W PS 2579- POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2574 How Adverse Selection There may be a price to pay (in terms of inefficient Affects the H ealth coverage) if competition Insurance Market among health insurers is encouraged as a way to give patients greater choice and to Paolo Belli achieve better control over insurance providers The World Bank Development Research Group Public Economics March 2001 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2574 Summary findings Adverse selection can be defined as strategic behavior by analyzes the following policy options relating to the the more informed partner in a contract against the public provision of insurance: interest of the less informed partner(s). In the health * Full public insurance. insurance field, this manifests itself through healthy * Partial public insurance with or without the people choosing managed care and less healthy people possibility of acquiring supplementary insurance and choosing more generous plans. with or without the possibility of opting out. Drawing on theoretical literature on the problem of In recent plans implemented in Germany and the adverse selection in the health insurance market, Belli Netherlands, where competition among several health synthesizes concepts developed piecemeal over more funds and insurance companies was promoted, a public than 20 years, using two examples and revisiting the fund was created to discourage risk screening practices classical contributions of Rothschild and Stiglitz. He by providing the necessary compensation across risk highlights key insights, especially from the literature on groups. But only "objective" risk adjusters (such as age, "equilibrium refinements" and on the theory of "second gender, and region) were used to decide which contracts best." to subsidize. Those criteria alone cannot correct the The government can correct spontaneous market effects of adverse selection. dynamics in the health insurance market by directly Regulation can exacerbate the problem of adverse subsidizing insurance or through regulation; the two selection and lead to chronic market instability, so forms of intervention provide different results. Providing certain steps must be taken to prevent risk screening and partial public insurance, even supplemented by the preserve competition for the market. possibility of opting out, can lead to second-best Belli considers the following three policy options for equilibria. The same result holds as long as the regulating the private insurance market: government can subsidize contracts with higher-than- * A standard contract with full coverage. average premium-benefit ratios and can tax contracts * Imposition of a minimum insurance requirement. with lower-than-average premium-benefit ratios. Belli * Imposition of premium rate restrictions. This paper-a product of Public Economics, Development Research Group-is part of a larger effort in the group to improve social service delivery in developing countries. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Hedy Sladovich, room MC2-609, telephone 202-473-7698, fax 202- 522-1154, email address hsladovich@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http:/ /econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at pbelli@hsph.harvard.edu or pbellil@worldbank.org. March 2001. (31 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Ceniter How Adverse Selection Affects the Health Insurance Market Paolo Belli Harvard School of Public Health Dr. Paolo Belli, Department of Population and International Health, Harvard School of Public Health, 677 Huntington Avenue, Boston MA 02115, Tel: 617-432-1185, Fax: 617-432-2181. Email: pbelliRhsph.harvard.edu. For their support and comments, the author is grateful to Jeffrey Hammer, Jean Dreze and Silvya Topolyn. The findings, interpretations; and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. 1. Introduction Adverse selection can be defined as strategic behavior by the more informed partner in a contract, against the interest of the less informed partner(s). In the health insurance market it is relevant because each individual chooses among the set of contracts offered by insurance companies according to his/her expected probability of using health services. In brief, those who foresee an intense use of health services will tend to choose more generous plans than those who expect a more limited use of them. In the extreme, for each premium and degree of coverage, those who will decide to purchase that particular health insurance contract are those who expect to have health expenditure greater or equal to the premium paid. Then, whatever the premium, the insurance company may end up with a loss on each customer. Insurance companies anticipate this purchasing behavior and devise contract offers in order to screen individuals. This "screening" strategy is even more critical to success in the market whenever there is regulation in place that does not allow health premiums to reflect individual risk (premium rate restrictions) or does not permit to acquire information on potential customers' health conditions before making contract offers (such as an open enrolment requirement). In any case, the screening practice by insurance companies hinders the achievement of an efficient risk pooling across individuals. There is a growing body of evidence that suggests that adverse selection is an important phenomenon in health insurance markets. Cutler writes (1996, p.30): "Almost all health insurance systems where individuals are allowed choice of insurance have experienced adverse selection. Medicare enrollees who choose managed carel are healthier than... [those] who do not. The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program.. .has adverse selection between more and less generous policies. The spread in premiums between more and less generous policies is 68 percent greater than benefits alone would dictate.. .And almost every large firm that has encouraged employee choice has found the cost of the most generous policies increases sufficiently rapidly than these policies are no longer viable" (this last phenomenon is named in the literature "price death spiral" and refers to the increase in the price of ffore generous insurance plans vis- a-vis moderate plans). It is also expected that in the United States, as the insurance market becomes more competitive and individuals are brought to face the true marginal cost of health insurance, the phenomenon of adverse selection will become more severe.2 'Managed care plans imnpose stricter controls and restrictions over use of health services than traditional indemnity plans. 2In the past, emnployers would pay a large share of the premniums. Increasingly, employees are offered lump-sum transfers for health insurance and they face almost entirely the relative marginal costs of alternative plans. I Adverse selection is often advocated as the main justification for the provision of compulsory universal public health insurance. The claim is that the state would ultimately bear a significant share of the total health costs even if it chose to subsidize health care only for those who are left out of the private insurance market, because adverse selection would lead to insufficient insurance coverage for those who most in need and because health expenditure is highly concentrated within a few segments of the population.3 Therefore, it would be preferable to force all individuals into the same insurance pool, where cross-subsidies are more transparent. The existing theoretical literature that we will survey in this work seems to suggest that the main consequence to be expected from screening strategies by insurance companies would be the incomplete coverage of low-risk rather than the exclusion of high-risk groups. So, the above "price death spiral" for generous plans is not really captured by the existing theory. This gap between theory and reality may reflect an insufficiency in the existing analytical framework. Moreover, the theory does not consider that high-risk individuals may be unable to pay a premium adequate to cover their expected health expenditure even in a world of perfect information, nor extends the analysis to a dynamic setting (if it is possible to write only incomplete and short-term contracts, those who end up having a probability of the loss close to one, for example patients who become chronically ill, ex post are not insurable, even if that is ex-ante inefficient). We will first illustrate the problem of adverse selection in the health insurance market by way of two examples and then present a survey of the existing theoretical literature. In the second part, the paper analyses different policy options to correct spontaneous market dynamics, either by direct public provision of health insurance or by regulation of private insurers. We shall try to provide a unitary representation of a set of concepts that have developed piece-meal over a period of more than twenty years. Given the aim of our survey and the broadness of the literature, our attention is focused on giving an intuitive understanding of the main results, rather than in presenting them rigorously. Whenever possible, we will make use of diagrammatical proofs. 2. Two Examples The first example builds on a similar case presented by Cutler and Zeckhauser (1997). Consider two health plans offered in a particular market, a generous and a moderate plan, and two types of individuals, high-risk and low-risk, each group making up 50 percent of the entire population. 3 International studies agree in showing that a small minority, consisting of about 5-7 per cent of the population, is generally responsible for 60-65 per cent of total health expenditure. 2 Suppose that the cost of treating individuals under the two plans, and their gains in benefit from the generous plan vis-a-vis the moderate plan, are as follows: Resource cost Resource cost Benefit difference of coverage (moderate) of coverage (generous) (generous - moderate) Low-risk 40 60 15 High-risk 70 100 40 Suppose that the insurance market is competitive (in equilibrium premiums are equal to expected costs) and that insurers do not know individuals' risk type, but know that there is an equal probability that each potential customer is either low or high-risk. They can also compute the cost of coverage for both groups and the expected costs of the contract that pools together both groups. First note that the first best equilibrium, which in this case would see the high-risk individuals enrolled in the generous plan for a price of 100 and the low-risk individuals in the moderate plan for a price of 40, is not an equilibrium with incomplete information. At these prices both groups would buy the moderate plan, which would start making losses and whose price would have to be increased. Suppose that initially a unique plan, the generous one, is offered in the market. If the market is competitive in equilibrium such plan must break even and it would be offered to everybody for a price of 80. Then, the moderate plan is devised and offered for a price of 64, which is low enough to attract low-risk individuals. All low-risks switch to the new plan (they can save 16 in exchange for a benefit loss of 15). In the new situation, the generous plan becomes unprofitable and its price has to be increased. At the same time, competition drives down the price for the moderate plan. As the price differential between the two plans exceeds 40 (given the above assumptions, it will eventually do so, because in equilibrium premiums must reflect relative costs), all high-risk individuals switch to the moderate plan and the generous plan has to be terminated. Then, the moderate plan also becomes unprofitable, as it has to shoulder all risk types, and its price has to be increased. New opportunities arise to undercut low-risk by offering even less generous and cheaper plans. The market is characterized by chronic instability. Now, consider the equilibrium that the market would reach by changing the above figures for net benefits as follows: Resource cost Resource cost Benefit difference of coverage (moderate) of coverage (generous) (generous - moderate) Low-risk 40 60 25 High-risk 70 100 60 As before, suppose that insurers do not know individuals' risk type. It is evident that the full-information equilibrium, that would in this case see both risk groups 3 purchasing the generous plan for a price of 60 (low-risk) and 100 (high-risk), can never be an equilibrium with incomplete information for the same reasons as before. Moreover, starting from the same initial situation considered in the first example (generous plan offered for a price of 80), it is profitable for low-risks to switch to the moderate plan as long as it is offered for a price lower than 55 (80-55 = 25 is now equal to the benefit difference between the generous and the moderate plan for low-risk individuals). Then, competition will drive the price of the moderate plan down to 40, while the price of the generous plan, burdened just with high-risk, will rise up to 100. Unlike the previous example, the price differential of 60 is not sufficient to induce high-risk to switch to the moderate plan (in fact, they are just indifferent between switching and maintaining the generous insurance plan). Thus, in this case the situation in which high-risk pay 100 for full insurance and low-risk pay 40 for incomplete insurance is an equilibrium. In this equilibrium low-risk are worse off than in the full information equilibrium, as they obtain only partial insurance, but the market equilibrium is stable. The market "sorts" out low- risk individuals from high-risks in a separating equilibrium, by offering plans with less than optimal coverage. 3. Rothschild-Stiglitz and the Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information The first article to analytically investigate the problem of adverse selection in the insurance market is that by Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976). We will begin our survey of the theoretical literature by presenting a detailed summary of their model because it provides the basic conceptual framework that is going to be used for presenting also subsequent contributions. On the demand side of the market, individuals' income without insurance is: WI = W, if 'accident' does not occur. W2 = W - d, if 'accident' occurs. Insurance companies offer indemnity a^2 if accident occurs in exchange for a premium cc. Individuals' income with insurance becomes respectively: W1 = W- a1 and W2 = W - clI + a2- d = W + a2 - d, where c2 = aA2 - XI If the probability of accident is p we can apply the expected utility theorem and represent individuals' preferences for income in the two states in the following way: V(p, aI,a2C) = (1-p)U(W-al) + pU(W + X2 - d) (1) Given p, each individual maximizes V( ) with respect to {al ,a2 }. 4 Rothschild and Stiglitz (hereafter, R.-S.) assume that individuals are risk averse, i.e. U"( ) < 0. So, V() being a linear combination of concave functions, is quasi-concave. They also assume that there is no moral hazard. The amount of the loss, as well as the probability p, are not influenced by the presence of insurance coverage. On the supply side of the market insurance companies are considered risk-neutral and only interested in expected profits. A contract offer C1 consists of a bundle {aI,a2} containing specific 'amounts of insurance' that the individual can buy and a particular price for that bundle (in the following diagrams we will frequently refer to points C1 as "contracts C," rather than as "wealth in the two states generated by the net premium- indemnity pair U1,OC2"). R-S assume that individuals can buy at most one insurance contract, thus recognizing that insurance companies are able to ration the degree of insurance coverage offered to individuals. On the other hand, the market is assumed perfectly competitive, such as that in equilibrium premiums are equal to expected costs. Expected profit for a contract offer to an individual who has probability p of incurring in a loss is: 7C (P, aC,02) =0 -p) al -p (aC2 - al) = (1-p) al -P p 2 (2) The equilibrium set of contracts is defined as: * customers maximize expected utility; * no contract in the equilibrium set entails negative expected profits; * no contract outside the equilibrium set, if offered, would make a positive profit. The equilibrium concept adopted is that of Nash-Cournot: each agent maximizes his/her objective function, independently of other agents' reaction. Finally, R-S make a strong assumption about information: when deciding to sign a contract, agents know the probability of the loss, while insurance companies do not. 3.1 Equilibrium with Identical Customers Let us first consider the equilibrium with identical customers. In Figure 1 we represent on the horizontal axis income if no loss occurs and on the vertical axis income if the loss occurs. Situations of full insurance correspond to points on the bisetrix, while situations of incomplete insurance lie to the right of the bisetrix (where WI >W2). Point E corresponds to the situation of no insurance. Each point to the northwest of E represents a specific insurance contract uniquely identified by a certain premium a l and a certain net indemnnity ax2 in case of accident. The segment EF represents the zero profit, or actuarial ("fair") odds line. Trading income in the two states at a rate equal S to the slope of EF (da2/dal = (1-p)/p = -dW2/dWI) leaves the insurance company with exactly zero profit. Starting from point E, any point to the south-west of EF entails positive profits and cannot be an equilibrium contract (as it can always be undercut by a new contract that attracts all customers and still earns positive profits), while any point to the north-east of EF entails negative profits and it is therefore not feasible. So, given free- entry and perfect competition in long-term equilibrium individuals find their preferred contract along the set of contracts belonging to the "zero profit" line, where s(p, al a2) = (1-p) a1 - pa2= 0. The zero-profit line identifies the "best" budget constraint available to the individual for trading income in the two states. We can represent individuals' preferences with a map of indifference curves. Given risk-aversion, the indifference curves are convex.4 Given any indifference curve, all the points to the northeast entail higher utility and all the points to the southwest entail lower utility. Equilibrium lies in correspondence to the highest indifference curve compatible with the expected budget constraint (point C5). In C5 the slope of the indifference curve is equal to the slope of EF. Figure 1: Equilibrium with Identical Customers 12 1 II W2 - F d{} . I I ;F . l~~~~~~~~~~ > WWd . 6aA 450 I I W-al WI~~I From the equation of the indifference curve: (l-p)[dU( )/dWl]dWl + p[dU( )/dW2]dW2 = 0, if we denote: dU( )/dWl=U'(Wl) and dU( )/dW2 =U(W2), the slope of the indifference curve is equal to: dW2/dWl = [U'(Wl)/U(W2)][(1-p)/p] (3) The tangency condition entails: [U' (W1)/U'(W2)][(l-p)/p] = (l-p)/p '> U' (W1) = U' (W2) * W1= W2, given that U" (.)<0 (4) Thus, given that individuals are risk averse and insurance companies are risk neutral, the first best is characterized by full insurance. Whenever the premium is set at a higher level than the actuarially fair premium, the degree of insurance coverage chosen by individuals is lower, but under R-S hypothesis of free entry it will then be undercut by competition until the zero-profit equilibrium is reached. 3.2 Equilibrium with Two Classes of Customers Let us now consider a market consisting of two groups of customers. They are characterized by the same utility function for income in the two states, U(.), but by different accident probabilities. h * high-risk individuals, with probability of accident = p * low-risk individuals, with probability of accident = p ,with p h> p Let the percentage of high-risk individuals be equal to x RS. The average probability EXP=_RS h 1_RSP of accident is then equal to: p = X p ±(1 X ) p In this case, it is possible to distinguish between two types of equilibrium: * pooling equilibria, in which both groups buy the same contract. 4A mathematical property states that the level curves of a quasi-concave function are convex. 7 In any pooling equilibrium, the zero profit condition must hold across all the individual types: EXP EXP (I-p )aC - p a2 =. * separating equilibria, in which different risk-groups choose different contracts. In any separating equilibrium, both contracts must yield zero expected profits: h h I 1 (i-p ) al - p a2 = 0 and (l-p ) a, - p a2 = () In Figure 2 we denote with the letter L and H the indifference curves and zero profit lines relative to respectively low-risk and high-risk individuals. Note that the slope of the zero profit line for low-risk individuals (L, with a slope equal to (1-pl)/pl) is steeper than that relative to high-risk individuals (H, with a slope equal to (l-ph)Iph ). From Figure 2 and equation (3) note also that the slope of the low-risk indifference curve passing through each point {W1; W2}is higher than that of the high-risk indifference curve through the same point. In other words, each high and low-risk indifference curve can intersect only once ("single-crossing property"). When there are two different groups of individuals first best equilibria are no longer sustainable, as they violate the high-risk group incentive-compatibility constraint. These constraints entail that, whenever two different contracts are offered to the two risk groups, they must be devised so that each group prefers the contract specific to its own risk group to the contract set for the other risk group. No one can be cheated or forced to buy a contract different from the most preferred one available in the market. Formally, if we denote by ah the set of contracts meant for the high-risk group and with a' the set of contracts meant for the low-risk group: V(ph, ah ) 2 V(ph, al ) and V(pI, al ) 2 V(pI, ah ) (I.C. constraints) First-best equilibria violate the first of these constraints. As Figure 2 shows, if contracts Cl and C2 are offered, all individuals would choose Cl. Then C, would make losses. As we have shown for the case of identical customers, only contracts on the line EF, such as C3 and C4, can be sustained as pooling equilibria. 8 Figure 2: Equilibrium with Two Classes of Customers W2 A L L4 H3H4 L F E 0>45 WI The second, important result that R-S graphically prove is that there cannot be a pooling equilibrium. Figure 3: Impossibility of a Pooling Equilibrium :~~ L 3 F (l EXP -(1-p')/ pi WI As Figure 3 shows, contract C3 can always be upset by a contract offer in the full area, such as contract C6. All low-risk individuals are induced to purchase the new contract when it is offered alongside C3. Contract C3 thus becomes unprofitable and cannot be sustained as an equilibrium. The impossibility of pooling contracts derives from the "single-crossing" property. 9 The only possible equilibrium with different risk-types is a sel)arating equilibrium: we can graphically represent the separating equilibrium in the WI W2 space and in the al,7aA2 space respectively. Figure 4: Separating Equilibrium with Two Risk Types a) W2 L Ar-C W b) - Ho P a) (p = Oh) HI 2 71(pEXPa)=O itr(p',aI)= E d aA 2=cal+a2 10 As Figure 4a) shows, contract C2, characterized by full insurance, is offered to high-risk individuals. To break even it must lie on the high-risk zero profit line. Then, contract C7 is offered to low-risk. C7 lies on the zero profit line for low-risks and it is the most preferred contract by the low-risks among all contracts that respect the high-risk group's incentive-compatibility constraint. Given C2, any contract along the low-risk group zero profit line above C7 would be purchased by both groups and would therefore yield negative profits (when both groups purchase the same contract, such contract must lie on segment EF). When the vector of contracts C2-C7 is offered, the high-risk incentive compatibility constraint is binding and the two groups of individuals sort themselves out by purchasing two separate insurance plans: HI= V(ph, C7 ) V(ph, C2) As Figures 4 shows, in any separating equilibrium the low-risk group gets incomplete insurance (C7 lays to the right of the bisetrix). Point C7 is not at the tangency point between any indifference curve for low-risks and their budget constraint. The same couple of separating equilibrium contracts can be represented in the al,a A2 space. Given C2, the best low-risk types can obtain along segment L is C7, which is characterized by incomplete insurance (acA2-A-C WI The last form of regulation we consider is premium rate restrictions. Rate restrictions are assumed to apply to a specified health insurance coverage.8 In terms of the above graphs, such form of regulation entails a restriction on the allowable gap between the rates charged to high-risk vis-a-vis those set for low-risk individuals. That is equivalent to force a cross-subsidy between the two groups, aimed at making health coverage more accessible for the high risk. Similarly to the case of the standard contract regulation, imposing rate-restrictions may actually exacerbate the effects of adverse selection, as 8 To prevent the insurers from rejecting new applicants or from cream-skimming high risk individuals, the regulator may complement premium rate restrictions with a periodic open enrolment requirement. 28 insurance companies struggle to dilute the share of loss-making contracts in their pool, by discouraging subscription of high-risk individuals and by competing for low risk individuals. 8. Conclusion The paper discussed the consequences of adverse selection on the functioning of insurance markets. To isolate the effects of adverse selection from other confounding factors, the paper considers a benchmark situation with no moral hazard and perfectly competitive market. In those circumstances, the full information equilibrium is characterized by complete insurance coverage. With incomplete information, however, insurance companies underbid each other's contract offers in order to attract low risk. The equilibrium is characterized by less than optimal insurance coverage and, under the hypothesis of myopic behavior by insurers and insurees, no equilibrium may exist. We have also shown that for a relevant range of parameters second best equilibria are characterized by a positive cross-subsidy across risk types and that in these circumstances the market separating equilibrium is in general sub-optimal. The government can intervene in the health insurance market in two ways: by directly providing subsidizing insurance or by regulation. Following Neudeck and Podczeck (1996), the paper shows that the two forms of intervention do not lead to identical results. Provision of partial public insurance, even supplemented by the possibility of opting out, can lead to second best equilibria. This same result holds as long as the government is able to subsidize contracts with higher than average premium/benefit ratios and to tax contracts with lower than average premium/benefit ratios. This theoretical conclusion seems to be of practical relevance. In recent reform plans implemented in Germany and Holland where competition among several health funds and insurance companies was promoted, to discourage risk screening practices a Public Fund was also created in order to provide the necessary compensation across risk groups. Unfortunately, only "objective" risk adjusters such as age, gender and region, have been used for deciding which contracts were to be subsidized. These criteria alone are not able to completely correct the consequences of adverse selection (Van de Ven and Van Vliet, 1992). Regulation of the private insurance market by imposition of a standard contract or by restricting premium rates, on the other hand, can exacerbate the problem of adverse selection and lead to chronic market instability. If the government is willing to safeguard competition in the insurance market to tame the consequences of risk screening it is necessary either to: a) impose limits to the possibility of undercutting existing contracts (through a minimum insurance requirement; b) impose limits for insurance companies on the possibility of selecting their insurees' pool. That explains why in Diamonds' original proposal (1992) for regulating the American health insurance market insurance 29 companies were obliged to serve all members of a Health Alliance. Competition for the market would have been preserved, but competition within each market (the market being identified by the population of each Health Alliance) had to be limited to avoid risk screening. In general, the above analysis has shown that there may be a price to pay in terms of inefficient coverage by enhancing competition among health insurers as a means to achieve greater patients' choice and better control over providers. References K.Crocker and A. Snow (1985), The Efficiency of Competitive Equilibria in Insurance Markets with Asymmetric Information, Journal of Public Economics 26, 207-219 D. Cutler (1996), Public Policy for Health Care, NBER Working Paper 5591, May. D. Cutler and R. Zeckhauser (1997), Adverse Selection in Health Insurance, NBER Working Paper 6107. B. Dahlby (1981), Adverse Selection and Pareto Improvements Through Compulsory Insurance, Public Choice 37, 547-558. P. Diamond (1992), Organizing the Health Insurance Market, Econometrica 60: 1233-54. W. Encinosa and D. Sappington (1997), Competition Among Health Maintenance Organizations, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 6, 129-150. G. Frank, J. Glazer and T. McGuire (2000), Measuring Adverse Selection in Managed Health Care, Journal of Health Economics 19, 6: pp.829-854. P. Gertler and J. van der Gaag, The willingness to pay for medical care: evidence from two developing countries, Baltimore, Md.: the Johns Hopkins Univ. Press, 1990. H. Grossman (1979), Adverse Selection, Dissembling and Competitive Equilibrium, Bell Journal of Economics 10, 336-343. M. Harris and R. Townsend (1981), Resource Allocation Under Asymmetric Information, Econometrica 49, 33-64. W. Manning et al. (1987), Health insurance and the Demand for Medical Care: Evidence from a Randomised Experiment, American Economic Review 77: 251-277. M. Marquis (1992), Adverse Selection with a Multiple Choice Among Health Insurance Plans: A Simulation Analysis, Journal of Health Economics 11, 129-151. H. Miyazaki (1977), The Rat Race and Internal Labor Markets, Bell Journal of Economics 8, 394-418. W. Neudeck and K. Podczeck (1996), Adverse selection and Regulation in Health Insurance Markets, Journal of Health Economics 15: 387407. J. Newhouse (1996), Reimbursing Health Plans and Health Providers: Efliciency in Production Versus Selection, Journal of Economic Literature 34, 1236-1263. J. Newhouse, (1993) J. Free for all?: Lessons from the Rand health insurance experiment. Cambridge Mass.: Harvard University Press. J. Newhouse, (1989), Do unprofitable patients face access problems? Health Care Financing Review 11: 2. Pp. 33-42 EMBASE J. Newhouse (1984), Cream Skimming, Asymmetric Information and a Competitive Insurance Market, Journal of Health Economics 3, 97-100 30 J. Riley (1979), Informational Equilibrium, Econometrica 47, 331-360. M. Rothschild and J. Stiglitz (1976), Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information, Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 630-649. M. Rothschild and J. Stiglitz (1997), Competition and Insurance Twenty Years Later, The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory 22, 73-79. M. Spence (1978), Product Differentiation and Performance in Insurance Markets, Journal of Public Economics 10, 427-447. J. Stiglitz, (1999), Incentives and Institutions in the Provision of Health Care in Developing Countries: towards an Efficient and Equitable Health Care Strategy. Paper presented at the IHEA II Meetings, Rotterdam, June. J. Stiglitz, (1977), Monopoly, Non-linear Pricing and Imperfect Information: The Insurance Market, Review of Economic Studies 44, 407-428. W. Van de Ven and R. Van Vliet (1995), Consumer Information Surplus and Adverse Selection in Competitive Health Insurance Markets: an Empirical Study, Journal of Health Economics 14, 149-169 W. Van de Ven and R. Van Vliet (1992), How can we Prevent Cream Skimming in a Competitive Health Insurance Market? The Great Challenge for the 90's, in P. Zweifel and H. Frech III eds, Health Economics Worldwide, Kluwer Amsterdam, 23-26. W. Van de Ven and R. Ellis, (2000), Risk-adjustment in competitive health plan markets, in Newhouse, J., Culyer, A. (EDS.) Handbook of Health Economics, North Holland, Elsevier, Amsterdam W. Van de Ven et al. (2000), Access to coverage for high-risks in a competitive individual health insurance market: via premium rate restrictions or risk-adjusted subsidies? Journal of Health Economics 19,3: pp.311-339. C. Wilson (1977), A Model of Insurance Market with Incomplete Information, Journal of Economic Theory 16, pp. 167-207. R. Zeckhouser (1970), Medical Insurance: A case Study of the Trade-off Between Risk Spreading and Appropriate Incentives, Journal of Economic Theory. 31 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS2554 Administrative Costs and the Estelle James February 2001 A. Yaptenco Organization of Individual James Smalhout 31823 Retirement Account Systems: Dimitri Vittas A Comparative Perspective WPS2555 Implicit Pension Debt, Transition Yan Wang February 2001 A. Datoloum Cost, Options, and Impact of Dianqing Xu 36334 China's Pension Reform: Zhi Wang A Computable General Equilibrium Fan Zhai Analysis WPS2556 Household Strategies for Coping with Michael M. Lokshin February 2001 P. Sader Poverty and Social Exclusion in Ruslan Yemtsov 33902 Post-Crisis Russia WPS2557 Decentralization and Accountability: Stuti Khemani February 2001 H. Sladovich Are Voters More Vigilant in Local than 37698 in National Elections? WPS2558 Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: Martin Ravallion February 2001 P. Sader Looking beyond Averages 33902 WPS2559 Deposit Insurance as Private Club: Thorsten Beck February 2001 P. Sintim-Aboagye Is Germany a Model? 38526 WPS2560 Catastrophe Risk Management: John D. Pollner February 2001 J. Pollner Using Alternative Risk Financing 30079 and Insurance Pooling Mechanisms WPS2561 Democracy and Income Inequality: Mark Gradstein March 2001 P. Sader An Empirical Analysis Branko Milanovic 33902 Yvonne Ying WPS2562 Decomposing World Income Branko Milanovic March 2001 P. Sader Distribution: Does the World Have a Shlomo Yitzhaki 33902 Middle Class? WPS2563 A Race to the Top? A Case Study of Tsunehiro Otsuki March 2001 L. Tabada Food Safety Standards and African John S. Wilson 36896 Exports Mirvat Sewadeh WPS2564 Economic Analysis of World Bank Ayesha Yaqub Vawda March 2001 E. James Education Projects and Project Peter Moock 31756 Outcomes J. Price Gittinger Harry Anthony Patrinos WPS2565 Does Fiscal Decentralization Improve David A. Robalino March 2001 0. Picazo Health Outcomes? Evidence from a Oscar F. Picazo 87954 Cross-Country Analysis Albertus Voetberg Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS2566 Convexity and Sheepskin Effects Norbert R. Schady March 2001 T. Gomez in the Human Capital Earnings 32127 Function: Recent Evidence for Filipino Men WPS2567 Policy Reform, Economic Growth, Susmita Dasgupta March 2001 Y. d'Souza and the Digital Divide: An Somik Lall 31449 Econometric Analysis David Wheeler WPS2568 Ownership Structure and the Robert Cull March 2001 Z. Kranzer Temptation to Loot: Evidence from Jana Matesova 38526 Privatized Firms in the Czech Mary Shirley Republic WPS2569 From Users to Custodians: Changing Liz Alden Wily March 2001 M. Yue Relations between People and the Peter A. Dewees 34102 State in Forest Management in Tanzania WPS2570 Asymmetries in Union Relative Wage Niels-Hugo Blunch March 2001 M. Clarke Effects in Ghanaian Manufacturing: Dorte Verner 31752 An Analysis Applying Quantile Regressions WPS2571 Stock Market Responses to Bank Daniela Klingebiel March 2001 R. Vo Restructuring Policies during the Randy Kroszner 33722 East Asian Crisis Luc Laeven Pieter van Oijen WPS2572 Nonfarm Income, Inequality, and Richard H. Adams, Jr. March 2001 N. Obias Poverty in Rural Egypt and Jordan 31986 WPS2573 The Gender Implications of Public Martin Rama March 2001 H. Sladovich Sector Downsizing: The Reform 37698 Program of Vietnam