wPs .306 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3 061 Reciprocity in Free Trade Agreements Caroline Freund The World Bank Development Research Group Trade May 2003 I POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 3061 Abstract Freund uses detailed trade, tariff, and income data for agreements because the value of a developing country countries involved in 91 trade agreements negotiated tariff preference in terms of its effect on trade since 1980 to test for reciprocity in free trade preferences from a rich country is quite small. The gains agreements. The results offer strong evidence of from unilateral liberalization are likely to far outweigh reciprocity in North-North and South-South free trade potential gains from using protection as a bargaining agreements, but there is little empirical support for chip in trade negotiations. reciprocity in North-South trade agreements. In The evidence is consistent with a repeated game model particular, after controlling for other determinants of of trade liberalization. The model presented shows that trade preferences, the results suggest that a one percent trade preferences granted are increasing in trade increase in preferences offered leads to about a one-half preferences received. This implies that countries can of a percent increase in preferences received in North- extract greater concessions from trade agreement North and South-South trade agreements. Freund also members if they have higher external trade barriers. finds evidence that large countries extract greater trade However, if a country's trade barriers are very large then concessions from small countries. This leads to a the gains from reneging on the agreement in the short modified form of reciprocity in North-South agreements. run will be high, making the agreement unenforceable A large increase in access to a developing country market despite offering long-term gains. So, there is a leads to only a small increase in access to a rich country reciprocity-credibility tradeoff. High tariffs may allow market. countries to extract more concessions from potential The results imply that there are incentives for trade agreement partners, but they also make the country countries to maintain protection in order to extract more less credible in actually implementing agreed tariff concessions from trade partners. But in general, such concessions. If a country's external tariff is very high perverse incentives should be less of a concern in relative to other countries, then it will not be able to developing countries involved in North-South commit credibly to any free trade agreement. This paper is a product of Trade, Development Research Group. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Paulina Flewitt, room MC3-333, telephone 202-473-2727, fax 202-522-1159, email address pflewitt@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at cfreund@worldbank.org. May 2003. (34 pages) The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Produced by Partnerships, Capacity Building, and Outreach Reciprocity in Free Trade Agreements Caroline Freund* The World Bank * I have benefited from comments by Daniel Lederman, Nuno Limao, Marcelo Olarreaga, John Romalis, Karnal Saggi, Maurice Schiff, Robert Staiger and participants at presentations at the 2003 AEA meetings in Washington, the World Bank, the University of Maryland, and the Regional Integration Network conference in Punta del Este, Uruguay. Correspondence: 1818 H Street, NW, Washington D.C. 20433, e- mail cfreundeaworldbank.org, ph: (202)473-7102, fax: (202)522-1159. Reciprocity in Free Trade Agreements I. Introduction The two pillars of the GATT are nondiscrimination and reciprocity. Article XXIV of the GATT, which allows for the formation of trade blocs, has been derided as antithetical to the GATT because it permits members of a trade bloc to discriminate against nonmembers. What is less clear, however, is whether article XXIV is in sync with the other pillar of GATT--reciprocity. The language on reciprocity in the body of the GATT is clear: governments seek a "balance of concessions" and when presented with the withdrawal of a trade concession, its trade partner is permitted to withdraw a "substantially equivalent concession". Article XXIV also includes language that could be interpreted as pertaining to reciprocity, in that it calls for trade barriers "to be eliminated with respect to substantially all trade between the constituent territories." Thus, by definition, preferential trade agreements involve some degree of reciprocity because both sides are expected to make full trade concessions. But, unlike traditional multilateral negotiations, this does not necessarily yield equivalent concessions since an agreement can involve members of various sizes with vastly different trade barriers, yielding gains in market access that are far from symmetric. In addition, some sensitive sectors are typically excluded, and many other types of trade barriers, such as antidumping claims or technical standards can remain in place, or even increase to offset tariff concessions. The purpose of this paper is to examine theoretically and empirically what role reciprocity has played in regional integration agreements. The application of reciprocity in multilateral tariff negotiations has strong theoretical foundations. In a series a papers, Bagwell and Staiger show that terms-of-trade motives provide countries with incentives 2 to have positive tariffs, creating a prisoner's dilemma, whereby all countries would be better off if they could cooperate and reciprocally lower tariffs.1 They argue that the articles of the GATT offer negotiating rules that help governments undo inefficient trade restrictions generated by the terms-of-trade externality. In other words, reciprocal tariff reduction allows countries to credibly commit to lower tariffs and reach a higher welfare level. Finger, Reincke, and Castro (1999) find some evidence of reciprocity in terms of tariff cuts offered in the Uruguay Round negotiations.2 The value of reciprocity in regional agreements is less clear. Unlike in multilateral negotiations, where reciprocity enhances overall trade liberalization, reciprocity in regional agreements (by definition) furthers discriminatory tariff reduction. Reciprocity may be especially damaging in North-South agreements, where asymmetries in size suggest that low-income countries will have to make relatively larger trade concessions to achieve an agreement with a high-income country. A need for reciprocity also implies that some agreements should be infeasible; for example, a large country would gain too little from a free trade agreement with a very small low-tariff country to make the agreement worthwhile. Finally, reciprocity could provide incentives for low- income countries to maintain higher trade barriers in order to obtain preferences from high-income countries, and as a result generate greater trade diversion. In this paper, we first examine the theoretical foundations for reciprocity in free trade agreements. We follow Bagwell and Staiger and use a repeated game model to analyze the question of what types of regional agreements are sustainable. In order to achieve a trade agreement, countries must have an incentive to sign the agreement and I See Bagwell and Staiger (2000) for a summary of the literature. 2 About 30 percent of concessions given are matched by concessions received. 3 the agreement must be self-enforcing. Using an oligopolistic model of trade, we show that it is easier to form an agreement with a large country, a high-cost country, or with one that has high tariffs. However, we also find that a country's credibility in enforcing the agreement is decreasing in its tariff level. Thus, there is a reciprocity-credibility trade-off; larger tariff reductions at home yield larger trade concessions abroad, but larger tariff cuts are less likely to be self-enforcing. The model also predicts that reciprocity should be more important in agreements between countries with similar cost structures. The intuition is that when costs differ, in addition to enhancing competition, a preferential agreement shifts production to the low-cost country, enhancing overall welfare gains and making the agreement easier to sustain. To examine reciprocity empirically, we use three measures of trade preferences. The first uses detailecl tariff and trade data to calculate the bilateral trade-weighted tariff for each country pair in a trade agreement. The second uses the same data to calculate the tariff revenue that will be lost as a result of a trade agreement; it is effectively a measure of the gain in producer surplus in the exporting country. The third focuses on changes in market access subsequent to the formation of a trade agreement, where market access is measured as changes in trade intensity indices (essentially trade shares adjusted for income growth) following a regional agreement. Using all three measures, we find that the trade preferences granted in a regional agreement are highly correlated across country pairs. Controlling for relative country size and separately also for country fixed effects, we find that preferential access is the single most important variable determining preferences granted. Blecause of issues of simultaneity, we also instrument for preferences with country-fixed effects. The results are robust to this innovation. 4 We also examine whether reciprocity in North-South agreements is different from reciprocity in other agreements. The model implies that countries with similar costs structures are more likely to require reciprocity to be self-enforcing. The variation in costs is likely to be greater when agreements are formed between North and South countries, suggesting that reciprocity would be less important in North-South agreements. In addition, work by John Whalley and various coauthors shows that concessions in North-South trade agreements, such as NAFTA, tend to be in areas other than tariffs.3 In particular, the South gains insurance for its access to the North's market, while the North gains concessions on environment and other non-tariff areas. Similarly, Staiger (1998) notes that GATT language does not require reciprocity by small countries, suggesting that reciprocity in preferential agreements between North and South countries is unlikely to be driven by the same underlying forces as reciprocity in the GATT.4 Our results show little evidence of reciprocity in North-South agreements. In particular, among North-South partners, preferences in one country are not correlated with preferences in the other country. There is, however, a modified form of reciprocity; North countries extract significantly more market access in South countries than South countries extract from the North. Specifically, a ten percent reduction in the developing- country tariff yields only about a 2 percent reduction in the rich-country tariff; in 3 Perroni and Whalley (2000) and Abrego et al. (1997). 4 Staiger's comment was made in reference to a paper by Davis and Kowalczyk (1998). They examine tariff phase-outs in Mexico and United States following NAFTA and look for evidence of reciprocity. Their main finding is that the length of tariff phase-outs by sector in both Mexico and United States is increasing in the U.S. tariff. The paper, however, analyzes a very narrow form of reciprocity because we typically think of reciprocity as being intersectoral. That is, we would expect the main trade concessions that Mexico gives the United States to be in different sectors from the concessions that the United States gives Mexico. 5 contrast, a 10 percent reduction in the large country tariff leads to an 33 percent reduction in the poor country tariff. The paper is organized as follows. The next section provides the theoretical framework. Section 3 examines the empirical importance of reciprocity in trade agreements. Section 4 concludes. II. The Theoretical Framework We use a three-country oligopolistic model of trade to evaluate the importance of reciprocity in free trade agreements. This model is appropriate for analyzing trade bloc questions because optimal tariffs are non-zero and because regional agreements expand the members' share of the world market and hence enhance profits abroad. Gaining preferential market access is an important and often clearly stated purpose of trade agreements.5 The model is meant to be illustrative and highlight the importance of country size, market structure, and reciprocity in achieving a free trade agreement. There is one good, which is produced by a single profit-maximizing firm in each country and segmented markets lead to trade in this good (as in Brander and Krugman (1983)). Since large markets are likely to have more firms, the one-firm assumption would be strong if we did not allow variation in production costs. Lower domestic production costs and more intense domestic competition will both have similar effects on trade. They will reduce the extent to which consumers benefit from international trade and will also depress the profits of foreign firms. 5For example, the U.S. Trade Representative argues that because Canada and Mexico have trade agreements with other countries in the region "U.S. businesses are losing marketshare. U.S. wheat and potato farmers, for example, are now losing markets in Chile to Canadian exports" (Robert Zoellick, May 7, 2001) 6 We assume that the inverse demand function, pi(Q), in each country (X, Y, and Z) is linear. Specifically, Pi (Q') = 1- a'Qt, and Q' = qi + qi + qz, where Q' is the total quantity consumed in country i, q' is the quantity produced by the firm inj for market i, and a' varies with the size of the market, smaller countries have larger a's. Competition is Cournot. Profits to the firm from countryX, in country i, ir, are (1) or' = qP' (Q')-cXxq -t ,tq, where, ci is the constant marginal cost of production in country i, and t' is the tariff that the firm from countryj faces in market i. Solving for the profit maximizing quantity of a firm from country X in market i, we have (2) qi = (1-3(cy +tX)+cy +cz +t +tz) (2) q,, ~~~4a' Equation (2) shows that higher domestic costs reduce quantity, while higher foreign costs increase quantity. A sufficient condition for each firm to sell in each market is that t, < (1- 3cx + c, + c,)/ 3, which we assumes holds. The government's welfare function, W, in country X, is the sum of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and tariff revenue. (3) W = U(Qx) PxQx + E (qIP' -cxq' -t'q')+txq +tq x,y,z If there are no free trade agreements then the government maximizes welfare, equation (3) over t' and tz, taking other countries' tariffs as given. Under MFN, the tariff on Y must be equivalent to the tariff on Z, resulting in an optimal tariff of 3 -cs -cy - cz t = x O . Note that in this model the optimal tariff in one country is not a 10 7 function of the tariffs implemented abroad or of the size of the market (a'). But it is a function of marginal production costs-higher costs are associated with lower tariffs in all countries. Regardless of what policy other countries follow, a single country is always better off with a positive tariff. However, if each country installs its optimal tariff then all countries are worse off than they would be at free trade. Each country is made better off if some reciprocal bilateral or multilateral tariff reduction is achievable. III. A Free Trade Agreement Two conditions must be met in order for countries to participate in a free trade agreement. First, an incentive constraint must be satisfied, the agreement must make countries better off. Second, the agreement must be self-enforcing, long-run gains must make it worthwhile for countries to commit to the agreement, as opposed to maintaining tariffs. Incentive constraint A free trade agreement will only be approved if the welfare of the member countries is improved. That is, it must be the case that welfare after the bilateral tariff reduction exceeds welf are with ex ante tariffs. Using the welfare function above, substituting quantities in from Equation (2) and solving yields the incentive constraint for an agreement between countryXand country Y. Specifically the constraint is: (-6+18cy +2c - 14c2)tx _tx2 6(1-3cx +,cy +c)ty -3ty2 32aX 16ay The first term in equation (4) represents the net domestic loss that results from the decline in a country's own tariff, the increase in consumer surplus and the loss in domestic profits 8 and tariff revenue. The second term is the gain in profits abroad that results from the decline in the foreign tariff. An agreement is more likely to be welfare improving when ax is large and a' is small-i.e. the small country gains more from the agreement. In addition, it is more welfare enhancing when the cost in the other member country, cy, is relatively large-that is, the low-cost country gains more from the agreement. A low domestic tariff, t, and a high partner-country tariff, tP, also increase the value of the agreement. The incentive constraint will always be satisfied for both countries, when countries are similar in size, cost structure, trade policy, and the extent of the tariff reduction-as is more likely to be the case in a North-North or a South-South agreement. Alternatively, the incentive constraint may be satisfied for both parties if the smaller country or the low-cost country offers greater trade concessions. Sustainability We use a repeated game framework to evaluate the extent to which a trade agreement between two countries is self-enforcing.6 In order for a bilateral agreement to be sustainable, the welfare gain from cheating on the agreement and then returning to the MFN tariff equilibrium forever must not exceed the welfare level from committing to the agreement. We consider cheating and punishment to consist of failing to install the preferences (i.e. maintaining status quo tariff) and returning to the ex ante tariff level forever. Alternatively, we could use the Nash tariff level as punishment, which would further the extent to which tariff reduction is achievable since the punishment phase would be more severe. However, since countries are constrained by the WTO, using the more conservative status quo punishment is more realistic. Specifically, 6 See Freund (2000) for more details on the repeated game analysis in this type of model. 9 (4) Wdevite + W * A A A 0 IL 0 10 20 30 tariff in X 28 Table 1: Determinants of Trade Preferences tij tij tij psij psij psij Alij Al\ij Ali _______ (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) () () 9 tji 0.58** 0.63** 0.57** (4.40) (3.47) (6.02) psji 0.51** 0.40** 0.56** (11.68) (3.91) (9.12) AIji .31** 0.31* 0.29** (3.82) (2.33) (2.54) gdpi 0.06 0.06 0.43** 0.38 0.02 0.02 (1.06) (1.06) (2.97) (2.49) (0.80) (0.79) gdpj -0.02 -0.02 0.47** 0.42 -0.02 -0.02 (-0.39) (-0.37) (6.65) (5.45) (0.92) (-0.83) Country No Yes No No Yes No No Yes No fixed effects Method OLS OLS IV OLS OLS IV OLS OLS IV NOB 104 104 104 104 104 104 182 182 182 R- 0.35 0.87 0.35 0.68 0.88 0.68 0.10 .44 0.10 SquareI II Mlij is the percenage change in i's export intensity toj. Errors corrected for heteroskedasticity and pairwise correlation. All regressions include a constant tenn, values for the constant not reported. **Significant at the 1 percent level.*Significant at the 5 percent level. In columns (3) and (4) country fixed effects are used as instruments for Alji. 29 T'able 2: Reciprocity in North-South Agreements tij _ PSi, AI,j North- Other North- Other North- Other North- Other South South South South ( __ _(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) tji -0.05 0.68** (-0.45) (6.53) PSjM -0.12 0.50** (-0.36) (11.98) AIji .39** 0.25* -0.11 0.37** (3.02) (2.55) (-0.54) (3.87) Ln(GDP1) 0.29 0.42 1.66** 0.43* 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.02 (1.42) (0.67) 3.09 (2.04) (0.72) (0.44) (0.63) (0.58) Ln(GDPj) 0.23 -0.00 1.63** 0.55** 0.00 -0.04 0.02 -0.04 (1.69) (-0.03) (3.38) (5.68) (0.11) (-1.59) (0.39) (-1.67) Method OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS IV IV NOB 22 82 22 82 58 124 58 124 R-Square 0.21 0.45 0.88 0.62 0.16 .07 0.00 .06 A constant is included in all regressions, value not reported. Errors corrected for heteroskedasticity and pairwise correlation. *Significant at the 5% level. ** Significant at the 1% level. 30 Table 3: Determinants of Large and Small Country Preferences Total North-South Other Large Small Large Small Large Small Access Access Access Access to Access Access to Small to Large to Small Large to Small to Large (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) tji 1.39** 0.58** 3.31** 0.17** 1.38** 0.63** (9.71) (9.71) (3.12) (3.12) (9.98) (9.98) PSji 2.11** .41** 1.00 0.10 2.25** 0.39** (11.04) (11.04) (1.05) (1.05) (10.05) (10.05) AIj; .64** .52** 1.59** .43** 0.42** 0.56** (6.07) (6.07) (5.89) (5.89) (4.11) (4.11) All regressions run with a constant and gdpi and gdpj using SUR. Only the coefficients on preference variables from each regression are reported. Columns (1), (3), and (5) report the results when the small country's preferences granted is the dependent variable. Columns (2), (4), and (6) report the results when the large countrys' preferences granted is the dependent variable. 31 Appendix Table 1: Regional Integration Agreements Used in Tariff and Agreement Date of entry Type of agreement Producer Surplus into force Measure CER/ Australia-New Zealand 1-Jan-83 Free trade No ______ _____ agreement N United States - Israel 19-Aug-85 Free trade No ______ _____ agreement N EC accession of Portugal and Spain 1-Jan-86 Accession to No customs union N Mercosur/ Argentina Brazil Paraguay 29-Nov-91 Customs union Yes Uruguay 29-Nov-91 Customs_union_Ye EC - Czech Republic 1-Mar-92 Free trade Yes _____________________ ~agreem ent EC - Slovak Republic 1-Mar-92 Free trade Yes _________ _________ _________agreem entYe EC - Hungary 1-Mar-92 Free trade Yes agreementYe EC - Poland 1-Mar-92 Free trade Yes ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ ag reem ent _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ EFTA - Turkey 1-Apr-92 Free trade No ______ ______ ______ ______ . ___agreem ent EFTA - Czech Republic 1-Jul-92 Free trade No ______________ ______________agreem ent N EFTA - Slovak Republic 1-Jul-92 Free trade No _______ _______ _______ _______agreem ent_ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Czech Republic - Slovak Republic 1-Jan-93 Customs union No EFTA - Israel 1-Jan-93 Free trade No ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem ent N CEFTA1 Bulgaria Czech Republic Hungary Poland Romania Slovak 1-Mar-93 FreeYes/ except Bulgaria Republic Slovenia agreement Yes EC - Romania 1-May-93 Free trade No ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entY e EFTA - Romania 1-May-93 Free trade N _____ ____ ____ ____ _____ _ __ ____ ____ agreem ent N Chile - Venezuela 1-July-93 Free trade Ye ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entY e EFTA - Bulgaria 1-Jul-93 Free trade No ________ _______ ___ ____ _______ agreem ent N EFTA - Hungary 1-Oct-93 Free trade No ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem ent N EFTA - Poland 15-Nov-93 Free trade No 32__ _ _ _ _ _ _agreement 32 EC - Bulgaria 31-Dec-93 Free trade No _________ _________ _________agreem ent N Chile -Colombia 1-Jan-94 Free Trade Yes ____ ____ ____ ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ A greem ent NAFTA 1-Jan-94 Free trade Yes .__ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _agreem ent BAFTAI Estonia Latvia Lithuania 1-Apr-94 Free trade No ______ _____ agreem ent _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Bolivia- Mexico 1-Jan-95 agreement Yes Colombia-Mexico-Venezuela 1 -Jan-95 Free trade Yes .____ ____ ____ ____ ____ ____agreem ent Costa Rica -Mexico 1-Jan-95 Free trade Yes EC - Lithuania 1-Jan-95 Free trade Yes agreementYe EC - Estonia 1-Jan-95 Free trade Yes agreement EC - Latvia 1-Jan-95 Free trade Yes agreementYe EC accession of Austria, Finland and 1-Jan-95 Accession to Yes Sweden customs union EFTA - Slovenia 1-Jul-95 Free trade No agreement CEFTA accession of Slovenia 1-Jan-96 Accession to free No trade agreement EC - Turkey 1-Jan-96 Customs union Yes EFTA - Estonia 1-Jun-96 Free trade No ______________ _____________agreem ent N EFTA - Latvia 1-Jun-96 Free trade No ______________ _____________agreem ent N Slovenia - Latvia 1-Aug-96 Free trade No EFTA - Lithuania 1-Aug-96 Free trade No ______________ _____________agreem ent N Chile - Mercosur 1-Oct-96 Free trade Yes ______________ _____________agreem entYe Slovak Republic - Israel 1-Jan-97 Free trade Yes __________ _________ _________agreem ent Poland - Lithuania 1-Jan-97 Free trade Yes agreementYe Slovenia - Estonia 1-Jan-97 Free trade No ____ ____ ___ ____ ____ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem ent N Canada - Israel 1-Jan-97 Free trade Yes ____ ____ ___ ____ ____ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entYe EC - Slovenia 1-Jan-97 Free trade No agreement 33 Slovenia - Lithuania 1-Mar-97 Free trade No ______ _____ agreement N Bolivia - Mercosur 2-Mar-97 Free trade Yes agreement _________ Israel - Turkey 1-May-97 Free trade Yes ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entY e CEFTA accession of Rornania 1-Jul-97 Accession to free Yes trade agreement 1-Ju-97agremet_N Slovak Republic - Latvia 1-Jul-97 Free trade No agreement Slovak Republic - Lithuania 1-Jul-97 Free trade No agreement No Czech Republic - Latvia 1-Jul-97 Free trade Yes agreement Yes Canada - Chile 5-Jul-97 Free trade Yes agreement Czech Republic - Lithuania 1-Sep-97 Free trade No ______ ______ agreementYe Czech Republic - Israel 1-Dec-97 Free trade Yes Hungar-Turke 1-Apragreement Yes Romania - Turkey 1-Feb-98 Free trade Yes Chile-Peru___ 1 -9agreement Yes Hungary - Israel 1-Feb-98 Free trade Yes ______ ______ agreementYe Czech Republic - Estonia 12-Feb-98 Free trade Yes ______ ______ agreementYe Slovak Republic - Estonie 12-Feb-98 Free trade No ______ ______ agreement Poland - Israel 1-Mar-98 Free trade agreement Lithuania - Turkey 1-Mar-98 Free tradeYe ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entYe Hungary -Turkey 1 -Apr-98 Free tradeYe agreementYe Estonia - Turkey 1-Jun-98 Free tradeYe agreementYe Chile - Pewu 1-Jul-98 Free Trade Yes __________ __________ _________agreem ent Mexico - Nicaragua 1-Jul-98 Free Trade Yes Agreement ________ Czech Republic - Turkey 1-Sep-98 Free tradeYe ______ ______ agreementYe Slovak Republic - Turkey 1-Sep-98 Free trade N ____ ____ ____ ____ ___ ____ ____ ____ ___ agreem ent N Slovenia - Israel 1-Sep-98 Free trade N ________ _______ ________ __ ____ _______ agreem ent No 34 Bulgaria - Turkey I-Jan-99 Free trade No agreement CEFTA accession of Bulgaria 1-Jan-99 Accession to free No trade agreement- Poland - Latvia 1-Jun-99 Free trade Yes agreementYe Chile - Mexico 1-Aug-99 Free trade Yes ____ ___ ____ ___ ____ ___ ___ ___ ____ ___ agreem entY e EFTA - Moroco 1-Dec-99 Free trade No 35__ _ _ _ _ _ _agreement 35 Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS3043 The Incentive-Compatible Design Thorsten Beck May 2003 K. Labrie of Deposit Insurance and Bank 31001 Failure Resolution: Concepts and Country Studies WPS3044 Impregnated Nets Cannot Fully Mead over May 2003 H. Sladovich Substitute for DDT: Field Bernard Bakote'e 37698 Effectiveness of Malaria Prevention Raman Velayudhan in Solomon Islands Peter Wilikai Patricia M. Graves WPS3045 Causes and Consequences of Civil Klaus Deininger May 2003 M. Fernandez Strife: Micro-Level Evidence from 33766 Uganda WPS3046 Migration, Spillovers, and Trade Ross Levine May 2003 E. Khine Diversion: The Impact of Sergio L. Schmukler 37471 Internationalization on Stock Market Liquidity WPS3047 Comparing Mortgage Credit Risk Robert Buckley May 2003 0. Himid Policies: An Options-Based Approach Gulmira Karaguishiyeva 80225 Robert Van Order Laura Vecvagare WPS3048 Targeted Transfers in Poor Countries: Martin Ravallion May 2003 P. Sader Revisiting the Tradeoffs and Policy 33902 Options WPS3049 Hidden Impact? Ex-Post Evaluation Shaohua Chen May 2003 P. Sader of an Anti-Poverty Program Martin Ravallion 33902 WPS3050 The Changing Financial Landscape: Wafik Grais May 2003 R. Vo Opportunities and Challenges for Zeynep Kantur 33722 the Middle East ancl North Africa WPS3051 Regional, Multilateral, and Unilateral Glenn W. Harrison May 2003 P. Flewitt Trade Policies of MERCOSUR for Thomas F. Rutherford 32724 Growth and Poverty Reduction in David G. Tarr Brazil Angelo Gurgel WPS3052 Long-Run Impacts of China's WTO Kym Anderson May 2003 S. Lipscomb Accession on Farm--Nonfarm Income Jikun Huang 87266 Inequality and Rural Poverty Elena lanchovichina WPS3053 Economic Impacts of China's Elena lanchovichina May 2003 S. Lipscomb Accession to the World Trade William Martin 87266 Organization WPS3054 The New Comparative Economics Simeon Djankov May 2003 G. Sorensen Edward Glaeser 37088 Rafael La Porta Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes Andrei Shleifer WPS3055 The Global Growth of Mutual Funds Deepthi Fernando May 2003 A. Yaptenco Leora Klapper 31823 Viktor Sulla Dimitri Vittas Policy Research Working Paper Series Contact Title Author Date for paper WPS3056 Avoiding the Pitfalls in Taxing Patrick Honohan May 2003 A. Yaptenco Financial Intermediation 31823 WPS3057 Teaching Adults to Read Better and Helen Abadzi May 2003 H. Abadzi Faster: Results from an Experiment 80375 in Burkina Faso WPS3058 Working for God? Evaluating Service Ritva Reinikka May 2003 H. Sladovich Delivery of Religious Not-for-Profit Jakob Svensson 37698 Health Care Providers in Uganda WPS3059 Do Capital Flows Respond to Risk Cesar Calder6n May 2003 T. Tourougui and Return? Norman Loayza 87431 Luis Serven WPS3060 World Market Integration through the Rui Albuquerque May 2003 T. Tourougui Lens of Foreign Direct Investors Norman Loayza 87431 Luis Serven