Publication: Shaping Future GATS Rules for Trade in Services
Date
2001-04
ISSN
Published
2001-04
Author(s)
Mattoo, Aaditya
Abstract
The new round of negotiations has begun
with a mechanical sense of "since we said we would,
therefore we must," says the author. To make the
General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) more effective
ay liberalization, the author suggests improving the
agreement's rules, countries' specific
commitments, and the negotiating methodology: 1) Wasteful
regulations, and entry restrictions pervade trade in
services. Unlike the GATT, the GATS has created no hierarchy
of instruments of protection. It may be possible to create a
legal presumption in favor of instruments (such as fiscal
measures) that provide protection more efficiently. 2) Many
countries have taken advantage of the GATS to create a more
secure trading environment, by making legally binding
commitments to market access. The credibility of reform
would increase with wider commitments to maintain current
levels of openness, or to increase access in the future. 3)
Multilateral rules on domestic regulations can help promote,
and consolidate domestic regulatory reform, even when the
rules are designed primarily to prevent the erosion of
market access for foreign providers. The pro-competitive
principles developed for basic communications, could be
extended to other network-based services sectors, such as
transport (terminals and infrastructure), and energy
services (distribution networks). The "necessity
test" instituted for accounting services, could be
applied to instruments in other sectors (so that doctors
judged competent in one jurisdiction, wouldn't have to
be retrained for another, for example). 4) Anticompetitive
practices that fall outside the jurisdiction of national
competition law, may be important in such sectors as
maritime, air transport, and communications services.
Strengthened multilateral rules are needed to reassure small
countries with weak enforcement capacity, that the gains
from liberalization will not be appropriated by
international cartels. 5) Explicit departures from the
most-favored-nation rule matter most in such sectors as
maritime transport, audiovisual services, and air transport
services - which have been excluded from key GATS
disciplines. Implicit discrimination can be prevented by
developing rules to ensure the non-discriminatory allocation
of quotas, and maintaining the desirable openness of the
GATS provision on mutual recognition agreements. 6)
Reciprocity must play a greater role in negotiations, if the
GATS is to advance liberalization beyond measures taken independently.
Citation
“Mattoo, Aaditya. 2001. Shaping Future GATS Rules for Trade in Services. Policy Research Working Paper;No. 2596. © World Bank, Washington, DC. http://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/19667 License: CC BY 3.0 IGO.”
Report Series
Report Series
Other publications in this report series
-
PublicationTaxation and Capital Structure : Evidence from a Transition Economy(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)The authors examine the effects of taxation on financing policy using the corporate tax reform in 2001 in Croatia as a natural experiment. Since the extant literature on tax effects on capital structure studies listed firms in developed countries, it is worth investigating whether the same results apply to privately-held, small and medium size firms in transition economies. The findings provide significant evidence that lower taxes have affected the capital structure of Croatian firms, resulting in increased equity levels and decreased long-term debt levels. The authors also find that smaller and more profitable firms were more likely to reduce their debt levels. These findings are consistent with the trade-off theory of capital structure, which suggests that lower taxes decrease the incentive to hold debt due to decreasing interest tax deductibility.
-
PublicationThe Market for Retirement Products in Australia(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)Australia introduced a mandatory retirement savings scheme in 1992. This built on pre-existing voluntary occupational plans. The new scheme has been very successful in expanding coverage and mobilizing large financial savings that are equal to close to 100 percent of GDP. However, Australia does not impose restrictions on payout options. The payout phase used to be dominated by lump sum withdrawals, which accounted for 80 percent of benefit payments as recently as 2002. But pension payments increased in recent years and now represent 45 percent of total payments. The vast majority of these pension payments take the form of term annuities and allocated annuities. The latter are similar to phased withdrawals in Chile but run for fixed terms of up to 25 years rather than for lifetime terms. The demand for life annuities and lifetime phased withdrawals is very limited. The paper discusses the factors that have shaped the pattern of demand for retirement products, including the availability of the universal age pension and the effect of clawback provisions, the impact of the high level of home ownership, and the widespread preference of retiring workers for reliance on self-annuitization. The paper also reviews the prudential regulation of superannuation funds and life insurance companies.
-
PublicationThe Market for Retirement Products in Sweden(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)Far-reaching changes in the regulation of financial markets and the organization of public pensions in the 1980s and 1990s transformed the landscape for retirement products in Sweden. First, banking and insurance were extensively deregulated in the 1980s, while the securities markets experienced major expansion. Insurance received a large boost from the authorization of unit-linked products in the early 1990s. Second, the public pension system was reformed. Survivor benefits for widows were eliminated from the public pillar in the late 1980s, leading to a large increase in demand for term life insurance. The old defined benefit public pension system was replaced by a notional or nonfinancial defined contribution (NDC) scheme, while a funded defined contribution (FDC) component was also created in the public pillar. The four occupational pension funds that cover the majority of Swedish workers were also converted into FDC schemes. This paper reviews the implications of these changes for the Swedish annuity market. It discusses the regulation of payout options in Sweden, highlighting the compulsory use of life annuities in the public pillar and the preference for term annuities in the occupational funds. It examines the performance of providers of retirement products, including the PPM, and reviews the increasing focus on risk-based regulation and supervision. The paper also emphasizes Sweden's success in moving in the direction of increased funding and privatization of old age insurance, while maintaining its basic character as a highly developed welfare state.
-
PublicationExport Surges : The Power of a Competitive Currency(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)How can countries stimulate and sustain strong export growth? To answer this question, the authors examine 92 episodes of export surges, defined as significant increases in manufacturing export growth that are sustained for at least seven years. They find that export surges in developing countries tend to be preceded by a large real depreciation-which leaves the exchange rate significantly undervalued-and a reduction in exchange rate volatility. In contrast, in developed countries, the role of the exchange rate is less pronounced. The authors examine why the exchange rate is so important in developing countries and find that the depreciation leads to a significant reallocation of resources in the export sector. In particular, depreciation generates more entries into new export products and new markets, and the percentage of new entries that fail after one year declines. These new products and new markets are important, accounting for 25 percent of export growth during the surge in developing countries. The authors argue that maintaining a competitive currency leads firms to expand the product and market space for exports, inducing a large reorientation of the tradable sector.
-
PublicationPolitical Alternation as a Restraint on Investing in Influence : Evidence from the Post-Communist Transition(World Bank, Washington, DC, 2008-10)The authors develop and implement a method for measuring the frequency of changes in power among distinct leaders and ideologically distinct parties that is comparable across political systems. The authors find that more frequent alternation in power is associated with the emergence of better governance in post communist countries. The results are consistent with the hypothesis that firms seek durable protection from the state, which implies that expected political alternation is relevant to the decision whether to invest in influence with the governing party or, alternatively, to demand institutions that apply predictable rules, with equality of treatment, regardless of the party in power.