooperatives or associations. The distributor system is based on the horizontal expansion o f smallholders, rather thantrying to improve the productivity o f smallholders who already participate in schemes. This i s also its major limitation, as distributors who are contracted on a commission basis based on loan recovery, have an interest in contracting a larger number o f producers (i.e. borrowers), rather than increasing yields o f existing farmers. Box 1 below presents the main differences between the centralized anddistributor models discussed above. Box 1: Comparisonof centralized and distributorOutgrowerModels Model 1: Centralized System(paprika) Model2: DistributorSystem(cotton) Extension Staff, responsible for recruitment o f Area Managers, having a supervisory and smallholders, provision o f inputs and extension, monitoring role. credit recovery and crop collection. Group leaders as intermediary link with farmers, Distributors as intermediary link with farmers, receiving small commission on crop volumes. receiving substantial commissionbased on credit recovery, crop volumes, and correct grading. Individually contracted farmers with no collateral. Distributors provide collateral, and are filly responsible for selection o f farmers, provision of inputsandextension, credit recovery andcrop collection. Characterizedby low credit recoveries (GO%), Characterizedby highcredit recovery rates (>85%), with little or nojudicial recourse. ifonly becauseofdistributorsbeing inapositionto exercise peer pressure. Highincidence o fside-selling. Muchreduced incidence o f side-selling. Hightransactioncosts per farmer or per kgo f Muchreduced transaction costs per farmer or kg o f produce. produce. Stagnant or reduced number o f farmers reached. Increasing numbers o f farmers mobilized. Model 3. Intermediary System Inthis modelthe agribusiness company is linkedto smallholders via intermediary organizations, such as cooperative societies (e.g., dairy, coffee and export vegetable sectors), farmer 31 associations (e.g., tobacco and paprika sectors2') or a management company (e.g., sugar), which manages smallholders on behalf o f outgrower promoters. The existence o f an intermediary between the individual producers and the industry is essentially an evolutionary arrangement in outgrower schemes. When this has been as the result o f natural process, the systems in place have proven successful as they carry the virtues o f developing sustainable smallholder organizational and commercial expertise, thereby enhancing human and social capital o f smallholders. The advantages for the industrial sector are securing a required quantity and quality o f produce while maintaining system competitiveness. A good example o f such higher level smallholder organizational evolution i s that o f the sugar industry, whose success is perhaps tied to the fact that it has been limited in terms o f numbers o f farmers involved (160 emergent farmers) and beingfocussed ina well defined geographical location (Box 2). Box 2: Kaleya Smallholder Company Ltd Smallholder sugar outgrower scheme i s managed by Kaleya Smallholder Company Limited (KASCOL), which was set up in 1980 to incorporate smallholder farmers into production and marketing o f sugar cane. The scheme was started as a community outreach by the Zambia Sugar Company who also saw the scheme as an opportunity to expand cane area for their mill. The KASCOL is essentially the management company for the outgrower scheme. It is responsible for production management, service provision, training, harvesting schedules and negotiations between the smallholder farmers and the market, Zambia Sugar Company Limited. Some 160 farmers are currently participating in the scheme. The average land area used by smallholders i s between 6.2 to 7.5 hectares, which includes also land for homestead and food crop production, where they are encouraged to build a house with a loan finance available from KASCOL. For food crop production, the scheme supports smallholders with land preparation and drainage water used to grow vegetables for their own consumption and for sale for extra income. Participating smallholder farmer sign a 14 year sub-lease for the land. This is signed simultaneously with a sugar cane supply agreement, which stipulates the smallholder and the scheme's responsibilities. Should farmers not adhere to the rules and regulations set by KASCOL, they are given warnings and can be given notice o n the termination o f their lease. Upon leaving they will be compensated for the value o f their dwelling and standing cane crop. Zambia Sugar provides bulk water supply for irrigation and 2 extension officers and agronomy services. KASCOL provides a range o f services to the smallholders: extension service, irrigation, input procurement and provision, cutting (contracted out), haulage (contracted out), land preparation, planting and training. Input loans are recovered at the time o f marketing. Loan recovery rate o f the scheme has been at 100 percent. Farmers do not negotiate on the input cost. They are however made aware and have the opportunity to compare with the retail prices o f similar products intown. Transport o f the cut cane from the smallholders i s outsourced to a private contractor. T o ensure traceability, each movement o f cane is accompanied by a crop ticket which has a farmer identification number, the crop variety, etc. The weight o f the cane i s recorded on the ticket, including the results o f the Estimated Recoverable Crystal (ERC) analysis. The average quality o f smallholder sugar i s around 12.5 ECR (minimumrequired quality level is 10.5 ECR). The pricing for the cane i s controlled by a `Division o f Proceeds' system (DOP). The system is market *'There are very few examples o f genuine producer associations inZambia. The best know ones include the Central Growers Association (CGA) o f Kabwe (tobacco, paprika and soybean) and the Lusaka Agricultural Marketing Company (LAMACO) (paprika, vegetables). LAMACO, inreality, i s not a producer associationbut a sort o f producer promoter company with a focus inpaprika production. 32 related and will establish the tabled prices based o n the ERC formula. The system takes all revenue from both domestic, export and bi-product sales, deducts cost o f milling and marketing and then divides it by agreed percentage, which i s 60 percent for the miller and 40 percent for farmer. This system creates a close partnership between the company and the farmers as any market fluctuations affect all stakeholders. Smallholders who participate in the scheme are more productive than the estate. Average yields o n smallholder are at 115 Mt per hectare/year where as the estate average yield per hectare i s 110 Mt per year. The annual incomes to farmers in2004 ranged from ZMK 19 - 45million (US$4,000 - 10,000). The export vegetable sub-sector also works with a limited number o f farmers. The link between the company and the farmers is through cooperative societies, called Lubulima Agricultural and Commercial Cooperative Union (LACCU), which i s managing the individual member outgrowers3'. The agri-business company does not deal on any scale with individual farmers. The agreement is made with the LACCU, which in turn organizes the local cooperatives to mobilize farmers according to supply and demand. Under this arrangement the agri-business companies (mainly York Farm Ltd.) only provides a market for the farmers. The company does not provide any direct support to farmers, nor does it provide any training or extension. Farmers have to purchase seeds and other inputs commercially and also finance capital investments. Farmers deliver their produce to the cooperative depot where it is weighed, graded, recorded and stored briefly before delivery to company. The dairy sector also does not have a formal outgrower-operator arrangement. The industrydoes not provide inputs to the producers, but only enters into a buying arrangement with dairy cooperatives at pre-fixed prices. The processor i s associated with an increasing number o f widely scattered smallholder groups. The industry has followed horizontal development approach through increasing the number o f smallholders, largely through donor driven initiatives, as processors need large volumes o f raw milk on a daily basis located within a reasonable distance to keep the overhead costs down. Parmalat for example cannot bring a tanker to a milk collection point unless it can secure 10,000 litres. The smallholder coffee outgrower scheme i s managed by the Zambia Coffee Growers Association (ZCGA). However, the arrangement i s slightly different than other sectors as the ZCGA does not take title to the produce from the smallholders but processes it for a fee before selling it on international markets. Inaddition, the Coffee Board o f Zambia (CBZ) i s supporting smallholder outgrowers through large scale coffee estates (the nucleus estate model). The private estates, however, do not buy coffee from the outgrowers as it i s sold through ZCGA's auction. Hence, it i s not an outgrower system inits traditional form but a contract for outsourced service provision. 30 Members o f LACCU are mainly individuals who retired early from government service or the private sector, who are thus much possess higher human capital than the average smallholder farmer in Zambia. As such, they are not representative for typical smallholder farmers, as they are more business minded, are capable o f planning of activities and budgeting for the crop requirements, and have a clear sense o f their obligations under contractual agreements with other parties. However, even these smallholders are not able to access markets without the help o f agribusinesses and the scheme remains heavily dependent on donor support. 33 All models described above are based on linkage-dependent relationships between smallholders and agribusiness enterprises, who guarantee markets for their produce. The common element o f the first two models is that companies provide smallholders inputs and technical support inreturn for access to smallholder produce. Inthe third model, procurement o f inputs is being carried out by smallholders themselves or by intermediaries. To facilitate working with smallholder farmers, in all cases the companies or participating intermediaries have organized smallholders into small `interest' groups. Rarely the groups are formally registered associations or cooperatives, with the exception o f dairy and vegetable sub-sectors. Table 9 compares the characteristics ofkey operational modalities o f three outgrower models discussed above. Table 9: Main Chr -acteristics of Outgrow( Models Model 1:Centralized Model 2: Distributor Model 3: System (paprika and System (cotton) Cooperative System tobacco) (dairy, vegetables, coffee) Quality 0 Blending o f different Least demandingin 0 N o compromise on requirements qualities possible respect o f quality stringent quality requirements Extension Own extension staff Local agents 0 Semi-commercial services or local scheme (distributors) farmers or operators intermediary organizations Numberof Intermediatenumber 0 Large number o f 0 Limitednumber o f smallholders o f growers involved growers involved growers involved (few thousand up to (ten-thousands up (few up to a several ten- to several hundred- several hundred) thousands) thousands) Concentrating on Widespread Close to central Geographical 0 fewer areas with production over processing plant concentration highest potential large parts o fthe country 34 Contract Terms and Conditions Typeof Contract Arrangements Contract terms and conditions vary widely from scheme to scheme3'. It normally covers the types o f services provided by the companies, pricing o f inputs, the interest rate on advances and the price paid for produce supplied to company. Inthe cotton industry,the contractualagreement is signed betweenthe company anddistributors, which places full legal responsibility for credit recovery upon the distributor. The contract with the distributor details that they must deliver to the company the crop to the value o f loan amount. of inputs provided. The distributor, on the other hand, does not have legally binding contracts with the producers. This has often led to a belief by smallholders that once the loan has been repaid to the company in the amount o f cotton, they can sell the remainder o f the crop to any party. Farmers interviewed for the case studies often mentioned that they would welcome more competition, meaning that with more companies operating in the same area they could off-set their loans with the company that provided them the inputs (and qualify again for inputs on credit in the following season), but sell the rest of their production to whoever would offer the best price32. In other sub-sectors investigated under the outgrower case studies there are no clearly defined contracts between the processing or procuring companies and the individual producers, reducing the transparency and relationship with the farmers. Companies often make agreements with the farmer organizations, many o f which have no legal standing, resulting in difficulties in the enforcement o f agreements. There i s a need for companies to deal with farmer organizations, as the large number o f producers diminish their ability to deal with individuals. This, however, diminishes a requirement for the producers to have individual responsibility within the system and a clear understanding o f where andhow they fit into the value chain. In coffee and partly also in fresh vegetable sub-sectors, the contracts or Memorandum of Understandings (MoU) between the outgrower companies/farmer organizations and various service providers are too ambiguous and non-binding in their nature. For example, the M o U between in the coffee sector between farmer groups involves 2-3 different parties with no clear separation o f responsibilities leaving the responsibility for the provision o f extension and marketing services for smallholders unclear. The case studies identified that there are some significant mis-perceptions held by many smallholder farmers regarding contract terms. In all reviewed cases, contracts were prepared by outgrower companies and are written in legal language which makes it difficult for the smallholders and their organizations to comprehend the full implications o f the contract along 3'The ACF survey o f outgrower operators showed that the majority o f outgrower schemes (90 percent) entered into a contract with their farmers. 32 Ithas beenperceived that the `oligopolistic' structure o f cotton industry harms the interests of smallholders. There are four major players inrelatively small Zambian cotton market who compete with each other. For comparison, there is only one major exporter insugar market, and two inpaprika, honey, dairy and export vegetables sub-sectors each. 35 with their full role and responsibility. This leads to misinterpretation, distrust and a perceived lack o f transparency - i.e. if a party does not understand its obligations, it is difficult them to adhere and meet them. There i s thus a need for guidelines, or agreed Codes o f Conducts, at all levels o f the value chain to clearly determine the terms and conditions o f contractual arrangements. Provision of Inputs Inputs provided are usually limited to (certified) seed, and sometimes agrichemicals (e.g. fertilizer, pest and disease control). Fertilizer inputs are rarely provided by outgrower promoters (both inpaprika and cotton sectors) as it i s considered too risky due to the diversion o f inputs to other crops (maize) or sold to other farmers, farmer default and side-selling, and unpredictable weather conditions that may result incrop failure. It was pointed out by agro-businesses that the first priority i s that farmers improve their management practices o f the crop before they are able to benefit from fertilizer application. There i s a wide range o f approaches inpricing o f inputs. Insome schemes (i.e. cotton) the price o f inputs is based on the cost o f procurement and delivery (including transport, distribution and interest charges), and the resultant price i s lower than the wholesale or retail price available to farmers due to economies o f scale o f bulk procurement and logistical arrangements of the agribusiness company. Inother schemes, such as tobacco andpaprika, the common procedure is to price the inputs at the wholesale price the companies pay, without any mark-up. Some outgrower promoters apply a small commission for handling charges, usually around 5 percent but insome cases up to 15-20percent over the procurementprice. The overall impressionis that prices o f inputs charged by the companies in credit schemes have been fair and in most cases lower than the smallholder can obtain from alternative supply sources. The terms o f these arrangements appear to be supportive to both the smallholder production activity and the processing and marketing process. Interest Rates Three types o f approaches were identified for setting the interest rates for the loans extended to smallholders. By far the most common is the practice that no interest is charged on the outstanding loan balances. This applies to majority o f outgrower schemes in Zambia. Another option i s to pass the cost o f capital of borrowed funds on to contracted smallholders (i.e. tobacco sector). The third used by some outgrower operators was to charge interest rates above the commercial rate (ZAHVAC), which varies from 15-30 percent on annual basis. If there was a default, then the interest rate was increased to the "commercial" rate o f 49 percent, plus a 10 percent collection fee. These rates can be considered high for smallholders and are not in line with the long-term target o fincreasingthe productionquality and quantity. Crop Pricing The approach to the pricing o f the procured crops presents a more complex picture. In general, farmers have no say in the determination crop purchase prices. According to the ACF survey, only 40 percent of outgrower schemes negotiated the price with the farmers. About one third o f 36 the outgrower operators offered fixed prices at the beginningo f the season. For example, some cotton companies guarantee a fixed minimum price for seed cotton. This i s later adjusted upwards if the world market price allows. As an example, the market situation improved between 2002 and 2003 and the farm gate price for seed cotton was increased by 43 percent. Zambian agribusiness companies were found to pay the highest average producer price calculated as a share o f the world market price when compared to other countries in the region. It is, however, more difficult for the companies to reduce the purchase price downwards should the world market price decline, as it could lead farmers to turn away from the crop or lead to increased side-selling. This would not be inthe interest o f the companies as it would imply the loss o fpart o fthe productionbase. In the cotton sector, uniform prices are being applied irrespective o f where the crop is being delivered and the distance to the ginneries, with only a differentiation for different grades. On the other hand, crop pricing inpaprika sector makes a distinction for deliveries o f produce to the processing plant (factory price) or to local depotshuying centers (farm-gate price), with farmers having a free choice to deliver to either o f the two. Prices for smallholder paprika produce are lower than for commercially produced paprika not only because o f a lower quality, but also because the investment costs insmallholder production i s muchhigher. Smallholder farmers often expect companies to announce pre-planting prices. This perception i s partly rooted in the past Government policies o f pan-territorial prices o f maize. However, enterprises operating in world market conditions find it often difficult to commit to pre-planting prices, because o f uncertainties over the development o f international market prices or macro- economic instability. Absence o f pre-planting prices, coupled with limited or no understanding o f why and how international market prices fluctuate and how companies derive farm gate prices, and limited access to information, particularly in a format that can be understood by farmers, leads to uncertainty and a feeling o f exploitation. Developing o f a transparent pricing system and explaining pricing system to smallholder farmers (or their group leaders) could greatly alleviate some o f these concerns. Provision of Extension Services There i s a well established positive relationship between the provision o f extension services and improved productivity o f smallholders inZambia. A survey o f outgrower schemes inZambia by ACF found a strong link between the increased provision o f extension services by outgrower companies and the improved revenues per hectare in several crops, particularly for cotton and tobacco. For example, long standing schemes in tobacco invested heavily into the provision of extension services andbuildingthe capacity o fthe farmers. The survey also demonstrated strong linkages between the mobility o f extension service providers and/or lower ratio o f extension providers to farmers, and increased revenues. Ingeneral, smallholder farmers perceive extension services providedbyoutgrower companies as free and therefore have minimal demands on the quality and regularity o f services the receive. Any services provided by the companies will beultimately recovered through the purchase price o f the crop. The sugar industry seems to be the only exemption where smallholders directly pay 37 for their extension services. Therefore farmers know exactly the cost o f extension services, and have inthe past demanded that the services be improved to meet their required standards. There i s evidence also from other programs that some commercializing smallholders are willing to contribute towards the cost o f extension provision if they are satisfied with the quality o f services. Insome cases farmers stated that they would be willing to pay up to 20,000 Kwacha for a training session. Paprika particularly i s a specialized and high value crop, which requires close control and supervision during production process. As standards in importing countries are becoming more stringent, especially on aflatoxins, companies cannot always rely on third parties beingincharge o fthe productionbase due to highrisks to them. As a result, outgrower companies inthe paprika industry employ their own extension officers, who are assisted by locally recruited field assistants. Also, specific to paprika industry, extension officers play an important role during the time o f marketing o f the paprika to ensure that the crop produced by contracted farmers is not diverted elsewhere. The overhead costs o f provision o f extension services are high for the industry, especially because o f low yields and production levels by smallholder farmers and the issue o f side-selling, coupled with a wide geographical distribution o f farmers. Both Cheetah and Central Growers Association reported overhead cost o f US$ 0.35-0.40 per kg. o f crop just for extension and procurement o f the paprika at the 2005 production levels, compared to paprika market prices o f US$l.15 to US$1.25 inLusaka. Some cotton companies, such as Dunavant, have by now replaced their own extension services with distributors in an effort to curb the overhead costs. However, utilizing the distributors as extension officers has often lead to a lower quality o f services provided to smallholders. As explained above, this is because the main objective o f the distributor i s to increase the number o f farmers and improve loan recovery, not necessarily to increase yields. Although they receive a limited amount o f training from Dunavant and are being supervised by its shed managers, and mustbe proven cotton farmers themselves, they may still lack the skills and ability to effectively disseminate extension messages. The other reason for declining quality o f extension services in cotton sector i s the large number o f smallholders serviced by one distributor. For example, a distributor may interact with up to 1,000 smallholders, which makes the provision o f quality extension services difficult. The lack o f mobility o f some distributors, whose main mode of transport is bicycle, also reduces their ability o f efficient service provision. Invegetables and dairy sub-sectors provision o f farm advisory services is organized largelyby commodity trusts (Le. ZEGA Training Trust and Livestock Development Trust). Inother sectors (mainly paprika), the extension services are sometimes provided opportunisticallyby NGOs. Although increase in smallholder production volumes should directly translate into reduction in overhead costs, lack o f public market infrastructure and support mechanisms contributes to high transaction costs. High risk o f farmer default and side-selling have made it difficult for companies to invest into service provision, leading sometimes to a vicious cycle o f low yields and low production volumes to fill their processing capacity. Understandably, outgrower promoters' primary objective i s to maximize profits and should therefore not be expected to provide public goods at their own private expense. The public extension services provided by the Government, however, have not been able to fill the gap as Government extension officers 38 are viewed by private sector companies as ineffective, expensive (due to high levels o f field allowances) and not having the specialized knowledge needed to provide support to farmers in cash crop production. Inpaprika sector outgrower companies have now realized that too wide geographical distribution o f smallholder farmers i s stretching their resources and have addressed this issue by concentrating on fewer geographic areas with the highest production potential and close proximity to transport infrastructure. Mechanisms are also being developed to curb side- selling by transferring more responsibilities to group leaders, for which they receive a commission based on recruitment o f farmers, credit recoveries and product volumes along the lines o f the distributor model developed incotton sector, without loosing control over production volumes and quality. Value Chain Financing and Credit Recovery Value chain financing arranged by outgrower companies is the dominant form o f smallholder credit in Zambia. The basic approach followed by almost all outgrower schemes i s where the promoter issues inputs to farmers on credit, in cash, or inkind. The agreed debt repayment will be deducted from the sale proceeds. The credit enables farmers to acquire required inputs to which they would not otherwise have access. The promoter guarantees to buy the farmer's produce. The repayment for the provided inputs i s deducted when the crops are sold to the contracting firm. The cotton sub-sector is the largest provider o f credit for smallholders. Total annual seasonal credit disbursements by cotton companies were estimated to approach US$10 million in 2003. The majority o f contracted farmers receive credit for seasonal input packages, which consist o f graded and treated cotton seeds, a package o f chemicals and sometimes also spraying instruments. Other supply chain credit schemes in Zambia are smaller in scale, with tobacco being the next largest source o f credit for smallholders, followed bypaprika sub-sector. The assessment o f performance o f credit schemes provided by outgrower promoters follows different principles than in standard financial sector operations. Inagricultural credit operations o f formal financial institutions, high recovery rates normally indicate profitability o f production activities and a strong appreciation by the farmers towards the partnership between them and the financial institution. This i s the general picture for value chain credit too: when farming fails and/or farmers do not see the benefits from the scheme, they often do not repay their loans in full. However, in the case o f outgrower arrangements, the scheme can be profitable for a promoter even when it faces a relatively high default rate, as long as it secures an adequate supply o f quality produce. On the other hand, full recovery o f input credit does not guarantee that the whole contract farming operation is a success and that the promoter would want to continue to implement it. Inall the reviewed outgrower operations, the objective o f companies i s to not to profit from input credit arrangements, but to gain access to raw materials and to profit on post-harvest activities up on the value chain. The credit amounts also tend to represent a relatively small share o f the value o f the crops. Therefore, if the produce buying targets of the company can be reached, reasonable credit losses are acceptable. In general outgrower scheme operators in Zambia did not see the non-availability o f collateral among small scale farmers as a constraint for their credit operations. The ACF survey showed 39 that only 30 percent o f outgrower companies considered smallholder collaterals as important or very important factor inthe development of their schemes. The repayment rate on the other hand was considered the most critical issue inthe success of an out-grower scheme. While the repayment o f credit performance varies significantly among various outgrower schemes, consistently high recovery rates have been achieved in input credit schemes in some sub-sectors. The average credit recovery rate among those outgrower operators who participated inACF surveywas 87 percent in 2003/04, up from 80 percent in 2001/02. After experiencing problems in the past, Dunavant operates today a smallholder credit schemes at over 95 percent recovery level. The tobacco sub-sector reported 95-98 percent recovery levels in their smallholder seasonal credit. Of the smaller credit schemes, C R M Farmreported a full recovery performance year after year, with recovery problems only in one season when the government confused the produce market with free deliveries o frelief fertilizer (Box 3). Box 3: CRM Farm:Successfulsmallholder credit by commercialfarmer CRM Farm i s a commercial family farming enterprise close to Kabwe, o f Lusaka, on the lien o f rail. The major businesses on the farm are wheat, production and manufacturing o f stock feeds, production and processing o f soybeans, and maize. The total area under cultivation i s around 1,000 hectares. The CRM smallholder credit scheme is an innovative approach to small-scale finance and also a reflection o f the structure and farmer relationships in Zambia's agricultural sector. The scheme has its origins inthe severe 1994195 drought. CRM Farm is on one side surrounded by a nature reserve, which is cultivated by a fairly large smallholder population. As government was late to react to the serious hunger caused by the drought, CRM farm started to face significant losses due to crop theft. To counteract the situation, the owner o f CRM Farm designed a private credit scheme to increase acreage and improve the yields o f smallholder maize production around his farm. In the first year, the 1995/96 season, CRM Farmprocured 200 bags o f fertilizer from the private traders and distributed it to 20 farmers operating around the commercial farm. The deal was that based o n the price fertilizer-maize price relation, the farmers were to pay the loan back to CRM Farm by delivering at harvest two bags o f maize for each bag of fertilizer received. The scheme achieved a 100 percent in-time recovery in its first year o f operation. It should be mentioned that the Government fertilizer credit scheme achieved a 6 percent recovery rate the same year. CRM Farm sold the maize received from the farmers on the commercial market and used the proceeds to increase the volume o f the scheme. Inthe next season, 1996/97 smallholders received 400 bags o f fertilizer as input advance and again paid back in full. Since then, the scheme has continued to grow annually. Inthe current season, CRM Farm disbursed 1 000 bags o f fertilizer to smallholders o n credit. New farmers inthe scheme received also quality seeds as a part o f the package. Some 70 farmers participated inthe scheme this year and the total value o f the inputs issued on credit to smallholder was some U S D 15,000. Repayments inthe scheme have remained nearly perfect and in 2002, the 100 percent recovery level was again reached. The operators o f the scheme see the following key factors behind this performance: The small-scale farmers see the scheme as a reliable source o f inputs to which they would otherwise have very little access. Default would automatically exclude them from this service. The Farm Supervisor, who manages the scheme has very good knowledge o f his clientele, which has been the basis for successful farmer selection to the scheme. H e has also used the local Chiefs to assist him in farmer selection. The Farm owners have from the start introduced the scheme as a commercial operation, not a social service, and the responsibility for repayments has beenmade clear to the farmers. The option to pay back inmaize has made it easy for the cash-poor farmers to take care o f the repayments. The only problems in recoveries were experienced in 2001. Two main reasons contributed to the problems. First, the price o fmaize dropped sharply and the price o f fertilizer went up. The repayment ratio was changed to 3.5 bags 40 of maize for one bag o f fertilizer. T h s caused some concern with the smallholders. Second, inthe mid-season the government started to distribute in the villages free fertilizer, which it has received from donor relief sources. This confused the commercial maize and fertilizer marketing situation in the area and adversely affected the credit scheme operations. In 2002, the price ratio was reduced to three bags o f maize to one bag o f fertilizer and the scheme achieved a 100percent recovery again. The farmers' positive view o f the importance o f this private sector credit scheme can be observed from their good repayment performance in a sector where willful default has been the rule o f the game, and in farmers' willingness to borrow more and intensify their maize cultivation. The more active smallholders have now much larger areas under maize, and the biggest borrower received 80 bags o f fertilizer inthis season and invested also own funds to his small-scale but increasingly commercialmaize operation. For CRM F a n the main impact has been that crop theft has virtually stopped. The owner considers that he has earned back his initial investment many times as a result o f reduced theft but also in the form o f a much smaller number o f required farm watchmen as compared to his neighboring commercial farmers who do not supply similar services to close-by smallholders. All the trading income from the repaid maize has been used to expand the scheme. As the biggest problemfor the continued successful operations o f the credit scheme the owner o f the CRM farm sees the continuous interference o f the government inboth the input market and the pricing o f maize. The key constraint for CRM Farm to progress inthis way i s that smallholders inthe area still lack the business orientation to farming which would be required for sustainable production o f more sophisticated and better paying cash crops based on outgrower contracts. Source: IFAD (2003) On the other hand, some other outgrower schemes achieved very low rates o f recovery for their input advances. For example, paprika operations recorded average recovery rates o f around 50- 60 percent in 2003, and some companies (e.g. ZAHVAC) were able to recover only 26-34 percent o f the credit provided to smallholders. Impact on Smallholder Incomes The outgrower case studies did not find the evidence o f exploitative nature in reviewed smallholder contract farming arrangements and in related input credit operations. Most o f the operations had a positive financial impact both to outgrower company and to smallholder farmers. Input credit packages by processing and marketing companies make it possible for small-scale farmers, who do not otherwise have access to formal credit and markets, to get involved in the production o f high-value crops. The companies also provide them with secured markets for their produce. Inmost o f the reviewed cases, this has meant increase in the cash earnings o f the participating households. Through participation in outgrower schemes, smallholders are able to generate a cash income (sometimes first time in their lives) to satisfy their cash expenditure requirements (school fees, hospitalbills andclothing), even inyears when their maizecrops have failed. There are significant differences between sub-sectors in terms o f the return to land and labor farmers received for participation in outgrower schemes. Crops such as paprika, coffee, vegetables and cotton produce much higher per hectare net earnings than is the case with the most common alternative, the low-input low-output production o f maize. Calculations made by the study teams show that on a per hectare basis sugar has the highest gross margins of about US$1,100 per hectare, followed by export vegetables (US$500 - 850 per ha) and coffee (US$250-400 per ha). However, these three crops involved only a small number o f smallholder households throughout the country and are therefore insignificant from the broader poverty 41 reduction point o f view. The two crops which had the largest number o f smallholders - cotton and paprika - had gross margins per hectare o f US$157 and US$120 respectively. This is considerably higher than maize, which has an average gross margin o f US$80 per hectare33. In terms o f returnto labor, cotton generated income o fUS$1.8 per day compared to US$1.4 per day for paprika. The returnto labor for maize was estimated at US$1.2 per day. However, income generated from outgrower operations would probably not lift majority of smallholders above the poverty line o f one-dollar-a-day, unless they are able to increase yields. For example, the farm model calculations carried out by study team showed that by increasing average cotton yield from 600 k g h a to 800 kgha with improved farm management practices would increase smallholder gross margins from US$120/ha to US$180/ha. The respective increase o f return to labor would be from US$1.8 per day to US$2.5 per day. Further improvement o f yields, with increased input use, to 1,000 kg/ha would increase gross margins to US$230/ha or return to labor o fUS$2.8 per day. Finally, there i s also an evidence o f positive spill-over effects from production under out-grower schemes to regular farming activities in form o f technology and skills transfer and inputs. For example, it was claimed by some cotton scheme operators that their farmers have higher maize yields than their fellow farmers, who are not connected to outgrower scheme, simply because they have become better farmers. However, it is also possible that farmers who get involved in outgrower arrangements are simply more advanced in their farming operations. In several tobacco schemes farmers were advised to cultivate maize after tobacco in order for the maize to benefit from residual fertilizer from tobacco. Incoffee schemes intercropping with other crops is promoted to bridge the first 3-4 years inwhich the coffee does not yet bear harvest. Sustainability of Outgrower Operations As discussed above, one o f the major problems to outgrower scheme sustainability emerges when the company fails to procure the expected volumes and qualities of crops from contracted smallholders. Ina number of the reviewed cases, despite the training provided, smallholders had difficulties to meet the quality standards required for export production. In paprika operations for some companies several containers were rejected on arrival in Europe in 2003-2004 due to highlevels o faflatoxin. The second factor what affects the scheme sustainability is the issue o f side-selling and side- buying. The contracting companies find it often difficult to buy crops from their own contracted farmers. Opportunistic competitors buy actively and systematically from farmers contracted by other companies, and often find willing sellers within the smallholder community. Side-selling has adversely affected the sustainability o f many input credit schemes and discouraged new companies from engaging in these activities. According to the ACF survey, side-selling was a strong concern to tobacco and cotton outgrower companies. In paprika sector some companies lose as much as 30-40 percent o f its outgrower production to their competitors. There i s a need to establish clear rules both on the company and the farmer side to direct the behavior o f the 33The study team did not estimate the returns o n tobacco. According to the ACF survey of outgrower arrangements, revenues generated by tobacco are comparable to vegetables and sugar. 42 market players. However, the issue o f side-selling and side-buying is linked to general problems related to weak law enforcement in Zambia. The companies have little trust in the law enforcement systems and seldom take legal action against firms buying illegally (sometimes with close political connections) from their outgrowers. Other issues related to the sustainability o f outgrower schemes have their roots in the past Government interventions inthe agriculture sector and economy ingeneral. The government has historically provided all inputs on credit to the farmers along with extension and markets. Donors and NGOs alike have been continuing this, and now smallholder farmers are expecting the same from private companies and continue to depend on them for their input needs. The study did not find any examples where smallholder farmers involved inoutgrower schemes were able or willing to secure their inputs independently grow the crop usingtheir own resources, and then sell the crop to the company o f their choice. The linkage-dependent relationship between the smallholder farmers and the private sector is essentially similar to the system which existed under former state parastatals. Furthermore, a culture o f credit non-repayment has developed over the years as a result o f government interventions in the sector. The legacy o f this i s at the core o f many o f the problems (and criticism) faced by the private sector in promoting smallholder outgrower schemes. On the one hand there i s a need to boost production by providing smallholders inputs and extension services, while on the other hand there is a risk of increased exposure o f the companies in view o f the prevailing high default rates. Efforts by some companies inpaprika sector (i.e. Cheetah) to make inputs for the new season available at the time when farmers are selling their paprika crop, and encourage farmers to use some o f the proceeds from the sales for securing the inputs for the following season have so far met limited but increasing success. Another challenge for outgrower schemes is the lack o f business orientation o f smallholder farmers. Dueto prevailing cultural attitudes a largenumber o f smallholders see farming still as a life style, and not a business activity. Furthermore, partly because o f past Government policies and partly because o f activities o f some NGOs, there i s still a wide spread dependency mentality in rural Zambia which further complicates developing an independent and business oriented smallholder farming community. Smallholder export vegetable production in Zambia i s a good example o f donor dependency. There is a wealth o f external support for smallholder groups, such as LACCU. Whereas the organization has stronger capacity than most smallholder groups in Zambia and has built up a strong support network to facilitate the development o f the organization and its members, it has become so donor-dependent that it is not able to survive independently ina business environment. However, probably the biggest challenges for the sustainability o f outgrower schemes lay beyond the domain o f the smallholder sector. According to the survey o f outgrower schemes by ACF, the large majority o f operators (95 percent) identified the fluctuations o f the world commodity prices and instability o f domestic exchange rate as a most critical factor what affects the sustainability o ftheir operations, followed bycost o f finance (85 percent). 43 Summary The outgrower schemes reviewed above have different operating modalities in terms o f the type and number o f fanners, their spatial distribution, contract arrangements, delivery o f inputs and technical support (extension services), marketing mechanisms, and quality requirements. It would not be realistic to recommend a single best practice outgrower model that suits all o f these diverse scenarios. However, it i s possible to extract some relevant elements and lessons learned from the reviewed outgrower models that could be incorporated into recommendedbest practice models suited to the specific conditions o f different sub-sectors. The best practice models which i s proposed in Annex 2, aims to move away from (Government/donor) dependency towards self- sufficient, economically viable supply chains, incorporating producers, service providers and processors, each party knowing and recognizing its roles and responsibilities and undertaking them ina responsible, profitable and sustainable manner. Characteristics of Smallholder Producer Groups in Zambia There are several advantages for smallholder farmers to organize themselves inproducer groups. Outgrower companies and agribusinesses in general prefer to work with fanner groups rather than with individual smallholders. Group approaches to farmer groups means reaching economies o f scale and thus reducing transaction costs, which i s beneficial for both farmers and outgrower companies. By working through fanner groups companies can reduce their cost on delivery o f services, whereas farmers can reduce transport and other transaction costs to bring their produce to the company, or negotiate better prices when delivering inbulk. Groups are also more efficient channels for the distribution o f inputs, dissemination o f technical advice, and procurement o f the crop. Below, we discuss the main types o f smallholder groups/organizations found invarious forms o f outgrower arrangements inZambia. Cooperative Societies Most dairy groups andvegetable growers operate as Cooperative Societies (CS). CSs are formed under the Cooperative Societies Act (1998). There are about 3,000 cooperative societies registered under the Cooperative Societies The main advantage for fanners to belong to a CS is that they can access the government's fertilizer subsidies (FSP), Food Security Packs and similar Government programs, or sell their maize to FRA at their procurement price. As a result, the CSs are still seen largely as being top-down and with a high level o f political influence in their formation and operations. Many o f the `new' cooperative societies are simply continuations o f the `old-style' cooperatives, or have been formed to serve the interests o f a few, usually relatively well educated and well off farmers, and do not necessarily represent the interests o f majority o f smallholders. Most CSs become active only at the beginning o f the growing season in order to access subsidized fertilizer become often dormant for the rest o f the season. Most CSs lack strong self-management and have been plagued by problems of mismanagement o f financial resources and poor accountability. Although some CSs have received capacity 34 Other sources mention tensof thousands of cooperative societies. 44 building in financial management, majority have not managed to set up proper accounting systems and procedures. Poor management o f CSs i s partly a result o f unrestricted membership with too little emphasis on commercial selection criteria. It is not uncommon for CSs to have a membership o f 100-200 farmers or more, but only very few active members. Farmer Associations FarmerAssociations (FA) have become an alternative to cooperative societies. While CSs have been promoted mainly by Government, FAs have developed mainly through donor fbnded operations as a means to deliver services to its members. The number o f FAs has rapidly expanded as evidenced by the number of associations seeking registration with the Registrar o f Societies. Although they provide an organizational framework for mobilizing farmers to participate in various programs and fill the institutional vacuum that exists in rural areas, many associations seem to some extent come into existence merely as a response to the availability of donor fbnds. It is not uncommon for an individual farmer to belong to as many as four or five different associations, all located within a small geographical area. As stated by some smallholders: `it i s always useful to belong to several associations, in case another donor or NGO passes by'. Membership fees are usually minimal, and paying a membership fee many times over i s far outweighed by the possible benefits that may come by belonging to the right association at the righttime. The flowing weaknesses o f the FAswere identified: 0 FAs are generally weakly organized, with limited managerial skills, limited access to capital, and generally suffer from low productivity resulting from late and inappropriate inputs andpoor management; Membership fees charged by associations were often inadequate to maintain a vibrant organizational structures, particularly for new associations which reduce its fees in order to attract membership. In many cases, regardless o f the fee levels, membership subscriptions are not proactively collected; There i s lack o f understanding o f recruitment concepts. When the initial or pioneering membership has been settled, there appears to be little focus on attracting new members; and 0 Insome instances, the associations have been formed on a single-issue basis, and ifthat issue disappears, there may not be incentives to sustain the association. The findings o f the study is that rhere are only few cooperative societies or farmer associations in Zambia that could become a genuine partners for outgrower promoters. They are widely scattered to provide a strong and reliable production base and effective supply network on the ground. Often outgrower promoters are approached by a cooperative society or farmer association wishing to grow a particular crop in collaboration with the outgrower promoter, whereby it soon transpires that the only thing really wanted is fertilizers on credit. It is therefore not surprising that outgrower promoters prefer to work with individuals, such as distributors, 45 who can provide the necessary guarantees, thus avoiding all the complexities o f working with formal farmer organizations. Characteristics of Successful Farmer Organizations in Zambia Farmer organizations are most successful with small, cohesive groups involved in simple activities in liaison with agribusiness. They are generally built upon pre-existing organizations and/or social groups, where members already share considerable trust and familiarity and have a strong sense o f local ownership. They tend to have a small membership, between 10 and 30 members, o f relatively homogeneous characteristics. The agenda o f successful organizations i s usually member-driven and shows internal cohesion, which tends to occur more in groups o f small size. Taking into account former misuse o f funds by formal cooperatives, transparency i s very important to establish farmers' trust ineach other and to the organization. Successful farmer organizations cases which were identifiedby the study were never associated with subsidized inputs or credit, but with viable business objectives. However, they need capacity building, particularly when aimed at integrating the group into the wider economy through development o f links with financial and market intermediaries. Other main characteristics o f successful farmer organizations which were identified in the outgrower case studies include the following: 0 Successful farmer organizations are generally involved in relatively simple marketing, input supply and saving/credit operations involving liaison with market intermediaries higher up the marketing chain; 0 They have a close match between the activity and services on the one hand and the group's experience, and financial and managerial capacity on the other hand; 0 They tendto begin with a single activity as more complex operations often fail; and 0 They tend to concentrate on relatively high value produce rather than low-value staples; or concentrate on produce with an added value component through grading andor processing and/or storing over seasons. LessonsLearned From Donor Funded Projects The presence o f donors and donor-funded NGOs in smallholder commercialization activities varies significantly by commodity sub-sector. While the large Zambian outgrower schemes, such as cotton and tobacco, are operated and funded entirely by private outgrower companies themselves, the smaller schemes, such as paprika, vegetables and dairy, have received substantial aid allocations. Annex 3 presents the major donor funded smallholder commercialization projects in Zambia. Ingeneral, schemes that have received little donor support (cotton, tobacco, sugar, honey, chilli) have shown relatively good performance, both in terms o f smallholder numbers and export value. On the other hand, two sectors which have received a largest amount o f donor support in Zambia, such as paprika and export vegetables, have seen declining number o f smallholder farmers and export volumes since their peak in2002. A number o f donor-funded NGOs have been involved in farmer mobilization and capacity buildingamong farmer groups, notably in impartinginbusiness skills training. While many o f 46 these activities have been successful in establishing farmer groups, others have however floundered because o f the lack o f direct market linkages and industryinvolvement. Often farmer groups were formed on an ad hoc basis or on a large scale as part o f development projects. This has often not lead to the emergence o f viable farmer groups. Often the groups were formed hastily with little reference to the underlying patterns o f social and economic organization or commitment to cooperative action. Farmers were typically required to join a group in order to receive inputs that were donated or subsidized, thus attracting those primarily interested in the subsidy. There is a need to clarify the roles and responsibilities o f NGOs which are supporting the development o f smallholder-private sector linkages, especially since some donor funded NGOs have become competitors rather than facilitators to the private sector. For example, some NGO's had a tendency to masquerade as agribusiness enterprises, cross-subsidizing their business activities with donor funding which has distorted markets. Beneficiaries from donor funded organizations with cheap financial sources have been pushingup market prices in an attempt to increase margins for smallholders (e.g. paprika) which has disadvantaged commercial outgrower companies who consequently have been facing viability problems and increased side selling. This has reduced the sustainability ofthe industry once the donor support ends. In some instances, extension services provided by NGOs have reduced the control that agribusiness companies have over the standardo f service provided or the content o f the technical advice and messages being given. This has resulted in inconsistent advice being given, causing confusion and having a negative impact on smallholder production. The situation with inappropriate NGO or donor involvement in extension services i s exacerbated when the project or funding ends and there i s no sound exit strategy to ensure that service continues to be provided ina sustainable manner. Onthe other hand, training and capacity building operations by some donor programs andNGOs have been instrumental inthe development o f farmers groups. Some donor funded projects have managed to broker functional relationships between the outgrower companies and farmer associations/groups, including financial links. The presence o f donor funded NGOs in the field has helped companies to reduce risks and transaction costs. These actions have often served as usefulstartingpoints inthe intensificationo fsmallholder agriculture inrural areas o fZambia. Overall, experiences from donor funded smallholder commercialization projects in Zambia suggests that funds for smallholder mobilization and capacity building should be preferably channelled through industry associations, agribusinesses/outgrower promoters and farmer organizations, in the form o f `results based contracts', in order to have a lasting impact. This could also lower the cost o f service provision as there will be no duplication o f overhead costs. The functions o f the development organizations interms o f farmer capacity building, extension, marketing, etc. should be the responsibility o f outgrower scheme operators who ensure their consistency with industry priorities and business needs, and who can contract NGOs or other service providers on a demand-driven basis. Finally, there is a need to ensure a more coordinated approach between development partners supporting smallholder outgrower sector in Zambia. Lack o f coordination o f agency policies and activities and competition for smallholders 47 i s often restricting the impact o f the assistance provided. It i s thus important that the role of each partner is clearly defined and understoodby all from the onset. `Summary The analysis above provides a review o f experiences and lessons learned from smallholder commercialization process in Zambia. There are many successful examples o f smallholder commercialization from other countries in the region or globally, which could serve as useful benchmarks for Zambia. In general, successful cases o f smallholder agricultural commercialization and value chain development have benefited from the active role o f public sector through the investments into complementary public goods, such as research and extension, transport infrastructure, improved regulatory environment, etc. That is, successful cases o f smallholder agricultural commercialization and value chain development did not, in general, emerge only from efforts o f the private sector. Given the increasing importance o f private value chains in agricultural production systems, a larger share o f limitedpublic resources may need to go to investments related to the development o f "software" (improving farm management, technology transfer, capacity building o f farmers and their associations), while private sector is expected to increase their investments into hardware (for example irrigation infrastructure). In the future, most benefits can be generated through co-financing and complimenting the special skills in the two sectors through public- private partnerships. In order for smallholders to become competitive in increasingly sophisticated global food markets, public sector support for the development o f innovation systems which i s based on public-private partnerships i s becoming an important focus o f "software" related investments. This is because effective innovation capacity often already exists within private sector value chains, because innovation systems and value chains often have many shared partners. Although they respond to different organizational principles, innovation systems and value chains are highly complementary and overlapping. Experience from China and elsewhere shows that innovation systems can be used to help to expand opportunities and means for resource-poor smallholder farmers to become actors and stakeholders in global value chains (Box 4). * Box 4 Reducingruralpovertyby linkingfarmer organizationswith public-private partnershipsin China Agriculture inWestern China i s characterizedby deep rural poverty linked to traditional production systems. World Bank support i s focusing o n assisting the national plan to restructure and modernize the sector. An especially innovative part o f this effort is the development and testing o f tripartite joint ventures between agribusinesses, small- scale farmers, and research providers to enhance knowledge-based value addition in agricultural production, especially farmers' share o f the value added. The focus on partnerships grew out of an assessment o f rural communities and their links with public and private stakeholders, which revealed: Increasingly complex and nonlinear linkages from research to product, with networks for public and private partners engaged ininnovation, development, production, and marketing. Consumer demand-driven research agendas, including the integration o f agricultural production and emerging environmental sustainability agendas (such as integrated pest management and "green" food). A changing public sector role away from productive activities and towards setting and enforcing regulatory 48 frameworks and quality standards. Partners inthese joint ventures (researcherhesearch institution, company, and farmedfarmer association) enter into a risk- and benefit-sharing arrangement in the form o f contracts, joint shareholding, or revenue sharing, which guarantees that benefits are not captured by one partner alone. Farmer organizations have legal support for negotiating contracts. This institutionalarrangement seeks to ensure that new products and technologies propagated, developed, or under development respond to market demand, are supported by research to stay competitive, and involve farmer organizations as business partners to assure fair benefit sharing. Source: Adaptedfrom Agriculture Investment Sourcebook World Bank (2006) Global experience also shows that institutional changes are needed to support the development o f competitive and efficient agricultural markets and increase smallholder farmers' access to these markets. Institutional innovation has been shown to reduce transaction costs related to markets and/or value chain coordination, facilitate expansion o f exchange outside o f personalized networks, and enhance market specialization (see Box 5). Box 5: Mali: "SiliconMali" Mali's success in establishmg a market information system earned it the title o f "Silicon Mali" from Forbes Magazine in 2002. Mali's market information system (Observatoire des Marchts Agricoles) i s based o n enumerators visiting 58 markets around M a l i and recording the high and low prices for grains, crops, and livestock. They enter these o n laptop computers and e-mail the information by FM radio waves-all solar-powered equipment-to other regional offices where data are compiled and reports prepared for different types o f producers. The system, built up over a decade, has helped make Malian grain farmers more efficient, by letting them know when and where to sell and for what price. With better information, the government can now rely on the private sector to shift surpluses to areas with shortages without resorting to foreign aid. Mali's information system has become a model for the rest o f West Africa, where such countries as Niger and Burkina Faso are setting up similar systems that will be linked together. Soon farmers will be able to carry out more selling across national boundaries. Source: Agriculture Investment Sourcebook, World Bank (2006). As discussed throughout this report, value chain competitiveness depends on a variety o f factors, such as good logistics, low transaction costs, enabling business environment, and macroeconomic stability. The public sector can create conditions for the development of efficient value chains by the private sector, but government capacity to support value chain development and increase the involvement o f smallholders i s typically limited. Boxes 6 and 7 below present two examples, one from Colombia and another from Madagascar, on the development o f effective productive agribusinesdfarmer partnerships which have emerged from clearly defined public-private collaboration. process Box6: Colombia: Buildingproductiveagribusiness-farmerpartnerships Liberalization o f the economy, coupled with an overvalued currency and falling world prices for commodities, have led to fundamental changes in the composition o f Colombia's agricultural production. However, the rural population's limited education and business skills, the high cost o f and limited access to capital (particularly for smallholders), and the prevalence o f rural violence have impeded smallholders' ability to deal with these changes. The challenge facing the rural sector is to increase its competitiveness ina free market economy. The government's strategy i s to promote farming systems that combine both perennial crops (agro-ecological conditions permitting) with subsistence and annual crops and animal husbandry. This strategy is expected to allow farmers to reduce debt levels, diversify risk, and increase employment and incomes. 49 The World Bank i s supporting the Government o f Colombia to establish economically viable and sustainable partnerships between agribusiness and organizations o f small-scale producers through the Productive Partnerships Support Project. A "productive partnership" i s considered as any collaborative arrangement between a small-farmer organization and an agribusiness that reduces technical, commercial, financial, and/or social risks; increases productivity; andproduces income gains ina value chain inways that benefit all parties. The development o f productive partnerships is based on three principles: (i) limited responsibilities o f the public sector are specifically defined; (ii) execution o f project activities is completely decentralized and transferred to the private sector; and (iii)participation o f stakeholders i s structured through a clear allocation of roles and responsibilities, basedo n the recognized competencies and capacities o f eachparty. The project supports the implementation o f productive partnerships by financing cost-sharing transfers as a financial incentive for participating producer organizations (i.e. on-farm infrastructure, such as irrigation canals, aquaculture facilities, greenhouses and storage facilities; durable goods, such as machinery and equipment; operational inputs, such as fertilizers and approved chemicals; special studies and inventories; etc.). It also finances techcal assistance and training for participants in productive partnership. The incentives can be used for farmers to access output markets and inputs (for example, high quality seed or credit for working capital). They also help agribusinesses to expand food processing activities by securing supplies from small-scale producers whose products meet predetermined quality standards, without the need to expand own production capacity. There i s now evidence that development o f productive partnerships between agribusinesses and small-farmer organizations has improved smallholders' access to input as well as output markets. Farmers' range o f production alternatives has increased, along with the profitability o f diversification alternatives. In conjunction with these changes, rural employment has increased, a broader range o f production systems has been established, and the financial and climatic risks associated with agricultural production have been reduced. Agribusiness investments in the sector have improved the provision o f new technologies and the linkages between farmers and the markets they serve. The main lessons learned from this program include the following: A flexible, open design is preferred, given the great diversity incapacity and socioeconomic conditions; The process o f designing partnerships should be participatory, drawing on the contributions o f local governments and local small-farmer organizations; Proper mechanisms must be set in place to provide participating farmers with independent sources of technical assistance to counterbalance dependence inrelationships with agribusinesses; Clearly defining contractual, arbitration, and conflict resolution mechanisms as well as operational, monitoring, and supervision procedures can ensure transparency infinancial transactions. Source: Agriculture Investment Sourcebook, World Bank 2006. 50 Box 7: Madagascar: Giventhe rightincentives,Africansmallholdersinsupply chains can compete andprosper. A recent study on smallholders in Madagascar producing for supermarkets, concludes: "given the right incentives and contracting systems, small farmers in developing countries - and in Africa in particular - can participate successfully in these emerging value chains. Thousands o f small farmers benefit because o f a combination o f effects, such as improved access to inputs, credit, extension services, technology adoption, and farm productivity spillover effects on other crops and enhanced income stability." This study analyzes primary data collected to measure the impact o f supermarkets o n small contract farmers in Madagascar (one o f the poorest countries in the world). Almost 10,000 farmers inthe Highlands o f Madagascar produce vegetables for supermarkets in Europe. In this global supply chain, small farmers' micro-contracts are combined with extensive farm assistance and supervision programs to fulfill complex quality requirements and phyto-sanitary standards o f supermarkets. Small farmers that participate in these contracts have higher welfare, more income stability, and shorter lean periods. There were also significant effects on improved technology adoption, better resource management and spillovers on the productivity o f the staple crop rice." The authors identify three key constraints: (i) road infrastructure and bad high transport costs; (ii)low humancapital and hightraining costs; and (iii) transaction costs for individualized high farmer contracts. Possible solutions are: (i)investments ininfrastructure; (ii) inc h l d and adult education and invest training; and (iii)promote group formation. Because o f the bad road infrastructure and high transport costs and other high transaction costs related to distance, all o f the contracted farmers live in a 120 km radius around the capital, where there is a processing plant and export productionunits are located. Source: LICOS Discussion Papers I64/2006. Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belguim. Minten, B, L. Randrianarison, and F.M.Swinnen (2006) 51 Chapter5 DevelopmentPotentialandOpportunitiesfor SmallholderCommercializationinZambia Potentialfor Smallholder Commercialization Smallholder agriculture has demonstrated some potential in Zambia. It is estimated that about one-third o f smallholders in Zambia are currently linked to global markets through various outgrower (Le., contract farming) schemes. Smallholders produce the majority o f cotton, tobacco, honey, and paprika exports, and contribute to the increasing share o f sugar. There are opportunities for import substitution as more smallholder producers have also started to make inroads into the domestic dairy sector and there i s evidence o f attempts to link into domestic supermarket chains. Availability o f land and low production costs (especially in labor-intensive activities) makes smallholders attractive partners for agribusinesses who require access to raw materials for processing and exports. Three major themes emerge from the Zambia SACS that might lead to a broader rethinking of Zambia's agricultural and rural development. These findings can serve as guidance for donors and Government inshaping their support programs for smallholder commercialization. First, there is a strong convergence of interests between agribusinesses, larger scale commercial farmers and smallholders. This convergence o f interests is evident in the different contract farming and outgrower arrangements. The majority of smallholder households in Zambia will not be able to access on their own increasingly sophisticated global value chains (regardless of their individual or organizational capacity) without the support o f agribusinesses, and will therefore continue to rely on outgrower schemes for their livelihoods. Agro-processing and marketing companies are therefore likely to remain the main drivers of growth for agriculture. However, increased competition on world markets implies that the comparative advantage of Zambian agricultural exports will continue to rely on low production costs o f smallholder production systems. This has important policy implications from macro and sectoral perspectives, and also interms o f the legal andregulatory framework. Addressing constraints for smallholder commercialization will therefore require multi-sectoral interventions which benefit both smallholder and large scale commercial agriculture sector, and agriculturalhon-agricultural enterprises in rural areas. This means that the greatest potential for smallholder commercialization lies not so much in addressing smallholder or commodity specific constraints, but in overall increases in the efficiency o f value chains arising from removal o f economy and sector-wide constraints, and the strengthening o f institutional mechanisms by which key stakeholders and their service providers can effectively link to each other by forming partnerships and alliances. Second, there i s a pronounced heterogeneity among smallholders in terms o f potential for commercialization which requires different targeting strategies. The heterogeneity of smallholder households with differential potential has also implications for poverty reducing impacts o f smallholder commercialization. It i s most likely that smallholders already involved in 52 commercial activity (located in more favored areas and having more household assets) and who already possess necessary productive and social assets, such as land and labor, human capital (education and health), social capital (e.g. hnctioning farmer groups), and access to physical and financial assets, will be the vanguard o f commercialization efforts. Most o f these smallholder households are still relatively poor, so there is potential for poverty reduction in the short-term, mainly through participation in outgrower schemes (i.e. improving productivity o f current smallholders as opposed to large scale expansion o f number o f smallholder farmers). In the longer-term, with new investments in transport and communication infrastructure, and in irrigation, some poor rural households in what are currently considered remote and/or drought- prone areas might also benefit from agricultural commercializationprocess. Third, addressing the issues o f rural poverty, and household risks and vulnerabilities requires holistic solutions which go beyond agricultural sector. The commercialization o f smallholder agriculture might create some rural linkages that can benefit non-commercializing smallholders. Smallholder agricultural production systems will continue to remain important from a household food security perspective, especially for those smallholders that do not have commercial potential. However, there will be still need for safety nets and/or off-farm and non-agricultural livelihood options for more vulnerable groups. Opportunitiesfor Smallholder Commercialization There i s a needto develop more realistic expectations about the short and medium-term potential o f moving smallholders to higher levels o f commercialization. If we draw upon past productivity performance, then it will probably take decades, not years, to achieve significant, sustainable andbroad-based increases insmallholder agricultural productivity and income levels. Donor support should therefore address simultaneously both smallholder specific and broader sector-wide issues what limit development o f value chains. It i s also suggested that the focus o f donor support be limited to more market neutral interventions (e.g. extension, research, infkastructure, etc.), as lessons learned discourage direct commodity or enterprise specific interventions. There is a need for a flexible investment approaches to accommodate changes in demand-side factors and to support development o f emerging market opportunities. It i s also equally important to recognize that many o f the key constraints for smallholder commercialization are multi-sectoral innature, and lay largely outside the domain o f MAC0 and the agriculture sector. The opportunities for the Government and donor support for smallholder commercialization can be organized around the following three strategies: 53 Strategy 1:Strengthen Existing Market Mechanisms Improve the efficiency o f existing mechanisms o f smallholder commercialization, such as outgrower schemes or nucleus estate models, and continue to support development o f new and more innovative collaborative arrangements for farm productivity improvement (i.e. independent management companies, input dealers, etc). First, there is a need to continue supporting the development o f appropriate farmer organizations, especially in the areas o f strengthening their business orientation and capacity, since it would make smallholders more attractive business partners for agri-businesses and input-credit provision by the companies. Second, there i s a need to continue to strengthen the working models and schemes, such as supporting the development o f existing and new outgrower schemes for improved service delivery. Resources could be made available to address the production and organizational constraints facing the functioning outgrower schemes that are constraining the positive momentum o f the more dynamic sub- sectors. Third, there i s a need to continue supporting efforts to increase farm level productivity by encouraging adoption o f innovative farming technologies which have proven to work in Zambia smallholder farming systems. Fourth, there i s a need to strengthen risk management practices by smallholders dealing with weather related risks that directly affect household choice o fproductions systems and willingness to participate incommercial agriculture activities. Develop Appropriate Farmer Organizations Development o f appropriate farmer organizations i s critical for individual farmers to capture economies o f scale and for developing the business orientation o f smallholders. Strengthening the capacity of existing and new farmers' organizations and producers groups, especially building their business orientation, would make smallholders more attractive business partners for agri-businesses and input-credit provision by the companies. Commercially oriented farmer organizations are needed. This should not be confused to old-time politically motivated farmer cooperatives. Well functioning associations can reduce transaction costs and risks to agribusinesses, which make credit delivery, input supply, extension, and produce collection easier to manage. Smallholders need technical support and training in business management skills order to establish and operate effective associations. This often involves higher up-front costs than companies are prepared or able to pay. A justified donor intervention would be to support the development o f farmer organizations, especially during their infant operational period. This could include facilitation o f business development services to viable and commercially oriented farmers organizations in the areas o f group formation, group governance skills, farm planning skills, market intelligence training, and business skills and training on contracts and understanding contractual obligations (for all parties). Develop Existing and New Outgrower Schemesfor Improved Service Delivery The modalities o f supporting development o f outgrower schemes vary from situation to situation and business opportunity. Incases where access to term capital i s the major constraining factor for the expansion o f service coverage, donor support could be in the form o f a targeted credit lines for outgrower scheme development and expansion, preferably through the formal financial institutions. Inother cases, support could be inthe form o f initial support for the establishment o f technical advisory services, financed either through loans or matching grants. To date, most 54 of the donor support for outgrower schemes has relied on contracted intermediaries or the project staff to play an active role in the implementation activity. However, many o f the large and successful credit-based input delivery operations rely solely on the companies' own networks linked to field activities with the smallholders. An interestingopportunity would be to develop the ways of using donor funding to widen the outreach o f the established contract farming operations through well-performing outgrower operators using companies' own networks to carry out their field operations. Building on existing institutional arrangements that are functioning successfully increases the chances o f continued success on the ground, while reducing transaction costs that arise from contracting intermediaries. Resources could be made available to address the production and organizational constraints facing the hnctioning outgrower schemes that are keeping up the positive momentum o f the agriculture and respective dynamic sub-sectors. On the other hand, since market and business opportunities are dynamic, provision should also be made to address new demands and markets that might arise in the context o f smallholder commercialization. Support ConservationFarming and Other Innovative Technology Transfer Efforts to Increase Farm Productivity Increasing farm productivity i s a key to Zambia agriculture exports to be competitive in global markets. Conservation fanning (CF) i s one o f the major positive innovations inrecent years in Zambia, which has improved farm productivity (i.e. crop yields) o f smallholder production systems. CF i s based on improved farm management technology, which can lead to improved profitability o f farm operations. Therefore, it has been also widely adopted by commercial and emergent farmers to minimize input costs and increase productivity. CF has gained popularity among smallholders in response to perceived needs to increase fertilizer efficiency, better conserve and manage water resources, increase productivity, and also to spread labor more evenly over the year. One o f the emergingsuccess stories has been the adoption o f CF by many smallholders who participate in cotton (i.e. Dunavant) outgrower schemes. There i s a potential to support the further expansion o f CF practices for a larger number o f smallholders, especially inconjunctionwith the development o foutgrower andother contract farmingschemes. Improve Smallholders Risk Management Capacity Zambia's smallholders face significant climatic, as well as market and health risks. Outgrower schemes directly address many o f the market related risks (e.g., price risk, market access risk). Health risks are best dealt directly with the health sector. This leaves weather-based risks, which for smallholders without irrigation, are very important. Weather-based insurance instruments can facilitate farmers' access to credit and thereby allow them to purchase the inputs which can boost productivity. Currently, commercial banks are unwilling to lend to smallholder farmers for a variety o f reasons, including the risk that farmers would not be able to repay their loans ifthere was drought. The index based weather insurance instruments can improve farmer's creditworthiness. Under these schemes, interested commercial banks can team up with insurance companies to provide loans that include insurance on weather risk that is based on the farmer's local rainfall index. The farmer would pay an interest rate that includes the weather insurance premium. Ifthere is a drought that triggers a pay out from the insurance contract, funds will be paid to the bank to pay o f f the farmers' loans. If there is no drought, the fanners will benefit 55 from selling the higher value production inthe marketplace. The index-based weather insurance instruments have been successfblly piloted inMalawi and it could be also introduced in Zambia where commercializing smallholders have, ingeneral, more diverse access to export markets due to the development o f a dynamic agribusiness sector. There i s a scope for donors, working with banks and insurance companies, to support implementation o f weather-based insurance systems by supportingtechnical assistance andnecessary start-upinvestments. Strategy 2: Reform and Strengthen Implementation of Sectoral, Multi-sectoral and Macro Policies Many issues that are critical for smallholder commercialization are part and parcel o f broader "investment climate" issues in the country, which could be addressed through the coordinated policy dialogue. There are opportunities for sectoral, multi-sectoral, and macro policy interventions that are relatively low cost, and have potentially significant impacts, and high returns. A constraint to rapidly,achieving these reforms is the broader political economy situation inZambia. Sectoral policies for agriculture need to reflect a strong growth orientation, with attention also devoted to food security and safety net issues. First, there is a need to speed-up policy reforms which improve enabling business environment, especially as they relate to weaknesses in legal and judiciary systems in Zambia, which affect the long-term sustainability o f contract farming (i.e., outgrower schemes) arrangements. Second, there i s a need to reduce the uncertainty o f the Government policy making process, which has a negative effect on developing the private sector led markets and appropriate market institutions. Third, there is a need to take a broader and more holistic multi-sectoral approach to agricultural and rural development. This approach should include differentiated strategies for different household types and areas o f the country based on economic potential. Disadvantaged households and areas will require different strategies that complement efforts at smallholder commercialization. Improve Implementation of Existing Policies The overall policy environment for agriculture sector is generally conducive towards agricultural commercialization as pronounced in various Government policy documents (ACP,NAP). The main issues are related to weak implementation and administration o f existing policies, which often lead to uncertainties o f policy-making process and ad-hoc reversals o f manifested policy decisions. Furthermore, there is a continuing and damaging ambiguity in Government actions related to the division o f roles between the public and private sector. The Government i s under strong external pressure to abandon its interventionist role, but frequently finds ad hoc justifications, such as weather related shocks, to intervene. These ad hoc interventions run counter to Governments's often stated commitments to allow market forces to operate. The unpredictability o f policy interventions has a negative impact on the development o f the private sector, in general, and agri-businesses in particular. Donors have a role, through effective and persuasive policy dialogue, to improve the transparency and consistency o f the Government's policy making processes. This could include improving the efficiency o f allocation budgetary resources towards public goods and phasing out input subsidies; redefining the role o f public sector institutions, such as FRAYwhich currently carry out private sector hctions; and 56 improving the overall efficiency o f agricultural markets through introduction and enforcing appropriate policy acts (i.e. Agricultural Marketing Act). There i s also a scope to strengthen the institutional capacity o f M A C 0 and its related agencies which would increase their ability to communicate more effectively with political interest groups and other stakeholders, and improve its services to commercial agriculture stakeholders (i.e. seed certification, SPS control, policy analysis and market information systems). Improve Enabling Business Environmentfor Contract Farming Most o f the relevant policy and regulatory issues which fall under this strategic action are driven largely by the PSD Steering Committee and on-going policy dialogue between GRZ and key donors (includingthe Bank). The specific actions which relate to smallholder commercialization include addressing the significant weaknesses related to the legal and judiciary systems in Zambia, which make enforcement o f financial and commercial contracts between agribusinesses and smallholders very difficult (if not impossible). Legislative reformshmprovements are needed in areas such as the regulations for collective bargaining, conflict resolution and development o f standard contracts which have full legal backing. Related to this issue i s the need to introduce and implement a code o f conduct between enterprises and smallholders which has some legal backing and/or introduce a stand-alone legal framework which would regulate contract farming arrangements inZambia, given that almost one third o f smallholders are already involved in some form o f contract farming arrangements and numbers are increasing. These reforms would aim at creating appropriate procedures and the development o f clearly understood and fblly acknowledged mechanisms which are accepted by all relevant parties in the smallholder commercializationprocess. Improve Macroeconomic Management The aim o f this strategic action is to improve Government's macroeconomic management and deepen of financial markets which would increase availability o f credit to private sector at more affordable costs and reduce exchange rate volatility. The following actions are suggested. First, improve and develop instruments available to the monetary and fiscal authorities to manage foreign inflows e.g. through introduction o f a (competitively priced) forward market and better surveillance as well as to stimulate the development o f hedging instruments by financial intermediaries that the private sector can use to insure itself against exchange rate volatility caused by the structural characteristics o f Zambia's economy i.e. dependence on copper as its main export earner. Second, there i s a need for the GRZ to continue to enforce strict fiscal discipline to avoid large budget deficits and reduce domestic borrowing which can bring down interest rates and allow for increased availability o f financial resources to the private sector. Third, there might be a need to readdress the composition o f public expenditures towards productivity enhancing public expenditures that favor the tradable sector. This could include larger allocations o f budgetary resources towards agricultural research, extension ,transport and other productive infrastructure. 57 Strategy 3: Investments in Public Infrastructure This strategy would focus on investments o f public good nature that have potential to generate new economic opportunities, improve accessibility and facilitate forward and backward linkages to other sectors inthe economy. There is a need to support the development o f new approaches and partnerships for the delivery o f productive infrastructure assets (i.e. irrigation infrastructure, storage and post-harvesting facilities, etc.) in order to intensify smallholder farming and to improve the competitiveness o f value chains. Secondly, Zambia is a large country and resources for infrastructure development are extremely limited. There i s therefore a need for geographically targeted approaches for transport, energy and communication infrastructure investments. The strategic focus for infrastructure development should be on those rural areas which have the highest potential for agricultural growth and linked activities (e.g., development o f infrastructure growth poles). Promote Innovative Public-PrivatePartnershipsfor ProductiveInvestments In order to intensify smallholder farming and to improve the competitiveness o f value chains, new approaches and partnerships needto be considered and tested for the delivery o f productive infrastructure assets o f quasi-public nature, such as infrastructure, storage and post-harvesting facilities, etc. Inmany cases, this will meanthat donor agencies may need to work directly with the private agribusiness companies as implementing partners, rather through Government structures. This calls for both donors and the government to use creative approaches in the program designs, with adequate room for private sector participation in the implementation process. For example, one of the innovative approaches for developing Zambian irrigation potential could be to support innovative public-private partnerships in irrigation development (perhaps via an "Irrigation Fund"), on a matching grant basis, where the subsidy element would cover the cost o f construction o f structures o f public good nature, while private sector contribution would cover the cost o f on-farm investments for smallholders, and operating and maintenance o f the scheme on a long-term lease basis, which may include contract farming arrangements with smallholders. Other opportunities could include cost sharing inthe provision o f extension and farm advisory services to smallholders, adaptive research, the development o f market information systems, etc. Develop Infrastructure Growth Poles Significant investments for infrastructure development are needed if Zambia wishes to be competitive in global and domestic markets and to acceleratehstain its current growth path. This includes investments into road transport network, railroads, communication and rural electrification. However, Zambia i s a large country andresources for infrastructure development are limited. Furthermore, agricultural production potential in Zambia, both in terms o f natural resource endowment and economic viability, varies widely across rural space. There i s therefore a need for geographically targeted approaches to identify specific high potential areas (Le., growth poles), which would be targeted for road and communication infrastructure investments. There i s an increasing significance o f rural-urban linkages inthe livelihoods o f rural population in Zambia. Urban centers, including secondary towns, contribute to rural development in adjacent areas by generating off-farm jobs and acting as centers o f demand and markets for 58 agricultural produce from their surrounding rural region, either for local consumers or as links to national (including supermarket and food retail sector) and export markets. At the same time urban centers act as centers for the production and distribution o f goods and services to their rural regions. Zambia has relatively large urban population compared to other SSA countries (i.e. some 36 percent). The Copperbelt-Lusaka-Livingstone "line-of-rail" and a highway connection to highpotential districts inEastern Province (i.e. ago-ecological Zone 11) represents about half o f total smallholder households in Zambia and more than 80 percent o f urban residents. The strategic focus for infrastructure development should be on those rural areas which have the highest potential for agricultural growth through development o f urban-rural market linkages. Strategies, SuggestedActions and Indicative Timeframe Given its limited resources, the Government o f Zambia needs to consider the priorities and sequencing o f policy reforms and public sector investments. There are also actions that need to take place immediately to energize the existing outgrower schemes and plan for medium and longer term actions. In the summary table below, the three main strategies are presented along with priority actions, and an indicative timeframe (Table 10). 59 Table 10: Strategies, t Short-term Medium-term Longer-term Key (upto 1year) (1-3 years) (3-5 years) Facilitators Strategy I:StrengthenExis Develop appropriate farmer Develop appropriate farmer Private sector, organizations through organizations through NGOs, capacity buildingin capacity buildingin donors group formation group formation governance skills governance skills farm planning and farmplanning and business management business management skills skills market intelligence market intelligence training on contracts training on contracts Support development o f Support development o f Private sector, existing and new outgrower existing and new outgrower NGOs, schemes through: schemes through: donors targeted lines o f credits targeted lines o f credits for for working capital and working capital and term term financing financing matching grants for matching grants for farmer farmer training, private training, private extension, extension, technology technology transfer, and transfer, and general general value chain value chain strengthening strengthening Promote innovative Promote innovative Private sector, technology transfer efforts technology transfer efforts Donors, to increase smalholder to increase smalholder farm NGOs, GRZ farm productivity productivity Promote weather-based Promote weather-based Private sector, insurance instruments: insurance instruments: Donors, GRZ technical assistance technical assistance training and capacity training and capacity building building Strategy2: Reform and Str, pthen Implementation of Sed ral, Multi-sectoral and M a *oPolicies Improve implementation o f Improve implementation o f Improve implementation GRZin existingpolicies: existing policies: o f existing policies: consultation improve the efficiency o f improve the efficiency o f improve the efficiency with private allocating budgetary allocating budgetary o f allocating budgetary sector and resources towards public resources towards public resources towards donors goods and productive goods and productive public goods and investments investments productive investments phase out FSP fertilizer phase out FSP fertilizer phase out FSP fertilizer subsidies subsidies subsidies redefine and restrict the redefine and restrict the redefine and restrict the role o f FRA to role o fFRA to role o f FRA to maintenance o f strategic maintenance o f strategic maintenance o f strategic food reserves food reserves food reserves improve the efficiency o f improve the efficiency o f improve the efficiency agricultural markets agricultural markets o f agricultural markets through adoption o f through adoption o f through adoption o f Agricultural Marketing Agricultural Marketing Agricultural Marketing Act following the Act following the Act following the 60 guidelines from the guidelines from the guidelines from the Agriculture Marketing Agriculture Marketing Agriculture Marketing Development Plan and Development Plan and the Development Plan and the Agriculture Input Agriculture Input the Agriculture Input Marketing Plan Marketing Plan Marketing Plan improve the improve the improve the competitiveness o f competitiveness o f competitiveness o f Zambian agriculture Zambian agriculture Zambian agriculture (especially cotton (especially cotton (especially cotton growers) by enacting bio- growers) by enacting bio- growers) by enacting safety legislation. safety legislation. bio-safety legislation. capacity buildingo f capacity buildingo f capacity building of MACO andrelevant MACO andrelevant MACO and relevant agencies agencies agencies Improve enabling business Improve enabling business Improve enabling GRZ in environment: environment: business environment: consultation introduce widely introduce widely accepted introduce widely withprivate accepted code o f code o f conducts for accepted code of sector and conducts for outgrower outgrower schemes conducts for outgrower donors schemes introduce and improve schemes introduce and improve legal framework for introduce and improve legal framework for contract farming which legal framework for contract farming which would regulate collective contract farming which would regulate collective bargaining, conflict would regulate bargaining, conflict resolution and collective bargaining, resolution and development o f standard conflict resolution and development o f standard contracts which have full development o f contracts which have full legalbaclung and standard contracts legal backing and enforcement capacity. which have full legal enforcement capacity. backing and enforcement caDacitv. Improve macroeconomic Improve macroeconomic Improve macroeconomic GRZ in and risk management and risk management and riskmanagement consultation through: through: through: with private improve and develop improve and develop improve and develop sector and instruments available to instruments available to instruments available to donors the monetary and fiscal the monetary and fiscal the monetary and fiscal authorities to manage authorities to manage authorities to manage foreign inflows, incl. foreign inflows, incl. foreign inflows, incl. development o f hedging development o f hedging development o f hedging instruments instruments instruments continue to enforce strict continue to enforce strict continue to enforce fiscal discipline to avoid fiscal discipline to avoid strict fiscal discipline to large budget deficits large budget deficits avoid large budget readdress the readdress the composition deficits composition o f public of public expenditures readdress the expenditures towards towards productivity composition o fpublic productivity enhancing enhancing public expenditures towards public expenditures that expenditures that favor the productivity enhancing favor the tradable sector. tradable sector. public expenditures that favor the tradable sector. 61 Strategy 3: Investments in 1 blic Infrastructure Promote innovative public- Promote innovative GRZtogether private partnerships for public-private with private productive investments: partnerships for sector, donors credit, matching grants productive investments: andbudget allocations for credit, matching grants productive infrastructure andbudget allocations operated and maintained for productive byprivate sector (i.e. infrastructure operated irrigation) and maintained by private sector (i.e. irrigation) Develop infrastructure Develop infrastructure GRZ with growthpoles: growthpoles: donors and 0 construction and 0 construction and private sector rehabilitation o f rural rehabilitation o frural roads roads 0 construction and 0construction and rehabilitation o fmain rehabilitation o f main national and cross-border national and cross- transport infrastructure border transport 0 investments into rural infrastructure energy and 0investments into rural communication energy and infrastructure communication 0 farm bloc development infrastructure 0farm bloc development 62 References ABD (2005a). Impact ofPolicies ofNeighbouring Countries onAgriculture Growth- Mozambique. Zambia Working Paper. Copenhagen, Denmark,AgroBusiness Development A/S, Denmark. Adams, D.W. andD.A. Fitchett (1992). InformalFinance inLow-Income Countries. Boulder, Colorado, Westview Press. Agrifood Consulting International (2002a). RiceValue Chain Study: Cambodia. A Report Preparedfor the World Bank.PhnomPenh, Cambodia, Agrifood Consulting International. Boughton, D., D.Tschirley, et al. (2002). Cotton Sector Policies and Performance inSub- SaharanAfrica: Lessonsbehindthe NumbersinMozambique andZambia. Maputo, Mozambique, MADERDirectorate of Economics. Bwalya, M.(1999) "Conservation farming with animal traction insmallholder farming systems: Palabanaexperiences." InConsewation TillagewithAnimal Traction.Editedby P.G. Kaumbutho and T.E. Simaklenga. Resource Book of the Animal Traction Network for Eastern and SouthernAfrica (ATNESA): Harare. CDC (1989).Review of Smallholder Development Programs. Vols 1 & 2. London, Commonwealth Development Corporation. CDT (2003b). Cotton Outgrowers Schemes ProgressReport 2002-2003. Lusaka, Zambia, Cotton Development Trust. CHC Commodities (2004). Public Private PartnershipPlan. Lusaka, Zambia, CHC Commodities. Chiwele, D.KandR. Sikananu (2004) "Agriculture Development andFood Security inSub- SaharanAfrica: Builing a Case for More Support, A Case Study for Zambia." Submitted to FAO, Agriculture Policy Analysis Unit. September. Cluskey, F. (2004). Strengthening Zambian ProducerAssociations. May. Lusaka, Zambia, Export Development Programme-11. Copestake, J. (1998). "Agricultural Credit ManagementinZambia: Business Development, Social Security, or Patronage." Development Policy Review 16:5-28. Copestake, J. G. (1997). Encouraging Sustainable Smallholder Agriculture inZambia. Agricultural Services Reform inSouthernAfrica Project R6452CA. April. Bath, UK, Centre for Development Studies, Universityof Bathand Environment and Development Consultancy Ltd. Coulter, J., A. Goodland, et al. (1999).Marrying Smallholder Co-operation and Contract Farming for Agricultural Service Provision inSub-SaharanAfrica. Guideto Developing Agricultural Markets and Agro-Enterprises Series. Washington, D.C., World Bank. 63 Deininger, K. and P. Olinto (2000) "Why LiberalizationAlone Has Not Improved Agricultural ProductivityinZambia: The Role of Asset Ownership and Working Capital Constraints." Policy ResearchWorking PaperNumber2302. The World Bank: Washington, D.C. D e l Ninno, C. and A. Marini (2005) "Household's Vulnerability inZambia." SP Discussion PaperNo. 0535. The World Bank: Washington, D.C. Dolan, C., J. Humphrey, et al. (1998). HorticultureCommodity Chains: The Impact o fthe UK Market on the African FreshVegetable Industry.IDS Working Paper 96. Brighton, United Kingdom, Institute for Development Studies, Universityof Sussex. Dolan, K.,C. and J. Humphrey(2000). Value Chains andUpgrading: The Impact o fUK Retailers on the FreshFruit and Vegetables Industry inAfrica." Journal of Development Studies 37(2): 147-176. Droppelmann, K.(2005). Report on the ACF Out-grower Survey Analysis in2004. Lusaka, Zambia, The Agricultural Consultative Forum Secretariat. Eaton, C. and A. W. Shepherd(2001). Contract Farming: Partnershipsfor Growth. A Guide. FA0Agricultural Services BulletinNo. 145.Rome, FoodandAgriculture Organization ofthe UnitedNations. Emongor, R. A., A. Louw, et al. (2004). Securing Small Producer ParticipationinRestructured NationalandRegional Agri-food Systems: Zambia Country Report. August. Pretoria, South Africa, Department ofAgricultural Economics, Extension andRuralDevelopment, University of Pretoria. FA0(2005). Zambia: AgriculturalDevelopment Support Project for Smallholder Commercialization. Working Paper 1: Value Chain Development. FA0 andAfDB (2004). Zambia: Smallholder Agricultural Production andMarketingSupport Project. Preparation Report No. 04/019 ADB-ZAM. 31 May 2004. Lusaka, Zambia, Food and Agriculture Organization of the UnitedNations and African Development Bank. Francis, P.A., J.T. Milimo, G.A.Njobvu, and S.P.M. Tembo (1997) "Listening to Farmers: Participatory Assessment of Policy ReforminZambia's Agriculture Sector." The World Bank: Washington, D.C. Glover, D.and K.Kusterer (1990). Small Smallholders, BigBusiness: Contract Farmingand RuralDevelopment. London, Macmillan. Goletti, F., T. Purcell, et al. (2003). Concepts of Commercialization andAgricultural Development. Agrifood DiscussionPaper Series Number 8. Washington, D.C., Agrifood Consulting International. 64 Govereh, J., T. S. Jayne, et al. (2002). Developments inFertilizer Marketing inZambia: Commercial Trading, Government Programs andthe Smallholder Farmer. Working PaperNo. 4. Lusaka, Zambia, Food Security ResearchProject. Haantuba, H.(2003). Linkages between Smallholder FarmProducersand Supermarkets in Zambia. October 2003. Lusaka, Zambia, Foodand Agriculture Organization. Haggblade, S. andP. Hazel1(1988). Prospectsfor Equitable Growth inRural Sub-Saharan Africa. A G W Economic Discussion Paper 3. Washington D.C., World Bank. Haggblade, S. andG. Tembo (2003) "Conservation Framing inZambia." EPTD Discussion PaperNo. 108. International FoodandPolicy ResearchInstitute (IFPRI): Washington, D.C. see www. ifpri.org IFAD(1999). Smallholder Enterprise andMarketingProgramme.Formulation Report: Volume 2: Working Papers.Rome, International Fundfor Agricultural Development. IFAD(2003). AgriculturalMarketingCompaniesas Sources of Smallholder Credit inEastern and SouthernAfrica Experiences, Insights andPotential Donor Role. December.Rome, International Fundfor Agricultural Development. IFAD(2004). RuralFinance Programme.Formulation Report: Volume 1.Rome, International Fundfor Agricultural Development. Jayne, T. S. (1994). "DOHigh FoodMarketing Costs Constrain Cash Crop Production?" Economic Development and CulturalChange42(2): 387-402. Jayne, T. S., J. Govereh, et al. (2003). "Fertilizer Market Development: a Comparative Analysis o f Ethiopia, Kenya, andZambia." FoodPolicy 28: 293-3 16. Jorgensen, S.L. and Z. Loudjeva (2005) "A Poverty and Social Impact Analysis o f Three Reforms inZambia: Land, Fertilizer, and Infrastructure." Social Development Papers, PaperNo. 49. The World Bank:Washington, D.C.; Key, N.andD.Runsten(1999). Tontract Farming, Smallholders, andRuralDevelopment in Latin America: the Organization of Agro-processing Firmsand the Scale o f Outgrower Production." World Development 27(2): 381-401, MACO (2004d). NationalAgricultural Policy (2004-2015). Final.November 2004. Lusaka, Zambia, Ministryof Agriculture andCooperatives, Republic of Zambia. MACO (2004e). Outgrower Support Programme HalfYear ProgressReport 2004. Lusaka, Zambia, Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperatives. MACO (2005). National IrrigationPlan- Draft. August. Lusaka, Zambia, Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperatives, Republic o fZambia. 65 M A C 0 andZNFU (2004). Agriculture Market Plan. Lusaka, Zambia, Ministryof Agriculture and Cooperatives, Republic o fZambia, andthe Zambian NationalFarmer'sUnion. MAFF(2001). Agricultural Commercialization Programme (ACP) 2002-2005. November. Lusaka, Zambia, Ministryof Agriculture, FoodandFisheries. Marsh, R. andD.Runsten(1995). The Potential for Small Holder Fruit andVegetable Production inMexico: Barriers and Opportunities,. Paperpresented at the XIX International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association, Washington. McCulloch, N.B. Baulch, andM.Cherel-Robson (2000) "Globalization, Poverty and Inequality inZambia Duringthe 1990s." Paperpresentedat the OECD Conference onPoverty andIncome Inequality inDeveloping Countries: A PolicyDialogue on the Effects of Globalization. November 30-December 1,2000. see http://www.ids.ac.uk Milimo and others (2004) "Incapacitated Poor Persons inZambia: Report on a Studyby Participatory Assessment Group and Public Welfare Assistance Scheme". GTZ Social Safety Net Project. Lusaka. Minten,B, L.Randrianarison, andF.M.Swinnen(2006). "Global Retail Chains andPoor Farmers: Evidencefrom Madagascar." LICOS DiscussionPapers 164/2006. Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium. Parker, M.(2004). Agribusiness Approach to Market and a Comparative Analysis ofKenya, SouthAfrica, Zambia and Zimbabwe. Project No. 8 ACP ZA 028. August. Lusaka, Zambia, Export Development Programme - 11. Parker, B. and F. Mwape (2004). "Rural Poverty andVulnerabilityinZambia, 2004: A Qualitative Study." Paperpreparedfor DFID and The World Bank, Social Protection Unit. Patrick, I. Contract Farming inIndonesia: Smallholders andAgribusiness Working (2003). Together. ACIAR Technical ReportsNo. 54. Canberra, Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. Pearce, D.(2003). Buyer and Supplier Credit to Farmers: Do Donors have aRole to Play? CGAP ResearchPaper. Pinder, C. andD.Wood (2003). The Socio-Economic Impact o f Commercial Agriculture on RuralPoor and Other Vulnerable Groups. February. Lusaka, Zambia, Department For International Development, SFAP (2003). Support to Farmer Associations Project (SFAP): Mid-TermReview. August 2003. Lusaka, Zambia, Institute of Economic and Social Research, Universityo fZambia andN O W . Siegel, P.B. (2005) "Poverty Reducing Potential of Smallholder Agriculture inZambia: Dualism andDualismwithinDualism." BackgroundPaperpreparedfor the Poverty andVulnerability Assessment Consultation Workshop heldinLusaka, Zambia March 1-2,2005. 66 http://www.sarpn.org.zddocuments/sOOOOOO1/PVA consultations Smallholders Febr2005.pdf Sieael, P.B. (2005) "Profile ofZambia's Smallholders: Where andWho are the Potential Beneficiaries o fAgricultural Commercialization?" Background Paper preparedfor the Zambia Smallholder Agricultural Commercialization Strategy. October 2005. Siegel, P.B. andJ. Alwang. (2005) "Poverty Reducing Potential of Smallholder Agriculture in Zambia: Opportunities and Constraints.Africa Region Working Paper Series. Number 85. http://www.worldbank.ordafr/ws/index.htm Simmons, P. (2003). Overview of Smallholder Contract Farming inDeveloping Countries. Armadale, University o fNew England. Skjonsberg, E. (2003) "A Report on 25 Years of Rural ChangeinKefaVillage, Eastern Province, Zambia." Background Report for Zambia PSIA. Preparedfor Social Development Department. The World Bank: Washington, D.C. World Bank (2003). Zambia: The Challenge o f Competitiveness andDiversification. Report No. 25388-ZA. Washington, D.C., Private Sector UnitAfrica Region. World Bank and International Monetary Fund(2002). Zambia: Poverty Reduction StrategyPaper and Joint StaffAssessment. Report No: 24035-ZA. April 23,2002. Washington, D.C., Prepared by Staffs ofthe International Development Association andthe International Monetary Fund. World Bank (2004a) "Zambia Country Economic Memorandum: Policies for Growth and Diversification." Report No. 28069-ZA Washington, D.C. World Bank (2004b). An Assessment o fthe Investment Climate inZambia -Africa Private Sector Group, Washington, D.C. World Bank (2004~).Zambia: Country Lending Assessment: PanelReport. Washington, D.C. World Bank (2005a) "The Republic ofZambiaJoint IDA-IMFStaffAdvisory Note on the SecondAnnual ProgressReport." Report 31572-ZA. Washington, D.C. World Bank (2005b) "Zambia: Poverty and Vulnerability Assessment. "Report No. 32573-ZA. Discussion Draft. Washington, D.C. June 29,2005. World Bank (2005~)"Summary of Zambia Investment Climate Assessment." Africa Region, Private Sector Group. NoteNumber 5. September.Washington, D.C. WorldBank (2006) Agriculture Investment Sourcebook. Washington, D.C. World Bank (2006) "Zambia: Agricultural Development Support Project: Project Appraisal Document." Report 35804-ZA.Washington, D.C. 67 Annex 1 Descriptionof Major Smallholder CommoditySub-sectorsin Zambia Cotton Cotton production in Zambia increased in the late 1 9 7 0 ' ~when the Lint Company o f Zambia ~ (LINTCO), a parastatal organization was established by GFU to control the cotton sector in Zambia, supplyingall inputs, extension services, credit facilities, technology and equipment, and procuring and processing all cotton produced. LINTCO was privatized in 1991. In 1996, London based Lonrho Plc established Lonrho Cotton Zambia Ltd and purchased three o f the LINTCO ginneries, making it the largest ginning company in Zambia. To meet its raw material requirements, Lonrho established an outgrower program providing inputs and extension services to farmers, resulting in a rapid increase in the number o f smallholder farmers producing cotton who were attracted by pre-financing o f inputs, guaranteed market access, pre-planting price guarantee and relatively favorable pricing. However, large scale side-buying and side-selling resulted in the inability to recover credits and secure enough produce to keep its activities profitable, and contributed to the withdrawal o f Lonrho from Zambia in 1999, after having sustained repeated heavy losses. Dunavant Ltd.took over Lonhro's cotton business and instituted a new system called "Dunavant Distributor System", whereby independent agents contract with the company to receive inputs on credit and deliver them along with extension services to farmers. Agents' earnings are a function o f credit recovery, so they have an incentive to provide quality inputs on time with extension and to have highyields andrepayment rates. Currently the cotton industry is dominated by four major companies; Dunavant (Z) Ltd, Clark Cotton (Z) Ltd, Continental Ginnery and Zambia-China Mulungushi Textiles. Of the four companies, Dunavant is the largest. All companies procure their cotton from smallholder farmers through outgrower arrangements. Smallholder produced cotton in Zambia i s known for its relatively good quality due to higher quality o f hand-picked cotton in comparison with mechanically harvested cotton, although the good quality is in part offset by the short staple length characteristic o f the cotton. The industry, which earlier suffered from side-selling and side-buying has been able to organize itself, largely thanks to the introduction o f the innovative distributor system which has had a highrecovery o f loans for the farmer's inputs. In2004, Zambia produced 172,000 ton of seedcotton, up from 45,000 tons in 1999. Exports of cotton lint have increased significantly from about US$ 8 million in 1999 to US$ 70 million 2005. The impressive performance o f the sector is due to significant investments made by private sector to encourage and stimulate smallholder production. All cotton produced in Zambia is ginned locally, however, none o f the ginneries in Zambia are runningat full capacity. This is mainly because o f the low and declining yields o f smallholder cotton production. It is estimated that more than 95 percent o f total cotton production in Zambia is produced by approximately 260,000 smallholder farmers - approximately one in every four rural households 68 derives a part o f its income from cotton production. According to the 2005 Crop Forecasting Survey, cotton was produced in 28 districts. However, production i s actually concentrated in a small number o f districts, with 3 districts producing 40 percent o f Zambia's cotton (Le. Choma district in Southern province and Lundazi and Chipata in Eastern province). The average yield attained by majority o f smallholders is about 600 k g h a or less, while with a good management practices and crop husbandry techniques it would possible to reach average yields o f 800 k g h a even with the same input 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Production (tons) 45,000 75,000 116,000 118,000 172,000 Export value (USD 8.1 15.0 24.3 29.5 51.6 70.0 mill.) Number of cotton 95,000 12,000 145,000 160,000 227,000 300,000 farmers Average yields (tons/ha) I 1.58 I 0.87 I 0.76 I 0.75 I 0.6 Source: Cotton Development Trust, Cotton Outgrowers SchemeProgress Report 2002-2003, and ZNFU Cotton planting is sensitive to prices; unusually high international prices in 1998 preceded a spike inland planted and production in 1999. Cotton prices have continued to fluctuate inrecent years and there i s some evidence o f a long term decline in real prices. Combined with international price movements, with smallholders recording lower average yields and ginneries runningbelow capacity, the long-term competitiveness and sustainability o f the cotton sub-sector i s uncertain. Tobacco Tobacco i s the second largest smallholder crop inZambia, and together with cotton, accounts for about 50 percent of Zambia's total agricultural exports. In 2004/5 there we 23,389 licensed tobacco farmers in Zambia in 2004/05, out o f which about 100 were large-scale commercial farmers36. Most o f the licensed farmers are contracted by four companies - StancordDimon, Zambia Leaf Tobacco Company, Tombwe Processing Ltd., and Associated Central Afiica Ltd. Zambia's tobacco exports show no noticeable trend. Production o f both flue-cured and burley tobacco have fluctuated over the years although there has been some modest increase in recent years, with the active participation o f major multinational tobacco buyers sourcing smallholder burleytobacco mainly from two districts inEasternProvince- Lundazi and Chipata. The bulk o f Zambia's tobacco is currently sold through Zimbabwe and Malawi, where there are well- developed auction and processing facilities. ' 35 For comparison, the average yield o f the world's largest cotton producer, China, is about 1,000 kg/ha. Average ields o f cotton inNortheast Brazil, which has similar agro-ecological conditions to Zambia are about 1,100 kgha. According to the ZNFU, licensedtobacco farmers employ up to 100,000 smallholders and rural dwellers to work on their tobacco fields though informal contract arrangements. 69 Zambia remains a very small player in international tobacco trade, with its total production o f 18,800 tons of burley and 15,000 tons of Virginia in2005, contrasting with Malawi's production of 150,000 tons burley and 15,000 tons Virginia flue-cured. Zimbabwean production was 68,000 tons in 2004 (down from 175,000 tons in 2002, mostly flue-cured). The political and economic instability in Zimbabwe has led international tobacco companies to search for potential alternative supply sources, including Zambia, Mozambique, and Tanzania. Tobacco production volumes increased from 7,000 tons in 1999 to 33,800 tons in 2005 season, o f which some 60 percent was produced by smallholders. Total value o f tobacco received by farmers in2005 was US$50.1 million, of which US$20.7 million went to burleytobacco farmers. Table 2: Tobacco productionandvalue, 1999 to 2005 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Weight (ton) 7,067 6,483 6,682 13,217 17,701 29,331 33,800 Value (USD 9,919 6,910 8,739 14,851 22,275 52,096 50,080 '000s~ Source: TAZ Paprika/Chilli Paprika was introduced to Zambia in 1993 by Cheetah Zambia Ltd. who started promoting paprika in the commercial farming sector. Support for smallholder paprika production began in 1997/1998. After the initial success, a number o f other organizations started to promote the crop inthe smallholder sector. In 1997 the Zambia High Value Agriculture Corporation (ZAHVAC) was established by a small group of people who wanted to promote smallholder paprika production around Lusaka. The members o f ZAHVAC (Enviro Oil & Colourants, Biopest, Mipachima and White Rose) provided inputs and market for paprika. ZAHVAC and its members received a significant donor support. However, most of the companies under ZAHVAC have ceased their operations when donor support stopped, or are continuing their activities on a much-reduced scale. Other enterprises and NGOs also supported smallholder paprika production at one time or another who sold their produce either to Cheetah or ZAHVAC for export37. Total production ofpaprika inZambia grew from 1,500 tons in 1998 to 3,000 tons in2002, when exports reachedUS$2.5 million. However, since this time there hadbeen a serious decline inthe sector, largely because o f rivalry between two main exporters which resulted inthe development of a culture o f side selling. In2004 the value of exports has declined to a mere US$ 0.9 million inspite of the significant support the sector has received from donors and the void inthe export market caused by the problems in Zimbabwe. The later is particularly disappointing as production in Zimbabwe started at the same time as in Zambia and export reached around US$ 20 million a year before the start o f its politicalproblems. 37 Some of the donor supportedNGO projects includedCLUSA programinEasternProvince,Africare and KalingwizaEnterprisesLtd. inEasternProvince, Agricrops Ltd. inWesternProvince, CONASA inSouthern Province. 70 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Weight (tons) 309 753 1,041 680 197 605 Value (USD 402 1,069 1,686 2,512 170 944 ,000) I I I I I I I I Source: Internal Accord Associates, based on Corntrade data The crop is suitedto smallholders who currently dominate production. The crop fits comfortably into a cotton-soya rotation and as Eastern province produces about 50 percent o f Zambia's cotton, the scope for paprika i s there to be developed. The number o f smallholders contracted through outgrower schemes reached 6,000 farmers in 2002, but has been in decline since then. The industry currently contracts less than 5,000 smallholders. More that 50 percent o f production comes from Chongwe district, Lusaka Province, with another 25 percent coming from Mazabuka district, Southern Province. Smallholder paprika crop i s generally o f a lower quality than commercially produced paprika, making it necessary to blend higher and lower qualities o f paprika to meet minimum export quality standards. In addition, paprika produced by smallholder farmers is often contaminated from aflatoxin, E. coli and salmonella. This i s due to poor management practices during drying and inadequate storage facilities. In addition, yields o f smallholder farmers are well below its potential. The average yield attained by majority o f smallholders is about 400 k g h a or less, whereas with a good management practices and crop husbandry techniques it would possible to reach average yields o f 600-800 k g h a even with the same input level. A new opportunity for Zambian smallholders is to produce chili peppers, which are closely related to paprika. African Spice Ltd. (ASL), which i s operating in Livingstone district, i s a chili processing company operating in Zambia and promoting chili as both a high value export and a development crop for Africa. It has been actively involved in the development o f chilli cultivation throughout the Zambezi Valley since 2001 and has a strong focus on helping smallholders to produce crops that are both profitable and sustainable. Incorporated in March 2004 inZambia as part o f the relocation o f business operations from Zimbabwe, ASL has started establishing linkages with small-scale and larger commercial farmers in Southern province around the Livingston region. The strength in ASL's offering lies in their exclusive contract to supply Tabasco chilli mash to McIlhenny Company USA. Inaddition ASL has built strategic relationships with merchants that export dried chili products to the USA, Europe and South Africa. Given that A S L can continue to produce high quality chili mash product and meet its targets, the room for expansion and increase sales i s forecasted at 300 percent growth per annum over the next four years. Current production which comes largely from some 100 contracted smallholders stands at 342 tons. Vegetables The export o f horticulture crops began in Zambia in the early-1980's with a small number of commercial producers. The development o f horticulture focused on exports o f mangetout, fine beans, baby carrots, baby corn and other crops to the UK and North European markets. The industry gradually expanded and became much more professional and is regarded as significant 71 competition to Kenya, which is the biggest exporter o f air-freighted horticultural produce to Europe. Horticulture exports peaked in 2003, but have decreased since then. This decline was mainly due to the biggest horticultural exporter - Agriflora - went into receivership in 2004. Currently there are three main exporters o f horticultural produce - York farm, Borassus and Chalimbana. The main market i s the EU (predominantly the UK supermarkets), with small amounts exportedto South Africa, Australia and the Far East Table 4: Values and weight of horticultural exports, 1999 to 2005 Source: ZEGA The vast majority o f export vegetables grown inZambia are produced within 50 km radius from Lusaka. Various donor supported projects have promoted smallholder export vegetable production through outgrower schemes. At its peak, Agriflora had established outgrower arrangements with up to 500 growers. This number is now reduced to 85 ex-Agriflora growers who are currently supplying baby corn to some commercial farms for export. These smallholders do not currently meet EUREPGAP quality and safety standards required by the industry, although baby corn is a relatively safe crop for small-scale commercial farmers to grow, due to the low volumes o f chemicals used and the protective sheath around the cob. Smallholder vegetable growers generally do not have the capacity to make the investments needed to upgrade their facilities to meet EUREPGAP standards, nor do they have the technical capacity to compete inthis highly competitive andregulated sector without continual supervision by a sponsoring partner. Commercial exporters that runtheir own packinghouses, however, are not prepared to engage in this supervisory activity - at least not without some special compensation from donors, NGOs or government. Sugar Sugar has remainedone o fZambia's leading agricultural export for the last decade and accounted for about 20 percent o f these exports during 1999-2003. Zambia has a quota under the EUSugar Protocol, allowing it to sell at a favorable price o f more than500 per ton and sell 20,000 tons to the Portuguese market. About 40 percent of Zambia's sugar exports go to the Great Lakes region in Africa, mostly to the Democratic Republic o f Congo (DRC), and more recently to Kenya. A further 10,000 tons goes to the South African market. Entryinto the latter market was the primary factor in the jump in exports in 2001. Internationally, Zambia is considered a low cost producer o f sugar and would benefit from Wher liberalization o f this highly distorted market. The major player o f the sub-sector, Nakambala Sugar Refinery based in Mazabuka district, Southern Province, has utilized its milling capacity, about 150,000 tons o f sugar, annually. Nakambala accounts for more than 80 percent o f the total production and over 90 percent o f Zambia's sugar exports. About 11percent o f sugarcane processed by the refinery i s supplied by 160 smallholders who have been linked to outgrower scheme through the independent management company called Kaleya Smallholder Company limited (KASCOL). However, 72 There i s very limited scope within existing outgrower schemes to easily expand smallholder sugar production. 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Sugar (US$ 23,143 22,754 37,043 35,111 35,249 35,990 65,296 `000) Source: EBZ Coffee The coffee sector was supported by the World Bank loans inthe 1980sand 1990sthrough Coffee IandI1projects, which includedprivatization ofthe government-owned Zambia Coffee Company and the subsequent plantings o f nearly 1,000 hectares by African Plantations Company. With the maturation o f this and other plantings, commercial coffee production has grown steadily, underpinning a rise in exports despite the unfavorable trend in international coffee prices. Production has grown steadily from 3,450 tons in 1999 to 6,655 tons in2005, and exports are about US$ 10 million a year. Ininternational terms, Zambia is a veryminor exporter ofcoffee. Itproduces about 6,000-7,000 tons o f Arabica coffee per year, o f which more than 99 percent comes from about 40 large-scale commercial estates. The number o f smallholder coffee growers i s estimated at 250 farmers who cultivate in average 0.5 ha o f coffee. Until recently, the quality of Zambian coffee was considered better than that of many o f its competitors. It i s regarded as having an acidic taste and thin body, which i s in high demand among the world's blenders and roasters. As a result, producers have regularly received a premiumover the benchmark coffee prices. However, Zambia i s a relatively high cost producer because nearly all production involves irrigation, while competitors obtain high yields under rain-fed conditions. The viability of the sector will thus depend upon its attaining and maintaining a reputation for high quality, and achieving the premium prices which accompany this. Efforts are being made to add value to Zambia coffee and attempts are made to develop niche market opportunities. 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Weight (tons) 3,450 2,200 5,868 5,000 6,500 5,881 6,655 Value ($US 9,695 4,492 9,048 6,250 6,810 7,578 9,712 thousands) 1Average price 2,811 2,041 1,542 1,250 1,135 1,289 1,846 ($US/t) Source: ZCGA Honey Smallholders inNorth-Western Province inZambia have beenproducing honey andbeeswax for many years. Traditionally, the honey was wild-harvested and used in the production of local beer. More recently there have been a number o f initiatives to encourage smallholder honey 73 production in hives and develop exports. It is now estimated that there are about 500,000 hives and 10,000 smallholder beekeepers inNorth-Westem Province who are linked to export markets through outgrower schemes. The province i s an accredited producer o f organic and "Fair Trade" honey and receives premiumprices inthe export market. The private sector estimates that total honey exports are about 600 to 700 tons, worth about USD 1.5 to 2 million each year, which i s higher than the Central Statistics Office data inthe table below. I (thousands) I I I I I Source: CSO There are two main exporters o f honey who organize also smallholder outgrower schemes - Forest Fruits and North Western Bee Products who, along with Honey Bee Farms, have formed the Zambia Bee Products Association. Despite the impressive growth o f honey exports and establishing a good name in the EUmarket, the Zambian honey industry reportedly operates on small margins. This is because o f the high costs o f transport to collect the honey from the rural villages and then move it from North-Western Province to Lusaka and then to the international markets. Inaddition, it requires a large number o f people to harvest the hives, organize and train the producer groups and operate the equipment in factories to separate the honey out from the combs. Since the Government-owned glass factory at Kapri Mposhi closed, Zambia has had to import glass jars, which has made retail packing o f honey very difficult. The retail packs of honey for the local market use low quality plastic jars which are unsuitable for export. The lack o f good quality packing facilities hampers the development o f regional market opportunities. Forest Fruits export most o f its honey to Europe inbulk where it i s blended with other sources and sold mainly into the catering or industrial market where it is used as an ingredient for organic pastriedcakes etc. Another exporter sends honey to Europe in bulk where it i s repackaged into glassjars for retailing. Dairy The dairy sub-sector is currently static in production and its processing capacity has declined from a decade ago. Parmalat, the largest processor in Zambia buys 85 percent o f its raw milk supplies from commercial farmers and enters in to a five year production contract with them. These farmers also hold shares in the processor so there i s a symbiotic relationship between the commercial producers and the processors. Parmalat sees its current processing capacity capped at 20 million liters a year, 15 percent o f which comes from small-scale farmers and estimates the total size o f the formal milk market at 35 million liters, with a hrther 15 million liters coming from the informal sector. Fresh milk consumption in Zambia is stagnant and the capacity to diversify into yoghurts and flavored drinks i s limited. Consumers on lower incomes tend to favor powdered milk as this allows them to consume exactly the quality they want and not have to contendwith an open packet that has a limitedshelf life. . 74 Monthly local processing output in Zambia i s about 3,354,000 liters per month and monthly imports of dairy products (estimated) i s currently runningat 250,000 - 300,000 liters per month. A lot o f these imports are beingbrought inby the supermarket chains and shows the scope for the industry to expand to meet demand if the large South African supermarket chains were to change their buying policies. Development o f regional markets i s talked about but has not materialized inany significant quantities yet due to transport difficulties andbarriers to entry into these countries both physical and political. 75 Annex 2 Recommendationsfor BestPracticeOutgrowerModels For outgrower models to succeed there must be ideally a demand-driven approach for all services. Processing or buyingcompanies, representing the markets, must be able to demonstrate a sustainable demand for their product prior to commencing the development o f an outgrower scheme. Producers should demonstrate a desire to participate in outgrower schemes, and for commercial development and income generation. There should be a demand (and readily available supply) from local service providers to be involved in schemes, providing inputs and services on a commercial basis. Finally, there should be interest and support from Government authorities at all levels in order to minimize disruptions and problems at a later stage. We will discuss below the key elements that could be incorporated into outgrower models based on the findings o f outgrower case studies: Criteriafor grower selection. Ifanoutgrower scheme is to succeed and eventuallybecome a self-sustaining income generating supply chain, focus has to be placed on ensuringthat the right caliber producers are contracted. There i s a need for developing selection criteria to ensure that potential participants inoutgrower schemes meet minimum standards. Selection criteria could include land availability, location and conditions, agricultural knowledge and experience, basic business-awareness and willingness to learn. Minimum acceptable production standards relating to yield and quality should also be developed. Farmers repeatedly failing to meet these standards should be removed from the scheme to increase its sustainability. Whereas this i s already happening to some extent through self- selection o f farmers, this issue may have to be approached much more pro-actively. Developing selection criteria and production standards will also help in assessing what level of support i s required to facilitate fix-ther development. Simple mechanisms that may enhance farmer selection are a contribution to the value o f inputs, or membership fees which entitle farmers to inputs at discounted prices. Registration of growers and maintenance of records. In order to ensure good and transparent management practices o f outgrower operations it is imperative to develop Management Information Systems (MIS) which would include information regarding personal details o f participating smallholders, location, credit provision, and previous crop history. Computer programs could be designed to facilitate monitoring the performance o f individual smallholder farmers (Le. providing a basis for assessing the eligibility o f farmers for higher input packages through tracking their performances). In more developed outgrower schemes the MIS could be linked to GIS aerial mapping systems, which include more detailed information about landuse planning. 76 Contracts. There i s need for a balanced contract design with risks, incentives and enforcements modalities being fairly applied for all parties. It is desirable that contracts or agreements between companies and farmers are transparent and comprehensive, incorporating as a minimumpersonal details o f the individual farmer, identification and registration number, area contracted, period o f agreement, quality requirements, grades and their descriptions, input costs and repayment modalities, extension provision, and obligations and responsibilities o f the two parties to the contract or agreement. Contracts and agreements should be understood by the farmers. This may require translation o f the contract or agreement into the local language. If necessary, the company or a third party must provide a degree o f training and capacity building amongst the farmers to ensure that they understand and accept the terms o f the contract. To facilitate this, a degree o f training and capacity buildingmay be required to ensure transparency. Input supply and loan recovery. Conditions that apply to the provision o f inputs, the range o f inputs made available, their cost, farmer contributions towards the value o f inputs, interest charged and repayment modalities must be clearly stipulated incontract terms. MIS could enable companies to record all inputs supplied on credit against the producers' IDS,as well as deductions made against crop delivery. Timely delivery o f inputs and other services needs to be properly planned and should respond to farmers' needs, creating incentives for farmers to honor contracts. The better and broader the range o f services offered, the closer the relationship between fanners and business, and the more the farmer will lose bybreaking the relationship. Extension services. There may be a need for companies to perform a training and extension needs assessment to establish a base line to enable them to plan the implementation or expansion o f extension services to smallholder farmers, who could be involved in the process to ensure that their needs are being addressed where feasible. If feasible, the costs of extension services should be reflected in the prices paid to smallholders so that there i s a clear understanding by the fanners that extension services received are not free o f charge. It i s imperative that farmers are charged for the service in a clear and transparent way so that they can evaluate the quality o f services provided and value for money. Pricing mechanisms. Farmers often expect a minimumpre-planting price for the crop they wish to grow. However, in view o f uncertainties with regard to developments on the international markets or macro- economic policies of governments, this is often not feasible for the outgrower companies. Absence o f pre-planting prices, coupled with limited or no understanding o f why and how international market prices fluctuate and how companies derive the price they pay for the produce, and limited access to information, particularly in a format that can be understoodby the farmers, leads to uncertainty and a feeling o f exploitation. Development o f transparent pricing systems could alleviate some o f these constraints. Furthermore, grading standards and their 77 relationships to product prices should be clear and transparent to the farmers. When possible, visual grading aids should be made available. Farmers need to be well trained in grading o f the produce. When there i s a differentiation inprices paid at the factory gate or at the depotshying centers (farm-gate price), farmers should have a free choice inwhere to deliver their produce. Payment modalities. Payment to farmers should be as prompt as possible. Any transaction should be properly recorded, indicating grades, corresponding weights and prices, total value o f the delivery, and any deductions for inputs or, ifapplicable, other services provided. Group development and communication facilitation. It is suggested that group leaders are the main linkbetweenthe companies and farmers. Selection o f a group leader i s mostly an interactive process between the company and the group. Group leaders must be literate and be able to keep a minimum o f administration, and also accepted and trusted by the farmers. Good communication and close monitoring remain particularly critical issues, especially with export products involving European and Northern American markets, where there i s a need to ensure quality and traceability o f produce. When communication between agribusiness and farmers is weak, group members can still monitor each other. More generally, good communications to foster good company-farmer relationships and a sense o f trust has a positive effect by reducing strategic farmer default. Peer pressure mechanisms with groups can further contribute to a reduction o f farmer default by eliminating potential defaulters. Development of a sub-sector specific Code of Conduct. The objective o f a Code o f Conduct would be to promote ethical and transparent trading between buyers (processing and procurement companies), service providers, and smallholder farmers, with the aim o f establishing minimum standards o f service and transparency. Most elements of outgrower best practices could be captured ina Code o f Conduct. Participationinthe Code should be voluntary. However, it i s suggsetd that outgrower companies and smallholder service providers that sign up to conform to the Code o f Conduct, will be certified after having been audited by independent auditors, with reviews being carried out at regular intervals to ensure that they continue following the code. The development and introduction o f a Code o f Conduct must be supported by discussions with the judicial system to ensure that contracts and agreements are enforceable, a problem that is currently faced by most outgrower companies. The Code o f Conduct could be used as a guideline to design agreements that are tailored to meet the specific requirements o f each industry, within the parameters outlined in the code. Adhering to the Code o f Conduct could possibly assist companies in exporting to the EU and other developed countries because o f compliance with increasingly stringent conditions. 78 Annex 3 Major On-goingDonor SupportedSmallholder CommercializationProjectsinZambia Duration Funding costs Objectives MainActivities Agency USD milli on 2006-2012 FAD 15 Increase inincomes and Measures to achieve a reduction inthe Livestock food security incidence o f ECF and CBPP Investment among poor smallholder Project (SLIP) farmers Re-stocking o f smallholder farmers through the restoration of who have lost their cattle due to their access disease to draught animal Dower 2000-2008 FAD 18.35 Increase the incomes o f Strengthen farmers' group, physical Enterprises smallholders by improving access to inputs, diversification and Marketing access to inputs,services legal/policy dialogue Program and marketing o f output (SHEMP) Small-scale 2001-2006 AfDB/AD 10.77 Increase food production Establishment of irrigation, rural Irrigation F and farmers' incomes in 3 banks, capacity buildingo f MAC0 districts and Cooperatives AfDB Support 1999-2004 AfDB 21.65 Enhance productive capacity Extension, credit, research, animal to A S P in the (extended o f smallholders and living health Eastern to 2007?) standards Province Agricultural 2003-2007 SIDA 42 Improved livelihoods in Crop diversification, seeds, land support terms of (a) increased food management, agribusiness. Program security, (b) increased (ASP) income through sale o f Development o f extension models agricultural related products based on "Farming as a business'' and services 79 Project Duration Funding costs Objectives MainActivities Agency USD million support to 2006- EC 19 Rural smallholders in Implementationo f the food Agricultural 2011 Western and North Western security components o f the N A P Diversification Provinces improve their operationalized and actionplans & Food performance with respect to implemented Security in food security and Western and agricultural diversification NorthWestern strategies Zambia Agricultural 2006- WB 37.2 To advance smallholder Provision o f capital for Deve1opment 2010 agriculture improved productivity, quality support commercializationalong and efficiency of value chains Program value chains W S P ) Targeted investments in publichollective goods such as feeder roads and key public service functions extension and technical advisory services to farmer groups and producer organizations Programme for 2006- FINLAND 13 Contribute to the Fisheries and Fish-farming Luapula 2009 development o f an efficient, Agricultural competitive and sustainable Agriculture and Non-Farm and Rural agricultural and rural sector, economic activities Development which ensures increased ( P L r n ) income and food security for Marketing and communication small-scale rural households inLuapulaProvince Institutional support Production, 2005- USAID 15 Increase smallholder client Finance and 201O? production and productivity, Improved reduce costs o fproduction, Technologies and, together with the Project private and public sectors, (PROFIT) extend services to some 100,000 smallholders in high-economic-potential areas o f Zambia. Market 2005- USAID 10 Increase access to markets Access, Trade 201O? and an improved enabling andEnabling environment for small and Policies medium agriculture and Project natural resource producers (MATEP) and processors 80