Publication: Development Financing during a Crisis : Securitization of Future Receivables
Date
2001-04
ISSN
Published
2001-04
Author(s)
Abstract
Mexico's Telmex undertook the first
future-flow securitization transaction in 1987. From then
through 1999, the principal credit rating agencies rated
more than 200 transactions totaling $47.3 billion. Studying
several sources, the authors draw conclusions about the
rationale for using this asset class, the size of its
unrealized potential, and the main constraints on its
growth. Typically the borrowing entity (the originator)
sells its future product (receivable) directly or indirectly
to an offshore special purpose vehicle (SPV), which issues
the debt instrument. Designated international customers make
their payments for the exports directly to an offshore
collection account managed by a trustee. The collection
agent makes principal and interest payments to investors and
pays the rest to the originator. This transaction structure
allows many investment-grade borrowers in developing
countries to pierce the sovereign credit ceiling and get
longer-term financing at significantly lower interest costs.
The investment-grade rating attracts a wider group of
investors. And establishing a credit history for the
borrower makes it easier for it to access capital markets
later, at lower costs. This asset class is attractive for
investors-especially buy-and-hold investors, such as
insurance companies-because of its good credit rating and
stellar performance in good and bad times. Defaults in this
asset class are rare, despite frequent liquidity crises in
developing countries. Latin American issuers (Argentina,
Brazil, Mexico, and Venezuela) dominate this market. Nearly
half the dollar amounts raised are backed by receivables on
oil and gas. Recent transactions have involved receivables
on credit cards, telephones, workers' remittances,
taxes, and exports. The potential for securing future
receivables is several times the current level ($10 billion
annually). The greatest potential lies outside Latin
America, in Eastern Europe and Central Asia (fuel and
mineral exports), the Middle East (oil), and South Asia
(remittances, credit card vouchers, and telephone
receivables). One constraint on growth is the paucity of
good collateral in developing countries. Crude oil may be
better collateral than refined petroleum. Agricultural
commodities are harder to securitize. Another constraint:
the dearth of high-quality issuers in developing countries.
Securitization deals are complex, with high preparation
costs and long lead times. The ideal candidates are
investment-grade entities (in terms of local currency) in
sub-investment-grade countries (in terms of foreign
currency). Establishing indigenous rating agencies can
slash out-of-pocket costs. Developing standardized templates
for certain types of securitizations might help. A master
trust arrangement can reduce constraints on size.
Multilateral institutions might consider providing seed
money and technical assistance for contingent private credit facilities.
Citation
“Ketkar, Suhas; Ratha, Dilip. 2001. Development Financing during a Crisis : Securitization of Future Receivables. Policy Research Working Paper;No. 2582. © World Bank, Washington, DC. http://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/19672 License: CC BY 3.0 IGO.”
Report Series
Report Series
Other publications in this report series
-
PublicationTaxation and Capital Structure : Evidence from a Transition Economy(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)The authors examine the effects of taxation on financing policy using the corporate tax reform in 2001 in Croatia as a natural experiment. Since the extant literature on tax effects on capital structure studies listed firms in developed countries, it is worth investigating whether the same results apply to privately-held, small and medium size firms in transition economies. The findings provide significant evidence that lower taxes have affected the capital structure of Croatian firms, resulting in increased equity levels and decreased long-term debt levels. The authors also find that smaller and more profitable firms were more likely to reduce their debt levels. These findings are consistent with the trade-off theory of capital structure, which suggests that lower taxes decrease the incentive to hold debt due to decreasing interest tax deductibility.
-
PublicationThe Market for Retirement Products in Australia(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)Australia introduced a mandatory retirement savings scheme in 1992. This built on pre-existing voluntary occupational plans. The new scheme has been very successful in expanding coverage and mobilizing large financial savings that are equal to close to 100 percent of GDP. However, Australia does not impose restrictions on payout options. The payout phase used to be dominated by lump sum withdrawals, which accounted for 80 percent of benefit payments as recently as 2002. But pension payments increased in recent years and now represent 45 percent of total payments. The vast majority of these pension payments take the form of term annuities and allocated annuities. The latter are similar to phased withdrawals in Chile but run for fixed terms of up to 25 years rather than for lifetime terms. The demand for life annuities and lifetime phased withdrawals is very limited. The paper discusses the factors that have shaped the pattern of demand for retirement products, including the availability of the universal age pension and the effect of clawback provisions, the impact of the high level of home ownership, and the widespread preference of retiring workers for reliance on self-annuitization. The paper also reviews the prudential regulation of superannuation funds and life insurance companies.
-
PublicationThe Market for Retirement Products in Sweden(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)Far-reaching changes in the regulation of financial markets and the organization of public pensions in the 1980s and 1990s transformed the landscape for retirement products in Sweden. First, banking and insurance were extensively deregulated in the 1980s, while the securities markets experienced major expansion. Insurance received a large boost from the authorization of unit-linked products in the early 1990s. Second, the public pension system was reformed. Survivor benefits for widows were eliminated from the public pillar in the late 1980s, leading to a large increase in demand for term life insurance. The old defined benefit public pension system was replaced by a notional or nonfinancial defined contribution (NDC) scheme, while a funded defined contribution (FDC) component was also created in the public pillar. The four occupational pension funds that cover the majority of Swedish workers were also converted into FDC schemes. This paper reviews the implications of these changes for the Swedish annuity market. It discusses the regulation of payout options in Sweden, highlighting the compulsory use of life annuities in the public pillar and the preference for term annuities in the occupational funds. It examines the performance of providers of retirement products, including the PPM, and reviews the increasing focus on risk-based regulation and supervision. The paper also emphasizes Sweden's success in moving in the direction of increased funding and privatization of old age insurance, while maintaining its basic character as a highly developed welfare state.
-
PublicationExport Surges : The Power of a Competitive Currency(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)How can countries stimulate and sustain strong export growth? To answer this question, the authors examine 92 episodes of export surges, defined as significant increases in manufacturing export growth that are sustained for at least seven years. They find that export surges in developing countries tend to be preceded by a large real depreciation-which leaves the exchange rate significantly undervalued-and a reduction in exchange rate volatility. In contrast, in developed countries, the role of the exchange rate is less pronounced. The authors examine why the exchange rate is so important in developing countries and find that the depreciation leads to a significant reallocation of resources in the export sector. In particular, depreciation generates more entries into new export products and new markets, and the percentage of new entries that fail after one year declines. These new products and new markets are important, accounting for 25 percent of export growth during the surge in developing countries. The authors argue that maintaining a competitive currency leads firms to expand the product and market space for exports, inducing a large reorientation of the tradable sector.
-
PublicationPolitical Alternation as a Restraint on Investing in Influence : Evidence from the Post-Communist Transition(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)The authors develop and implement a method for measuring the frequency of changes in power among distinct leaders and ideologically distinct parties that is comparable across political systems. The authors find that more frequent alternation in power is associated with the emergence of better governance in post communist countries. The results are consistent with the hypothesis that firms seek durable protection from the state, which implies that expected political alternation is relevant to the decision whether to invest in influence with the governing party or, alternatively, to demand institutions that apply predictable rules, with equality of treatment, regardless of the party in power.