WPS5875 Policy Research Working Paper 5875 Should Cash Transfers Be Confined to the Poor? Implications for Poverty and Inequality in Latin America Pablo Acosta Phillipe Leite Jamele Rigolini The World Bank Latin America and Caribbean Region Office of the Chief Economist November 2011 Policy Research Working Paper 5875 Abstract This paper compares for 13 Latin American countries choosing carefully categories of beneficiaries is almost the poverty and inequality impacts of cash transfer as important as targeting the poor for achieving a high programs that are given to all children and the elderly poverty and inequality impact. Overall, the findings (that is, “categorical� transfers), to programs of equal suggest that although in the Latin American context budget that are confined to the poor within each poverty targeting tends to deliver higher poverty impacts, population group (that is, “poverty targeted� transfers). there are circumstances under which categorical targeting The analysis finds that both the incidence of poverty confined to geographical regions (sometimes called and the depth of the poverty gap are important factors “geographic targeting�) may be a valid option to consider. affecting the relative effectiveness of categorical versus This is particularly the case in low-income countries with poverty targeted transfers. The comparison of transfers widespread pockets of poverty. to children and the elderly also supports the view that This paper is a product of the Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and Caribbean Region. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at jrigolini@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Policy Research Working Paper 5875 Should Cash Transfers Be Confined to the Poor? Implications for Poverty and Inequality in Latin America Pablo Acosta Phillipe Leite Jamele Rigolini The World Bank Latin America and Caribbean Region Office of the Chief Economist November 2011 Policy Research Working Paper 5875 Abstract This paper compares for 13 Latin American countries choosing carefully categories of beneficiaries is almost the poverty and inequality impacts of cash transfer as important as targeting the poor for achieving a high programs that are given to all children and the elderly poverty and inequality impact. Overall, the findings (that is, “categorical� transfers), to programs of equal suggest that although in the Latin American context budget that are confined to the poor within each poverty targeting tends to deliver higher poverty impacts, population group (that is, “poverty targeted� transfers). there are circumstances under which categorical targeting The analysis finds that both the incidence of poverty confined to geographical regions (sometimes called and the depth of the poverty gap are important factors “geographic targeting�) may be a valid option to consider. affecting the relative effectiveness of categorical versus This is particularly the case in low-income countries with poverty targeted transfers. The comparison of transfers widespread pockets of poverty. to children and the elderly also supports the view that This paper is a product of the Office of the Chief Economist, Latin America and Caribbean Region. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at jrigolini@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team SHOULD CASH TRANSFERS BE CONFINED TO THE POOR? IMPLICATIONS FOR POVERTY AND INEQUALITY IN LATIN AMERICA1 Pablo Acosta Phillipe Leite Jamele Rigolini The World Bank 1 We would like to dedicate this paper to Gozalo Llorente, who unexpectedly left us during its writing. We would like to thank Gonzalo and Alinne Veiga for excellent research assistance. We also thank helpful comments from Margaret Grosh, Ruslan Yemtsov, and Javier Baez. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. 1. Introduction Cash transfer programs have become the centerpiece of many Latin American countries’ social protection agenda. They have become popular not only as short term instruments to help the poor cope with economic shocks, but also as longer-term poverty alleviation programs supporting minimum consumption levels and promoting the accumulation of human capital. Yet, while several evaluations have demonstrated the impact of cash transfers on poverty reduction and human development outcomes, they do absorb an important share of governments’ budgets (Grosh et al., 2008; Fiszbein and Schady, 2010; World Bank-IEG, 2011). Most countries in the Latin America and Caribbean (LAC) region count with conditional cash transfer programs (CCTs) targeted to poor households with children that account for budgets up to 0.6 percent of GDP (see Table 1). Some countries in the region (fewer than those with CCTs) also provide cash transfers to the elderly, many of them on a universal (i.e. categorical) basis, that require an even more sizeable share of public budget – up to 1.3 percent of GDP (see Table 2). These programs can account, in a country like Brazil, for up to 1.7 percent of GDP, and for the average in the region, between 1 and 2 percent of GDP (Grosh et al., 2008). Resource constraints and ethical considerations have led to a heated debate on the scope and coverage of cash transfers. Few doubt about providing benefits to people falling within demonstrable categories of vulnerable groups, such as the children, the elderly or the disabled, though there is still an open debate on how children and the elderly compete as the primary group to focus social assistance.2 But there is less consensus on whether transfers should be given to all people within these categories (i.e. be “categorical�), or if they should be restricted to poor people within categories of beneficiaries (i.e. be “poverty targeted�). While poverty targeted transfers are more cost effective because limited resources are distributed among fewer beneficiaries, they remain more complex and costly to administer. And even the most sophisticated targeting systems miss some of the poor, 2 Some argue that political lobbying tends to favor the elderly (“the elderly can vote, the children cannot:� Preston, 1984). Even in countries with well-developed social assistance schemes with a family accompaniment approach like Brazil and Chile, public spending per older is significantly higher than public spending per child (Turra et al., 2011). 2 and may have difficulties to adapt to entry and exit to and from poverty because registers of beneficiaries cannot be updated frequently. Table 1: Conditional Cash Transfers in Latin America and the Caribbean Amount Number of Beneficiaries Cost Country Program Target Population (monthly US$) (latest available) (% of GDP) Household Heads, Pregant Argentina Programa Familias 40-80 per child 500,000 households Females, Children <19 Public school children up to Bolivia Juancito Pinto 2 per child 500,000 households grade 6 Poor and extreme poor 30 per household + Brazil Bolsa Familia 11,100,000 households 0.36 households 7 per child Extreme poor households Chile Chile Solidario 14 per child 256,000 households 0.08 (means-tested) Extreme poor households Education: 8-33 per Colombia Familias en Accion 1,700,000 households 0.20 with children <7 (health), and child; Health: 28 per Dominican with children <17 (education) Poor and extreme poor household Solidaridad 29 per household 461,000 households Republic households with children <17 Bono de Desarrollo Households in first 2 income Ecuador 15 per household 1,060,000 households 0.60 Humano quintiles with children <17 Comunidades Extreme poor households Education: 15 per El Salvador 100,000 households Solidarias Rurales with children <16 in 100 rural household; Health: municipalities households Extreme poor 15 per household Education: 20 per Guatemala Mi Familia Progresa 250,000 households 0.20 with children <16 in 130 household; Health: Programa de municipalities with Poor households 20 per household Education: 5 per Honduras 240,000 households Asignacion Familiar children 6-12 years old up tp household; Health: Program of Poor 4 gradehouseholds (means- 4 per household Jamaica 100 per child 100,000 households Advancement through tested) until they graduate Health and Education from secondary school Extreme poor households Education: 12-23 Mexico Oportunidades 5,000,000 households 0.40 (means-tested) per household; Red de Extreme poor households Health: 17 per Panama 50 per household 70,000 households Oportunidades (means-tested) Extreme poor households Paraguay PROPAIS II 120 per household 5,800 households 0.08 with children <15 in rural areashouseholds with Poor Peru Juntos 33 per household 454.000 households 0.11 children <15 Source: Based on Fiszbein and Schady (2010). It is not therefore always obvious that poverty-targeted social assistance programs are the best approach to alleviate poverty. At the heart, the optimal design relates to societal preferences for redistribution and taxation (Mkandawire, 2005), as well as tolerance to exclusion errors or deviating from a “rights� approach. But the choice of design can also be informed by technical considerations, such as looking at the accuracy and cost effectiveness of different targeting mechanisms, which is the focus of this paper. 3 Table 2: Non-Contributory Social Pensions in Latin America and the Caribbean Transfer Number of Beneficiaries Cost Country Program Target Population (monthly US$) (latest available) (% of GDP) Argentina Pensiones No 65+ without contributory 151.5 65,900 Contributivas pension and in poverty Bolivia Asistenciales por Renta Dignidad 60+, universal 22-29 782,660 1.30 (former Bonosol) Brazil Rural Pension 65+ in rural areas 342 800,000 Chile Pension Basica 65+, in 3 lowest quintiles of 150 407,000 0.50 Solidaria income distribution Costa Rica Regimen No 65+ in poverty 135 53,492 0.24 Contributivo Ecuador Pension Asistencial 65+ without contributory 35 502,828 pension El Salvador Pension Basica 70+ in severe extreme poor 50 19,534 Universal municipalities Mexico 70 y mas 70+ in selected municipalities, 28.5 2,000,000 universal Oportunidades Adulto 70+ in households receiving 22.7 80,000 Mayor CCTs (Oportunidades) Pension Alimentaria 70+ in Mexico DF, universal 63.2 470,000 Peru Gratitud 75+ without contributory 36 0.03 pension and in poverty Trinidad and Senior Citizen Pension 65+, income means-tested 189-472 73,110 1.30 Tobago Uruguay Beneficio No 70+, Income means-tested 240 31,577 Contributivo Source: Murrugarra (2011). This paper simulates impacts of categorical and poverty targeted cash transfers on poverty and inequality in 13 Latin American countries: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guatemala, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, and Peru. The simulations focus on two programs that tend to be the most widespread in the region: transfers to children up to five years of age, and to elderly people that are older than 65. While, by their nature, poverty targeted transfers always deliver a higher poverty impact, both the incidence of poverty and the depth of the poverty gap appear to be important factors affecting the relative effectiveness of categorical vs. poverty targeted transfers. The comparison of transfers to children and the elderly also supports the view that choosing carefully categories of beneficiaries is almost as important as targeting the poor for achieving a high poverty impact. Overall, the findings suggest that in the Latin 4 American context targeting assistance to the poor tends to deliver higher poverty impacts. There are nonetheless circumstances under which categorical targeting confined to geographical regions may be a valid option to consider. This is particularly the case in low income countries with widespread pockets of poverty. The paper proceeds as follows. The next section summarizes trends in social assistance and the ongoing debate on categorical vs. targeted social transfers. Section 3 discusses the methodology used in the simulations. Section 4 presents the simulation results for the 13 Latin American countries. Section 5 concludes. 2. The cash and targeting revolutions All over the developing world, and particularly in Latin America, social protection programs are moving from universal in-kind benefits and subsidies, to targeted cash transfers. The rationale behind the silent revolutions towards cash lies in higher welfare impacts (cash can support households’ needs beyond food), economic efficiency (e.g., avoidance of dead- weight losses and distortions from subsidies), transparency and accountability, and simplification of the administrative procedures in service delivery (Grosh et al., 2008). While cash transfers are far from being a panacea and should be designed in the context of a broader social assistance strategy that takes into account the local context and political economy, they undoubtedly improved in many countries both beneficiaries’ welfare and the cost effectiveness of social assistance programs. With the expansion of cash transfers, a debate has however arisen on the extent to which assistance should be provided to all people falling within demonstrable vulnerable categories (such as the children, the elderly or the disabled), or only to the poor within these categories. Is it optimal, and, equally important, is it ethically correct to handpick beneficiaries within categories? From an ethical perspective, many advocate that social assistance programs should favor horizontal equity and that any person falling into a category that tends to be vulnerable should have the right to receive assistance (ILO-UN Social Protection Floor initiative, 2010). This universal view of social assistance is strengthened by three potential 5 drawbacks of confining assistance only to poor beneficiaries within each category. First, poverty targeting may generate behavioral distortions and induce informality. For instance, poverty targeted pensions and health insurance programs financed out of general taxation that coexist with contributory ones may generate incentives to remain in the informal labor market and thus avoid contributing to the system (Levy, 2008). Poverty targeted cash transfers may also discourage labor force participation. Second, there is no targeting system that can perfectly identify vulnerable individuals within a given category. Even the most sophisticated targeting mechanisms miss some of the poor (exclusion error), and include some wealthier individuals (inclusion error). The question there is up to which point a society is ready to exclude some of the poor from assistance because of efficiency considerations. Finally, potential stigmas related to poverty targeting may also affect participation of the most vulnerable (Grosh et al., 2008). Leite (2011) finds, for instance, that in Tanzania some of the elderly from rural poor villages did declare having 3 meals a day to avoid the stigma of being perceived as poor. The extent to which these drawbacks represent a strong argument against targeting still remains an open discussion. When the benefits of social assistance programs do not become disproportionate, existing studies find that labor market distortions from poverty targeting remain moderate (Parker and Skoufias, 2000; Skoufias and Di Maro, 2011; Fiszbein and Schady, 2010; World Bank-IEG, 2011). And while exclusion error may still be considerable, many categorical programs also miss some of the poor – though in lower proportions – because of information failures and high participation costs in remote areas (Barrientos, 2008; Sluchynsky, 2008). The categorical approach is also challenged by the reality of hard budget constraints and political economy considerations. Countries have limited resources to fight poverty and promote equity. Broad social assistance policies in developing countries cost already on average 2 percent of GDP (Weigand and Grosh, 2008; Grosh et al., 2008), though wide disparities subsist across countries.3 And even if some countries may have the fiscal space to expand further coverage, this can be politically costly. In general, policy discussions tend to center on how to improve the programs’ impact within the existing resources. 3 Programs focused on the elderly poor range for instance from 0.1 percent of GDP in the Seychelles to 10.6 percent of GDP in Ethiopia. See Schwarz (2003), and Kakwani and Subbarao (2005). 6 In addition to ethical and political economy considerations, there are also technical arguments both in favor and against targeting. The main advantage of poverty targeting is to increase the amount that can be transferred to each beneficiary for a given budget, which maximizes the poverty impact of transfers. For instance, Grosh and Leite (2008) analyze cash transfer for the elderly in four countries – Yemen, Niger, Panama and Kyrgyzstan. They find that, despite exclusion errors, poverty targeted social pensions are much more cost- effective per dollar spent, and, for a fixed budget, convey a higher poverty impact. On the other hand, however, targeting is costly. Caldes et al. (2006) and Grosh et al. (2008) find that administrative costs of poverty targeted conditional cash transfers (including the cost of collecting the data needed to construct a proxy means test and periodical reclassification of beneficiaries) tend to be around 10 percent of the program’s budget. In some extreme cases it can absorb up to 30 percent of it, which can seriously affect the ability to provide larger transfers. Unless targeting really delivers strong differences in impact, categorical transfers should thus be considered as a valid option. In sum, the optimal design of programs and the extent to which to target depends very much on local conditions (Coady et al., 2004; Grosh et al., 2008). In designing a cash transfers program, one must have a clear idea of the incidence of poverty among the target population and political economy considerations in favor and against poverty targeting. How many people are poor or at risk of poverty? How many belong to the target population group? Where do they live? What are their characteristics? What are the causes of their poverty and vulnerability? And, also, which system would be subject to less local capture? Is there enough capacity to support an effective and transparent targeting system? Only thereafter a clear assessment on whether and how to target can be performed. This paper abstains from ethical considerations, and aims at contributing to the technical debate. The objective is to understand, by means of simulations, gains from poverty targeting in Latin America with respect to simpler categorical targeting. In doing so, it also provides some guidance on circumstances under which targeting may bring more benefits. It does not provide however a definitive answer for three reasons. First, because simulations are done for 13 countries only – too few to conduct a statistical meta analysis. Second, because the simulations do not consider behavioral changes of beneficiaries that could alter labor market decisions and poverty status. Third, and more importantly, because 7 there is no clear-cut answer to the question, which depends very much on budget, societal preferences and political economy considerations. 3. Data and methodology In what follows, we look first at the impact on poverty and inequality of poverty-targeted and categorical cash transfers to children up to five years of age. We then repeat the exercise for social pensions to elderly people of age 65 and higher, and conclude by comparing the two. Our workhorse simulation consists of a hypothetical cash transfer program that transfers an amount equal to 0.5 percent of GDP to a reference group (i.e. children or the elderly). The amount was chosen to strike a balance between large CCT programs such as Oportunidades or Bolsa Familia that transfer around 0.3 - 0.4 percent of GDP, and more costly social pensions programs that in some countries transfer up or even more than one percentage point of GDP. In choosing a common metric, we will be better able to compare the poverty impact of both types of programs. The simulations run as follows. For the targeted variant, we consider all households that meet the categorical criteria, and that have a gross income below USD 2.5 a day in per capita terms (an international widely used poverty line). In the literature, this group is referred to as the extreme poor. In 2010 the extreme poor consisted on average of 15 percent of the Latin America population (World Bank, 2010), and is the main beneficiary of social assistance programs. To estimate the size of the transfer, we then allocate 0.5 percent of GDP in equal shares to all beneficiaries (if there are 2 beneficiaries in one household, we give twice the transfer). To allow comparisons across countries, all simulations are done in 2005 PPP US Dollars. For the categorical variant, we repeat the same exercise but consider all households meeting the categorical criteria regardless of their poverty status. Having allocated the funds, we re-calculate for both variants households’ poverty status. Our estimations are based on several assumptions. First, we assume there are no behavioral changes, in particular that the program has no impact on labor market decisions and poverty status. The current evidence suggests that labor market distortions of cash transfer programs remain moderate, and we do not expect results to change dramatically if behavioral responses were considered. Second, the impact of a national program can 8 change substantially by urban and rural areas, and hence in a robustness exercise we discuss the impacts by geographical areas separately. Finally, the basic simulations neglect considerations related to the effectiveness of targeting, and assume that our hypothetical program is able to perfectly target the poor. To address this issue, we also discuss a simulation where we assume that targeting has 15 percent higher administrative costs than categorical transfers (so that the targeted program only distributes 0.425 percent of GDP), and that exclusion errors lead to missing 30 percent of the (randomly selected) poor, who do not receive the transfer. Observe, also, that we look at the poverty and inequality impact of programs that are in addition to the ones that are already implemented. Ideally, it would be preferable to first subtract from households’ income all transfers that they already receive, and subsequently add our transfer from the hypothetical program. In doing so, it would be possible to provide an idea on the extent to which the coverage of current programs could be improved to enhance cost effectiveness. Unfortunately, we only have limited and imperfect data about the amounts transferred to households in each country survey. We chose therefore not to explore that avenue. The simulations are based on household surveys from 13 Latin American countries that have been collected and harmonized as part of the Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean (SEDLAC), a partnership between the Center for Distributive, Labor and Social Studies (CEDLAS) and The World Bank. The list of countries and of surveys used is shown in Annex 1. The analysis uses the income aggregates provided in SEDLAC, which we convert in 2005 USD PPP. 4. Results Children We begin by looking at the poverty and inequality impact of targeted and categorical cash transfers programs to families with children up to 5 years of age. Several features emerge. First, we can observe a relationship between income per capita, and the effectiveness of the program in reducing poverty under both the targeted and untargeted modality. The same 9 program (if implemented ideally) is more than twenty times more effective in reducing poverty rates in Argentina than in Nicaragua under both modalities, and eight times more effective in reducing the poverty gap. Without even considering implementation issues, it is thus far easier to achieve a poverty impact in wealthier countries than in poorer ones. Two main reasons stand out: transfers remain higher in wealthier countries because of larger budgets available, making it easier to lift people above USD2.5 dollars a day: 0.5 percent of GDP corresponds to an average of 715 USD per capita (in PPP terms) in 2008 in Argentina, but only to 134 USD per capita in Nicaragua. In addition, wealthier countries also display lower poverty rates and a lower proportion of children in the population, and therefore, under the targeted modality, a higher budget is distributed among fewer beneficiaries. Figure 1: Changes in Extreme Poverty Rates - Children 80% Categorical 60% Targeted 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases Figure 2: Changes in Poverty Gap - Children 80% Categorical 60% Targeted 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases 10 Figure 3: Changes in the Gini coefficient - Children 5% Categorical 4% Targeted 3% 2% 1% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases Second, targeted programs are, on average, 3.2 times more effective in reducing poverty rates (and 2.3 more effective in reducing the poverty gap) than categorical programs. There is, however, considerable variation across countries: in Nicaragua, a perfectly targeted program would only be 2 times more effective in reducing poverty rates than a categorical one, while in Colombia (the other extreme) this ratio jumps to 7.1. These differences are not explained by income levels alone: effectiveness in Nicaragua and Argentina, two countries with very different income levels, is for instance very similar. Rather, differences in impact depend on a more complex combination of factors, such as how widespread are pockets of poverty with people far off the poverty line. In Colombia, not only poverty is more widespread, but the poverty gap is twice as much as in Argentina. That implies the need of higher transfer levels to the poor to lift them out of poverty, hence a categorical transfer, which dilutes available resources among more beneficiaries, remains less effective. Targeted programs are also much more effective in reducing income inequality. On average, in our sample, a categorical transfer of 0.5 percent of GDP to children reduces the Gini coefficient by 1.4 percent, against 2.6 percent for a targeted program. However, in contrast with poverty, there is little connection between the initial level of inequality, and the higher effectiveness of targeted programs as opposed to categorical ones. 11 Elderly Next, we turn attention to social pensions given to beneficiaries of age 65 and older (Figures 4 to 6). Observe that some countries in the sample have already in place large and widespread contributory and non-contributory pensions systems (Argentina, Brazil, and Chile) that have already dramatically lowered poverty among the elderly to reach less than 5 percent of this demographic group. In these countries, it makes little sense to compare the effectiveness of categorical vs. targeted programs, and we have therefore excluded them from the analysis. Figure 4: Changes in Extreme Poverty Rates - Elderly 80% Categorical 60% Targeted 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases Figure 5: Changes in Poverty Gap - Elderly 80% Categorical 60% Targeted 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases 12 Figure 6: Changes in the Gini Coefficient - Elderly 5% Categorical 4% Targeted 3% 2% 1% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases The first, striking contrast with respect to transfers to children is that in all countries (with the exception of Nicaragua, and under some circumstances Guatemala), both targeted and categorical transfers to the elderly have a significantly lower impact on poverty than an equivalent program for children. The difference in poverty impact is large: on average, categorical transfers to children are 1.6 times more effective in reducing poverty than categorical transfers of equal budget to the elderly, and targeted transfers twice more effective. The reasons are straightforward: poverty rates among the elderly are, on average, lower than for children; and poorer families have more children, but not more elderly people. The simulations also suggest that the common belief that cash transfers to the elderly can reduce substantially poverty by trickling down to all family members has limited validity: with fewer elderly than children living in poor households, for the trickledown effect to be effective money should be transferred across family members living in different households, a much less likely event. There is nevertheless considerable variation across countries in the poverty impact of transfers to the elderly. The maximum reduction in poverty rates (close to 20 percent) is achieved, as expected, in countries with high poverty incidence among the elderly, such as Mexico and Colombia. Effectiveness of a targeted program as opposed to a categorical one also varies substantially across countries, being 0.7 times higher in Nicaragua, to 1 in Guatemala, to 2 in Colombia and 3.2 times in Costa Rica, and 2.8 percent on average across countries. Similar conclusions apply for the reduction in poverty gaps (poverty targeted transfers are on average 2.3 more effective in reducing poverty gaps than categorical ones). 13 In addition to lower impacts on poverty, transfers to the elderly have also a lower impact on inequality than transfers to children. While, on average, targeted transfers to poor children reduce income inequality by 2.6 percent on average, the same amount of resources targeted to the elderly poor reduces income inequality by 1.7 percent. Again, poverty-targeted transfers are more effective in reducing income inequality than categorical ones across countries (2.3 times more on average), though the difference is less pronounced in Costa Rica and Mexico. Cost-effectiveness of categorical vs. targeted programs The previous section deals with the extent to which, for a given budget, targeted programs are more effective in reducing poverty and inequality. But the reverse question is also of interest: how much would it cost to achieve the same poverty impact of a targeted program using a categorical one? To address this question, we proceed as follows. For a categorical program to achieve the same poverty impact than a targeted one, it must transfer the same amount of resources but to all beneficiaries – not simply poor ones. With this simple rule in mind, we look at the cost-effectiveness of categorical vs. targeted cash transfers, which is summarized in Figure 7. In all countries under consideration, a targeted cash transfer can achieve the same poverty impact than a categorical one using from 2 to 13 times less resources. The large difference in costs suggest that in most countries some form of targeting, even if costlier and far from perfect, can lead to large efficiency gains and allow for more generous transfers to the poor. Efficiency gains show, however, strong heterogeneity across countries, with poorer countries demonstrating lower gains than wealthier ones, from around 2 in Nicaragua, Bolivia and Guatemala to around 7 in Argentina and Costa Rica, to 13 in Chile. In all cases, the cost-effectiveness of targeted interventions is even greater for transfers to the elderly than for children. The heterogeneity seems to have a direct link to the fact that wealthier countries have fewer poor people, and therefore, for a given overall budget, they can transfer a significantly larger amount of resources to a narrower set of people under targeted programs. 14 Figure 7: Cost-effectiveness of targeting 16 Cost effectiveness of targeting Children 12 Elderly 8 4 0 Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases The heterogeneity in efficiency gains also suggests that targeting methods should vary by country. For instance, in low income countries with widespread poverty, implementing a sophisticated proxy means test (PMT) may lead to high costs and strong implementation challenges without being necessarily much more effective than simpler targeting based on categorical and geographic exclusion restrictions. In contrast, in wealthier countries, unless pockets of poverty show strong geographical concentration, implementing a more sophisticated targeting mechanism (such as proxy-means or means-tested mechanisms) could lead to large efficiency gains. In these countries, stronger implementation capacity could also better resolve some of the technical implementation challenges that lead to exclusion errors. Imperfect targeting and administrative costs These basic simulations miss an important feature. Actual poverty targeting, means or proxy-means tested, is costly and far from being perfect. As a robustness exercise, we simulate therefore the impact of an “imperfect� poverty-targeted program to children. To do so, we presume that the targeted program spends 15 percent more than the categorical program in administrative costs (so that 15 percent less resources are being transferred to the beneficiaries), and that exclusion errors lead to missing 30 percent of the extremely poor (randomly selected among potential beneficiaries). For comparison purposes, we also explore the possibility that categorical targeting is also subject to a degree of imperfectness, 15 missing 10 percent of the poor.4 These assumptions are in line with what is suggested by targeting evaluations of transfer programs in the region (Fiszbein and Schady, 2010). Figure 8 presents the poverty impacts of the various variants. In all countries, the imperfectly targeted program continues to deliver a better poverty impact than the categorical programs. The impact remain in fact closer to the perfectly poverty targeted program, than to the categorical ones. Nevertheless, in countries where differences between targeted and categorical systems were already small, the attractiveness of a categorical program with respect to an imperfectly targeted one has now increased: in Nicaragua, for instance, a categorical program only achieves almost the same poverty reduction than an imperfectly targeted program that costs the same – but does not “miss� 30 percent of the extreme poor. In contrast, in wealthier and more unequal countries, such as Colombia, the need to transfer higher amounts to a fewer pool of poor beneficiaries makes an imperfectly targeted system still an attractive option. Figure 8: Imperfect targeting and administrative costs (children only) 80% Imperfectly Categorical Categorical Change in Ext. Poverty 60% Imperfectly Targeted Targeted 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases Relative targeting Some countries do not target beneficiaries using an absolute poverty line, but a relative one, in which case transfers are targeted to people below a certain percentile, rather than those 4 To keep the budget at 0.5 percent of GDP, under the categorical variant of the simulation we distribute all the resources of the program to the remaining 90 percent of the population. 16 below a particular income threshold. Accordingly, we simulate the poverty impact of a program that targets the poorest income quintile, and compare the results with a program that targets the population below 2.5 USD per day. Figure 9: Relative targeting (children only) 80% Categorical 60% Targeted bottom 20% Targeted Extreme Poor 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases The poverty impact of targeting the poorest quintile varies dramatically according to the poverty headcount and gap of each country. In Peru and Ecuador, where extreme poverty incidence among children is close to 20 percent, the two approaches are equivalent. In cases where poverty incidence is lower than 20 percent, a relative targeting would still reach all poor, but will dilute the average transfer due to the inclusion of non-poor beneficiaries. The resulting lower average transfer would imply that some of the poor will not be able to be lifted out of poverty. The lowest poverty impact in targeting the poorest quintile is however in countries with widespread pockets of poverty exceeding 20 percent, and in countries that have large poverty gaps, such as Nicaragua, Guatemala and Bolivia. In these cases, targeting the bottom quintile misses the beneficiaries who remain close to the poverty line, hence the transfers lift very few (or no) beneficiaries out of poverty. At the same time, however, the transfers reach more generously the poorest beneficiaries that remain far from the poverty line. It is not possible to assess, from a welfare perspective, which modality delivers higher welfare. The exercise shows however that changing the targeting modality can affect 17 significantly the profile of beneficiaries, and hence how to target should be at the center of the discussion when discussing a program’s objectives. Alternative age groups All simulations assume that the targeted beneficiaries are children 0 to 5 years old, and elderly who are 65 years old or more. This section investigates whether slightly changing the eligibility age profiles can affect the poverty impact of the program. It is to be expected that the poverty impact will be affected only if the poor are concentrated in specific age or profile groups. Figure 10 explores alternative age group definitions for children (it considers children 0 to 2 and 2 to 5 separately), to check if the poverty impact changes significantly by narrowing the age groups. With the exception of the Dominican Republic, the age group under consideration for a categorical transfer does not seem to alter significantly the results. This suggests that, overall, the distribution of income across age groups of children is such that providing higher transfers to a narrower group delivers a similar poverty impact than delivering lower transfers to a wider group. In all cases, the poverty impact under categorical targeting remains lower than under the targeted modality. Figure 10: Poverty impact targeting different age groups (children only) 80% 0-5 Targeted 0-5 Categorical 60% 0-2 Categorical 2-5 Categorical 40% 20% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases 18 Geographic targeting The poverty impacts of targeted vs. categorical programs may also vary geographically, for instance between urban and rural areas. Figures 11 and 12 present the differential poverty impact of a national program in urban and rural areas that transfers equal amounts to beneficiaries in both regions. Overall, despite the poverty incidence being on average three times higher in rural areas, there appears to be surprisingly little differences in program’s impact between rural and urban areas. In fact, a few results may appear counter intuitive at first sight, and we discuss them next. In many countries, both categorical and targeted transfers achieve greater poverty reduction in urban than in rural areas. This is because, independently of poverty incidence levels, the poverty gap is smaller in urban areas (poverty gaps in rural areas are on average 3.5 times higher), hence, equal amounts transferred to beneficiaries achieve greater poverty reduction in urban areas. However, aside from Bolivia where the same targeted program achieves twice as much poverty reduction in urban than in rural areas, differences in poverty impact remain fairly modest, from 1.6 times in Nicaragua to 0.9 times in Colombia. This suggests that, on average, benefits ought not to differ much between urban and rural areas, though they could be slightly higher in rural areas. Figure 11: Impact on urban areas (children only) 60% 50% Categorical Change in poverty Imperfectly Targeted 40% Targeted 30% 20% 10% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases 19 Figure 12: Impact on rural areas (children only) 60% 50% Categorical Change in poverty Imperfectly Targeted 40% Targeted 30% 20% 10% 0% Source: Own calculations based on SEDLAC databases The lower poverty gap in urban areas also provides an explanation of why targeted transfers do not necessarily perform better in urban than in rural areas, despite the lower poverty incidence. In fact, the picture remains quite heterogeneous. In Nicaragua, where two thirds of the population in rural areas lives in extreme poverty (against a quarter in urban areas), targeting performs much better in urban than in rural areas: in urban areas, it achieves 2.7 times higher poverty reduction than a categorical program, as opposed to only 1.7 times in rural areas. But in Panama, on the opposite side of the spectrum, poverty targeting performs way better in rural areas. This is because the poverty gap in urban areas remains so small (2.3 against 12 in rural areas), that even a “diluted� categorical transfer would achieve massive poverty reduction. In contrast, targeted transfers in rural areas perform way better because they allow to transfer higher resources to the poor, and hence to overcome more easily the higher poverty gap. 5. Conclusions From a theoretical perspective, targeting social assistance to the poor always improves the programs’ poverty impact since, for a given budget, targeted programs transfer more resources to fewer beneficiaries. However, the extent to which these gains are substantial enough to overcome some of the drawbacks related to targeting remains an empirical 20 question. The findings suggest that the incidence of poverty is key, but not the only factor affecting the relative effectiveness of targeted vs. categorical transfers. The rural-urban analysis strengthens the view that the relative effectiveness depends on a variety of factors, in particular the depth of the poverty gap: if it is relatively low, the difference in poverty impact of categorical vs. targeted transfers may not be that large. The comparison of programs for children and the elderly also supports the view that choosing carefully the beneficiaries is almost as important as targeting to achieve poverty reduction. The simulations show that because, overall, there are less elderly than children who are poor, for given resources social assistance programs to the elderly achieve a lower poverty impact – even if they are poverty targeted. This does not necessarily call for phasing out social pensions, but for a rebalancing of the budget of social assistance programs towards the largest vulnerable groups. Overall, the findings support the view that in the Latin American context targeting assistance to the poor tends to deliver higher poverty impacts. There are nonetheless circumstances under which simpler schemes, such as categorical cash transfers for vulnerable groups that are geographically confined to regions with strong pockets of poverty, may be a valid option to consider as an alternative to means tested or proxy means tested programs. This is particularly the case in low income countries with widespread pockets of poverty. We would like to conclude with a note of caution. To achieve comparability across countries, the simulations abstained from looking at country specific factors that ought to be considered in the design of effective social assistance programs. Among these are more precise identifications of vulnerable groups and of geographic differences. The results should thus be taken as they are – a suggestive cross country comparison with no ambition to provide guidance for specific countries, which ought to include more country specific factors. 21 References Barrientos, A. (2008) “Social Pensions in low-income countries� in Closing the Gap, Editors Holzmann, R., Robalino, D., and Takayama, N. ISBN 978-0-8213-7971-4 Caldes, N., Coady, D., and Maluccio,J. (2006) “The cost of poverty alleviation transfer programs: A comparative analysis of three programs in Latin America.� World Development 34(5): 818-837 Coady, D., Grosh, M. and Hoddinott, J. (2004). “Targeting of Transfers in Developing Countries: Review of Lessons and Experience.� World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies. World Bank and IFPRI. Fiszbein, A. and Schady, N. (2010). “Conditional Cash Transfers: Reducing Present and Future Poverty.� World Bank Policy Research Report. Grosh, M., del Ninno, C., Tesliuc, E., and Ouerghi, A. (2008) “For protection and promotion: the design and implementation of effective safety nets� ISBN 978-0-8213-7581-5 (alk. paper) — ISBN 978-0-8213-7582-2 Grosh, M., and Leite, P.G. (2009) “Defining Eligibility for Social Pensions: A view from a Social Assistance Perspective� in Closing the Gap, Editors Holzmann, R., Robalino, D., and Takayama, N. ISBN 978-0-8213-7971-4 World Bank - IEG (Independent Evaluation Group) (2011) “Evidence and Lessons Learned from Impact Evaluations on Social Safety Nets� Washington, DC: World Bank. http://ieg.worldbankgroup.org/content/dam/ieg/ssn/ssn_meta_review.pdf ILO-UN Social Protection Floor initiative (2010). http://www.ilo.org/global/about-the- ilo/press-and-media-centre/insight/WCMS_141818/lang--en/index.htm Kakwani, N, and Subbarao, K. (2005) “Aging and Poverty in Africa and the Role of Social Pensions.� Social Protection Discussion Paper 0521, World Bank, Washington, DC Kakwani,N., Veras Soares, F. and Son, H. (2005). “Conditional Cash Transfers in African Countries� UNDP International Poverty Center, Working Paper No. 9, November 2005. Leite, P.G. (2011) “Improving cost-effectiveness of targeting in Tanzania: The CB-CCT program� mimeo 22 Levy, S. (2008) “Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes : Social Policy, Informality, and Economic Growth in Mexico� Brookings Institution Press 2008 c. 357pp, ISBN – 978-0-8157- 5219-6 Mkandawire, Thandika (2005). “Targeting and Universalism in Poverty Reduction� Social Policy and Development Programme Paper No. 23, UNRISD, Geneva, 2005 Murrugarra, E. (2011). “Aging, Poverty and Social Protection in Colombia: Evidence and Policy Options.� Mimeo, World Bank. Parker, S. and Skoufias, E. (2000) “The impact of PROGRESA on work, leisure and time allocation� Final report at International Food Policy Research Institute. Preston, S. (1984) “Children and the Elderly: Divergent Paths for America’s Dependents� in Demography, Volume 21, Issue 4. Sluchynsky, O. (2009) “Administration of Social Pension Programs� in Closing the Gap, Editors Holzmann, R., Robalino, D., and Takayama, N. ISBN 978-0-8213-7971-4 Skoufias, E., and Di Maro, V. (2009) “Conditional Cash Transfers, Adult Work Incentives, and Poverty� in Journal of Development Studies, Volume 44, Issue 7, 2008 Schwartz, Anita M. 2003. “Old Age Security and Social Pensions.� Social Protection Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. Turra, C., Holz, M., and Cotlear, D. (2011) “Who Benefits from Public Transfers? Incidence across Income Groups and across Generations in Brazil and Chile� in Population Aging: Is Latin America Ready?, Directions in Development, World Bank, Washington, DC. UNICEF (2010). “Progress for Children: Achieving the MDGs with Equity (No. 9).� UNICEF, http://www.unicef.org/publications/index_55740.html Weigand, C., and Grosh, M. (2008) “Levels and Patterns of Safety Net Spending in Developing and Transition Countries.� Social Protection Discussion Paper 0817, World Bank, Washington, DC. World Bank (2010). “Did Latin America Learn to Shield the Poor from Economic Shocks?� LAC Poverty and Labor Brief. 23 Appendix Annex 1: Household surveys Observations Country Year Survey (Households) Argentina 2009 Encuesta Permanente de Hogares 27,842 Continua Bolivia 2007 Encuesta de Hogares 4,148 Brazil 2009 Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de 129,333 Domicilios Chile 2009 Encuesta de Caracterización 71,460 Socioeconómica Nacional Colombia 2009 Gran Encuesta Integrada de Hogares 112,102 Costa Rica 2009 Encuesta de Hogares de Propósitos 13,244 Múltiples Ecuador 2009 Encuesta de Empleo y Subempleo y 19,435 Desempleo Guatemala 2006 Encuesta Nacional de Condiciones de 13,686 Vida México 2008 Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y 29,468 Gastos de los Hogares Nicaragua 2005 Encuesta Nacional de Hogares sobre 6,884 Medición de Nivel de Vida Panamá 2009 Encuesta Continua de Hogares 13,386 Perú 2009 Encuesta Nacional de Hogares- 21,753 Condiciones de Vida y Pobreza Dominican 2009 Encuesta Nacional de Fuerza de 8,281 Republic Trabajo 24 Annex 2: Simulation results Argentina Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 8.34 6.01 8.10 3.26 7.83 P1 3.49 2.25 3.37 1.40 3.29 P2 2.20 1.33 2.11 0.92 2.07 Poverty line of US$4 P0 16.86 14.21 16.33 12.14 16.34 P1 6.90 5.17 6.68 3.74 6.59 P2 4.07 2.80 3.93 1.89 3.86 Gini 45.84 44.61 45.50 43.81 46.19 Annual Cost (in Millions) 2,658.6 2,658.6 2,658.6 2,658.6 Number of beneficiaries 2,268,498 2,531,433 326,361 36,797 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 3.21 2.88 22.32 197.95 Bolivia Categorical Targeted Original Income (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 33.34 32.34 32.60 30.49 30.92 P1 14.48 13.63 14.09 12.60 13.48 P2 9.15 8.40 8.89 7.54 8.52 Poverty line of US$4 P0 50.40 49.93 49.99 50.40 49.84 P1 25.14 24.35 24.60 23.86 24.08 P2 16.03 15.23 15.63 14.45 15.11 Gini 57.19 56.76 56.92 56.40 56.57 Annual Cost (in Millions) 189.0 189.0 189.0 189.0 Number of beneficiaries 1,347,935 576,899 581,007 145,778 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 0.38 0.90 0.89 3.55 25 Brazil Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 15.02 13.06 14.86 9.39 14.40 P1 6.90 5.54 6.78 3.82 6.63 P2 4.70 3.49 4.57 2.44 4.49 Poverty line of US$4 P0 27.53 26.14 27.21 26.44 26.92 P1 12.40 10.87 12.22 9.34 12.00 P2 7.81 6.43 7.67 4.95 7.51 Gini 53.74 53.28 53.58 52.78 53.57 Annual Cost (in Millions) 9,118.8 9,118.8 9,118.8 9,118.8 Number of beneficiaries 16,181,389 15,087,966 4,971,594 421,067 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.54 1.66 5.03 59.33 Chile Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 4.25 3.39 3.99 2.10 3.56 P1 1.61 1.22 1.50 0.86 1.40 P2 0.98 0.72 0.91 0.56 0.87 Poverty line of US$4 P0 11.72 10.13 11.10 9.59 11.02 P1 3.84 3.14 3.62 2.56 3.45 P2 2.03 1.59 1.90 1.20 1.79 Gini 51.94 51.23 51.51 50.95 51.66 Annual Cost (in Millions) 1,105.9 1,105.9 1,105.9 1,105.9 Number of beneficiaries 1,362,349 1,831,181 101,987 38,906 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 2.22 1.65 29.71 77.88 26 Costa Rica Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 8.09 7.08 7.66 4.17 6.88 P1 3.57 2.94 3.24 1.95 2.99 P2 2.38 1.89 2.06 1.39 1.95 Poverty line of US$4 P0 19.61 17.83 18.51 16.98 18.52 P1 7.19 6.27 6.70 4.90 6.39 P2 4.20 3.53 3.83 2.54 3.59 Gini 50.21 49.65 49.87 49.17 49.77 Annual Cost (in Millions) 230.9 230.9 230.9 230.9 Number of beneficiaries 410,092 330,723 58,776 28,524 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.54 1.91 10.76 22.18 Colombia Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 16.11 14.63 15.35 10.73 13.43 P1 7.23 6.28 6.55 4.40 5.71 P2 4.73 3.95 4.09 2.77 3.61 Poverty line of US$4 P0 29.95 28.37 29.05 29.27 28.44 P1 13.15 12.01 12.38 10.37 11.39 P2 8.15 7.20 7.45 5.56 6.66 Gini 56.02 55.51 55.75 54.96 55.23 Annual Cost (in Millions) 1,883.5 1,883.5 1,883.5 1,883.5 Number of beneficiaries 4,807,219 2,962,392 1,109,547 524,883 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.07 1.74 4.65 9.83 27 Dominican Republic Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 16.37 14.42 15.31 9.73 13.72 P1 4.82 3.87 4.48 2.51 3.98 P2 2.09 1.57 1.92 0.99 1.71 Poverty line of US$4 P0 34.66 33.14 33.25 33.73 32.66 P1 12.59 11.37 11.92 9.93 11.15 P2 6.24 5.34 5.85 4.13 5.34 Gini 48.86 48.03 48.42 47.34 47.89 Annual Cost (in Millions) 386.4 386.4 386.4 386.4 Number of beneficiaries 1,000,142 692,105 249,589 74,183 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.06 1.53 4.24 14.27 Ecuador Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 19.17 17.46 18.08 13.55 16.00 P1 7.56 6.62 7.08 4.88 6.26 P2 4.48 3.77 4.12 2.71 3.66 Poverty line of US$4 P0 37.21 35.94 36.20 37.00 35.73 P1 15.36 14.18 14.64 12.90 13.67 P2 8.86 7.91 8.33 6.48 7.56 Gini 48.93 48.28 48.61 47.57 47.94 Annual Cost (in Millions) 511.4 511.4 511.4 511.4 Number of beneficiaries 1,386,874 1,253,728 364,580 204,886 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.01 1.12 3.84 6.84 28 Guatemala Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 33.83 32.82 32.98 31.58 31.53 P1 14.35 13.38 13.78 12.17 13.02 P2 8.12 7.28 7.70 6.31 7.23 Poverty line of US$4 P0 53.37 52.73 52.69 53.37 52.82 P1 25.49 24.57 24.87 24.06 24.20 P2 15.65 14.74 15.11 13.87 14.46 Gini 55.85 55.25 55.50 54.80 55.03 Annual Cost (in Millions) 272.2 272.2 272.2 272.2 Number of beneficiaries 2,086,598 616,632 901,217 179,004 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 0.36 1.21 0.83 4.17 Mexico Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 13.96 11.61 12.74 6.96 11.32 P1 5.59 4.37 4.89 2.71 4.46 P2 3.35 2.47 2.87 1.59 2.67 Poverty line of US$4 P0 28.74 25.99 27.15 25.76 26.59 P1 11.36 9.70 10.35 7.59 9.73 P2 6.53 5.29 5.81 3.66 5.38 Gini 50.52 49.44 49.88 48.56 49.45 Annual Cost (in Millions) 7,153.3 7,153.3 7,153.3 7,153.3 Number of beneficiaries 11,633,955 7,189,108 2,393,781 1,120,543 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.68 2.73 8.19 17.49 29 Nicaragua Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 42.52 41.92 41.90 41.30 40.86 P1 17.65 16.95 17.24 16.33 16.55 P2 9.79 9.20 9.49 8.69 9.02 Poverty line of US$4 P0 63.30 63.12 62.80 63.30 63.26 P1 31.11 30.50 30.65 30.27 30.27 P2 19.14 18.51 18.75 18.08 18.23 Gini 52.26 51.86 52.01 51.56 51.61 Annual Cost (in Millions) 63.3 63.3 63.3 63.3 Number of beneficiaries 663,747 270,890 342,936 86,167 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 0.26 0.64 0.51 2.01 Panama Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 15.99 13.53 14.73 7.65 13.00 P1 5.76 4.28 5.19 2.34 4.62 P2 3.02 2.05 2.68 1.17 2.43 Poverty line of US$4 P0 29.58 27.87 28.31 27.79 27.32 P1 12.25 10.49 11.39 8.21 10.53 P2 6.80 5.39 6.21 3.61 5.63 Gini 52.09 50.96 51.56 50.10 50.99 Annual Cost (in Millions) 205.2 205.2 205.2 205.2 Number of beneficiaries 370,654 282,508 92,402 36,492 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 1.52 1.99 6.08 15.41 30 Peru Original Income Categorical Targeted (before transfers) Children Elderly Children Elderly Poverty line of US$2.5 P0 19.52 17.83 18.48 14.26 16.31 P1 6.93 5.75 6.40 3.91 5.72 P2 3.43 2.59 3.12 1.60 2.82 Poverty line of US$4 P0 34.99 33.89 34.17 34.94 33.54 P1 14.68 13.44 14.00 12.20 13.09 P2 8.10 7.02 7.60 5.63 6.94 Gini 48.03 47.18 47.63 46.51 46.97 Annual Cost (in Millions) 1,143.7 1,143.7 1,143.7 1,143.7 Number of beneficiaries 3,751,466 2,517,343 1,199,495 421,194 Transfer per beneficiary (2005 US$ Daily) 0.84 1.24 2.61 7.44 31