OLP5 3013 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3 063 Trade Liberalization, Firm Performance, and Labor Market Outcomes in the Developing World What Can We Learn from Micro-Level Data? Paolo Epifani The World Bank Ri! l Development Research Group iI Trade May 2003 A POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3063 Epifani reviews the micro-level evidence on the effects of 0 There is evidence of a pro-competitive effect of trade and investment liberalization in the developing trade liberalization. world. He focuses, in particular, on the effects of the o There is no evidence either of learning-by-exporting 1991 trade reform in India since it provides an exczllent effects or of beneficial spillover cffects from foreign- controlled experiment in which the effects of a drastic owned to local firms active in the same sectors. trade regime change can be measured. His main findings o There is evidence, however, of positive vertical are: spillovers from foreign direct invcstment. o There is evidence of trade-induced productivity gains o There is evidence of skill upgrading induced either (in this respect, however, India is an exception). by technology imports or by traee-induced reallocations o These gains mainly stem from intra-industry of market shares in favor of plants with higher slcill- reallocation of resources among firms with different intensity. productivity levels ' There is no evidence of trade-induced increases in o The gains are larger in import-competing sectors. lbor demand elasticities. But direct cvidence suggests o There is no evidence of significant scale efficiency that trade exposure raises wage volatility. gains. Unilateral trade liberalization is often associated - There is no evidence of substantial employment with a reduced scale efficiency. contraction in import-competing sectors. This paper-a product of Trade, Development Research Group-is part of a larger effort in the group to assess the impact of trade and investment liberalization in developing countries. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Paulina Flewitt, room MC3-333, telephone 202-473-2724, fax 202-522-1159, email address pflewitt@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers arc also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at paolo.epifani@uni-bocconi.it. May 2003. (68 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about developm;zent issues. An obhectve of tbe series is toget the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the autthors and should he cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclz!sions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executdve Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by Partnerships, Capacity Building, and Outreach RTade Liberalization, Firm Performance and Labor Market Outcomes in the Developing World What Can We Learn from Micro-Level Data?* Paolo Epifanit University of Parma and CESPRI-Bocconi University 'This papci is part of the joint Centro Studi Luca d'Agliano-World Bank proje(t "Trade, technology diffusion aud performnauce ini Indian iuaiiufacturtng" I haive benefitecl from thc coniments of Francesco Daveri, Anna Falzoni, Rocdolfo Helg, Gianniarco Ottaviano, AlessancIra Tutcci aud Alebsan(lro Turrini I am especially gratefuil to Giorgio Barba Navaretti for helpful dibcitbsion anid advise The uisuial caveat applies tColrespondlelice UTnversitA Conimucrciale L Bocconi, via Sarfatti, 25 - 20136 Milano (Italy) Phone +39 02 58363378 Fax +39 (12 58363399 E-imail paolo opifamCimni-bocconi it 1 Introduction In the last decades, many developing countries (e g, Chile in the late 1970s, Turkey in 1983, Mexico in 1985, Colombia in 1990-91, India in 1991) have undergone a deep economic transformation which has involved a process of dramatic trade hberalization. This paper reviews the main erhpirical studies using firm and plant-level panel data to investigate the effects of trade reforms on firm performance and labor market outcomes in developing countries. We discuss, in particular, the effects of the 1991 trade reform in India, since it provides an excellent controlled experiment in whuch the effects of a drastic trade regime change can be measured The allocative efficiency argument for free trade has been extensively debated by the traditional trade theory in the context of perfectly competitive markets Since the late 1970s, however, the so-called new trade theory has shown that the gains from trade originating from specialization according to comparative advantage are only part of the story, since in the presence of imperfectly competitive markets trade liberalization can bring additional gains by reducing the deadweight losses created by domestic firms' market power. In particular, it has been argued that trade liber- alization, by increasing competition, forces firms to lower price-marginal cost mark-ups and hence move down their average cost curves, thereby raising firm size and scale efficiency. Recently, it 2 has also been shown that in the presence of within-industry firm heterogeneity, trade liberalization causes more productive firms to expand at the expense of less efficient firms (which either shrink or exit), thereby inducing additional efficiency gains Moreover, trade and investment liberaliza- tion may foster technology advancement and productivity growth in developing countries through several channels, such as technology advancement embodied in imported capital goods and interme- diate inputs, technology transfers accompanying foreign direct investment, learning-by-exporting effects, etc. In the last decade, a number of empirical works have resorted to firm and plant-level panel data to see whether the predicted gains from trade liberalization have materializedi in some recent episodes of drastic trade reform in the developing world. Most of these studies find that trade reform in developing countries was indeed accompanied by productivity growth, technology advancement, falling mark-ups and a reshuffling of resources toward the more efficient firms, although in some cases the evidence may fail to convince because of the hurdles involved in the methodology used in these studies. This is true, in particular, for India, where in some cases studies using slightly different methodologies find opposite results. However, aside from methodological issues, India seems an exception with respect to other trade liberalizing developing countries, since most studies find that the 1991 trade reform was in fact accompanied by a reduced productivity growth. One explanation for this result is that India is still a heavily regulated economy, and hence the expected benefits of industrial restructuring and of the trade-induced reallocation of resources are probably smaller and will take longer to materialize. Although the efficiency argument for trade liberalization has generally been accepted, the main argument against trade reform in the developing countries that have opted for ar import substi- tution industrialization strategy has often been that trade liberalization would exacerbate income inequality and hence deteriorate the conditions of the poor. In particular, concerns regarding higher unemployment among workers displaced by the contraction of import competing sectors, greater uncertainty and precariousness of job conditions, and the creation of new job opportunities only 3 for the most qualified segments of the workforce have often been deemed inevitable consequences of trade liberalization. In this respect, the traditional trade theory (which removes, by assumption, uncertainty and unemployment) should have been reassuring, since its most celebrated theorem (the Stolper- Samuelson theorem) predicts that a skill-poor developing country opening up to international competition will experience a reduction in wage income inequality However, the empirical evi- dence contradicts this prediction, since it shows that the recent episodes of trade liberalization in developing countries are generally accompanied by a dramatic increase in wage inequality The recent theoretical and empirical literature can explain this puzzling evidence, since it shows that in the presence of imperfectly competitive markets, increasing returns to scale and firm heterogeneity, trade hberalization can indeed exacerbate wage inequality even in a skill-poor developing country Plant-level evidence also shows that trade reforms in developing countries do not generally bring a sharp contraction of import competing skill-intensive sectors. Further, the evidence shows that trade exposure is associated with a greater wage volatility, but also with a greater investment in technology and human capital This evidence, too, can generally be explained by trade models based on increasing returns to scale and imperfectly competitive markets. A few recent papers address related issues from different perspectives. Harrison and Hanson (1999) focus on three empirical issues concerning the impact of trade reform First, they address the question of the weak econometric link between trade policy and long-run growth, and argue that it may be due to the fact that, because of the lack of data, trade policy cannot yet be measured adequately The second and third issues addressed by the authors are the small impact on employment and the large Impact on wage inequality of trade reforms in developing countries We will mention their results on these topics in the second part of the paper Matusz and Tarr (1999), and Bacchetta and Jansen (2001) survey the evidence on the adjustment costs of trade liberalization They show that the overwhelming majority of the studies find that adjustment costs are small in relation to the benefits of trade liberalization Finally, Tybout (2001) reviews 4 the plant-level evidence in the light of the new trade theory. Our work is complementary to his, since our review also extends to the effects of trade reforms on the labor markcets and, most important, it provides a more extensive treatment of the theoretical foundations of empirical work. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 illustrates the theoretical predictions concerning the effects of trade liberalization on firm performance. Section 3 discusses the relevance of these effects for trade liberalizing developing countries in the light of the micro-level evidence. Section 4 reports the plant-level evidence on the impact of trade liberalization on learning and technology diffusion. Sections 5 and 6 examine the labor market outcomes of trade liberalization Section 7 analyzes the effects of the 1991 trade liberalization in India. Section 8 concludes. 2 Thade Uleralbe atio and ISr PeirarmT cze When markets are imperfectly competitive, trade liberalization may affect firm-level variables, such as mark-ups, size and productivity This section illustrate these effects, while the next reviews the plant-level evidence on their empirical relevance. To see how trade liberalization can affect firm performance, first consider a simple setting with representative firms 1 Next we will show that more can be learned by alloving for firm heterogeneity. Consider then n identical firms competing d la Cournot in a sector producing a homogeneous good. Aggregate demand has a constant elasticity a. Technology features plant-level scale economies and is summarized by the following total cost function. TC = f 1 q (1) where q is firm output, f is a fixed overhead cost and 1/40 is a constant marginal cost. Both f and 1/0 are in terms of labor, the only production factor, chosen as numeraire. Profit maximization by TiTIs vxa,uple (Iraws on Markusen (1981). Sunilai results indei different abbumuptions about nmarket struc.ture (an be foiind iu Krugman (1979) ancd Helpmuan and Krugman (1985) 5 individual firms (taking the output of rivals as given) implies the following mark-up pricing rule _ _ _ _ -(2) an-1 ,( Equation (2) is crucial for understanding the pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization. It shows that a firm's price-marginal cost mark-up, f,n , depends negatively on the perceived product demand elasticity, (Tn. Thus, when firms face a fiercer competition due to a rise in the number (n) of rivals, they perceive a higher demand elasticity and consequently lower their mark-up. With unrestricted entry, profits (ir) are zero in equilibrium: 7r = (p- /I)q-f = O => q = fv((an-1) (3) Finally, full employment of labor (L) requires: L = nl = n(f + q/p) (4) where 1 = f + q/l represents labor employed by each firm. Solving equations (3) and (4) for n and q gives. (>f ) ' g f'# [(YL _ ) 1 (5) It can be shown that trade integration among countries with similar tastes and technology is formally equivalent to an increase in the size of the economy, as captured by an increase in L. The effects on firm performance are straightforward: 1) Equation (5) shows that trade integration (i.e., a rise in L) raises the number of firms n. From (2), this implies that.firms perceive a higher demand elasticity and hence lower their price and mark-up. This is the pro-compettttve effect of trade integration 2) Trade integration raises firm size q (see equation (5)) 6 3) The trade-induced increase in firm size raises firm productivity (given by q/l) due to a better exploitation of scale economies. This is the scale effictency gazn from trade integration. 2. I Tntroducing firm heteroge neity The above results have been derived from a setting with representative firms Several reasons suggests, however, to extend the general equilibrium trade models to allow for firm heterogeneity. In particular: 1) Recent work inter alta by Roberts and Tybout (1996), Olley and Pakes (1996), Aw, Chen and Roberts (1997) reports evidence of a significant degree of within-industry plant-level heterogeneity. Hence, allowing for firm heterogeneity may add an important element of realism to the framework of analysis. 2) Micro-level empirical evidence shows that exporting firms have different characteristics with respect to non-exporting firms. In particular, the former are larger, more efficient, more skill- intensive and pay higher wages (Bernard and Jensen, 1997, 1999; Clerides et al., 1998). 3) Most plant-level empirical studies show that trade-induced productivity gains stemrning from the reshuffling of resources between plants with different productivity levels are more relevant than the scale efficiency gains due to a better exploitation of plant-level scale economies (Tybout, 2001; Tybout and Westbrook, 1995; Pavcnik, 2002). Therefore, trade models based on representative firms may miss an important mechanism through which trade reform affects the allocation of resources, aggregate productivity and income inequality. One of the most rigorous attempts to embed firm heterogeneity into a general equilibrium trade model is provided by Melitz (2002), who generalizes Krugman (1980) by dropping the assumption of symmetric firms2. This model provides new insights on the impact of trade liberalization on the intra-industry reallocation of resources and can help explain the stylized facts mentioned above. 2Althoiigh Krugmian (1980) is a cornerstone of the new trade theory, it is uninteresting (in thQ absence of firm heterogeneity) fioni the standpoint of the effects of trade liberalization on firn performance The reason is that, siiic in tlus model firnsb face a constant demnand elastiLity, trade integration hab no effects on firms' ruark-upb, and ou their size anud pioductivity 7 On the demand side, the model features love for variety, captured by a standard CES util- ity function, as in Krugman (1980) The production side of the economy is characterized by a continuum of firms, each producing a different variety. The technology features plant-level scale economies and is summarized by a total cost function as in equation (1), TC(cp) = f + q/l. The only difference is that now firms have different productivity levels, indexed by W. Hence, W cap- tures firm heterogeneity in this model. Firms face a demand curve with a constant elasticity (a > 1 Profit maximuzation imphes the familiar mark-up pricing rule, p(W) = ' I Firms' profits are then xr(p) = r(p)/a -f, where r(W) is revenue It can be shown that the ratios of any two firms' outputs and revenues only depend on the ratio of their productivity levels: q_(__) ( W, ) e ( ) ) A (6) q(~'2) Y'P2 J r(W2) 'Pi2J Equation (6) and the expressions for p(w) and 7r(g) show that more productive firms (i e., firms with a higher W) are bzgger, charge a lower price and earn hzgher profits than less productive firms. The equilibrium aggregate price index P is a generalization of the standard price index associ- ated with a CES utility function: P = [L p(P)"-npl(W)d W] TI7(7) where ji(o) is the equilibrium distribution of productivity levels and n is the equilibrium number of firms. Using the expression for p(W), the price index can be written as P = n p p(b) = n ee (8) where io is the weighted average of firms' productivity levels. Note that the inverse of the price index equals real per capita income W (i e, W = P-1) Hence, as in Krugman (1980), both an increase in the number of available varieties n and in the average productivity , raise real 8 per capita income and welfare. However, while in Krugman (1980) the average o:oductivity is exogenously given and trade reform can only exert its effects through an increase in n, in this model o is endogenous and hence it can be influenced by trade integration. Melitz shows that in the absence of any trade costs, a move from autarky to free trade has no effect on the distribution of productivity levels and average productivity. In this case, the effects of trade integration are identical to those predicted by Krugman (1980), i.e., a welfare increasing expansion in product variety, and firm heterogeneity has no impact on average industry productivity. In order to give firm heterogeneity an important role to play, two routes can be taken. One is to relax the assumption of an exogenously fixed demand elasticity (a) for each variety. The other is to assume the existence of sunk entry costs into foreign markets. As far as the former is concerned, (in a separate appendix) Melitz shows that, even in the ab- sence of any trade costs, firm heterogeneity is crucial for the impact of trade when firms' demand elasticity endogenously increases with product variety, as in Krugman (1979). In this case, trade integration among two identical countries expands the variety of products and henca increases the elasticity of substitution among them. In turn, an increased elasticity of substitution induces a reallocation of market shares towards more efficient firms and thus generates an aggregate pro- ductivity gain. The intuition for this result is that a higher elasticity of substitution generates a premium in terms of market shares in favor of firms charging a lower price, i.e., the more efficient ones. The second setting carefully explored by Melitz builds on the assumption of sunkc entry costs into foreign markets. Melitz refers to the results of empirical studies confirming that firms face significant fixed costs associated with the entry into foreign markets: "These costs are related to the fact that a firm must find and inform foreign buyers about its product and learn about the foreign market. Further, it must adapt its product to foreign standards and set up new distribution channels in the foreign country". 9 The assumption that exporting firms face a fixed cost of exporting has striking implications 3 In the presence of firm heterogeneity, only the more efficient ones can afford to pay the fixed cost of exporting Hence, these costs generate a partition of firms into exporting and non-exporting firms The former sell to both the domestic and the foreign markets, whereas the latter only sell to the domestic market Hence, this partition of firms implies that exporting firms are larger and more productive than non-exporting firms, and this is consistent with the plant-level empirical evidence This setting based on firm heterogeneity and fixed costs of exporting can help explain the effects of trade liberalization on intra-industry reallocation of resources and aggregate productivity In particular, it allows to explain the empirical finding that output share reallocations among firms with different productivity levels are the main source of trade-induced productivity gains. The intuition is the following. In the trade regime, all domestic firms face foreign competition in their domestic market, which induces a loss of revenue and market share. For non-exporting firms this translates into a loss of profits. Among these non-exporting firms, the less efficient incur negative profits and exit, whereas the other non-exporting firms survive with a lower market share than in autarky. Conversely, exporting firms expand their market share and profits because their access to foreign markets more than compensate the loss of revenue in the domestic market. Hence, trade induces both the exzt of less efficient firms and the reallocatton of market shares towards the more efficient exportzng firms. Both effects contrbute to an mncrease zn average productivity. 'Iln ection 5 we will see that, as shown by Manasse and Tturrini (2001), the interaction of fixed costs of exporting itiid fain hLetetugeneity has also striking implications with regard to the effects of tiade liberalization on wage inie(qiuaihty 10 3 Evidence an the EFect- o ')Fraele libeTLinainc an o75irm Perform~ance4 3.1 Evidence on the prc-co=aetitive e0b:ct, of trade 1iHerEal'atlon The pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization has traditionally been investigated by using industry-level data. Thls literature exemnes the correlation between trade exposure and price- cost margins at the industry level, using import penetration rates as a measure of trade exposure. Empirical studies for industrial countries (see, for instance, Schmalensee, 1989) show a negative corielation between price-costs margins and import competition, especially when domestic con- centration is high. This result is consistent with the argument that import competition reduces profits in industries which enjoy above normal returns.5 As for the developing world, the country studies reported in Roberts and Tybout (1996), relative to Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Morocco and Turkey, add to the standard industry-level analysis a study of the correlation between trade exposure and price cost-margins at the plant-level, to see whether the observed effects at the industry-level Ere common to all producers in an industry or are concentrated in a subset of producers 3.1.1 Industry-level evidence As far as the industry-level analysis is concerned, the country studies use the industry-level price- cost margin to measure industry-level performance. It is immediate to show that, if we assume that unit expenditures on labor and materials are constant with respect to output, then the price-cost margin is a monotonic transformation of the price-marginal cost mark-up. The price-cost margin in industry j at time t, PCM,t, is measured as the value of output (P,tQ,t) minus expenditures 4See also Tybout (2001) on the topics covered in this scetion. 'Usilig a data set coimprisilig 28 indubtries in 42 developed and clevelopmg countries for 18 years, Hoekcian andl KIce (2003) fihod in a iccent paper that import o:rplctition significantly reduces inciistry mark-upi. aTlie autilios of the country studies reportedl in Roberts and Tybouit (1996) are J Tybouit for Chile (ch 9), M Folbcrts foi Colomnbia (ch 10), .1 -M. Grcther for Mexico (cl 11), M Haddad, J. (le Melo and B Horton for Morocco (clh 12) and F Forouitan for Tuirkey (c1 13) on labor and materials over the value of output. It equals profits (H3t) plus payments to capital as a proportion of the industry's value of output: PCM1, = (fl3t + (rt + 6)K,t) /P,tQ,j (9) where Kt is capital stock, rt is the competitive gross return on capital and 6 is the depreciation rate Equation (9) shows that sectoral PCMs are influenced by both the rate of profit and the capital intensity. The country studies use the following basic model: PCM,t = f (H1t, IMP,t, H,t IMPt, Ktl/Q,t, I,, Tt) (10) Here, H,1 is the Herfindahl index, an index of industry structure which is inversely correlated with the degree of competition among domestic producers. IMP,t is the import penetration ratio; the pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization should show up as a negative correlation between the price-cost margin and import penetration. The interaction term H,t- IMP,t tests the hypothesis that, if highly concentrated industries enjoy above normal profits because of market power, then they should be more sensitive to foreign competition. Kjt/Q3t is the capital-output ratio, which controls for sectoral differences in capital-intensity (see equation (9)). Finally, I, and Tt are industry and time dummies, respectively. Since most of variation in the panel data used in these country studies is across industries, it is not surprising that the estimation results crucially depend on whether or not industry dummies are included in the regression equation When industry dummies are excluded, four out of five countries studies (i.e., those for Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Morocco) find that the coefficients of both IMP,t and H,t IMP3t are negative and highly significant. This suggests that import competition is negatively correlated with sectoral profitability and that the effect is larger for highly concentrated industries These results are substantially weakened, however, when industry dummies are included in the 12 regression equation Note that in this case estimated coefficients only reflect temporal variation in the data, and hence they are better suited to isolate the pro-competitive effect of increased foreign competition. The country studies show that, when industry dummies are included, evidence of a significant pro-competitive effect of trade hberalization is found only in Colombia and Mexico 3.1.2 Plant-level evidence The country studies also examine the pro-competitive effect of foreign competition by looking at plant-level evidence on price-costs margins. They use the following basic model. PCM,,= f(S,,t, S,2,,, IMP7t S .,t IMP1t, K3tIQ,I,,Tt) (11) where PCM,,t is the price-cost margin of plant i in industry . and time t, S5,t is the share of plant i's output in sector j's total domestic production, and the other variables in (11) have the same interpretation as in equation (10). The interaction term S,,t IMP7, tests the hypothesis that the pro-competitive effect of foreign competition is stronger among firms with a higher domestic market share. The coefficient of the linear term S,,t is generally positive and significant, whereas that of the quadratic term S, is generally negative. This suggests that price-costs margins rise at a decreasing rate with market shares. More interestingly, in every country studied the coefficients on IMP1t and S,,, IMP,,, are negative and highly significant, whereas industry dummies do not generally have any explanatory power. Thus, exposure to foreign competition is associated with lower price- cost margins, and the effect is concentrated among the large plants. This result suggests that looking at plant-level evidence highlights a powerful and systematic pro-competitive role of foreign competition. 13 3.2 Plant-level evidence on trade-induced productivity gains The literature which uses plant-level data to investigate the productivity gains from trade liberal- ization shows mixed results. Tybout, de Melo and Corbo (1991) find little evidence of productivity growth in manufacturing after trade reform in Chile Conversely, Harrison (1994) finds a signif- icant productivity increase after trade liberalization in Cote d'Ivoire. In section 7, we show that empirical works using a similar methodology find opposite results with regard to the effects of the 1991 trade liberalization in India. In this section, we briefly review two recent studies which will help us clarify the methodological hurdles involved in estimating the effect of trade reform on productivity. Tybout and Westbrook (1995) use plant-level panel data to study the efficiency gains induced by the Mexico trade liberalization. Prior to 1985, Mexico was an inward-looking economy due to heavy policies of trade protection 7 In 1985, the Mexican government announced its decision to join the GATT and undertook major reforms leading to a reduction in tariffs by 45% and import licenses by more than 75% within three years. Hence, the Mexican experience provides an interesting setting to study the empirical relevance of trade-induced productivity gains in developing countries. The methodology employed by Tybout and Westbrook allows them to disentangle three poten- tial sources of productivity gains. The first derives from exploitation of scale economies As shown in Section 2, trade integration, by increasing the perceived product demand elasticity, causes firms to loose market power and forces them down their average cost curves, thereby inducing scale efficiency gains. The second source of productivity gains derives from market share reallocations among plants with different levels of efficiency As shown in Section 2, in the presence of sub- stantial firm heterogeneity, market share reallocations can be a relevant source of trade-induced productivity gains. Finally, the authors include a catch-all residual term which captures changes in productivity not accounted for by scale effects or share reallocations, such as technical change, learning-by-doing, externalities, capacity utilization, elimination of waste, managerial effort, and 7The (lata ,isecl by the autlhors are froni Mexico's Annual Industrial Survey and cover the period 1984 throtugh 1990) Thc bsamlple plants iepresent 80% of total oUtput 14 so on. The main findings of Tybout and Westbrook are the following. a) Scale efficiency effects Most manufacturing sectors show increasing returns to scale, and for the smallest plants in these industries returns to scale are often relevant (as high as 1 2). However, the largest plants in these industries generally appear to have reached a minimum efficient scale. Thus, given that large plants account for a disproportionate share of sectoral output, industrial expansion does not induce large gains in scale efficiency. More precisely, the mean output growth was more than 50% in the period 198&1990. But despite this substantial output growth, the exploitation of scale economies accounts for only the 0.55% rise in average productivity. These results suggest that the focus of trade models with imperfect competition and representative firms on the gains from scale economies exploitation may be somewhat misplaced, since these gains appear modest in magnitude. b) Output share reallocatzons. This effect accounts for more than 1% rise in average productivity Although this figure is quite modest, it suggests that output share reallocations among firms with different productivity levels mighit be empirically more relevant than scale efficiency effects, and hence that firm heterogeneity can be a key determinant of the efficiency geans from trade liberalization c) Residual effect. Most of the average increase in productivity comes from the cetch-all residual effect, which accounts for 9.6% rise in average productivity. This implies that most of the estimated overall efficiency gains (11 16%) are indeed left unexplained. The above results must be interpreted with caution, because of the hurdles involved in the methodology used by Tybout and Westbrook, which are common, however, to most analyses of the efficiency gains from trade liberalization. The main methodological problems involved in estimating the productivity gains from trade reform can be summarized as follows (see Pavcnik, 2002). 1) Identificatzon of the trade effects In most studies, the identification of trade effects relies on the comparison of plant productivity before and after a trade policy change. As a consequence, 15 this approach attributes productivity changes originating from other sources to trade policy. To see how serious this problem can be, note that most studies use data covering only a short time period after trade reform, which implies that the estimates of productivity growth can be heavily affected by the cyclical behavior of the economy in the aftermath of the reform. Note, further, that in some episodes of trade liberalization, a deep economic downturn is often the trigger of these reforms, and hence productivity gains from liberalization can be underestimated if a prolonged recession leads to reduced capacity utilization 2) Simultanesty bias Assume that plant i's technology is described by the following Cobb- Douglas production function: + it + e,t; eit = wit + e6 (12) J=1 where all variables are in logarithms, y,t is output and x,, is the 7th input. The error term e,t is composed of a stochastic disturbance e,t plus an unobserved plant-specific efficiency term w,t Note that, since more productive plants are willing to hire more inputs, the error term e,t is positively correlated with factor inputs. This implies that OLS estimates (or between estimates, as in Tybout and Westbrook, 1995) of the production function coefficients are biased upward, thus involving biased estimates of w,j 8 In some cases (e g, in Harrison, 1994) this problem has been tackled by assuming that the plant-specific efficiency term is time-invariant, which allows to estimate equation (12) using a fixed effects estimator. This approach only removes the bias originating from the time-invariant component of plant-specific efficiency, so it does not solve the problem completely. What is more worrisome, however, is that this approach, by treating plant-specific efficiency as time-invariant, also removes the possibility to measure how it evolves after trade reform. Hence, in general, the simultaneity problem is either neglected or tackled improperly in the "EbtiLnatteb of Wt, le irn fact. basel on the difference between actuial o,itpnit and oitpiot predicte(d from estimates of the prod htion fonction coefficients 16 literature. 3) Self-selection bzas. The literature generally neglects the self-selection bias induced by plant closing Pavcnik (2002) shows that, under certain conditions, a negative correlation is to be expected between the efficiency term La,, and capital stock, conditional on surviving plants. This implies that the estimated coefficient of capital stock in production function (12) is generally biased downward. Pavcnik (2002) proposes an alternative methodology which addresses most of these issues In particular, the problem of identification of the trade effects is addressed by comparing plants' pro- ductivity growth in the export oriented and import competing sectors with that of firms in the iion-traded sector The simultaneity ard self-selection biases are addressed by using a semipara- metric procedure in which the plant-specific efficiency term is modeled as a time-varying function of capital and investment " Pavcnik implements her methodology using data on Chilean manufacturing plants for the period 1979 to 1986, i.e, in the aftermath of a drastic trade hberalization. Plants are partitioned into three groups. Plants belonging to a 4-digit ISIC industry exporting more than 15% of its total output are characterized as export oriented. Plants belonging to an industry whose ratio of imports to total output exceed 15% are instead characterized as import competing. The rest of the plants belong to the non-traded sector. Pavcnik uses the mentioned procedure to obtair consistent estimates of plants' productivity growth in each of these groups. The results are striking. In the period 1979-1986, thc productivity of export oriented plants grew, on average, by 25.4%, that of import competing plants grew by even more (31 9%), while that of plants in the non-traded sector grew by only 6 2%. These results suggest a dramatic productivity growth differential in favor of plants exposed to international competition with respect to inward-oriented plants. They also suggest that, in the case of a "Siruilarly, a re(eut paper by Fernandez (2002) uses a panel of Colomubian plants from 1977 to 1091 to estimate pio(luation functionis separately across manufacturing industries These estimates are then used to dcerive plant-level tilue-varying productivity meastues She finds a btrong negative impact of tradc protection on plant produictivity 17 unilateral trade liberalization (such as the one experienced by Chile), trade-induced productivity gains can be higher for import competing plants relative to export oriented plants Pavcnik also uses a procedure similar to that used by Tybout and Westbrook (1995) to dis- entangle the contribution of output share reallocations among firms with different productivity levels to productivity growth She finds that in the export oriented sector, average productivity growth due to output share reallocations equals 16 6%, while the rest (8 7%) is due to within plants productivity growth The figures for the import competing sector and the non-traded sector are, respectively, 21 3% and 10 7%, and 2 4% and 3 8% These results strongly suggest that the reshuffling of resources in favor of more productive firms is a critical determinant of productivity growth and that, consistent with Melitz (2002)'s model, this effect can be largely due to trade liberalization ii) 3.3 More on trade policy and scale efficiency Tybout and Westbrook (1995) also look at patterns of sectoral change in measures of foreign competition to see whether they are correlated with estimated productivity changes. Correlations are generally insignificant. The only robust finding is that heightened import competition reduces scale efficiency. This result seems to contradict one of the main predictions of the simplest models of the new trade theory (such as the one illustrated in Section 2), i e , that in the presence of imperfect competition the trade-induced increase in firm size can be an important source of efficiency gains Indeed, most general equilibrium models based on imperfect competition (see, for instance, Cox and Harris, 1985) predict that trade liberalization will generate welfare gains primarily through the mechanism of increased scale The empirical evidence on the effects of trade liberalization on firm size is mixed Roberts and Tybout (1991) find that higher import penetration is associated with lower employment per plant '"Coli.istent with thc,e resildts, uibng data on Brazilian rianifactiring, Miiendiler (2002) finds thilt thle shut- (II)wii piohl,ality of inefficient firms lises with competition frorii abroad, thiis contributing positively to aiggregate p1 uod,ct.ivity 18 in Chile and Colombia. Conversely, other works on developed countries find that th-e removal of tariff protection increases output."1 The theoretical literature emphasizes that the effects of trade policy in the presence of imperfect competition are generally sensitive to the specific assumptions concerning market structure and industry characteristics. Following Head and Ries (1999), now we argue that a slight modification of the simple model illustrated in Section 2 can help explain the finding of Tybout and Westbrook (1995) that increased import competition may reduce firm size and scale efficiency. Consider n domestic firms and nt foreign firms competing d la Cournot in an industry producing a homogeneous good. Domestic and foreign firms employ the same production technology, featuring a fixed cost f and a constant marginal cost 1/0. Markets are segmented, as in Brander (1981). Let ri, and rf denote the ad valorem tariffs charged by the domestic and foreign country, respectively The profits of domestic and foreign firms (-r and 7r', respectively) are given by 7r = (Ph -l 5)qh + (pf/(1 + rf)-1/1)qf-f (13) 7r' = (pi,/(l + r,,)-1/5)qh + (pf- 1/0)q' -f Here, ql, and qh denote, respectively, domestic and foreign firms' sales to the domestic market, whereas qf and qr are domestic and foreign firms' sales to the foreign market, respectively pi, and pf are the final consumer prices in the domestic and foreign market, respectively. Since the two markets are segmented (and marginal costs are constant), a firm's choice of output in one market is independent of its choice of output in the other markcet. Hence we can concentrate on the domestic market to study the impact of rh on ql, and qh, noting that the impact of rr on qf is analogous to that of r1, on q'. The first order conditions for profit maximization in "Sce, foi mitance, Baldwin and Goiecki (1986) and Caves (1984) for an analysis of average plant scale in Canada anitd Anistialid, respectively 19 the domestic market are given by: a--r = phqh+Ph-1/0=0 (14) 87r* =phql*, + pi, -(1+T,/ 0 Totally differentiating equations (14) with respect to qh, qh and rh, using Cramer's rule and assuming that firms' outputs are strategic substitutes, it is possible to show that: - > 0, aq <0 (15) Inequalities in (15) show that a home tariff raises output per firm in the domestic country and lowers output per firm in the foreign country. Similarly, a foreign tariff raises output per firm in the foreign country and lowers output per firm in the domestic country. The intuition is that a home tariff raises the marginal cost of foreign exporting firms, forcing them to lower output to raise marginal revenue and restore the equality between marginal cost and marginal revenue. In turn, foreign firms' contraction allows domestic firms to expand. To sum up, competition a la Cournot in the context of segmented markets implies that unilateral trade liberalization by the domestic country reduces firm size and scale efficiency in the domestic country and raises scale efficiency in the foreign country.'2 This result may help explain why empirical studies often find that increased import competition due to unilateral trade liberalization reduces firm size in developing countries Head and Ries (1999) test the implications of this model using a panel of 230 Canadian 4-digit SIC industries for the period 1987-1994. The focus of their empirical analysis is on the effects on firm size of the 1988 Canada-U.S F'ree Trade Agreement, which led to a gradual bilateral tariff "Head aud Ries (1999) show that this result holds also under the assumption of free entry of firms 20 removal between the two countries Their basic regression equation is: Ilnqtt = %+ Pt +yc.'ArCA + zUSrY t + eSt (16) where q,j, is average output per plant in the ith industry at time t, a. and /3t are industry and time fixed effects, respectively, rCA and rus are the industry tariff rates charged by the Canadian and U S governments, respectively, and et is an error term. Regression results show that Canadian tariff reductions lowered plant scale in Canada, while U.S. tariff reductions had the opposite effect. Both effects are highly significant and quite large in magnitude. For instance, estimated coefficients imply that the average reduction of Canadian tariffs by of 5.4% caused a 6.1% scale reduction in Canada, while the average reduction of U.S. tariffs by 2 8% caused a 4 6% scale incre-se in Canada. An other interesting result is that tariff effects are smaller in industries characterized by high turnover rates (measured as the sum of entry and exit divided by the number of establishments). This suggests that plant entry and exit dampen scale adjustments, and hence that industries characterized by free entry and exit are not much affected by tariff reductions. This result is in line with results reported by Roberts and Tybout (1991) for Chile and Colombia, showing that the effect of import penetration on employees per plant decreases with industry turnover. Head and Ries also look at plant size heterogeneity to examine whether plants belonging to different size groups show a different response to trade policy changes Their main result is that only the scale of large plants is responsive to tariff reductions. Conversely, small plants are de facto insulated from the effects of trade liberalization.13 To sum up, the plant-level evidence illustrated in this section suggests that trade-induced scale efficiency gains are generally small in magnitude, because: 1) a disproportionate share of industry output is produced by large firms, which appear to have reached minimum efficient scale; 2) small plants' output does not respond much to tariff reductions; 3) entry and exit of firms in response 3Simlilarly, Fernandez (2002) finds that, among Colombian firmis, the negative impact of protcetion on produtc- tivity L8 stionger for large plants relative to small plants. 21 to changing profit opportunities lower the quantity adjustment by incumbent firms in sectors with high turnover rates The evidence also shows that unilateral trade liberalization generally reduces firm size and scale efficiency in import competing sectors This is not a worrisome result, however, since the evidence also shows that, notwithstanding this negative effect, overall trade-induced productivity gains are higher in import competing sectors. 4 Trade and Technology Advancement In addition to the static effects illustrated in Section 2, trade liberalization has also been argued to have other static and dynamic effects, most of which are related to knowledge diffusion and technology advancement Here we briefly review some of these effects. Imports of dzfferentiated intermedtate inputs and capztal goods As first shown by Ethier (1982), in the presence of firm-level scale economies, free trade in differentiated intermediate inputs is formally equivalent to technical progress. The reason is that imports of intermediates allow a finer division of labor which increases firms' efficiency A similar reasoning applies to imports of differentiated capital goods. Further, through imports of inter- mediates and capital goods, domestic firms can benefit from foreign innovations incorporated in these goods This argument is particularly relevant for developing countries In a dynamic ex- tension of Ethier (1982)'s model, Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991) have also shown that, under certain conditions (indeed quite restrictive), trade in differentiated intermediates can permanently increase the rate of innovation and growth 14 Finally, as shown by Lee (1993), if capital goods are capital-intensive, then trade liberalization reduces the price of capital goods in capital-poor developing countries, thereby increasing the return to investment and the growth rate of capital stock in these countries; similarly, trade liberalization reduces the price of imported technology in developing countries, thereby stimulating technology advancement. "'See Mtendiler (2002) for a pielinhmnary attempt at evaluating the impact of foreign intermediate inputs on p1o(hict.ivity (hange 22 Foreign dzrect tnvestment Foreign investment can generate several benefits for the host country. For instance, it can finance the expansion of industries in which the domestic country enjoys a comparative advantage. Further, it can lead to the transfer of knowledge from foreign to local firms. Finally, it can provide local firms with the critical know-how to break into foreign markets If foreign entrants possess a better technology, they can foster productivity improvements in the domestic industry either directly, by raising the productivity of the resources used in production, either indirectly through knowledge spillovers to local firms As far as the latter effect is concerned, local firms can learn from foreign firms either by simply observing them, or through turnover of labor, as employees move from foreign to local firms. Learning by exporting It is often argued, mainly on the basis of anecdotal evidence, that there are several channels through which domestic exporters can benefit from the technical expertise of foreign buyers.'5 In particular, breaking into foreign markets allows firms to acquire knowledge of international best practice Further, foreign buyers often provide their suppliers with technical assistance and product design in order to improve the quality of imported goods. It has also been noted that in some cases foreign buyers transmit to their suppliers located in low-wage countries the tacit knowledge acquired from their other suppliers located in technologically advanced countries. Hence, exporting may foster learning and productivity growth Aside from these beneficial effects, trade liberalization has also been argued to have potentially negative dynamic effects for developing countries. These negative effects can be thought of as the dynamic counterpart to the static gains from specialization based on comparative advantage. For instance, as shown by Lucas (1988) and Young (1991), in the presence of sectoral asymmetries in the relevance of learning-by-doing, a developing country which in the free trade regime switches its production mix toward technologically stagnant sectors may suffer a permanent reduction in liSee, ?rote, alea, World Bauk (1993) 23 its rate of productivity growth Similarly, Grossman and Helpman (1991) have shown that trade liberalization can adversely affect the rate of innovation and growth in a human capital-poor developing country by diverting its resources away from R&D Further, Rodrik (1988) argues that, if firms invest in superior technology to reduce their costs, then their incentive to invest depends positively on output. It follows that trade liberalization may reduce the incentive to invest in new technology for firms belonging to the import competing sectors, since these sectors should contract after trade hberalization In the previous section, we have already shown that there is evidence of trade-induced produc- tivity gains in the developing world, and that these gains are larger for import competing firms Hence, the available micro-level evidence suggests that the potentially negative effects of trade reforms are actually offset by their positive effects In section 7, we will report more micro-level evidence on the effects of trade reform in India In the rest of this section, we discuss the empirical relevance of some of the mentioned channels of international technology diffusion 4.1 The import channel of technology diffusion'6 In the absence of plant-level studies on the link between imports and productivity growth, here we briefly discuss the evidence based on more aggregated data Coe and Helpman (1995) is one of the first attempts to perform a rigorous test of the relevance of imports as a vehicle for the international transmission of technology Using a sample of OECD countries, these authors ask how much of a country's total factor productivity can be explained by domestic and foreign R&D activities, where the latter is crucially defined as the import share-weighted average of partner countries' R&D activities Coe and Helpman find that both domestic and foreign R&D have a positive and significant effect on domestic TFP. Further, for small countries (only), the TFP elasticity to foreign R&D is significantly larger than that to domestic R&D. Similarly, using patent data, Eaton and Kortum (1996) find that innovations that originate abroad explain more than 90% of productivity "'See also Barba Navaretti and Tarr (2000) and Keller (2001a) for two recent surveys of interna- tional trade and technology diffusion. 24 growth of small OECD countries, and that more than half of these innovations originate from only three countries, i e, the U.S., Japan and Germany 17 Coe, Helpman and Hoffmaister (1997) extend their analysis to a large sample of developing countries. One important difference is that import shares are computed by considering imports of machinery and equipment only, since these goods are more likely to embody new knowledge. Their results strongly suggest that intermediate goods imports raise total factor productivity also in developing countries Meyer (2001) restricts even further the definition of imports used to compute import shares by considering machinery only and finds that in this case the TFP elasticity to foreign R&D in developing countries is twice as large as in the case in which all imports are used to compute foreign R&D. A recent paper by Barba Navaretti and Soloaga (2002) looks at the role of imported machines in transferring embodied technological progress. They use data on unit values of machines exported by the EU to a sample of neighboring developing and transition countries in Central-Eastern Europe and in the Southern Mediterranean. Here, unit values proxy for the technological complexity of machines The authors find that imported machines have a positive impact on total factor productivity, and that the impact is larger the higher the technological complexity of imported machines. The above studies examine the link between '-'FP, R&D and imports at the aggregate level However, as noted by Keller (2001b), R&D spending is highly concentrated by industry For in- stance, about 80% of total manufacturing R&D is conducted in only four 3-digit ISIC industries in OECD countries (chemical products, electrical and non-electrical machinery and transport equip- ment) Therefore, Keller performs separate regressions for the sample of low-R&D industries and finds that TFP elasticities are significantly smaller in these industries. To sum up, preliminary evidence using aggregate data suggests that imports are a highly relevant channel of international technology diffusion, and that the domestic productivity effect of 17See al,,o S.hiff and Wang (2002) and Schiff and Olarreaga (2002) for an analysis of trnde-related technology diffilsioll 25 knowledge originating abroad is greater the smaller the size and the lower the level of development of the domestic country, and the greater both the technology intensity of industries and the complexity of imported machines 4.2 Foreign direct investment Haddad and Harrison (1993), Aitken and Harrison (1994) and Harrison (1996) are among the first to use plant-level panel data to analyze the impact of joint ventures and foreign subsidiaries on local firms' productivity in developing countries. These studies ask two related questions, namely, whether foreign firms exhibit higher productivity levels than local firms, and whether knowledge spillovers from foreign to local firms raise the latter's productivity level Data come from three developing countries, Cote d'Ivoire (1975-87), Morocco (1985-89) and Venezuela (1983-88). Foreign firms are defined as all firms with foreign equity that exceed 5% of assets As far as the performance of foreign relative to local firms is concerned, these studies find that, consistent with other evidence, foreign firms generally exhibit higher total factor productivity, pay higher wages and have much higher import and export propensities.'8 A more interesting question is whether local firms benefit from spillovers generated by their foreign counterparts Aitken and Harrison (1994) test this hypothesis by assuming that, if knowl- edge is transmitted from foreign to local firms, then the productivity of the latter should be higher in sectors with a larger foreign presence They use a panel of Venezuelan firms to estimate the following Cobb-Douglas production function: log Y,,t = log A,,t + a, log SL,t + a2 log UL,,t + a3 log M,,t + a4 log K,,t (17) Here, Y,,t is output of firm i in sector J at time t, A is total factor productivity, SL is skilled labor, UL is unskilled labor, M is raw materials, and K is capital stock. In order to capture the effect of 8Tlie (evidence on total factor productivity growth is mixed. In particular, only in the case of Venezuela TFP gi owtli ib hugher for foreign firms The converse is true for Mexico, and the (lifference is insignificant for Cote ( 'Ivoiro 26 foreign presence on local firms' TFP, A is modeled as follows: log A,t = bi + b2FDI3t + b3D, + b4Dt + e,t (18) where FDI,, is the share of foreign firms (as measured by the share of foreign assets in total sector assets) in sector j at time t, D, and Dt are sector and time dummies, respectively, and e,t is an error term. A positive effect of foreign presence on local firms' TFP should show up as a positive and significant coefficient b2. Estimation results critically depend on whether or not sectoral dummies D, are included in the regression. When sectoral dummies are excluded, the coefficient b2 is positive and significant. This suggests a positive correlation between fbreign presence and local firms' efficiency. The correlation may be spurious, however, since foreign firms may be attracted to sectors in which local firms make higher profits. In fact, when controiling for unobserved fixed industry characteristics through sectoral dummies, b2 turns negative and highly significant. Notice that in this case only temporal variation in the FDI variable is exploited to estimate b2, which suggests that increased foreign presence has a negative short-run impact on local firms' productivity. One possible explanation for this result is that foreign firms reduce the market share of local firms, thereby reducing their capacity utilization. Another possibility is that foreign firms, by paying higher wages, attract the best workers, thereby reducing the productivity of local firms. The above results are broadly consistent with the available micro-level evidence on transition countries. In particular, Djankow and Hoekman (2000) use firm-level data for the Czech Republic during the initial post-reform period (1992-1996) to investigate the impact of foreign direct invest- ment and joint ventures on the productivity of Czech firms They find that both FDI and joint ventures have a positive impact on TFP growth of recipient firms, although the impact of the former is greater. This result suggests that parent firms transfer more Inowledge to local affiliates than foreign firms do to local partners. Further, and most important, Djanlcow and Hoekman find a large negative overall impact of FDI and joint ventures on the TFP of local firms that do not 27 have foreign partnerships. This negative effect becomes much smaller, however, when only FDI is considered. Although the micro-level evidence suggests the absence of positive horizontal spillovers from FDI in developing and transition countries'9, there is a growing literature providing evidence of positive vertical spillovers from FDI In particular, as noted by Smarzynska (2002), it is possible that researchers have been looking for FDI spillovers in the wrong place. The reason is that, since multinationals have an incentive to prevent any kind of spillovers that would increase the productivity of their local competitors20, but also want to transfer information to their local suppliers, FDI spillovers are more likely to be vertical than horizontal in nature. In order to test this hypothesis, Smarzynska uses firm-level data from Lithuania for the period 1996-2000 She finds evidence of positive vertical FDI spillovers through backward linkages and no evidence of horizontal FDI spillovers. Similarly, Blalock (2001) and Kugler (2000) find evidence of positive vertical FDI spillovers using, respectively, a panel of Colombian and Indonesian firms. Hence, it is fair to conclude that, while the available plant-level evidence strongly suggests the absence of positive horizontal FDI spillovers in the developing world, it also suggests that relevant productivity gains may accrue to developing countries' firms due to the linkages between foreign firms and their local suppliers. 4.3 Learning by exporting? The micro-level evidence shows a positive robust correlation between exporting and productivity. There are two plausible non incompatible explanations for this stylized fact. One is that, as shown by Melitz (2002) and discussed in Section 2, more efficient firms self-select into export markets The other is the learning-by-exporting argument, according to which exporting causes efficiency gains. Two recent papers address the question of the direction of causality. Bernard and Jensen "The only available micro-level evidence of positive horizontal spillover effects comes from developedl countries Sev Haskel et al, 200)2, for a bttidy oii UK dlata 2'As Lioted by Simarzynska, this can be achieved thro,igh trade secrecy, or by paying higher wages or by locating in indtstries or countries where local firms have limilte(d imitative capacities, etc 28 (1999) use data relative to U.S. manufacturing plants for the period 1984-1992 They find that size, wages, productivity and capital intensity are all higher for exporters relative to non-exporters. They also find clear evidence that good firms become exporters, since performance is higher ex- ante for exporters. However, they do not find evidence that exporting improves performance, since productivity and wage growth are not higher ex-post for exporters relative non-exporters Clerides, Lach and Tybout (1998) address the same question and reach similar results. They use plant-level manufacturing data for Colombia (1981-1991), Mexico (1986-1990) and Morocco (1984- 1991) Their approach is based on the idea that, if exporting fosters productivi';y growth, then the productivity trajectory of exporting firms should change after they break into foreign markets To test this hypothesis, they estimate econometrically the reduced form of a theoretical model derived from the hysteresis literature (Baldwin, 1989; Dixit, 1989) which explicitly considers two possible explanations for the correlation between exporting and productivity, namely, self-selection and learning-by-exporting In particular, they estimate, indtistry by industry, by full information maximum likelihood (FIML), the following two-equations system .1 . = 1 if O.X, t++P,et+EZ'/3n(AVC,t-j)+Eby,t-,+ (19) J-I .7 =1 +7.7,t < 0; and y,t = O otherwzse 1, .'1 *1. ln(AVC,t) = yn + y,ln(et) + EZy[ln(K,,) + E yjln(AVCt-j) + Eyj,'y,. +v,t(20) 7-1 2J=i J=i Equation (19) represents the export market participation decision by plant 2 at time t It is a dynamic discrete choice equation in which Y,t takes a value of one if the firm d-ecides to export and a value of zero otherwise Here, X,t is a vector of exogenous plant characte-istics, e, is the real exchange rate (which proxies for changes in relative prices that are common to all plants), the summation of the terms AVC,t7 is a distributed lag in the average variable cost (which proxies for marginal cost), the summation of the terms yt,- is a distributed lag in the participation variable, 29 and ,, is a disturbance.2' This equation allows to test whether, after controlling for plant-specific characteristics, for movements in industry relative prices and for past export participation decisions, past realizations of marginal costs are negatively correlated with the decision to break into foreign markets If this is the case, we can conclude that, ceteris paribus, firms experiencing a productivity increase (as proxied by a fall in marginal costs) are more likely to be exporters For all countries and for most industries, FIML estimation results show that the sum of co- efficients of the distributed lag in marginal costs is negative. Individual coefficients are never significant, however, (maybe because of the high collinearity among them) and some of them are positive In sum, these results provide weak evidence in favor of the hypothesis that firms improving their relative performance self-select into foreign markets.22 Equation (20) allows to test the learning-by-exporting hypothesis. if firms experience cost reductions after entering foreign markets, then, after controlling for firm-specific differences in capital stock (KXt-) and in past realization of marginal costs, we should observe a negative correlation between export experience and marginal costs FIML estimation results show, however, that the coefficients -y' on lagged export experience are generally insignificant In some cases they are significant, but with the wrong (positive) sign. Only in a few cases these coefficients are negative and significant, e.g, in the Moroccan apparel and leather industries.23 In short, these results do not support the learning-by-exporting hypothesis 21 There are several reasons, however, to be cautious in interpreting the results In particular, since the time span covered by the data is very short, the econometric analysis can only pick up gains in efficiency which materialize in the short-run (within three years) Further, even if these gains materialize immediately (which is quite unlikely, given that learning is a gradual process), in the short-run they can be offset by the sunk entry costs associated with becoming an exporter. Indeed, sunk 21In Irboth cqlations, the disturbance' are composed of ,,nobserved plant randorn effects plis tranmitory noise 22FIML estimation resuilts also show that, in all countries and all industries, firms with large (apital stocks are mole likely to become exporters Fiurther, firms with past export experience are more likely to be exporters This lattel result is conibibtent with the literatuire on hysteresis 2 FIML ebtimationi results of eqiiation (20) also show that firms with a larger capital stock have lower niaiginal (osts, and that marginal costs ten(d to follow a second order auitoregressive process 24Note, howevei, that inlike the above imientioned works, Kraay (1999) findb evidence of leainuirg-by-exportirig ufte(ts musilig ai panel of 2105 Cbuiiebe furius fiom 1988 to 1992 30 entry costs may contribute to explain the positive and significant correlation betv.een exporting and marginal costs found by the authors in some cases. Hence, this evidence simply suggests that becoming an exporter does not generate short-run efficiency gains 25 M Thade,9 Tachxology a=d WIage LequalHiy ln Dzvelping Countries According to the traditional trade theory, trade liberalization should pose no serious distributional issues in developing countries. The reason is that, since developing countries are high-skilled labor scarce relative to industrial countries, their trade-induced specialization in low-skillcd intensive ac- tivities should increase the relative demand for low-skilled labor, thereby reducing vage inequality in these countries. This prediction has often been used to argue in favor of trade liberalization in developing countries, since it would both increase efficiency and lower wage dispersion in these countries The empirical evidence on wage inequality in developing countries seems to contradict this optimistic prediction.2" As shown, inter alia, by Robbins (1996) and Harrison and Hanson (1999), many developing countries experiencing drastic trade liberalizations in the recent past, such as Chile, Mexico, Costa Rica and Uruguay, have seen a concomitant mcrease in wage inequality and a generalized increase in the relative demand for skilled labor (i e, skill upgrading). This puzzling evidence has stimulated an impressive body of research by way of new explana- tions of the link between trade and labor markets Here we briefly review the main explanations, 25Also, as correctly noted by the authors, their approach does iiot allow to detect efficiency gains accriiing to workers in the form of hligher wages, buit that leave average variable costs unchanged '('The prediLtioll iS based on the simple Stolper-Sainuelson theorem However, as noted by Tiurrini (2(002), ui a muore realistic higher (limensional setting, i e , in the prebence of muany countries, sectors and produlctioln factors, it is hard to disrern empirically in which factor *. cointry is relatively abundant and in which trade conitext that factor is going to gain fron trade hiberahzation. For instance, Turrim perfornms computable ,enreral eqlillibriuim simLlations to bhow that the effects of trade liberalization on the relative wage of the unskilled in Latin Ameiica (ritically depends oil whether or not agricultutre is also liberalized A iu iilar point is madte by Hlalrubon and Hanson (1999) They argute that the dramatu increaise in wage inequality after the 1985 trade reform irn ?lexico dloes inot necessauily couitra(lict the Stolpei-Saninelson theorem The retason is that, prior to reform, protection in Mexico was skewed toward low-bkilledl intensive sectors, and it fell mobt in these sectors after trade reform. 31 focusing on their implications for labor market outcomes in developing countries. Outsourczng Feenstra and Hanson (1996) formulate a model with capital mobility and a continuum of pro- duction activities with different skill-intensities. They show that trade and investment liberal- ization bring about North-South outsourcing of production activities which are at the same time unskill-intensive relative to other activities performed in the North, and skill-intensive relative to activities performed in the South The main implication is that, contrary to the standard two- sector Heckscher-Ohlin model, trade and investment liberalization increase the relative demand for skilled labor in both regions, and can thus potentially explain the worldwide increase in the skill premia The argument put forth by Feenstra and Hanson is consistent with the main stylized facts concerning the labor market dynamics in both the developed and the developing world Its empir- ical relevance deserves further scrutiny, however. As argued, for instance, by Robbins (1996), this model can be relevant for countries, such as Mexico, that experienced large FDI inflows in the last decades. It is less so, however, for much of trade-liberalizing Latin America, which did not receive substantial FDI in the 1980s. Intra-rndustry trade and wage znequaltty Dinopoulos, Syropoulos and Xu (1999) are the first to investigate the potential role of intra- industry trade for wage inequality They build a one sector model which features monopolistic competition and plant-level increasing returns to scale on the production side, and love for variety on the consumption side As in Krugman (1979), they assume that the price elasticity of demand faced by each producer increases with the number of competitors Further, they assume that the skill-intensity of production increases with firm size. In this model, trade liberalization raises the number of competitors, which implies that prices fall As a consequence, some firms are forced to exit, thereby raising the average size of surviving firms The effect of trade on the skill premium follows immediately from the assumption that firm size is skill-biased This latter assumption finds 32 support in several plant-level empirical studies, e.g., in Idson and Oi (1999), who report that large firms tend to employ a higher proportion of skilled workers. Related work by Epifani and Gancia (2002) illustrates a new channel through which intra- industry trade may increase wage inequality. The authors formulate a two-secto-r general equilib- rium model which features monopolistic competition in both sectors to show that an elasticity of substitution in consumption greater than one and higher scale economies in the skill-intensive sec- tor imply that any increase in the volume of trade, even between identical countries, is skill-biased. The intuition is simple. Trade expands the market size of the economy, which is beneficial because of increasing returns. In relative terms, however, output increases by more in the skill-intensive sector, since it is characterized by stronger economies of scale, and the relative price of the skill- intensive good therefore falls. With an elasticity of substitution in consumption greater than one, the demand for skill-intensive goods increases more than proportionally, raising their share of total expenditure and therefore also the relative wage of skilled workers. This result implies that, if the skill-biased scale effect is strong enough to overcome the standard factor proportions effect, international trade will spur inequality even in the skill-poor developing economies, making the model consistent with the evidence of rising skil1-premia in developing countries that have experienced trade liberalizations. The authors also show that physical capital accumulation leads to higher skill premia, and that the intersectoral mobility of capita: is likely to magnify the effects of trade integration on wage inequality. These findings are consistent with both the evidence on capital relocation towards skill- intensive sectors (Caselli, 1999) anc the large literature on capital-skill complementarity (Krusell et al, 2000). Manasse and Turrini (2001) are the first to study the effects of intra-industry trade on labor market outcomes in the presence of heterogeneous firms and workers. They build a one sector monopolistic competition trade model a l1 Krugman (1980). Production of each variety involves a constant marginal requirement in terms of a raw input and one unit of skilled labor as a fixed cost. 33 Workers are heterogeneous in terms of skills High-skilled workers produce high quality varieties and earn higher wages, since quality is valued by consumers Trade liberalization has striking implications for income distribution. Because of foreign competition, all firms loose market shares in their domestic market. At the same time, the access to foreign markets represents a concrete opportunity to expand total sales and profits only for some firms The reason is that access to foreign markets entails a fixed cost Hence, only those firms whose profits are higher than the fixed cost of exporting can effectively break into foreign markets As a consequence, high-skilled workers employed in firms producing high quahty goods see their earnings rise after trade integration. Conversely, less-skilled workers employed in firms producing only for the domestic market see their earnings fall after trade integration Thus, the model provides a trade-induced mechanism of reallocation of resources and increasing wage dispersion which operates at the firm rather than the sectoral level. Further, it is in line with the plant-level empirical evidence (reported below) showing that changes in the skill premia are significantly associated with the export status of firms. Dhade-znduced skill-biased technical change The main alternative explanation for the worldwide increase in wage inequality is exogenous skill-biased technical change. It has been argued that technology can be at the root of the in- crease in inequality because recent innovations in the production process, such as the widespread introduction of computers, have boosted the relative productivity of skilled workers 27 A recent literature on dzrected technical change, initiated by Acemoglu (1998, 1999), asks whether the bias of technological change is endogenous. In these models, innovation originates in the skill abundant North and is then exported to the South An important implication is that innovation responds to economic incentives in the North In particular, it is shown that skill-complement innovations are more profitable in a country relatively endowed with skilled workers This implies that the skill bias of technological change depends positively on the relative endowment of skilled workers in the North This result may help explain the puzzling concomitant increase both in the skill 27Sec, uniong others, Autor et al [1Y981 34 premium and in the relative supply of skilled workers experienced by most advanced countries in the last decades. The intuition is that the increase in the relative supply of skilled workers, which would ceteris paribus depress the skill premium, strengthens the incentive to skill-complement in- novations. Under certain conditions (in particular, a high elasticity of substitution between high and low sldlled-workers) the latter effect prevails and determines a rise in the skill premium in the North. As far as the South is concerned, since it passively adopts the technology developed for the needs of the North, it is bound to import more and more skill-complement machines, with a consequent generalized increase in the relative demand for skilled labor and in the sldll premium. The literature on directed technical change can also shed light on the relation between interna- tional trade and the sklll bias of technical change It is shown, in particular, that North-South trade liberalization, by increasing the relative price of skill-intensive goods in the Norlb, increases the profitability of skill-complement innovations relative to unskill-complement innovations, thereby magnifying the skill bias of technical change. It is worth mentioning two other recent works investigating the link between international trade and technical choice. Neary (2001) formulates a general oligopolistic equihbrium model where a reduction in trade barriers encourages more strategic investment by incumbent firms in order to deter entry. In particular, it is shown that, as the number of competitors in an industry increases after trade liberalization, each firm has a greater incentive to increase its investment in order to improve its position in the strategic oligopolistic game. Strategic over-investment by incumbent firms thus raises the ratio of fixed to variable costs Assuming that fixed investment costs are skill-intensive relative to variable costs, the model predicts that a move towards free trade induces a higher sklll premium, a higher ratio of sldlled to unskilled workers in all sectors (i.e., skill upgrading) and little changes in trade volumes. Hence, the model predicts that trade liberalization can affect technical change and skill premia even in the absence of significant increases in actual trade volumes 28 "8There is auother important channel through which trade may increase wage inequality im the presence of oligopoilstic markets For inbtante, Borja. and Ramney (1995) formullate a model where the tradedl sector ib an 35 In the same vein, Ekholm and Midelfart-Knarvik (2001) develop a model where trade hberal- ization affects the technical choice of firms and can thus lead to skill-biased technical change They assume the existence of two technologies one is characterized by a high (skill-intensive) fixed cost and a low (unskill-intensive) marginal cost, while the other features a low fixed cost and a high marginal cost It is then shown that the market size expansion induced by trade liberalization increases the relative profitability of firms characterized by a high fixed cost and a low marginal cost, thus inducing the adoption of the more skill-biased technology 5.1 Plant-level evidence on the determinants of skill upgrading 5.1.1 The role of imported technology A recent work by Pavcnik (2000) is one of first attempts to analyze the determinants of skill upgrading in developing countries She uses data on 4547 Chilean manufacturing plants spanning the years 1979-1986. Chile represents an interesting setting to study the relation between trade liberalization and skill upgrading in developing countries since, between 1974 and 1979, most non-tariff barriers were eliminated and tariff rates were reduced from more than 100% to 10% Following this drastic trade liberalization, from 1979 to 1986, the share of skilled workers in total manufacturing employment increased by almost 17%, and the skill premium grew by more than 10% One possible explanation for these trends is the following. Falling trade and investment barriers bring about a decrease in the relative price of imported technology in developing countries such as Chile, thereby stimulating technology adoption 29 If the adoption of new technology is a skill- intensive activity, then skill upgrading and rising skill prernia may be closely linked to the trade- induced process of technology advancement oligopoly and is low-skille(d itensive relative to the rest of the economy Firms and workers share oligopolistic rents in the tiaided sC(tor In this setting, .n exogenotis increase in imports reduces rents in the oligopolistic se(tor, thereby ied,in.ng the relative wage of the unskilled Hence, the trade-induiced( fall of rates of retiurns in highly o,ii(eiitiatecl and iiiionizecl industries, such as the automobile industry, masy contribute to a worldwide increase in wage inequality ')Thc evidence reported by Eaton cud( Kortim (1996) confirms that the international diffusion of technology is signifialitly influenced by the degree of piotectionisrn 36 The data used by Pavcnik provide several plant-level variables to measure technology, such as imported materials, expenditures on patent use and rights, and expenditures on foreign technical assistance. All of these technology measures, together with new capital investment, show a dra- matic increase in the period following trade liberalization. In order to test whether skill upgrading in Chile was influenced by the process of technology adoption, Pavcnik partitions plants according to whether or not they used imported materials (or received foreign technical assistance, or used patented technology) in the years following the trade reform She then studies the distribution of the wage bill share of skilled workers (which proxies for plants' skill-intensity) for the twso groups of plants. The results are striking: the distribution of the wage bill share of plants investing in new technology is markedly right-skewed with respect to that of non-investing firms, which means that the probability of observing a skill-intensive plant is much higher among plants investing in new technology. This result suggests that technology adoption is a skill-biased activity, so that plants endowed with a higher share of skilled worlkers invest more in new technology. Pavcnik also performs a regression analysis which confirms that technology measures are pos- itively correlated with the plants' share of skilled workers. However, the correlation disappears when plant-specific fixed effects are included in the estimating equation. Hence, the evidence re- ported by Pavcnik does not allow to conclude that plants investing in new technology become more skill-intensive over time. However, the strong evidence reported in the paper concerning the skill-biased nature of investment in new technology still helps explain within-industry skill upgrad- ing, as firms investing in new technology, thanks to their investment, expand their employment share relative to non-investing firms. In other words, it is the reallocation of resources towards more skill-intensive plants, rather than plants' skill upgrading, which might explain why industries become more skill-intensive over time. 5.1.2 The role of exporters While Pavcnik (2000) focuses on the role of imported technology, a related paper by Bernard and Jensen (1997) centers instead on the role of exporting plants for skill upgrading and wage 37 inequality.30 Contrary to previous studies on the determinants of skill upgrading in manufacturng, that analyze within-industry and between-industry shifts in employment using fairly aggregated data, Bernard and Jensen look at the contribution of individual (exporting and non-exporting) plants to the aggregate increase in the relative demand for skilled labor. In particular, they ask whether skill upgrading and the rise in the skill premia stem from within-plants increases in the relative demand for skilled labor pr from a reallocation of resources toward the more skill-intensive plants The question is of particular interest since it can shed light on the relative contribution of trade and technology to the increased demand for skilled labor. More precisely, within-plants skill upgrading can be mostly attributed to skill-biased technical change, i.e, to changes in production practices (such as the widespread introduction of computers and related technologies) that have increased the relative demand for more educated workers. On the other hand, between-plants employment shifts can be mostly attributed to cross-plants demand shifts, and in particular to trade-induced demand shifts. The decomposition performed by Bernard and Jensen reveals that between-plants shifts explain 46% of the total increase in the relative demand for skilled labor and 58% of the total increase in the skill premium These results stand in sharp contrast to previous studies carried at the industry level, where the within-industry component explain virtually all of the increase in the relative demand for skilled labor (Katz and Murphy, 1992; Berman, Bound and Griliches, 1994), and hence suggest that decompositions based on industry-level data hide substantial within-industry plant heterogeneity and potentially overestimate the importance of skill-biased technical change. In order to determine the role of the export status of firms for the dynamics of relative wages and employment, Bernard and Jensen look at the contribution of exporting plants to the within and between increases. They find that non-exporters have a within effect on relative employment 21% larger than exporters, whereas the between effect on employment is entirely explained by the exporters As for wages, the role of exporters is even stronger The within effect on wages is 26% '41The lata uised by Bernard and Jensen come from U S. manLfactiring plants and cover the period 1973-1987 Samuple plants account foi almost two thirds of total manufacturing employment in the U S. 38 larger for exporters than non-exporters, whereas the between effect on wages is entirely explained by the exporters. These results suggest that the rise in wage inequality is due to employment gains at exporting plants, even though skill upgrading is taking place at both exporters and non- exporters. Finally, in order to test more directly the role of technology and product demand shifts for labor market dynamics, Bernard and Jensen regress the within and between components of relative wage and employment increases on changes in export sales, domestic sales and technology variables, such as the change in the R&D to sales ratio or in computer investment The main results are that between-plants changes (both in wages and employment) are strongly positively related to increases in both foreign and domestic demand, with the coefficient of the former three times larger than the latter The impact of technology measures on the between components is instead weaker. These results suggest that the between-plants movements of workers and wages, which are crucial for the increase in the skill premium, are largely determined by demand shifts across plants and in particular by export demand shifts. As for the impact of demand increases and technology variables on the within components of wage and employment increases, it is shown, instead, that the impact of technology measures is relatively stronger than that of demand increases, confirming that within-plants skill upgrading is mainly driven by skill-biased technical change. The main conclusion from the work of Bernard and Jensen is that looking at plart-level evidence instead of aggregate industry-level data reveals that trade-induced demand shifts are responsible for substantial relocation of resources across plants, and in particular in favor of exporting plants, and that this might explain much of the recent increase in wage inequality. T Tadle and LaTicr ElE-R:i astk ties In the previous section we have summarized the main findings of the theoretical and empirical lit- erature on the determinants of the rise in wage inequality in trade liberalizing developing countries However, the rise in wage inequality is not the only adverse effect of globalization on the welfare 39 of workers A new strand of literature, initiated by Rodrik (1997), argues that there are more subtle ways through which globalization may reduce the welfare of workers and jeopardize social stability The main argument, set out informally by Rodrik, is that reduced barriers to trade and investment exacerbate the asymmetry between groups that can cross international borders and those that cannot. The former groups, which include skilled workers, professionals and owners of capital, are freer to take their resources where their reward is highest The latter groups, which mainly include unskilled workers, are instead tied to their country of origin because they are less capable of taking advantage of the richer menu of opportunities offered by the global market. The main consequence is that the demand for large segments of the working population becomes more elastic, since these workers can be more easily substituted by other workers across national borders. Rodrik argues that a trade-induced increase in labor demand elasticities has the following adverse consequences for the welfare of workers: 1) a shift of the incidence of non-wage labor costs towards labor and away from employers; 2) more uncertainty due to more volatile responses of wages and employment to any exogenous shock to labor demand, 3) a reduced bargaining power of workers. Given the relevance of the labor demand elasticity for the welfare of workers, it is useful to see more formally how it can be influenced by trade liberalization. As shown by Hamermesh (1993) and Slaughter (2001), an industry's labor demand elasticity, 77, can be decomposed as follows 77 = [1- sIE + sa (21) where s is the labor share of total industry revenue, e is the constant-output elasticity of substitution between labor and all other factors of production, and (7 is the industry product-demand elastlcity 31 Equation (21) shows that 97 consists of two parts The first, [1-s]e, captures the substitution effect. It tells, for a given level of output, how much the mdustry substitutes away from labor towards other factors when wages rise. The second part, sCr, captures the output effect: higher wages it equation (21) all the elasticities are defined to be positive 40 imply higher costs and thus a lower demand for an industry's output, which translates into a lower demand for labor. Thus, both the substitution and the output effects contribute to reduce labor demand when wages rise. Finally, note that the higher the share s of labor in total cost, the higher the relative importance of the product demand elesticity for the labor demand elasticity. Note that trade liberalization can influence the elasticities e and a, and thus also the derived labor demand elasticity 77. First consider (. As shown in Section 2, trade models based on imperfect competition generally imply that trade liberalization increases the product-market demand elas- ticity Consider now the constant-output elasticity of substitution e between labor and all other factors. Suppose that an industry is vertically integrated with a number of production stages. With international trade, stages can move abroad either within firms by establishing multinational corporations with foreign affiliates (as in Helpman, 1984), or by buying the output of those stages from other firms (as in Feenstra and Hanson, 1996). Trade thus gives access to foreign production factors either directly through foreign affiliates or indirectly through intermediate inputs. As a con- sequence, trade and investment liberalization expand the set of factors an industry can substitute towards in response to higher domestic wages, thus increasing e. To summarize, trade and investment liberalization can potentIally increase the labor demand elasticity either by increasing the product-market demand elasticity or by increasing the elasticity of substitution between labor and all other production factors. Next, we turn to the empirical evidence to see whether trade liberalization actually increased labor demand elasticities. 6.1 Evidence on patterns in 1ezoar denmad eRasticities 6.1.1 lEndustry-level evidence The first rigorous attempt to estimate the impact of international trade on labor demand elasticities is provided by Slaughter (2001). He uses the NBER Productivity Data Base to estimate time series of labor demand elasticities from 1961 to 1991 for production and non-production workers for U.S manufacturing overall and for eight manufacturing industries. The estimated elasticities are then 41 regressed on several trade measures to see whether patterns in trade can explain the estimated patterns in the labor demand elasticities The main trade measures used by Slaughter include exports, imports or net exports as a share of shipments, measures of trends in transport costs (e.g., the ratio of c i f import value to customs import value), measures of outsourcing (e g, the share of imported intermediates), multinational measures (e.g, foreign affiliate share of U.S. multinationals' total employment), et cetera. The main findings of Slaughter can be summarized as follows In the period of analysis, the demand elasticity for production labor has increased in manufacturing overall and in most manu- facturing industries (in particular, it has almost doubled since the mid-1970s) On the other hand, there is no sign of an increase over time in the demand elasticity for non-production labor (indeed, this elasticity has fallen in the last decades) As far as the effect of trade on production labor is concerned, Slaughter finds that most of his trade measures have a positive impact on the elasticity of demand for production labor and are generally statistically significant. The results turn insignificant, however, when time dummies or a time trend are included in the regressions 32 One possible explanation for the lack of robustness of trade measures to the inclusion of time controls may be the high collnearity between time and these trade measures. However, the high statistical significance and robustness of the coefficient of the time trend suggests that time is picking up some force constantly making production labor more elastic over time In this respect, it is likely that it is not actual trade that matters, but rather potential trade. That is, what might matter for labor demand is just the ability to transact internationally regardless of whether such transactions actually occur Thus, trade might be playing an important role independent of changes in observables such as trade and foreign direct investment flows. Finally, as far as the effect of trade on non-production labor is concerned, Slaughter finds that many of his trade measures have a negative and significant effect on the elasticity of demand i 2 Sinilarly, using data from a broad sample of OECD countries, Bruno, Falzoni and Helg (2001) find little impdct of various trade measures on labor demand elasticities in most of these cotntries 42 for non-production labor, and that, contrary to the case of production labor, these measures are generally robust to the inclusion of time controls. 6.1.2 Plant-level evidence Krishna, Mitra and Chinoy (2001) use Turkish plant-level data spanning the course of a dramatic trade liberahzation to test whether greater openness led to an increase in labor demand elasticities. Until the early 1980s, the manufacturing sector in Turkey received an extraordinarily high level of protection the average tariff in 1981 was estimated to be 49% Further, for over half of the products, tariff equivalent of non-tariff barriers were estimated to be over 100%. An import liberalization program was announced in December 1983 and implemented soon Efter, leading to a dramatic fall of both tariff and non-tariff barriers. Krishna et al use annual data from the Turkish manufacturing census for 10 three-digit ISIC industries covering all plants in the greater Istanbul area and spanning the years 1983-1986. Eight of the ten industries saw a dramatic fall in protection after trade reform. The labor demand elasticity is estimated for each of the tcr industries separately, including firm-specific dummies to control for firm heterogeneity The main result is that, although most elasticit:cs are precisely estimated and fall in a reasonable range, estimates of the changes in labor demandl elasticities are small in magnitude and largely insignificant 33 The failure to reject the nul of no changes in labor demand elasticities is somewhat surprising, since previous studies using the same date. (e g, Levinsohn, 1993) strongly suggest that trade liberahzation in Turkey led to substantial increases in product-market demand elasticities From (21) we know that higher product demand elasticities should have translated into higher labor demand elasticities. One possible explanation for this contradictory evidence is that labor demand decisions by firms are subject to several frictions, so that it takes time before changes in product demand elasticities lead to observable chEnges in labor demand elasticities iFajozylber arid Maloney (2001) mse plant-levcl panel daita for Chilc, Colombia and Mexico iurosb their periods of lefoinm to estimate labor demand clasticities ii these countries Their resuilts show little evidence of structural lbieaks aftei trade reform in these countrieb, and of trade-iiduLed increases in labor deruand elasticities 43 7 Evidence on the Effects of Trade Reform in India 7.1 Salient aspects of trade and investment reforms Until the late eighties India's economic system was highly regulated, so much to lead some com- mentators to lump (erroneously, according to Basu and Pattanaik, 1997, p 123) India together with Russia and China as examples of centrally planned economies In June 1991, following a balance of payment crisis, a newly elected government manifested its willingness to undertake deep structural reforms and introduced drastic policy changes in the subsequent years. The main features of these policy changes can be summarized as follows The trade pol2cy regime changed abruptly and dramatically. Prior to the reform, it was one of the world's most regulated and protectionist trade regime, characterized by severe quantitative restrictions and very high import tariffs. On the export side, there were both export controls and export incentive schemes. Following the reform, the maximum tariff was reduced from 400% to 150% in July 1991 and still further later to reach 64% in 1994. The average tariff was reduced from 128% to 94% in 1992 and then to 55% in 1994. In 1992, import hcences were abolished except for a group of sectors mainly producing consumption goods. Export subsidies and controls were abolished The industrial poltcy was completely overhauled.34 Most barriers to entry into industries were removed. Industrial licensing was abolished in almost all sectors. Controls over investment and expansion by large industrial firms were also relaxed, while the list of industries reserved for the public sector was drastically reduced. The forezgn investment policy was also completely restructured Prior to the reforms, India's policy toward foreign investment was very restrictive Equity participation was limited to 40%, except in a few high-tech or export-oriented sectors. With the reform, this limit was raised to 51% and foreign investment was permitted in a much larger number of sectors. Further, the Foreign 34 Sec, %utev ai,a, Jha (2000) 44 Investment Promotion Board was created to stimulate FDI in India and the coun, ry entered into bilateral and multilateral investment guarantee schemes. Finally, the exchange rate regzme was restructured The highly controlled regime based on a chronically overvalued exchange rate was dismantled. In 1992, a dual exchange rate was introduced, and in 1994 the rupee became fully convertible on the current account. The capital account has not yet been liberalized. The restructuring of the exchange rate regime was accornpanied by two substantial devaluations of the rupee However, due to an immediate pass-through to domestic inflation, the real devaluation of the :upee was less than 7% (annually) in the years following the reforms. In the rest of this section, we review the main empirical studies that use firm and plant-level panel data to investigate the effects of this dramatic trade and investment liberclization on the performance of Indian manufacturing firms and labor markets. 7.2 T[rade liberalization and flrm performance in JTndian m ufacturing Two recent studies, Krishna and Mitra (1998) and Balakrishnan et al. (2000), provide an attempt at a rigorous test of the effects of trade liberalization on firm performance in Indian manufacturing Both studies use firm-level data obtained from the Center for Monitoring Indian Economy (CMIE) In both papers, the empirical analysis draws on the methodology developed by Ilall (1988) and Harrison (1994), which allows to examine the effects of the 1991 trade liberalization on firms' mark-ups, productivity growth and the degree of exploitation of returns to scale. Notwithstanding these similarities, the two papers reach completely different conclusions. The data used by Krishna and Mitra (1998) spans the years 1986-1993 and cover the following manufacturing industries: Electronics, Electrical machinery, Non-electrical machinery and Trans- port equipment. The authors find that in all industries except Electrical machiiery there were ieductions in returns to scale after 1991. This reduction in returns to scale may reflect an in- creased exploitation of returns to scale by firms operating at too small a scale prior to the reform. 45 Krishna and Mitra also find evidence of significant reductions in mark-ups in the same industries in the years following the reform.35 Finally, they find evidence of increases in the growth rate of productivity (ranging from 3 to 6%) in all industries except Transport equipment. This evidence suggests that the 1991 trade liberalization in India was associated with a strong pro-competitive effect leading to falling mark-ups, to an increased exploitation of scale economies and an increased growth rate of total factor productivity. Notice that these effects are in line with the predictions of the simple model illustrated in Section 2. The data used by Balakrishnan et al. (2000) span the years 1988 to 1998 and cover the following manufacturing industries Machinery, Transport equipment, Textiles, Textile products and Chemicals. In contrast to Krishna and Mitra (1998), these authors find a 1% fall in the annual rate of productivity growth in the post-trade liberalization period. Further, they find a slight increase (rather than a reduction) in returns to scale after the trade reform, although the returns to scale estimated by these authors for the pre-reform period are much lower than those estimated by Krishna and Mitra (1998). Indeed, Balakrishnan et al. (2000) find evidence of decreasing returns to scale, whereas Krishna and Mitra (1998) find evidence of strong increasing returns to scale in all sectors except Electrical machinery. Given the substantial overlap between the time periods and industries covered by the data used in the two studies, the striking differences in the results are likely to be caused by differences in the methodology used to measure factor inputs and in the econometric strategy. In particular, Balakrishnan et al. (2000) use the fixed-effects estimator, use instrumental variables to control for the endogeneity of factor inputs and pool together firms belonging to different sectors In contrast, Krishna and Mitra (1998) use the random-effects estimator, do not control for the endogeneity of inputs and perform separate regressions for each sector. Finally, notice that, similar to Balakrishnan et al. (2000), other works find a reduction in the rate of productivity growth of Indian firms in the post-liberalization period. Srivastava (2000) uses ''Foi Electrical muachinery, Krishna and Mitra find a slight increase in the mark-up They argue, however, that iiiirk-up estimates for this industry are httle reliable 46 data for about 3000 Indian companies for the period 1980 to 1997 He finds a decline in the rate of productivity growth in the 1990s as compared to the 1980s Kumari (2000) uses firm level data relative to engineering industries (electrical and non-electrical groups) for the period 1985 to 1995. She finds that productivity growth of engineering firms has declined in the post-reform period as compared to the pre-reform period To sum up, contrary to other trade liberalizing developing countries, the available micro-level evidence does not allow yet to discern the effects of the 1991 trade reform in India on firms' mark- ups, on the degree of exploitation of returns to scale and on productivity growth. Aside from methodological issues (see section 3.2), one possible explanation for this lack of positive results is that India is still a highly regulated economy, and hence the expected beneficial effects of the trade-induced reallocation of resources will take longer to materialize. 7.3 Trade and technical eintciency of -ar--c-.m ZuifactuIriLg 27>MS Parameswarn (2000) uses firm-level data to analyze the evolution of technical efficiency of Indian firms. The data (obtained from COvIE) span the years 1989 to 1998 and are relative to 640 firms belonging to four industries Electrical machinery, Non-electrical machinery, Electronics and Transport equipment. In order to estimate technical in/efficiency, the author uses the stochastic frontier production approach developed by Battese and Coelli (1995), which involves estimating a production function of the type Y= f (k., lt,rn,t, t) - u,t + E,t (22) where all variables are in logarithms, and y,t is output of firm i at time t The function f(-) represents the frontier technology, whose inputs are physical capital (k,t), labor (1,,), materials (m*t) and time t (to allow the frontier to shift over time) C,t is an error term, and u,t is a non- negative random variable that captures technical inefficiency Parameswarn asks which variables affect technical efficiency in Indian manufacturing industries. His main findings are the following. 47 Technical efficiency (-u,t) is positively and significantly correlated with R&D intensity in all sectors, suggesting that R&D activities may contribute to reduce technical inefficiency of Indian firms Export intensity has a positive effect on technical efficiency in all sectors except Electronucs, where it has instead a negative and significant effect on technical efficiency Technology import intensity has a positive and significant effect on technical efficiency in Electrical machinery and Transport equipment and a negative and significant effect in the other two sectors The negative impact of technology imports on technical efficiency in high-tech sectors such as Electronics and Non-electrical machinery is indeed surprising. Another surprising finding is that in all sectors technical efficiency is negatively correlated with a time dummy variable which takes a value of zero up to 1991 and a value of one thereafter Hence, trade liberalization seems to be associated with an increased average technical inefficiency in Indian manufacturing One possible explanation for these results is the failure by Indian firms in the adoption and mastering of new technology Another possible explanation is that trade liberalization may have changed the kind of technology imported by Indian firms In particular, technology imports may have shifted away from technology which contributes to profits and productivity within a relatively short time lag and toward technology which makes a more direct contribution to firms' technological capabilities but requires a longer gestation lag If this is the case, this shift in the kind of technology imports may contribute to explain why most studies find that trade liberalization in India is associated with a reduced productivity growth 7.4 Trade liberalization and R&D effort in Indian manufacturing Kumar and Aggarwal (2000) use firm-level data for the period 1992-1997 to study the trend and determinants of R&D activity in Indian manufacturing after trade liberalization. The analysis is motivated by the concern for the declining importance of R&D activity in India. In particular, while the proportion of world CDP devoted to R&D has steadily increased in the last decades to reach 2 5% in the 1990s, the opposite occurred in India, where the proportion of national resources 48 devoted to R&D fell from 0.98% in 1988 to 0.66 in 1097. Since more than 70% of R&D expenditure in India is financed by the government, much of this downward trend is explained by the fiscal reform of the 1990s, which drastically reduced investment expenditure and subsidics to firms in order to reduce the fiscal budget deficit. At the micro-level, the evidence shows different patterns in R&D expenditure between local firms and MNE affiliates in India. In particular, while in the 1990s the average R&D intensity (the ratio of R&D spending to sales) of local firms is still slightly higher than that of MNE affiliates (0.854% versus 0.818%, respectively), the trend for local firms is declining (from 0.868% to 0.831%), while that for MNE affiliates is steadily increasing (from 0.766% to 0 852%) These trends suggest an increasingly central role of MNE affiliates for technological upgrading of Indian manufacturing. The firm-level econometric analysis performed by Kumar and Aggarwal shows that firms' R&D intensity is positively and significantly correlated with technology imports, outward orientation and capital goods imports. However, when performing separate regressions for local firms and MNE affiliates, it turns out that, in contrast to local firms, MNE affiliates' R&D effort is not correlated with export intensity and capital goods import intensity. MNE affiliates' R&D intensity is instead positively correlated with their profitability, as measured by the price-cost margin. According to the authors, one possible explanation for thcse findings is that local firms direct their R&D activity toward absorption of imported technology and outward expansion. In contrast, given their captive access to the laboratories of their parents and associated companies, MNE affiliates' R&D effort is primarily directed toward customization of their parents' technology for the local market in those activities that are more profitable. 7.5 Employment effects of trade reform :n indiarn mamuactzr:ng According to the traditional trade theory, trade liberalization expands the (comparative advan- tage) exporting sector at the expense of the (comparative disadvantage) import competing sector. However, this trade-induced sectoral reallocation of resources has no effect on aggregate employ- 49 ment, because of the assumption of factor market clearing. In practice, in the presence of frictions in the labor market and of a sluggish intersectoral mobility of resources, a drastic trade liberaliza- tion, such as the one experienced by India in recent years, can reduce employment in the import competing sector and thus raise the short-run rate of unemployment Indeed, fear of increased unemployment in the import competing sector has often been the main reason against trade lib- eralization in developing countries pursuing a development strategy based on import substitution However, as noted by Harrison and Revenga (1994), contrary to the predictions of the standard trade theory, most empirical studies find only a modest effect of trade liberalization in developing countries on the employment level in import competing sectors 3(i Kambhampati et al (1997) examine the effects of the 1991 trade reform in India on employment in five import competing sectors 37 They use firm-level data taken from CMIE. The data cover the period 1987-1993 Similar to the results from previous studies, they find no sigruficant employment effect of trade reform overall and in each of the five sectors studied. More interestingly, the authors formulate and test a specific explanation for the lack of employment contraction in the import competing sectors They argue that, in the presence of imperfect competition, trade liberalization raises firms' perceived product demand elasticity and hence induces them to lower mark-ups and expand output Hence, the pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization may involve an increase in the demand for labor. This effect may partially offset the labor demand reduction in import competing sectors induced by the forces of comparative advantage 38 In order to test this prediction, Kambhampati et al (1997) estimate the following equation 'It = )30 + 3iWt + P20.t + I%3kIt + 34m,, + 35D + E,t (23) where, 1, w, k and m are the logs of employment, real wage, capital stock and raw materials, l'Sec, for instance, Raama (1994) oni Uriguay, Revenga (1994) oni Mexico, CGirrie ancl Harrison (1994) oni Moro(lo See also Hairison andl Hanson (1999) on Mexico ancd Morocco '7The ive imnport competing sectors are Electronics, Electrical mahinery, Non-electrical machinery, Transport equipminct andl a se( tor that only includes firms that prodiice Diversified prodiicts "FiScc also Hariisoin and Hanson (1999) on this point 50 respectively; a is the price-margmal cost mark-up; D is a liberalization dummy, which takes a value of zero for the years 1991 and before and a value of 1 for the years after; E is a stochastic error. The regression results reported by the authors, obtamed by using the random-effzct cstimator, show that, overall and in four of the five sectors studied39, both the real wage and the mark-up are negatively and significantly correlated with firms' labor demand. This evidence suggests that when the import competing sectors of a liberalizing country are imperfectly competitive, then the output contraction in these sectors (and the consequent short-run surge in unemployment) may be much less dramatic than expected in the light of the traditional trade theory. 7.6 Trade liberalization in lHnia: grPeater uncertainty vers-s a richer menu of opportunities ? In Section 6, we have shown that a trade-induced increase in product demand elasticities should also bring about an increase in the derived labor demand elasticities As shown by Rodrik (1997), this implies that workers exposed to international competition should face a higher volatility of wages and employment in response to exogenous shocks to labor demand. Daveri, Manasse and Serra (2002) argue that trade-induced increases in the volatility of factor prices and employment are only part of the story, since firms and workers exposed to international competition may also have a greater incentive to invest in productivity enhancing activities, such as training and effort, in order to hedge the risk of lower incGmes. The aim of the authors is hence to test the empirical relevance, in the case of India, of what they call "the twin effects of globalization", i.e, higher uncertainty versus a richer menu of opportunities for firms and workers involved in international competition. The data used by the authors come from a survey of 895 Indian firms belonging to five manu- facturing sectors: Garments, Textiles, ?harmnaceuticals, Electronic consumer goods and Electrical white goods. The data, which cover the period 1997-1999, have recently been collected by the "'Resitltb for the sector producing Diversified products turn out to be statistically insignificant. 51 World Bank. In order to test their hypotheses, the authors partition firms into the following three groups Firms exporting at least 30% of their output are defined as Exporters (they represent 37% of the total), non-exporting firms declaring to face foreign competition in their domestic market are defined as Import-Competmng firms (27% of the total), and the rest of the firms belong to the group of Protected firms (36% of the total). Note that firms belonging to the former two groups are directly exposed to international competition and hence, by comparing their evolution to that of protected firms, we can infer something about the pros and cons of globalization Consider un- certainty first Let w,t- =, + V,t represent a variable pertaining to firm t at time t (i.e, the wage rate, profits, sales, employment or prices), where A, and v,t are is its permanent and transitory components. The variance of w,t can then be written as the sum of a' + a2, where the former represents cross-sectional variation and the latter temporal variation of w,t. Hence, a2, captures uncertainty due to, e.g, wage volatility Performing this decomposition shows that exporters and import-competing firms are characterized by a higher transitory variance of wages, employment, sales, prices and (to a lesser extent) profits. The authors also perform a regression analysis in which the transitory component of firm-level variables is regressed on dummies for exporters and import-competing firms, sectoral and regional dummies, and size. Estimation results show that in most specifications the dummies for exporters and import-competing firms are positive, and they are often also highly significant These results suggest that, consistent with the authors' prior, exposure to international trade is associated with greater uncertaanty due to higher volatility of wages, profits and employment. Consider now the potential pros of trade exposure The authors focus, in particular, on traaning and promotions. Their prior is that firms exposed to foreign competition have a greater incentive to train their workforce in order to increase its productivity, thereby reducing the uncertainty due to more volatile profits At the same time, workers have an incentive to produce a greater effort to obtain promotions, thereby reducing the uncertainty due to higher wage and employment volatility In this respect, data reveal that the share of workers engaged in training programs is 52 31% for exporters, 36% for import-competing firms and only 19% for protected firms. Further, the percentage of workers being promoted in the firm's ladder in 1999 equals 4% for exporting firms, 1.4% for import competing firms and 1.7% for protected firms. The regression analysis performed by the authors shows that the percentage of trained workers is positively and significantly correlated with the dummy for import-competing firms, even after controlling for size and for sectoral and regional dummies. Further, they regress thc probabihty of a promotion on the dummies for exporters and import-competing firms. Estimation results reveal that the former dummy is positive and significant, even after controlling for sectorel dummies, for size and for a proxy of productivity growth.40 Hence, the evidence on Indian manufacturing firms suggests that, although trade liberalization may have increased uncertainty for firms and workers, it may also have induced more investment in training of the workforce on the part of firms, and more effort (aimed at promotions) on the part of workers. 7.7 Trade amnd performance in Hnd n manufacturinag: sorye tenative conclusions The lack of micro-level evidence of trade-induced productivity gains after trade liberalization in India is at odds with the experience of other trade liberalizing developing countries One explana- tion for these somewhat disappointing results is that, as noted by Srinivasan (2001, p. 9), "despite radical changes in the trade policy reforms compared to the pre-1991 situation, India has remained one of most autarkic developing countries". Indeed, as far as quantitative restrictions (QRs) are concerned, although in 1991 the list of imports subject to QRs was drastically shortened, it still remained quite long As estimated by Pursell (1996), although the share of manufacturing GDP protected by quantitative restrictions and other non-tariff barriers was reduced from 90% in the 4"The authors also check the robuistness of their results with respect to the methodology of estimation In partic- itai, they estimate the iupact of trade exposure on incertainty, training andl promotions uising a non-parametric appinao h which protiuces remarkably consibtent resultb 53 pre-reform period to 36% in 1996, it remained high in absolute magnitude, mainly because of the very high share of QR-protected consumer goods. As far as tariff barriers are concerned, Pursell (1996) compares unweighted average tariff rates across 26 countries for 13 product categories Strikingly, he finds that India's tariff rates rank highest or second highest for all product categories and that India's average tariff rate of 51.6% is nearly three times as high as the average level for 26 developing countries Hence, more effort is needed on the part of India's government to reach a degree of trade liberalization comparable to that of more successful developing countries Another explanation for the lack of positive results may be related to India's endowment and the structure of world trade In particular, when compared to other Asian countries that have successfully exploited the opportunities disclosed by a greater participation in the world economy, India is extremely poor in terms of human capital. For instance, as reported by Bajpal and Sachs (1997), in 1992, the adult literacy rate in India was 50%, while the corresponding figures for Indonesia, Thailand and Korea were 84%, 94% and 97%, respectively. This suggests that, at in least in the medium-run, export-led growth in India has to rely on specialization in extremely low- skill intensive productions This may not be that easy, however, since the problem of market access is particularly relevant in these sectors As is well known, tariff peaks and tariff escalation in low- skill intensive sectors severely limit access to industrial countries' markets by skill-poor developing countries. As a symptom of how serious this problem may be for India note that, as shown by Srimvasan and Tendulkar (2001), in the post-liberalization period, within manufacturing, the share of exports of traditional labor-intensive goods either declined steeply (e g., leather manufactures) or remained unchanged (e.g., ready-made garments) In contrast, the share of exports of chemical products and engineering goods increased substantially. These trends suggest, among other things, that because of the issue of market access in low-skill intensive industries, it may paradoxically be easier for a skill-poor developing country to expand into comparative disadvantage rather than comparative advantage industries after trade liberalization In this respect, an immediate policy implication is that, as also suggested by Srinivasan (2001), India has no alternative to actively 54 participate in a new round of multilateral trade negotiations in order to enhance access for its low-skill intensive exports. Finally, several 'behind-the-border' constraints may have prevented India from reaping more of the benefits of liberalization. In particular, notwithstanding the government's effort at deregulating the economy, a still excessive regulation may have resulted in lower mobility of resources and hence in little exploitation of trade-induced efficiency gains As an example (reported by Srinivasan, 2001), until 2000 the garment industry was reserved to the small-scale non-factory sector This constraint prevented the organized factory segment of manufacturing, which is characterized by much higher productivity per worker, to expand into a sector of strong comparative advantage for the Indian economy 8 Concuions In this paper we have reviewed the mucro-level evidence on the effects of trade hberalization in developing countries We have focused, in particular, on the empirical relevance of the effects predicted by the trade theory in the presence of increasing returns to scale, imperfect competition and firm heterogeneity. The main findings can be summarized as follows 1) There is indirect evidence of trade-induced oroductivity gains in the developing countries opting for freer trade. In particular, firms' productivity growth generally rises after trade reforms. More interestingly, the evidence shows that the productivity of firms exposed to international competition (i.e., exporters and import-competing firms) grows much more than that of firms belonging to the non-traded sectors. 2) The evidence suggests that output share reallocations among firms with different productivity levels are the main source of trade-induced productivity gains. This result is in line with trade models, such as Melitz (2002), in which firm heterogeneity and sunk entry costs into foreign markets play a crucial role in the mechanics of efficiency gains from trade liberalization. 3) Firms in import-competing sectors enjoy the highest efficiency gains from trade. One ex- 55 planation for this result is that the disciplining effect of trade liberalization is stronger in import competing sectors Another is that the benefits stemming from cheaper imports of (embodied or disembodied) technology are more relevant for firms belonging to the comparative disadvantage technology-intensive sectors 4) There is no evidence of relevant scale efficiency gains This result, which runs counter to conventional wisdom about the sources of gains from trade in the presence of scale economies, can be explained as follows First, the evidence suggests that large firms, which account for a disproportionate share of industry output, are close to minimum efficient scale and hence their scale efficiency is unaffected by trade liberalization Second, most small firms operating at an inefficient scale are de facto insulated from foreign competition, since they only compete for local market niches Third, the recent episodes of trade reform in the developing world often represent examples of unilateral trade liberalization, which does not imply scale efficiency gains. Indeed, the trade theory suggests that under certain conditions (e g , competition d la Cournot with segmented markets) unilateral trade liberalization reduces scale efficiency in the trade liberalizing country. 5) There is robust evidence of a pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization The pro- competitive effect shows up as reduced price-marginal cost mark-ups for firms exposed to foreign competition, especially if they belong to highly concentrated industries 6) There is no evidence, in the short-run, either of learning-by-exporting effects or of beneficial spillover effects from foreign owned firms to local firms active in the same sectors In particular, exporting firms are more efficient than non-exporting firms, but their productivity trajectories do not seem to change after they break into foreign markets Similarly, foreign owned firms are in general more efficient than local firms, but their presence does not seem to positively influence the productivity of local firms belonging to the same sectors 7) There is evidence, however, of positive vertical FDI spillovers Hence, relevant productivity gains may accrue to developing countries' firms due to the linkages between foreign firms and their local suppliers. 56 8) Plant-level evidence suggests to reconsider the role played international tradc in the dramatic increase in wage inequality observed in most trade liberalizing developing countries. In particular, there is weak evidence that skill upgrading is correlated with measures of impoited technology. Hence, trade liberalization, by reducing the price of imported technology, may spur the demand for imported technology, which in turn may increase the relative demand for sldlled labor, as technology adoption is a skill-intensive activity Further, there is evidence that exporting plants expand at the expense of non-exporting plants after trade liberalization. Since the former are skill- intensive relative to the latter, this implies that trade-induced output share reallocations among firms with different skill-intensity can be a crucial determinant of industry sklll upgrading and rising wage inequality. 9) There is evidence of a substantial increase in the demand elasticity for unskilled labor and of a stable or decreasing demand elasticity for skilled labor, although it is not clear whether the upward trend in the former is trade-induced From a theoretical standpoint, the labor demand elasticity is relevant because its rise generally brings about a rise also in wage volatility. As for the latter, however, there is direct evidence that firms exposed to international competition face a higher wage volatility than firms belonging to the non-traded sectors. 10) There is no evidence of substantial employment contraction in import competing sectors after trade reforms This implies that a dramatic short-run surge in unemployment is not a likely consequence of trade liberalization. One possible explanation for this result is that, at least in the short-run, the tendency toward contraction of the comparative disadvantage sectors is offset by other forces. For instance, in the presence of imperfect competition, trade liberalization, by reducing mark-ups, may force firms to expand output and employment to cover fLxed costs. In short, trade liberalization brings about efficiency gains, mainly through a reallocation of resources toward more efficient, outvard oriented and skill-intensive firms. In turn, this involves skill upgrading, higher wage inequality and higher wage volatility. All this suggests that a greater availability of skilled workers may magnify the efficiency gains from trade reform, on the one hand, 57 and dampen its negative distributional effects on the other. These results naturally lead to the policy implication that a successful trade liberalization should be accompanied by policies aimed at improving the average level of education of the workforce. This would in fact facilitate the expansion of more efficient skill-intensive firms and the absorption of imported technology, while at the same time reducing the pressure on the skill premium. As far as India is concerned, a further policy implication suggested by the somewhat disap- pointing evidence on the effects of trade reform on Indian firms' productivity growth is to further deregulate the economy in order to stimulate the firm to firm mobility of resources so as to allow a better exploitation of trade-induced efficiency gains It is worth noting, in closing, that the above results are not robust enough, however They are often plagued by methodological hurdles (in particular, by the difficulty to identify the trade effects), or by the poor quality of the data, and in particular by the fact that, while most trade effects only materialize in the long-run, most empirical analyses are bounded, instead, to look at data which only cover very short time spans. Empirical studies on the effects of India's trade liber- alization are not exempt from these problems. This may help explain, for instance, the contrasting results concermng the productivity gains from India's trade reform. Hence more effort is necessary to better our understanding of the effects of trade reforms in developing countries in general, and in India in particular. References [1] Acemoglu, D.(1999) "Patterns of Skill Premia," NBER Working Paper W 7018. [2] Acemoglu, D.(1998). "Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1055-1090 [3] Aitken, B. and A. Harrison (1994). "Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct In- vestment? Evidence from Panel Data," Policy Research WP. No.1248, Policy Research 58 Department, World Bank, Washington DC. [4] Autor, D.H, L.F Katz and A.B. Krueger (1998) "Computing Inequality: zave Computers Changed the Labor Market?," Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1169-1213. [5] Aw, B , X Chen and M J. Roberts (1997), "Plant-Level Evidence on Productivity Differen- tials," mtmeo, Pennsylvania State University. [61 Bacchetta, M. and M. Jansen (2001). "Adjusting to Trade Liberalization," m2meo, WTO. [7] Bajpai, N. and J. Sachs (1997). "India's Economic Reforms: Some Lessons from East Asia," The Journal of International Trade and Economic Development 6, 135-164. [8] Balakrishnan P., K. Pushpangs.dan and M.S. Babu (2000). "Trade Liberalization and Pro- ductivity Growth in Manufactunng: Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data," Economic and Political Weekly, October 7, 3679-3682. [9] Baldwin, R (1989). "Sunk Cost Hysteresis," NBER VW/orking Paper W 2911. [101 Baldwin, J. and P. Gorecki (1986). "The Role of Scale in Canada-U.S. Productivnty Differ- ences in the Manufactunng Sector, 1970-1979," University of Toronto Press, Toronto. [11] Barba Navaretti, G. and I. Soloaga (2002). "Weightless Machines and Costless Knowledge. An Empirical Analysis of Trade and Technology Diffusion," CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3321. [12] Barba Navaretti, G. and D.G. Tarr (2000). "International Knowledge Flows and Economic Performance A Review of the Evidence," WVorld Bank Economic Review 14, 1-15. [13] Basu, K. and P.K. Pattanaik (1997). "India's Economy and the Reforms of the 1990s: Genesis and Prospects," The Journal of International Irade & Economic Development 6, 123-133. [14] Battese, G.E. and T.J. Coelli (1995). "A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a Stochas- tic Frontier Production Function for Panel Data," Empincal Economics 20, 325-332. 59 [15] Berman, E, J Bound and Z. Griliches (1994). "Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor within U S Manufacturing Industries Evidence from the Annual Survey of Manufacturing ," Quarterly Journal of Economzcs 109, 367-398. [16] Bernard, A. and J.B. Jensen (1999). "Exceptional Exporter Performance Cause, Effect or Both?," Journal of International Economzcs 47, 1-25 [17] Bernard, A and J B Jensen (1997). "Exporters, Skill Upgrading and the Wage Gap," Journal of Internatzonal Economics 42, 3-31. [18] Blalock, G (2001). "Technology from Foreign Direct Investment: Strategic Transfer through Supply Chains," mimeo, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley. [191 Borjas, C. and V. Ramey (1995) "Foreign Competition, Market Power and Wage Inequality," Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 1075-1110 [20] Brander, J (1981). "Intra-Industry Trade in Identical Commodities," Journal of Internatzonal Economzcs 11, 1-14. [21] Bruno, G., A Falzoni and R. Helg (2001). "Measuring the Effect of Globalization on the Labor Demand Elasticity: An Empirical Application to OECD Countries", mimeo. [22] Caselli, F (1999). "Technological Revolutions," American Economtc Revzew 89, 78-102 [23] Caves, R.(1984). "Scale, Openness and Productivity in Manufacturing Industries," in R Caves and L. Krause (ed ) The Australian Economy: A Vzew from the North, Brookings Institution, Washington DC [24] Clerides, S.K, S Lach and J.R. Tybout (1998) "Is Learning by Exporting Important? Micro- Dynamic Evidence from Colombia, Mexico and Morocco," Quarterly Journal of Economzcs 113, 903-947 [25] Coe, D.T and E Helpman (1995) "International R&D Spillovers," European Economic Review 39, 859-887 60 [26] Coe, D T., E. Helpman and A Hoffinaister (1997) "North-South Spillovers," Economic Journal 107, 134-149. [27] Cox, D and R Harris (1985) "Trade Liberalization and Industrial Organ-ization: Some Estimates for Canada," Journal of Political Economy 93, 115-145. [28] Currie, J. and A Harrison (1994) "Tade Reform ard Labor Market Adjustmert in Morocco," paper prepared for the World Bank Labor Markets Workshop. [29] Daveri, F, P Manasse and D. Serra (2002). "The Twin Effects of Globalization," paper prepared for the joint Luca d'Agliano-World 3ank project 'Trade, Technology Diffusion and Performance in Indian Manufacturing' [30] Dinopoulos E, C. Syropoulos and B Xu (2001) "Intra-Industry Trade and WVage Income Inequality," mimeo, University cf Florida. [31] Dixit, A.(1989). "Exit and Entry Decisions Under Uncertainty," Journal of Polztical Economy 157, 620-638 [32] Dixit, A and J Stiglitz (1977) "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diver- sity," American Economic Revzew 67, 297-308. [33] Djankov, S and B. Hoekman (2C00). "Foreign Investment and Productivity Growth in Czech Elnterprises," World Bank Economzc Review 14(1), 49-64. [34] Eaton, J. and S Kortum (1996). "Trade in Ideas. Productivity and Patenting in the OECD," Journal of International Economics 40, 251-278. [35] Ekholm, K and K.H. Midelfart-Knarvik (2001). "Relative Wages and Trade--Induced Changes in Technology," CEPR Discussion Paper No 2677 [36] Epifani, P and G A Gancia (2002) "The Skill Bias of World Trade," W P. CESPRI-Bocconi University No.129. 61 [37] Ethier, W (1982). "National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade" American Economtc Revzew 72, 389-405. [38] Fajnzylber, P. and W. Maloney (2001) "Labour Demand and Trade Reform in Latin Amer- ica," World Bank Workzng Paper No. 2491, Washington DC [39] Feenstra, R C and G.H. Hanson (1996). "Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and Relative Wages," in R.C. Feenstra, G.M Grossman and D A. Irwin eds, The Polztzcal Economy of Trade Policy Papers 2n Honor of Jagdtsh Bhagwatz, MIT Press, 89-127 [40] Fernandes, A (2002) "Trade Policy, Trade Volumes and Plant-Level Productivity in Colom- bian Manufacturing Industries," mzmeo,World Bank. [41] Grossman, G.M. and E. Helpman (1991) "Innovation and Growth zn the Global Economy," MIT Press, Cambrndge MA. [42] Haddad, M and A. Harrison (1993). "Are there Positive Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from Panel Data for Morocco," Journal of Development Economtcs 42, 51-74 [43] Hall, R.E. (1988) "The Relation Between Price and Marginal Cost in U S Industry," Journal of Poldtical Economy 96, 921-947. [44] Hamermesh, D S (1993) "Labor Demand," Princeton University Press, Princeton [45] Harrison, A (1996). "Determinants and Effects of Direct Foreign Investment in Cote d'Ivoire, Morocco and Venezuela," in M J Roberts and J.R. Tybout (ed ) Industrial Evolution in Developtng Countries, Oxford University Press, Oxford [46] Harrison, A (1994) "Productivity, Imperfect Competition and Trade Reform," Journal of Internattonal Economzcs 36, 53-73. [47] Harrison, A. and G. Hanson (1999). "Who Gains from Trade Reform? Some Remaining Puzzles," NBER Workzng Paper W 6915 62 [48] Harrison, A. and A Revenga (1994). "The Effect of Trade Policy Reform: What Do We Really Know7," mimeo, Columbia University [49] Haskel, J E, S C Pereira and M. J. Slaughter (2002) "Does Inward Foreign Direct Invest- ment Boost the Productivity of Domestic Firms?" 1VBER Working Paper W 8724. [50] Head, K. and J. Ries (1999) "Rationalization Effects of Tariff Reductions," Journal of In- ternattonal Economics 47, 295-320 [51] Helpman, E.(1984) "A Simple Theory of International Trade with Multinational Corpora- tions," Journal of Polttzcal Economy 92, 451-471. [52] Helpman, E. and P R Krugman (1985) "Market Structure and Forezgn Trade," MIT Press, Cambridge MA [531 Idson, T L and W Y Oi (1999). "Workers are More Productive in Large Firms," Amer-can Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 104-108. [54] Jha, R.(2000) "Reducing Povexty in India: Has Liberalization Helped?," VIIDER Workzng Paper No 204 [55] Kambhampati, U., P. Krishna and D Mitra (1997) "The Effect of Trade Policy Reforms on Labor Markets Evidence from India," The Journal of International Trode 8 Economic Development 6, 287-297. [56] Katz, L and K. Murphy (1992). "Changes in Relative Wages: Supply and Dermand Factors," Quarterly Journal of Economtcs 107, 35-78 [57] Kee, H. L. and B Hoekman (2003). "Imports, Entry and Competition Law Ls Market Dis- ciplines", mzmeo,World Bank [58] Keller, W (2001a) "International Technology Diffusion," NBER Working Paper W 8573. [59] Keller, W.(2001b) "Geographic Localization of International Technology Diffusion," forth- coming, American Economic Review. 63 [60] Kraay, A.(1999). "Exportations et Performances Economiques Etude d'un Panel d'Entreprises Chinoises" Revue d 'Economze Du Developpement 1-2, 183-207. [61] Krishna, P., D. Mitra and S Chinoy (2001) "Trade Liberalization and Labor Demand Elas- ticities. Evidence from Turkey," Journal of International Economzcs 55, 391-409. [62] Krishna, P. and D Mitra (1998) "Trade Liberalization, Market Discipline and Productivity Growth: New Evidence from India" Journal of Development Economics 56, 447-462 (63] Krugman, P R (1980). "Scale Economies, Product Differentiation and the Pattern of Trade," American Economtc Revzew 70, 950-959. [64] Krugman, P.R.(1979) "Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition and International Trade," Journal of Internattonal Economics 9, 469-479 [65] Krusell, P, L.E. Ohanian, J -V Rfos-Rull and G L Violante (2000). "Capital-skill Comple- mentarity and Inequality A Macroeconomic Analysis" Econometrica 68, 1029 -1053 [661 Kugler, M (2000) "The Diffusion of Externalities from Foreign Direct Investment. Theory Ahead of Measurement," Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics, University of Southampton, U.K [67] Kumar, N and A Aggarwal (2000). "Liberalization, Outward Orientation and In-House R&D Activity of Multinational and Local Firms: A Quantitative Exploration for Indian Manufacturing," mimeo, Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi. [68] Kumari, A (2000) "Productivity Growth in Indian Engineering Industries During Pre- Reform and Post-Reform Period An Analysis at Company Level," mimeo, Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi. [69] Lee, J.-W (1993) "Capital Goods Imports and Long-Run Growth," Journal of Development Economzcs 48, 91-110. 64 [70] Levinsohn, J.(1993). "Testing the Imports-as-Maxket-Discipline Hypothesis,' Journal of In- ternational Economics 35, 1-22. [71] Lucas, R.E.(1988). "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3-42 [72] Manasse, P and A. Turrini (2001). "Trade, Wages and Superstars," Journal of International Economtcs 54, 97-117. [73] Markusen, J.R.(1981). "Trade and Gains from Trade with Imperfect Competition," Journal of Internatzonal Economics 11, 531-551. [74] Matusz, S.J. and D. Tarr (1999). "Adjusting to Trade Policy Reform," World Bank Workzng Paper No. 2142, Washington DC. [75] Melitz, M.J.(2002). 'The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity," mimeo, Harvard University. [76] Meyer, J.(2001). "Technology Diffusion, Human Capital and Economic Growth in Developing Countries," UNCTAD Working Paper No.154, Geneva. [77] Muendler, M.-A (2002). 'Trade, Technology, and Productivity: A Study of Brazilian Manu- facturers, 1986-1998", mimeo, UC San Diego. [78] Neary, P.(2001). "Foreign Competition and Wage Inequality," mimeo, University College Dublin. [79] Olley, S. and A. Pakes (1996). "The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry ," Econometnca 64, 1263-1297. [80] Parameswarn, M.(2000). "Trade Liberalization on Technical Efficiency: Evidence from Indian Industry," mimeo, Centre for Development Studies, Kerala. [81] Pavcnik, N.(2002). "Trade Liberalization, Exit and Productivity Improvements: Evidence from Chilean Plants," Review of Economic Studies 69, 245-276. 65 [82] Pavcnik, N.(2000). "What Explains Skill Upgrading in Less Developed Countries?," NBER Worktng Paper W 7846. [83] Pursell, G.(1996) "Indian Trade Policies since the 1991/1992 Reform," mimeo, World Bank. [84] Rama, M.(1994). "The Labor Market and Trade Reform in Manufacturmg," in M. Conolly and J. de Melo (ed ) The Effects of Protection on a Small Country, World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies, Washington DC. [85] Revenga, A.(1994). "Employment and Wage Effects of Trade Liberalization. The Case of Mexican Manufacturing," paper prepared for the World Bank Labor Markets Workshop. [86] Rivera-Batiz, L.A. and P.M. Romer (1991). "Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 531-555. [87] Robbins, D.(1996). "HOS Hits Facts: Facts Win; Evidence on Trade and Wages in the Developing World," OECD Technical Paper No. 119. [88] Roberts, M.J. and J.R. Tybout (1996). "Industrzal Evolutton tn Developing Countries," Ox- ford University Press, Oxford. [89] Roberts, M J and J.R. Tybout (1991). "Size Rationalization and Trade Exposure in Develop- ing Countries," in R. Baldwin (ed.) Empincal Studies of Commercial Policy, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [90] Rodrik, D.(1997). "Has Globaltzatton Gone Too Far?," Institute for International Economics, Washington DC. [911 Rodrik, D.(1988). "Imperfect Competition, Scale Economies and Trade Policy in Developing Countries," in R. Baldwin (ed.) Trade Policy Issues and Empzrical Analysts, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [92] Schiff, M. and M. Olarreaga (2002). "North-South and South-South Trade-Related Technol- ogy Diffusion: An Industry-Level Analysis," mimeo, DECRG-IT, World Bank, April. 66 [93] Schiff, M. and Y. Wang (2002) "On the Quantity and Quality of Knowledge Diffusion: The Impact of Openness and Foreign R&D on North-North and North-South R&D Spillovers," mzmeo, DECRG- IT, World Bank. [94] Schmalensee, R.(1989). "Inter-Industry Studies of Structure and Performance," in R. Schmalensee and R Willig (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, North-iSTolland, Am- sterdam. [95] Slaughter, M.J.(2001). "International Trade and Labor-Demand Elasticities," Journal of In- ternational Economtcs 54, 27-56. [961 Smarzynska, B. (2002). "Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domes- tic Firms? In Search of Spillovers through Backward Linkages," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 2923 [97] Srimvasan, T N. (2001). "India's Reform of External Sector Policies and Future Multilateral Trade Negotiations," EGC Discusston Paper No. 830, Yale University. [98] Srinivasan T.N. and S.D. Tendulkar (2001). India in the World Economy, Nev; Delhi, Indian Council for Reasearch on International Economic Relations and Whasington D.C, Institute for International Economics [99] Srivastava, V.(2000). "The Impact of India's Economic Reforms on Industriel Productivity, Efficiency and Competitiveness," report of a project sponsored by the Industrial Development Bank of India, National Council of Applied Economic Research, New Delhi. [100] Turrini, A.(2002). "International Trade and Labour Market Performance. Mein Results and Open Questions," UNCTAD Policy Issues, in International Trade and Commodity Study Series, forthcoming. [101] Tybout, J.R.(2001) "Plant-and Firm-Level Evidence on 'New' Trade Theories," NBER Workzng Paper W 8418. 67 [102] Tybout, J R and M D Westbrook (1995). "Trade Liberalization and the Dimensions of Ef- ficiency Change in Mexican Manufacturing Industries," Journal of International Economics 39, 53-78 [103] Tybout, J.R., J. De Melo and V. Corbo (1991). "The Effects of Trade Reforms on Scale and Technical Efficiency New Evidence from Chile," Journal of Internatzonal Economzcs 31, 231-250. [104] World Bank (1993) "The East Astan Mzracle," Oxford University Press, New York. [105) Young, A.(1991). "Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade," Quarterly Journal of Economcts 106, 369-405 68 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS3043 The Incentive-Compatible Design Thorsten Beck May 2003 K. Labrie of Deposit Insurance and Bank 31001 Failure Resolution. Concepts and Country Studies WPS3044 Impregnated Nets Cannot Fully Mead over May 2003 H. Sladovich Substitute for DDT. Field Bernard Bakote'e 37698 Effectiveness of Malaria Prevention Raman Velayudhan in Solomon Islands Peter Wilikai Patricia M. Graves WPS3045 Causes and Consequences of Civil Klaus Deininger May 2003 M. Fernandez Strife: Micro-Level Evidence from 33766 Uganda WPS3046 Migration, Spillovers, and Trade Ross Levine May 2003 E. Khine Diversion The Impact of Sergio L. Schmukler 37471 Internationalization on Stock Market Liquidity WPS3047 Comparing Mortgage Credit Risk Robert Buckley May 2003 0 Himid Policies. An Options-Based Approach Gulmira Karaguishiyeva 80225 Robert Van Order Laura Vecvagare WPS3048 Targeted Transfers in Poor Countries: Martin Ravallion May 2003 P Sader Revisiting the Tradeoffs and Policy 33902 Options WPS3049 Hidden Impact? Ex-Post Evaluation Shaohua Chen May 2003 P Sader of an Anti-Poverty Program Martin Ravallion 33902 WPS3050 The Changing Financial Landscape: Wafik Grais May 2003 R Vo Opportunities and Challenges for Zeynep Kantur 33722 the Middle East and North Africa WPS3051 Regional, Multilateral, and Unilateral Glenn W Harrison May 2003 P Flewitt Trade Policies of MERCOSUR for Thomas F. Rutherford 32724 Growth and Poverty Reduction in David G. Tarr Brazil Angelo Gurgel WPS3052 Long-Run Impacts of China's WTO Kym Anderson May 2003 S. Lipscomb Accession on Farm-Nonfarm Income Jikun Huang 87266 Inequality and Rural Poverty Elena lanchovichina WPS3053 Economic Impacts of China's Elena lanchovichina May 2003 S. Lipscomb Accession to the World Trade William Martin 87266 Organization WPS3054 The New Comparative Economics Simeon Djankov May 2003 G. Sorensen Edward Glaeser 37088 Rafael La Porta Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes Andrei Shleifer WPS3055 The Global Growth of Mutual Funds Deepthi Fernando May 2003 A Yaptenco Leora Klapper 31823 Viktor Sulla Dimitri Viftas FoD5cy ReseaYcG WoERing VaF% er ng contact 71Vae Au~htfrDcja for paper WPS3056 Avoiding the Piffalls in Taxing Patrick Honohan May 2003 A Yaptenco Financial Intermediation 31823 WPS3057 Teaching Adults to Read Better and Helen Abadzi May 2003 H Abadzi Faster: Results from an Experiment 80375 in Burkina Faso WPS3058 Working for God? Evaluating Service Ritva Reinikka May 2003 H. Sladovich Delivery of Religious Not-for-Profit Jakob Svensson 37698 Health Care Providers in Uganda WPS3059 Do Capital Flows Respond to Risk Cesar Calder6n May 2003 T Tourougui and Retum? Norman Loayza 87431 Luis Serven WPS3060 World Market Integration through the Rui Albuquerque May 2003 T Tourougui Lens of Foreign Direct Investors Norman Loayza 87431 Luis Serven WPS3061 Reciprocity in Free Trade Caroline Freund May 2003 P Flewitt Agreements 32724 WPS3062 Labor Effects of Adult Mortality in Kathleen Beegle May 2003 E de Castro Tanzanian Households 89121