WPS5981 Policy Research Working Paper 5981 How Does Bank Competition Affect Systemic Stability? Deniz Anginer Asli Demirguc-Kunt Min Zhu The World Bank Development Research Group Finance and Private Sector Development Team February 2012 Policy Research Working Paper 5981 Abstract Using bank level measures of competition and co- and regulatory environment on systemic stability shows dependence, the authors show a robust positive that banking systems are more fragile in countries with relationship between bank competition and systemic weak supervision and private monitoring, with generous stability. Whereas much of the extant literature has deposit insurance and greater government ownership focused on the relationship between competition and of banks, and public policies that restrict competition. the absolute level of risk of individual banks, they Furthermore, lack of competition has a greater adverse examine the correlation in the risk taking behavior effect on systemic stability in countries with low levels of of banks, hence systemic risk. They find that greater foreign ownership, weak investor protections, generous competition encourages banks to take on more safety nets, and where the authorities provide limited diversified risks, making the banking system less fragile guidance for bank asset diversification. to shocks. Examining the impact of the institutional This paper is a product of the Finance and Private Sector Development Team, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at danginer@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team How Does Bank Competition Affect Systemic Stability? Deniz Anginer, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Min Zhu1 JEL Classifications: G21, L11, L14 Keywords: Systemic risk, bank competition, credit risk, merton model, distance to default, default risk, lerner index, bank concentration 1 Anginer, World Bank, danginer@worldbank.org; Demirguc-Kunt, World Bank, ademirguckunt@worldbank.org; Zhu, World Bank, mzhu1@worldbank.org. This paper’s findings, interpretations and conclusions are entirely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, their Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. 1. Introduction The impact of bank competition on financial fragility has always been a subject of active academic and policy debate. However public policy interest in this topic has intensified after the global financial crisis, with both academics and policymakers questioning to what extent the “dark side� of competition and the resulting financial innovations in search of higher margins were responsible for the crisis. While greater competition in the banking sector has no doubt led to greater innovation and efficiency, there is still no academic consensus on whether this competition has also led to greater fragility, with conflicted theoretical predictions and mixed empirical results. In parallel, the financial crisis also led to a re-examination of risk assessment practices and regulation of the financial system, with a renewed interest in systemic fragility and macro- prudential regulation. This requires a focus not on the risk of individual financial institutions, but on an individual bank’s contribution to the risk of the financial system as a whole. Hence, there is a growing consensus that from a regulatory perspective of ensuring systemic stability, the correlation in the risk taking behavior of banks is much more relevant than the absolute level of risk taking in any individual institution. In this paper we address both sets of issues by re-examining the empirical relationship between competition and systemic stability. Unlike the extant literature which has focused on stand-alone bank risk, our focus in this paper is on systemic stability. Hence instead of looking at the absolute level of risk in individual banks, we examine the correlation in the risk taking behavior of banks, measured as the total variation of changes in default risk of a given bank explained by changes in default risk of all other banks in a given country. We follow Anginer and Demirguc-Kunt (2011) and use Merton’s (1974) contingent claim pricing framework to measure bank default risk and its contribution to systemic risk. Using a sample of 1,872 publicly traded banks in 63 countries, over the period 1997 to 2009, we investigate the impact of bank concentration and competition, as measured by the Lerner index of bank market power. Our results suggest a positive relationship between competition and systemic stability, consistent with the view that greater competition encourages banks to take on more diversified risks, making the banking system less fragile to shocks. We also examine the 2 impact of the larger institutional and regulatory environment on this relationship. Correlated risk taking behavior is higher in countries with weak supervision and private monitoring, low levels of activity restrictions, with generous deposit insurance, high government ownership of banks, and public policies that restrict competition. The competition – systemic fragility relationship is also sensitive to the underlying institutional environment. We find lack of competition has a greater adverse effect on systemic stability in countries with low levels of foreign ownership, weak investor protections, generous safety nets, and where the authorities provide limited guidance for bank asset diversification. Our paper contributes to a large literature on the relationship between competition and stability in the financial system.2 Economic theory is conflicted on the impact of banking structure on financial stability. On the one hand, the charter value view of competition suggests there could be significant stability costs of competition, since too much competition may lead to excessive risk taking as it reduces margins (Marcus, 1984, Keeley, 1990 and Allen and Gale, 2004). Proponents of this view argue that in an environment with greater competition, the pressure on profits will make banks choose riskier portfolios, leading to greater fragility (Hellman, Murdoch and Stiglitz, 2000). Others argue that in a more competitive environment, banks earn lower rents, which also reduces their incentives for monitoring (Boot and Thakor 1993, Allen and Gale 2000).3 Large banks can also diversify better so that banking systems dominated with a few large banks are likely to be less fragile than banking systems with many small banks (Allen and Gale, 2004). Finally, some hold that a few large banks are easier to monitor and supervise compared to competitive banking systems with a large number of small banks. These arguments are all consistent with competition leading to greater fragility. On the other hand, lack of competition may also exacerbate bank fragility. Banks with greater market power tend to charge higher interest rates to firms, inducing them to take on greater risk, and hence increasing the fragility of the financial system as well (Boyd and De 2 See for example literature reviews by Carletti (2008) and Degryse and Ongena (2008). 3 Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2004) show that more intense competition may induce banks to switch to more risky, opaque borrowers; and Hauswald and Marquez (2006) show competition makes banks acquire less information on borrowers. 3 Nicolo, 2005).4 Importantly, large banks frequently receive “too-big-to-fail� subsidies from safety net policies, distorting their risk taking incentives and destabilizing the financial system as a whole (Kane, 1989). Finally, as the global financial crisis has amply illustrated, large banks also can be more difficult to supervise given their complexity, and their ability to politically capture their supervisors (Johnson and Kwak, 2010). Most of the theoretical literature on bank competition and stability focuses on individual bank risk, not on correlated risk taking by banks. Modeling correlated risk taking has been the focus of papers after the recent crisis (see for example Brunnermeier 2009, Daneielsson, Shin and Zigrand 2009, Battiston, Gatti, Gallegati, Greenwald, and Stiglitz, 2009 among others) but these papers do not address issues of bank competition. Given the current policy relevance of the topic and conflicting theoretical predictions, there is also a growing empirical literature on the impact of bank competition on bank fragility. Individual country studies - mostly for the US - have not come up with conclusive findings.5 Cross-country analyses have shown that more concentrated banking systems are less likely to suffer a systemic banking crisis but so are more competitive banking systems, potentially suggesting a stabilizing effect for having a contestable banking system (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine 2006, Schaeck, Cihak, and Wolfe 2009). Others have shown that banks in more competitive banking systems hold more capital, which could explain the positive effect of bank competition on stability (Schaeck and Cihak 2010, Berger, Klapper, and Turk-Ariss, 2009). Beck, De Jonghe, and Schepens (2011) find a positive correlation between accounting measures of bank soundness and market power, and examine the cross-country heterogeneity in this relationship, identifying links with regulatory and institutional features. Our contribution to this literature is three-fold. First, unlike most of the previous papers using bank level data to investigate the link between competition and bank fragility, we do not look at individual bank risk, but the co-dependence of those risks, hence addressing macro- 4 In extensions of Boyd and de Nicolo model that allow for imperfect correlation in loan defaults, Martinez-Miera and Repullo (2010) and Hakenes and Schnabel (2011) show that the relationship between competition and risk is U shaped. Wagner (2010) allows for risk choices to be made by borrowers as well, which overturns the Boyd and De Nicolo results. Allen and Gale (2004) also show that competition –stability relationship can be complex, where competition can also increase stability. 5 See for example, Boyd and Runkle (1993) for an analysis of US bank holding companies. 4 prudential regulation issues of current policy interest. Second, we compute default risks from the structural credit risk model of Merton (1974) instead of the commonly used accounting based measures of risk such as Z-scores of bank soundness. Using Z-scores in investigating the relationship between bank risk and competition is particularly problematic since Z-scores and Lerner index of market power are both calculated using profitability measures, making their positive correlation potentially spurious. In contrast, we use risk measures developed in Anginer and Demirguc-Kunt (2011), applying the recent advances made in the risk pricing literature6 to an international sample of publicly traded banks in 63 countries. Finally, the cross-country nature of our dataset allows us to examine the impact of the institutional and regulatory environment on systemic stability as well as the relationship between competition and correlated risk taking behavior of banks, which are of particular interest for policy. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the construction of the sample and variables. Section 3 presents the empirical results and discusses the implications. Section 4 concludes. 2. Data and Empirical Methodology 2.1 Sample In this section we describe the data sources used in this paper. We obtain bank level financial information from Bankscope. We use stock market information from Compustat Global for international banks and stock market information from CRSP for U.S. banks. The Bankscope database reports detailed balance sheet and income statement information for both public and private banks and covers over 90% of the total banking assets in a given country. The Compustat Global database provides daily stock price information for both active and delisted companies accounting for 98% of the global stock market capitalization. CRSP is the standard source for stock price information of U.S. companies. Our final sample consists of 1,872 unique publicly traded banks in 63 countries from 1997 to 2009. Sample size varies across regression specifications because not all variables are available for all bank year observations. 6 See Adrian and Brunnermeier (2009), Huang, Zhou, and Zhu (2009), Chan-Lau and Gravelle (2005), Avesani, Pascual, and Li (2006), and Elsinger, Lehar and Summer (2005). 5 2.2 Systemic Default Risk Measure We use the Merton (1974) contingent claim framework to measure bank default risk. This approach treats the equity value of a company as a call option on the company’s assets. The probability of default is computed using the “distance-to-default� measure, which is the difference between the asset value of the firm and the face value of its debt, scaled by the standard deviation of the firm’s asset value. The Merton (1974) distance-to-default measure has been shown to be good predictor of defaults outperforming accounting-based models (Campbell, Hilscher and Szilagyi 2008; Hillegeist, Keating, Cram, and Lundstedt 2004; Bharath and Shumway 2008). Although the Merton distance-to-default measure is more commonly used in bankruptcy prediction in the corporate sector, Merton (1977) points out the applicability of the contingent claims approach to pricing deposit insurance in the banking context. Bongini, Laeven and Majnoni (2002), Bartram, Brown and Hund (2007) and others have used the Merton model to measure default risk of commercial banks. We follow Campbell, Hilscher and Szilagyi (2008) and Hillegeist, Keating, Cram, and Lundstedt (2004) to calculate Merton’s distance-to-default measure. Specifically, the market equity value of a company is modeled as a call option on the company’s assets: (1) In equation (1), VE is the market value of a bank. VA is the value of the bank’s assets. X is the face value of debt maturing at time T. r is the risk-free rate and d is the dividend rate expressed in terms of VA. sA is the volatility of the value of assets, which is related to equity volatility through the following equation: (2) We simultaneously solve the above two equations to find the values of VA and sA. We use the market value of equity for VE and total liabilities to proxy for the face value of debt X. Since 6 the accounting information is on an annual basis, we linearly interpolate the values for all dates over the period, using beginning and end of year values for accounting items. The interpolation method has the advantage of producing a smooth implied asset value process and avoids jumps in the implied default probabilities at year end. sE is the standard deviation of daily equity returns over the past year. In calculating standard deviation, we require the bank to have at least 90 non-missing daily returns over the previous twelve months. T equals one year. r is the one year US treasury yield, which we take to be the risk free rate. We use the Newton method to simultaneously solve the two equations above. For starting values for the unknown variables, we use VA = VE + X and sA = sEVE/(VE+X). We winsorize sE and VE/(VE+X) at the 5th and 95th percentile levels to reduce the influence of outliers. After we determine asset values VA, we follow Campbell, Hilscher and Szilagyi (2008) and assign asset return m to be equal to the equity premium (6%). Merton’s distance-to-default (dd) is finally computed as: (3) The default probability is the normal transform of the distance-to-default measure and is defined as PD = F (–dd), where F is the cumulative distribution function of a standard normal distribution. As mentioned earlier, our focus in this paper is on systemic stability. Hence instead of looking at the absolute level of risk in individual banks, we examine the correlation in the risk taking behavior of banks, measured as the total variation of changes in default risk of a given bank explained by changes in default risk of all other banks in a given country. We use as our measure of systemic stability the R-squared obtained from regressing changes in bank default risk on changes in average default risk of all banks in a given country. To calculate this measure, for each bank i in country j in week w of year t, we first compute a weekly Merton’s distance-to- default (ddi,j,t,w). Then for each bank i in year t, we run a time series regression of bank i’s weekly change in distance-to-default on country average weekly change in distance-to-default excluding bank i itself: 7 (4) We follow Morck, Yeung, and Yu (2000) and Karolyi, Lee, and Van Dijk (2011) and use the logistic transformation of R-squared from the above regression, which is equal to log(rsqi,j,t) / (1-rsqi,j,t)), to measure systemic risk posed by bank i. R-squared is only computed for banks with at least twenty-six weeks of changes in weekly distance-to-default data in a year. In terms of measuring co-dependence, using R-squared has advantages over alternative measures as described in Pukthuanthong and Roll (2009) and Bekaert and Wang (2009). Higher R-squared for a given bank suggests that the bank is exposed to similar sources of credit risk as other banks in a given country. Higher R-squared also suggests that there are channels of inter-dependency between the bank and others in a given country. Both interconnectedness and common exposure to risk makes the banking sector more vulnerable to economic, liquidity and information shocks. 2.3 Competition Measure In this paper, we use the Lerner index as our main measure of lack of competition. The Lerner index is a proxy for profits that accrue to a bank as a result of its pricing power in the market. It is measured at the bank level and has been utilized in a number of banking studies.7 We follow the methodology used in Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez-Peria (2010) and first estimate the following log cost function for each country: log(Cit) = α + β1×log(Qit) + β2×(log(Qit))2 + β3×log(W1,it) + β4×log(W2,it) + β5×log(W3,it) +β6×log(Qit)×log(W1,it) + β7×log(Qit)×log(W2,it) + β8×log(Qit)×log(W3,it) + β9×(log(W1,it))2 + β10×(log(W2,it))2 + β11×(log(W3,it))2 + β12×log(W1,it) ×log(W2,it) (5) + β13×log(W1,it) ×log(W3,it) + β14×log(W2,it) ×log(W3,it) + Θ×Year Dummies + Ω×Bank Specialization Dummies + εit 7 See for instance, Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez-Peria (2010) and Beck, De Jonghe, and Schepens (2011). 8 In equation (5) above, Cit is total costs and is equal to the sum of interest expenses, commission and fee expenses, trading expenses, personnel expenses, other admin expenses, and other operating expenses, measured in millions of US dollars. Qit is the quantity of output and is measured as total assets in millions of US dollars. W1,it is the ratio of interest expenses to the sum of total deposits and money market funding. W2,it is measured as personnel expenses divided by total assets. W3,it is the ratio of administrative and other operating expenses to total assets. The subscript i denotes bank i and the subscript t denotes year t. We take natural logarithm of all variables and estimate the regression for each country in our dataset using pooled ordinary least squares (OLS). We include calendar year and bank specialization dummies in the regression. All variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile levels to reduce the influence of outliers. We further impose the following five restrictions on regression coefficients to ensure homogeneity of degree one in input prices: β3+β4+β5 = 1; β6+β7+β8 = 0; β9+β12+β13 = 0; β10+β12+β14 = 0; β11+β13+β14 = 0 (6) We then use the coefficient estimates from the previous regression to estimate marginal cost for bank i in calendar year t: MCit = Cit/Qit = Cit/Qit × [β1 + 2×β2×log(Qit) + β6×log(W1,it) (7) + β7×log(W2,it) + β8×log(W3,it)] The Lerner index is then computed as: Lernerit = (Pit - MCit) / Pit (8) Above, Pit is the price of assets and is equal to the ratio of total revenue (sum of interest income, commission and fee income, trading income, and other operating income) to total assets. In section 3.4, as a robustness check, we use bank asset concentration as an alternative proxy for bank competition.8 Untabulated results show that country level bank concentration, as measured by the three bank asset concentration ratio, is correlated with the country level average Lerner index with a Pearson correlation coefficient of 0.077 (p-value < 0.0001). The three bank 8 We use the three bank asset concentration ratio from the Financial Structure Dataset (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and Levine 2010) as a measure of bank concentration. 9 asset concentration ratio is also highly correlated with the Hirschmann-Herfindahl index of bank assets concentration with a Pearson correlation coefficient of 0.798 (p-value < 0.0001). 2.4 Institutional and Regulatory Variables As mentioned in the introduction we are also interested in the impact of the larger regulatory and institutional framework on the competition and systemic stability relationship. The main regulatory and institutional variables used in this study come from the three surveys conducted by Barth, Caprio, and Levine (2008). The survey is conducted in the years 1999, 2002, and 2005. Since country level regulations change slowly over time, we use the previously available survey data until a new survey becomes available. Specifically, we use the survey data of 1999 for years 1996 to 2001, the survey data of 2002 for years 2002 to 2004, and the survey data of 2005 for years 2005 to 2009. We consider four groups of bank regulation/institutional variables. The first group of regulatory variables is related to entry restrictions and bank ownership. Entry barrier index, entry_bar, measures bank entry requirements, which is constructed based on eight questions in the Barth, Caprio, and Levine surveys regarding legal submissions required to obtain a banking license in a given country. Application denied, ap_denied, is the percentage of applications to set up a bank which were denied in the past five years. Government ownership, gov_own, measures the fraction of banks that are 50% or more owned by the government. Foreign ownership, foreign_own, is the fraction of banks that are 50% or more owned by foreign investors. The second variable we use is related to deposit insurance coverage. We obtain this variable from Demirguc-Kunt, Kane, and Laeven (2008). Deposit insurance coverage ratio, covratio, is the amount of deposit insurance coverage divided by GDP per capita. It is set to 1 if a country offers full coverage. Since the data ends in year 2003 and most countries did not change their deposit insurance coverage till the recent financial crises, we use the deposit insurance coverage in 2003 for years 2003 to 2007.9 The third group of bank regulation variables measure activity restrictions and other dimensions of bank supervision. Activity restrictions index, activity_restriction, measures the degree to which the national regulatory authorities allow banks to engage in securities, insurance, and real estate businesses. Capital 9 See Demirguc-Kunt, Kane, and Laeven (2008) for a detailed analysis of various features of deposit insurance mechanisms. 10 stringency index, capital_stringency, measures the amount of capital a bank must maintain. Supervisory power index, supervisory_power, indicates whether the supervisory authorities have the power and the authority to take specific preventive and corrective actions. Diversification index, diversification_index, captures whether there are explicit, verifiable, quantifiable guidelines for bank asset diversification and whether banks are allowed to make loans outside of national borders. Finally, we also use data on the investor protection index (investor_protection), depth of credit information sharing (credit_info_depth), and the existence of a private information bureau (private_bureau) from Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer (2007) and the World Bank Doing Business Survey.10 These variables measure the strength of private monitoring and information sharing in each country. A full list of variables, definitions and sources are provided in Appendix I. 2.5 Control Variables In examining the relationship between competition and systemic stability we control for a number of bank and country level variables. Bank level controls come from Bankscope. For each bank, each year, we calculate bank size (natural logarithm of total assets), leverage (liabilities divided by total assets), market-to-book ratio (market value of assets divided by book value of assets), provisions (loan loss provisions divided by total assets), reliance on deposits for funding (deposits divided by total assets) and profitability (net income divided by total assets). We winsorize all financial variables at the 1st and 99th levels of their distributions to reduce the influence of outliers. Country level controls are collected from a number of sources. We obtain economic development measures from the World Bank’s World Development Indictor (WDI) database. We use the natural logarithm of GDP per capita to measure the economic development of a country, the variance of GDP growth rate to measure economic stability, the natural logarithm of population to measure country size, and imports plus exports of goods and service divided GDP to measure global integration (Karolyi, Lee, and Van Dijk 2011). In addition, we obtain years in 10 Details on how these variables are constructed are available on World Bank’s Doing Business Survey website at http://www.doingbusiness.org/methodology. 11 which a country experienced a banking crisis from Laeven and Valencia (2008). We also use stock market capitalization divided by GDP and private credit divided by GDP from the Financial Structure Dataset (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine 2010) to control for differences in financial development and structure. As the R-squared measure may be a mechanically linked to the number of cross-sectional observations, we also control for the log of the number of banks in each country. 3. Summary Statistics In this section we describe our empirical results. Figure 1 shows the evolution of average bank market power, as measured by the average Lerner index, from year 1996 to 2009. The pattern of time series changes in the Lerner index is consistent with that in Beck, De Jonghe, and Schepens (2011). The Lerner index has been steadily increasing since 1998 but has declined sharply after 2007 after the onset of the global financial crisis. Figure 2 shows the evolution of the average R- squared, our measure of systemic stability. Consistent with Anginer and Demirguc-Kunt (2011), we find an increase in systemic risk leading up to the sub-prime financial crises. The graphs also indicate that there seems to be a positive relation between bank market power and systemic risk, which we will examine further in Section 3.1. Panel A of Table 1 provides the summary statistics of variables used in this study. An average bank in the sample has log total asset value of 8.22, leverage ratio of 0.90, market-to- book ratio of 1.07, deposits to assets ratio of 0.71, provision to net interest income ratio of 0.17, return on assets of 0.01, and Lerner index of 0.18. These numbers are comparable to those in previous studies such as Beck, De Jonghe, and Schepens (2011). Panel B of Table 1 presents the Pearson correlations for bank level variables. The univariate correlations suggest that larger banks, highly leveraged banks, banks that have higher loan loss provisions to net interest income ratios, and banks that are less competitive (more market power) have higher systemic risk. It also suggests that the Lerner index is positively correlated with bank growth options, as measured by market-to-book ratio, and bank profitability, as measured by return on assets, and is negatively correlated with leverage and the loan loss provisions to net interest income ratio. 12 Panel C of Table 1 presents the Pearson correlations for country level variables. Countries with more concentrated banking industries have higher ratios of applications denied, higher government and foreign ownership of banks, higher deposit insurance coverage, and more stringent requirements on bank capital. These countries with more concentrated banking industries also are less likely to have specific guidelines regarding bank diversification, and they tend to have lower entry barrier, lower activity restrictions, lower supervisory power, lower investor protection, and lower levels of credit information sharing. Panel A of Table 2 shows the sample distribution by calendar year. The number of banks increased markedly in 2001 as Bankscope increased its coverage of banks. Panel B of Table 2 presents the sample distribution by country. U.S. and Japan have the highest number of banks in the sample. While U.S. and Japanese banks account for about 55% of our bank-year observations, our results are robust to the exclusion of these banks. Panel B of Table 2 also suggests that there are a handful of countries with very few bank year observations. Since our measure of systemic risk can be affected by the number of bank observations in each country- year, we also checked that our results are robust to excluding countries with fewer than seven banks in any given year from our analyses and confirmed that they are. 3.1 Competition and Systemic Stability: Baseline Results In this section we examine how bank competition affects systemic stability after controlling for bank and country level variables. We use the following regression specification for our main analyses: riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank_controlsijt-1 + Θ×country_controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + αi + λt + εijt (8) Our dependent variable is bank i’s systemic risk (in country j in year t), riskijt, and is equal to the logistic transformation of R-squared from a regression of bank i’s weekly changes in distance to default on country j’s average weekly changes in distance to default in year t excluding bank i itself. Our main explanatory variable of interest is bank competition, measured by the Lerner index. Bank level control variables include bank size (size), leverage (leverage), market-to- book ratio (mb), provisions to net interest income ratio (provision), reliance on deposits for funding (deposits) and profitability (roa). Country level control variables include natural 13 logarithm of GDP per capita (loggdppca), variance of GDP growth rate (vargdpgr), natural logarithm of population (logpop), imports plus exports of goods and service divided GDP (trade_gdp), stock market capitalization divided by GDP (stmktcap), private credit divided by GDP (pcrdbofgdp), crisis year dummy (crisis) and the log number of banks in each country and year (log_nbank). All explanatory variables are lagged by one year. In the regression, we also include bank fixed effects, αi, to control for time invariant bank heterogeneity and use calendar year fixed effects, λt, to control for time varying global business cycle effects. Table 3 presents the coefficient estimates for the bank fixed effect regressions. Column (1) of Table 3 shows that larger banks pose greater systemic risk. Banks with higher market-to- book ratios have lower systemic risk, suggesting that the availability of growth options reduces systemic risk. Greater profitability also tends to be associated with higher systemic risk. For country level variables, we find that openness to trade is associated with lower systemic risk. Similarly financial institution depth as captured by private credit to GDP is associated with lower systemic risk, suggesting that banks take more diversified risks in these countries. Log number of banks is positively correlated with systemic risk, which is consistent with more accurate estimation of systemic risk in countries with a larger number of banks. In Column (2) of Table 3, we include the Lerner index as an additional explanatory variable for bank systemic risk. We find that the relationship between Lerner index and bank systemic risk is both positive and statistically significant at the 1% level. The coefficient estimate indicates that a one standard deviation increase in competition (i.e., a 0.2 unit decrease in the Lerner index) is associated with a 0.1 standard deviation reduction in systemic risk. If we were to rank all banks according Lerner and systemic risk, after all controls, a bank that moves up a quintile in Lerner rankings, would move up one decile in systemic risk rankings. In terms of control variables, the coefficient estimates in Column (2) are similar to those in Column (1). Furthermore, the positive relation between bank profitability and systemic risk becomes much weaker after we control for the Lerner index. In addition, country level variables do not seem to affect bank systemic risk significantly once we control for bank competition, except for the crisis year dummy which is now positively and significantly related to bank systemic risk. Overall, the evidence in Table 3 suggests that competition enhances stability. 14 3.2 Competition, Regulation, and Systemic Stability We further examine how each country’s regulatory and institutional environment affect bank systemic stability and whether it exacerbates or mitigates the positive relationship between competition and systemic stability. We use the following regression specification: riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 (9) + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×competitionijt-1×regulationjt-1 + αi + λt + εijt As before, our dependent variable is bank i’s systemic risk (in country j in year t), riskijt. We use the same controls as described in the previous section. The regression specification is similar to what we used in equation (8) except that we now add in country level bank regulation variables (regulation) and the interactions between country level regulation variables and the Lerner index as additional explanatory variables. 3.2.1 Competition Policies and Systemic Risk Table 4 presents the coefficient estimates for bank fixed effects regressions with competition policy variables included as additional explanatory variables. Columns (2), (4), (6) and (8) show the baseline results of competition policy variables. In columns (3), (5), (7) and (9) we report results from regressions that include interaction terms between the Lerner index and the competition policy variables. We expect government ownership as well government policies that inhibit competition to result in correlated risk taking incentives which would increase systemic risk. We also expect the relationship between competition and systemic stability to be weaker in countries with greater government ownership and policies that inhibit competition. The relationship between of foreign ownership systemic stability is ambiguous. Foreign ownership could result in opportunities for greater risk diversification, but at the same time help propagate economic, liquidity and information shocks across national borders. The interaction effects likewise remain an empirical question. 15 In the baseline results, we find the government ownership and applications denied variables to significantly increase correlated risk-taking by banks. Examining the interaction terms, we only find the interaction term for foreign ownership to be negative and significant at the 10% confidence level. Hence, while foreign ownership does not have a direct effect on systemic fragility, it appears to mute the negative effect of market power on systemic fragility. 3.2.2 Deposit Insurance and Systemic Risk Table 5 presents the coefficient estimates for bank fixed effects regressions with deposit insurance dummy included as an additional explanatory variable. How deposit insurance affects systemic stability is not immediately clear. While deposit insurance may prevent bank runs (Matutes and Vives 1996) and ensure systemic stability, it may also lead to moral hazard and excessive bank risk taking (Demirguc-Kunt and Kane 2002, and Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga 2004). Furthermore, generous safety nets tend to be correlated with other implicit state guarantees. If there is an implicit guarantee provided by the State to cover losses stemming from a systemic crisis, banks will have incentives to take on correlated risks (Acharya 2005). Guaranteed banks will not have incentives to diversify their operations, since the guarantee takes effect only if other banks fail as well. In Column (2) of Table 5, we include a deposit insurance coverage ratio as an additional explanatory variable. In Column (3) of Table 5, we include both the deposit insurance coverage ratio and the interaction between the Lerner index and deposit insurance coverage ratio as additional explanatory variables. The main effect of deposit insurance on systemic stability is positive and significant. That is, on average deposit insurance increases banks’ incentives to take on correlated risk consistent with the notion of moral hazard. Furthermore, the interaction term is positive and significant, suggesting the effect of deposit insurance on incentives is more pronounced in less competitive markets. 3.2.3 Bank Supervision and Systemic Stability Table 6 presents the coefficient estimates for bank fixed effects regressions with bank supervision variables included as additional explanatory variables. The variables we consider are activity restrictions, capital stringency, supervisory power and explicit asset diversification guidelines provided by regulators. Activity restrictions can reduce potential channels of credit 16 risk contagion (Anginer and Demirguc-Kunt 2011). However activity restrictions may also result in herding behavior and greater correlated risk taking if the banks are unable to venture into new markets, or seek new lines of businesses or clients. Stringent capital requirements would help minimize contagion and may also incentivize bank investors to control systemic risk taking. Investors tend to prefer well capitalized banks as these banks have a relatively higher incentive to monitor (Repullo 2004, Allen, Carletti, and Marquez 2011). We would also expect greater supervisory power and explicit guidelines for diversification to have a positive impact on systemic stability by incentivizing banks to take on diverse risks. The baseline results reported in columns (2), (4), (6), and (8) suggest that this is indeed the case. Except for capital stringency all variables are negative and significant. As before, we interact these supervision variables with the Lerner index. The coefficient on the interaction variable for the diversification guidelines is negative (column 9), suggesting that the benefit in reducing systemic risk with diversification guidelines is greater in less competitive markets. The interaction variable for activity restrictions is also negative (column 3). The coefficient on the interaction variable between supervisory power and the Lerner index is positive (column 7). That is, the benefit from having strong supervisory powers is less pronounced in less competitive markets. This is consistent with the notion of regulatory capture in highly concentrated industries. The other interaction terms are insignificant. 3.2.4 Private Monitoring and Systemic Risk Table 7 presents the coefficient estimates for bank fixed effects regressions with private monitoring variables included as additional explanatory variables. The variables we consider are investor protection, depth of credit information and the existence of private information collection agency. Both better investor protection and greater information availability facilitates shareholder monitoring. We expect greater monitoring and lower asymmetry in information to be associated with lower systemic risk. A number of papers have used constrained information asymmetry framework to explain risk contagion and crises (Genotte and Leland 1990, Kodres and Pritsker 2002, Hong and Stein 2003, and Barlevy and Veronesi 2003, Yuan 2005). It is not entirely clear how the impact of private monitoring and information asymmetry on systemic stability would vary with competition. 17 The baseline results are provided in columns (2), (4) and (6). Consistent with our expectations, both depth of credit information and the existence of private information collection agency significantly reduce systemic risk after controls. In columns (3), (5) and (7) we present results from regressions including the interaction between private monitoring variables and the Lerner index. The results indicate that the effect of investor protection and depth of credit information in reducing systemic risk is lower in less competitive markets. 3.3 Robustness Checks In this section we show that our results are robust to alternative regression specifications as well as alternative definitions of competition and systemic stability. A number of previous studies have used concentration, measured as the percentage of total assets held by top three or five bank in a given country, as a proxy for competition. While concentration is correlated with bank competition, the recent literature also emphasizes the differences between the two, suggesting concentration is a less reliable indicator of competition (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine, 2006; Demirguc-Kunt and Martinez Peria, 2010). Nevertheless, as an alternative measure of competition, we use the three bank asset concentration ratio from the Financial Structure Dataset to measure banking concentration. We run the same regressions specified in equations (8) and (9) replacing the Lerner index with bank concentration. Unlike the Lerner index, bank concentration is measured at the country level each year. All other control variables are the same as those used in Sections 3.2 and 3.3. The regression results are provided in Table 8. Although our bank systemic risk variable is measured at the bank level while our concentration variable is measured at the country-year level, our regression results using bank concentration as a proxy of market power and lack of competition are largely consistent with what we find using the Lerner index. In unreported regressions, we also used a number of alternative measures for systemic stability as a robustness check. We have computed R-squared using equity returns instead of changes in distance-to-default. In unreported results, when we repeat the regression specified in equations (8) and (9) above using the new R-squared, we obtain similar results. We have also computed a variance ratio as discussed in Anginer and Demirguc-Kunt (2011). These results are also qualitatively similar but not as significant. 18 In our main analyses in Section 3.2, we use bank fixed effect regression to control for the impact of time invariant bank heterogeneity on bank systemic risk. In this section, we consider two alternative regression specifications. First, we use country fixed effect regression to control for country heterogeneity while also controlling for year fixed effects. The regression results are presented in Column (1) of Table 9. The relationship between Lerner index and bank systemic risk is still positive and statistically significant. Second, we follow Beck, De Jonghe, and Schepens (2011) and use a time varying country fixed effect to capture time varying country- specific regulation or business cycle effects on systemic risk taking by banks. The coefficient estimates in Column (2) of Table 9 show a statistically significant positive relationship between the Lerner index and systemic risk. Our results on bank competition and systemic risk are robust to these alternative specifications.11 In addition, we conduct a battery of robust checks using different sample selection criteria such as excluding banks in USA and Japan, including bank observations in 2010, excluding bank-year observations prior to 2001, and dropping countries with fewer than seven banks. The regression results are presented in Columns (3) – (6) of Table 9. Our results are robust to these alternative sample selection criteria. 4. Conclusion Competition in the financial sector has a long list of obvious benefits: greater efficiency in the production of financial services, higher quality financial products and more innovation. When financial systems become more open and contestable, generally this results in greater product differentiation, a lowering of the cost of financial intermediation and more access to financial services. But when we turn to the issue of financial stability, it is no longer so obvious whether competition is beneficial or not, with a continuing debate among academics and policymakers alike. In this paper we investigate the relationship between bank competition and systemic stability, and using bank level measures of competition and co-dependence, we show a robust 11 Regulatory and institutional variables are more sensitive to including country fixed effects as opposed to bank fixed effects. Nevertheless, the main results on entry (applications denied), generosity of deposit insurance, and private monitoring (investor protection and credit information depth) remain robust. 19 positive relationship between the two. Whereas much of the extant literature has focused on the relationship between competition and the absolute level of risk of individual banks, we examine the correlation in the risk taking behavior of banks to capture systemic fragility. Our results indicate greater competition encourages banks to take on more diversified risks, making the banking system less fragile to shocks. We also examine the impact of the institutional and regulatory environment on systemic stability and see that banking systems are more fragile in countries with weak supervision and private monitoring, with generous deposit insurance and greater government ownership of banks, and public policies that restrict competition. Furthermore, lack of competition has a greater adverse effect on systemic stability in countries with low levels of foreign ownership, weak investor protections, generous safety nets, and where the authorities provide limited guidance for bank asset diversification. Our paper has important policy implications. Unlike most of the earlier literature, our findings suggest that concentration, as well as market power, are associated with greater systemic fragility. Hence when competition and systemic stability are concerned, we do not observe a trade-off, which emphasizes the importance of ensuring a competitive environment in banking. However, our results also stress the importance of the underlying regulatory and institutional framework. Allowing entry (by rejecting fewer applications) reduces systemic fragility, but so do activity restrictions and diversification guidelines, particularly in less competitive banking environments. Our results also suggest that while government ownership is directly associated with higher systemic fragility, foreign bank ownership can have an indirect yet positive impact on fragility by muting the negative effect of market power on fragility. Overall, our results lend support to the view that fostering the appropriate incentive framework is very important for ensuring systemic stability. These incentives are shaped by the design of entry and exit policies, existence and generosity of deposit insurance and safety net policies, good prudential regulation, and availability of information. In addition to entry barriers, we see having an explicit deposit insurance system with a high coverage ratio significantly increases systemic fragility. The fact that activity restrictions, supervisory power and private monitoring are all associated with lower systemic fragility is also consistent with the important 20 role of both prudential regulation and market discipline in ensuring stability. Importantly, the effectiveness of these in controlling systemic fragility is reduced in less competitive banking environments where there is likely to be greater regulatory capture. In conclusion, it is important for the regulatory framework to strike the right balance between curbing excesses while avoiding potential anti-competitive effects. Our results suggest information availability, prudent capital requirements for entry as well as operation, and better credit monitoring are the types of actions that would improve systemic stability without impairing competition. In contrast, increases in regulatory costs that raise domestic and foreign entry barriers into the financial sector make markets less contestable, depriving countries of many of the benefits of an efficient and innovative banking system, as well as leading to greater fragility. 21 References Acharya, V. 2009, “A theory of systemic risk and design of prudential bank regulation,� Journal of Financial Stability, 5(3), 224-255. Adrian, T., and M. K. Brunnermeier, 2009, “CoVaR,� Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 348. Allen, F., E. Carletti, and R. Marquez, 2011, “Credit market competition and capital regulation,� Review of Financial Studies 24(4), 983-1018. Allen, F., and D. Gale, 2000, “Comparing financial systems,� Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press. Allen, F., and D. Gale, 2004, “Competition and financial stability,� Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36(3), Part 2, 453-480. Anginer, D., and A. Demirguc-Kunt, 2011, “Has the global banking system become more fragile over time?,� World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5849. Avesani, R., A. G. Pascual, and J. Li, 2006, “A new risk indicator and stress testing tool: A multifactor Nth-to-default CDS basket,� IMF Working Paper. Barlevy, G., and P. Veronesi, 2003, “Rational panics and stock market crashes,� Journal of Economic Theory 110(2), 234-263. Barth, J., G. Caprio, and R. Levine, 2008, “Bank regulation and supervision database,� The World Bank. Bartram, S., B. Gregory, and J. Hund, 2007, "Estimating systemic risk in the international financial system," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 86(3), 835-869 Battiston, S., D.D. Gatti, M. Gallegati, B.C. Greenwald, and J.E. Stiglitz, 2009, “Liaisons dangereuses: Increasing connectivity, risk sharing, and systemic risk,� National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 15611. Bharath, S. T., and T. Shumway, 2008. “Forecasting default with the Merton distance to default model,� Review of Financial Studies 21(3), 1339-1369. Beck, T., O. De Jonghe, and G. Schepens, 2011, “Bank competition and stability: cross-country heterogeneity,� Working Paper, Tilburg University. Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2006, “Bank concentration, competition, and crises: First results,� Journal of Banking and Finance 30(5), 1581-1603. Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine, 2010, “Financial institutions and markets across countries and over time: The updated financial development and structure database,� World Bank Economic Review 24 (1):77-92. 22 Bekaert, G., and X. Wang, 2009, “Globalization and asset prices�, Working Paper, Columbia University. Berger, A.N., L.F. Klapper, and R. Turk-Ariss, 2009, “Bank competition and financial stability,� Journal of Financial Services Research 35, 99-118. Bongini, P., L. Laeven, and G. Majnoni, 2002, “How good is the market at assessing bank fragility? A horse race between different indicators,� Journal of Banking and Finance (26)5: 1011-1028. Boot, A. W. A., and A. V. Thakor, 1993, “Self-interested bank regulation,� American Economic Review 83(2), 206-212. Boyd, J.H., and G. De Nicolo, 2005, “The theory of bank risk-taking and competition revisited,� Journal of Finance 60, 1329-1343. Boyd, J. H., and D. E. Runkle, 1993, “Size and performance of banking firms - testing the predictions of theory,� Journal of Monetary Economics 31(1), 47-67. Brunnermeier, M. K., 2009, “Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007-2008,� Journal of Economic Perspectives 23: 77-100. Campbell, J.Y., J. Hilscher, and J. Szilagyi, 2008, “In search of distress risk,� Journal of Finance 63, 2899-2939. Carletti, E., 2008, “Competition and regulation in banking,� in Handbook of Financial Intermediation and Banking, ed. by A. W. A. Boot, and A. V. Thakor. Elsevier, San Diego, pp. 449-482. Chan-Lau, J.A., and T. Gravelle, 2005. “The END: A new indicator of financial and nonfinancial corporate sector vulnerability,� IMF. Danielsson, J., H.S. Shin, and J.-P. Zigrand, 2009, “Risk appetite and endogenous risk,� Working paper, London School of Economics. Degryse, H., and S. Ongena, 2008, “Competition and regulation in the banking sector: A review of the empirical evidence on the sources of bank rents,� in Handbook of Financial Intermediation and Banking, ed. by A. W. A. Boot, and A. V. Thakor. Elsevier, San Diego, pp. 483-554. Dell’Ariccia, G., and R. Marquez, 2004, “Information and bank credit allocation,� Journal of Financial Economics, 72(1), 185-214. Demirguc-Kunt, A., and H. Huizinga, 2004, “Market discipline and deposit insurance,� Journal of Monetary Economics 51(2), 375-399. 23 Demirguc-Kunt, A., and E. Kane, 2002, “Deposit insurance around the globe: Where does it work?,�, Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(2), 175-195. Demirguc-Kunt, A., E.J. Kane, and L. Laeven, 2008, “Determinants of deposit-insurance adoption and design,� Journal of Financial Intermediation 17(3), 407-438. Demirguc-Kunt, A., and M.S. Martinez Peria, 2010, “A framework for analyzing competition in the banking sector: an application to the case of Jordan,� World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5499. Djankov, S., C. McLiesh, and A. Shleifer, 2007, “Private credit in 129 countries,� Journal of Financial Economics 84, 299-329. Elsinger, H., A. Lehar, and M. Summer, 2005, “Using market information for banking system risk assessment,� Working Paper, Austrian National Bank. Gennotte, G., and H. Leland, 1990, “Market liquidity, hedging, and crashes,� American Economic Review 80, 999-1021. Hakenes, H., and I. Schnabel, 2011, “Capital regulation, bank competition, and financial stability,� Economics Letters, forthcoming. Hauswald, R., and R. Marquez, 2006, “Competition and strategic information acquisition in credit markets,� Review of Financial Studies 19(3), 967-1000. Hellmann, T. F., K. C. Murdock, and J. E. Stiglitz, 2000, “Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: Are capital requirements enough?,� American Economic Review 90(1), 147-165. Hillegeist, S., E. Keating, D. Cram, and K. Lundstedt, 2004, “Assessing the probability of bankruptcy,� Review of Accounting Studies 9, 5-34. Huang, X., H. Zhou, and H. Zhu, 2009, “A framework for assessing the systemic risk of major financial institutions,� Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 2036-2049. Hong, H., and J. C. Stein, 2003, “Differences of opinion, short�sales constraints, and market crashes,� Review of Financial Studies 16(2), 487-525. Johnson, S., and J. Kwak, 2011, “13 bankers: The Wall Street takeover and the next financial meltdown,� Pantheon. Kane, E.J., 1989, “The S&I. insurance mess: How did it happen?,� The Urban Institute, Ann Arbor. Karolyi, G.A., K.-H. Lee, and M.A. Van Dijk, 2011, “Understanding commonality in liquidity around the world,� Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. 24 Keeley, M. 1990, “Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking,� American Economic Review 80, 1183-1200. Kodres, L. E., and M. Pritsker, 2002, “A rational expectations model of financial contagion,� Journal of Finance 57(2), 769-799. Laeven, L., and F. Valencia, 2008, “Systemic banking crises: A new database,� IMF Working Paper. Marcus, A.J., 1984, “Deregulation and bank financial policy,� Journal of Banking and Finance 8, 557-565. Martinez-Miera, D., and R. Repullo, 2010, “Does competition reduce the risk of bank failure?,� Review of Financial Studies 23(10), 3638-3664. Matutes, C., and X. Vives, 1996, “Competition for deposits, fragility, and insurance,� Journal of Financial Intermediation 5(2), 184-216. Merton, R. C., 1974, “On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates,� Journal of Finance 29, 449–470. Merton, R.C., 1977, “On the pricing of contingent claims and the Modigliani-Miller theorem,� Journal of Financial Economics 15, No. 2, 241-250. Morck, R., B. Yeung, and W. Yu, 2000, “The information content of stock markets: why do emerging markets have synchronous stock price movements?,� Journal of Financial Economics 58, 215-260. Pukthuanthong, K., and R. Roll, 2009, “Global market integration: An alternative measure and its application,� Journal of Financial Economics 94 (2), 214-232. Repullo, R., 2004, “Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking,� Journal of Financial Intermediation 13(2), 156-182. Schaeck, K., and M. Cihak, 2010, “Competition, efficiency, and soundness in banking: An industrial organization perspective,� European Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-20S. Schaeck, K., M. Cihak, and S. Wolfe, 2009, “Are competitive banking systems more stable?,� Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41(4), 711–734. Wagner, W., 2010, “Loan market competition and bank risk-taking,� Journal of Financial Services Research 37(1), 71-81. Yuan, K., 2005, “Asymmetric price movements and borrowing constraints: A rational expectations equilibrium model of crisis, contagion, and confusion�, Journal of Finance 60, 379 - 411. 25 Figure 1: Time series change in Lerner index This figure shows the evolution of Lerner index over time. Bank Market Power 1996-2009 Lerner Index 0.20 0.19 0.18 0.17 0.16 0.15 0.14 0.13 0.12 0.11 0.10 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Year Figure 2: Time series change in R-squared This figure shows the evolution of R-squared from a regression of a bank’s weekly change in distance to default on country average weekly change in distance to default (excluding the bank itself). R-squared 1997-2010 R-squared 0.250000 0.240000 0.230000 0.220000 0.210000 0.200000 0.190000 0.180000 0.170000 0.160000 0.150000 0.140000 0.130000 0.120000 0.110000 0.100000 0.090000 0.080000 0.070000 0.060000 0.050000 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Year 26 Table 1: Summary statistics To be included in the sample, we require a bank to have stock price information from Compustat Global/CRSP and financial information from Bankscope. Definitions of variables are in Appendix I. Panel A presents the summary statistics of all variables used in this study. Panel B presents the correlation matrix of bank level variables. Panel C presents the correlation matrix of country level variables. * indicates significance at the 5% level. Panel A: Summary statistics Variable n p5 p25 mean median p75 p95 sd risk 12,530 -7.211 -3.863 -2.550 -2.189 -0.883 0.609 2.557 lerner 11,332 -0.089 0.125 0.179 0.202 0.272 0.413 0.200 concen 12,493 0.212 0.231 0.437 0.352 0.574 0.875 0.216 size 12,530 5.495 6.685 8.221 7.915 9.577 11.998 1.986 leverage 12,530 0.795 0.891 0.901 0.914 0.936 0.963 0.073 mb 12,530 0.951 1.001 1.071 1.042 1.103 1.274 0.123 deposits 12,530 0.312 0.636 0.709 0.756 0.835 0.909 0.184 provision 12,530 -0.004 0.036 0.169 0.085 0.189 0.615 0.289 roa 12,530 -0.005 0.005 0.010 0.009 0.013 0.028 0.013 loggdppca 12,530 6.533 9.685 9.762 10.436 10.517 10.564 1.258 vargdpgr 12,530 0.402 0.813 1.489 1.256 1.627 3.757 1.267 logpop 12,530 15.494 17.684 18.408 18.991 19.487 19.534 1.438 trade_gdp 12,530 22.393 24.347 53.189 28.849 60.671 138.461 54.731 stmktcap 12,530 0.181 0.614 1.084 1.202 1.427 1.732 0.597 pcrdbofgdp 12,530 0.241 0.884 1.328 1.539 1.826 2.024 0.592 crisis 12,530 0.000 0.000 0.146 0.000 0.000 1.000 0.353 log_nbank 12,530 1.684 2.813 4.489 4.827 6.232 6.413 1.755 entry_bar 12,374 6.000 7.000 7.411 8.000 8.000 8.000 0.849 ap_denied 11,695 0.000 0.000 0.077 0.004 0.014 0.600 0.198 gov_own 12,316 0.000 0.000 0.076 0.000 0.042 0.440 0.161 foreign_own 11,885 0.035 0.050 0.137 0.085 0.190 0.479 0.143 covratio 11,251 0.810 1.890 3.160 2.670 2.890 4.910 16.585 activity_restriction 12,374 5.000 8.000 8.251 8.000 9.000 11.000 1.825 capital_stringency 12,374 3.000 5.000 5.169 5.000 5.000 7.000 1.015 supervisory_power 12,374 7.000 11.000 11.938 13.000 14.000 14.000 2.326 diversification_index 12,374 1.000 1.000 1.356 1.000 2.000 2.000 0.558 invest_protection 3,489 4.000 5.700 6.952 7.700 8.300 8.300 1.590 credit_info_depth 4,727 2.000 4.000 5.053 6.000 6.000 6.000 1.469 private_bureau 12,506 0.000 1.000 0.892 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.310 27 Panel B: Correlation matrix of bank level variables risk size leverage mb deposits provision roa lerner risk 1 size 0.3737* 1 leverage 0.1038* 0.3643* 1 mb -0.0478* -0.0700* -0.2669* 1 deposits 0.0099 -0.1504* 0.4039* -0.1112* 1 provision 0.0354* 0.1513* 0.0678* -0.1186* -0.0215* 1 roa 0.0096 -0.1263* -0.4982* 0.4508* -0.2375* -0.3623* 1 lerner 0.0705* 0.0269* -0.1379* 0.2715* -0.0131 -0.4611* 0.6919* 1 Panel C: Correlation matrix of country level variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 1 concen 1 2 entry_bar -0.0497* 1 3 ap_denied 0.2669* -0.0422* 1 4 gov_own 0.2153* -0.2700* 0.5135* 1 5 foreign_own 0.2737* 0.1536* 0.0203* 0.0393* 1 6 covratio 0.0237* 0.0335* 0.2073* -0.0154 0.1892* 1 7 activity_restriction -0.5104* -0.1699* -0.1172* -0.0561* -0.2690* -0.0449* 1 8 capital_stringency 0.1214* -0.0689* 0.0503* 0.0463* 0.0651* -0.0321* -0.0732* 1 9 supervisory_power -0.5820* 0.1109* -0.1684* -0.2174* -0.1198* -0.0380* 0.3304* -0.0320* 1 10 diversification_index -0.0250* -0.0034 0.0088 -0.1048* 0.1264* 0.0327* -0.3238* 0.0559* 0.0538* 1 11 invest_protection -0.5967* 0.2304* -0.3752* -0.5091* -0.2336* -0.0439* 0.0993* -0.1246* 0.3716* -0.1134* 1 12 credit_info_depth -0.4004* 0.2234* -0.4862* -0.5488* -0.2601* 0.0197 -0.1615* -0.2335* 0.2006* -0.0163 0.6229* 1 13 private_bureau -0.2069* 0.1143* -0.3545* -0.3800* -0.1446* -0.0045 0.0859* -0.0686* 0.1880* 0.0592* 0.4016* 0.7088* 28 Table 2: Sample distribution Panel A reports the sample distribution by calendar year and Panel B presents the sample distribution by country. Panel A: Sample distribution by calendar year Year Freq. Percent 1997 541 4.32 1998 596 4.76 1999 652 5.2 2000 693 5.53 2001 914 7.29 2002 932 7.44 2003 1,101 8.79 2004 1,175 9.38 2005 1,184 9.45 2006 1,245 9.94 2007 1,210 9.66 2008 1,180 9.42 2009 1,107 8.83 Total 12,530 100 Panel B: Sample distribution by country Country Name Freq. Percent ARGENTINA 63 0.5 AUSTRALIA 126 1.01 AUSTRIA 27 0.22 BAHRAIN 3 0.02 BANGLADESH 84 0.67 BELGIUM 37 0.3 BOTSWANA 20 0.16 BRAZIL 48 0.38 BULGARIA 4 0.03 CHILE 51 0.41 COLOMBIA 32 0.26 CROATIA 26 0.21 CYPRUS 23 0.18 CZECH REPUBLIC 18 0.14 DENMARK 340 2.71 EGYPT 62 0.49 FINLAND 25 0.2 FRANCE 231 1.84 GERMANY 202 1.61 GREECE 122 0.97 HONG KONG 143 1.14 HUNGARY 28 0.22 ICELAND 17 0.14 INDIA 216 1.72 INDONESIA 164 1.31 IRELAND 27 0.22 ISRAEL 51 0.41 ITALY 406 3.24 29 JAPAN 1,092 8.72 JORDAN 130 1.04 KENYA 64 0.51 KOREA REP. OF 106 0.85 KUWAIT 62 0.49 LITHUANIA 20 0.16 LUXEMBOURG 4 0.03 MALAYSIA 198 1.58 MAURITIUS 14 0.11 MEXICO 23 0.18 MOROCCO 38 0.3 NETHERLANDS 53 0.42 NIGERIA 96 0.77 NORWAY 93 0.74 OMAN 36 0.29 PAKISTAN 206 1.64 PERU 37 0.3 PHILIPPINES 129 1.03 POLAND 163 1.3 PORTUGAL 68 0.54 ROMANIA 16 0.13 SAUDI ARABIA 61 0.49 SINGAPORE 95 0.76 SOUTH AFRICA 129 1.03 SPAIN 182 1.45 SRI LANKA 49 0.39 SWEDEN 76 0.61 SWITZERLAND 204 1.63 THAILAND 220 1.76 TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO 2 0.02 TUNISIA 77 0.61 TURKEY 92 0.73 UNITED KINGDOM 209 1.67 USA 5,849 46.68 VENEZUELA 41 0.33 Total 12,530 100 30 Table 3: Competition and systemic risk: baseline results Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank_controlsijt-1 + Θ×country_controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + αi + λt + εijt, Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) VARIABLES risk risk size 0.250** 0.223** (0.108) (0.109) leverage -0.961 -1.408 (1.134) (1.232) mb -1.154*** -0.980** (0.406) (0.447) deposits -0.014 -0.057 (0.429) (0.461) provision -0.183 -0.176 (0.126) (0.153) roa 21.395*** 9.709* (3.954) (5.541) loggdppca -1.130 0.363 (1.054) (1.136) vargdpgr -0.042 -0.053 (0.033) (0.035) logpop -2.259 1.293 (1.561) (1.973) trade_gdp -0.010*** -0.003 (0.003) (0.003) stmktcap 0.233 -0.055 (0.155) (0.165) pcrdbofgdp -0.764*** 0.333 (0.197) (0.261) crisis 0.116 0.214* (0.105) (0.114) log_nbank 1.375*** 1.399*** (0.195) (0.213) lerner 1.179*** (0.303) Constant 46.067 -35.831 (28.765) (39.272) Observations 12,530 11,332 R-squared 0.437 0.424 31 Table 4: Competition policies and systemic risk Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×competitionijt-1×regulationjt- 1 + αi + λt + εijt. Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.223** 0.232** 0.230** 0.257** 0.255** 0.228** 0.225** 0.237** 0.239** (0.109) (0.110) (0.111) (0.118) (0.118) (0.111) (0.111) (0.114) (0.113) leverage -1.408 -1.303 -1.134 -1.232 -1.222 -1.472 -1.412 -1.258 -1.330 (1.232) (1.248) (1.265) (1.509) (1.506) (1.258) (1.259) (1.295) (1.286) mb -0.980** -1.000** -0.995** -0.903** -0.993** -1.135** -1.218*** -1.350*** -1.288*** (0.447) (0.449) (0.450) (0.455) (0.464) (0.451) (0.458) (0.456) (0.456) deposits -0.057 -0.098 -0.093 -0.441 -0.446 -0.047 -0.043 -0.205 -0.162 (0.461) (0.466) (0.466) (0.512) (0.511) (0.463) (0.463) (0.477) (0.479) provision -0.176 -0.161 -0.125 -0.227 -0.229 -0.156 -0.135 -0.156 -0.173 (0.153) (0.157) (0.152) (0.172) (0.174) (0.157) (0.157) (0.160) (0.161) roa 9.709* 9.990* 10.469* 11.678* 12.423** 10.567* 11.432** 10.500* 11.064* (5.541) (5.631) (5.511) (6.192) (6.300) (5.630) (5.654) (5.753) (5.771) loggdppca 0.363 0.098 0.083 -0.119 -0.126 0.532 0.551 1.121 1.166 (1.136) (1.167) (1.164) (1.247) (1.249) (1.163) (1.160) (1.207) (1.214) vargdpgr -0.053 -0.046 -0.047 -0.098** -0.111*** -0.039 -0.050 -0.008 -0.003 (0.035) (0.035) (0.036) (0.041) (0.042) (0.036) (0.037) (0.038) (0.038) logpop 1.293 1.460 1.587 4.435* 4.536* -0.157 -0.126 1.424 1.455 (1.973) (2.032) (2.045) (2.598) (2.602) (2.010) (2.025) (2.188) (2.191) trade_gdp -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 0.003 0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.010** -0.010** (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) stmktcap -0.055 0.053 0.053 -0.181 -0.170 0.049 0.034 -0.059 -0.049 (0.165) (0.180) (0.180) (0.218) (0.218) (0.177) (0.178) (0.201) (0.203) pcrdbofgdp 0.333 0.250 0.265 0.058 0.024 0.166 0.162 -0.339 -0.331 (0.261) (0.263) (0.264) (0.283) (0.285) (0.271) (0.271) (0.332) (0.332) crisis 0.214* 0.221* 0.220* 0.198* 0.203* 0.215* 0.217* 0.336*** 0.351*** (0.114) (0.117) (0.117) (0.120) (0.120) (0.116) (0.116) (0.124) (0.124) log_nbank 1.399*** 1.457*** 1.438*** 1.410*** 1.412*** 1.518*** 1.525*** 1.606*** 1.607*** (0.213) (0.215) (0.214) (0.227) (0.227) (0.216) (0.217) (0.226) (0.227) 32 lerner 1.179*** 1.163*** -1.513 1.136*** 1.239*** 1.150*** 1.369*** 1.192*** 1.502*** (0.303) (0.305) (2.004) (0.336) (0.351) (0.305) (0.346) (0.318) (0.373) entry_bar 0.029 -0.035 (0.085) (0.098) lerner_x_entry_bar 0.358 (0.262) ap_denied 1.058*** 1.116*** (0.258) (0.265) lerner_x_ap_denied -0.733 (0.565) gov_own 1.305** 1.544** (0.637) (0.673) lerner_x_gov_own -1.723 (1.234) foreign_own -0.235 0.266 (0.460) (0.495) lerner_x_foreign_own -2.645* (1.389) Constant -35.831 -37.026 -38.802 -89.781* -91.468* -11.130 -11.862 -45.387 -46.579 (39.272) (40.327) (40.562) (51.384) (51.387) (40.467) (40.716) (43.381) (43.349) Observations 11,332 11,178 11,178 10,562 10,562 11,129 11,129 10,734 10,734 R-squared 0.424 0.424 0.425 0.430 0.430 0.427 0.427 0.435 0.435 33 Table 5: Deposit insurance and systemic risk Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×competitionijt-1×regulationjt-1 + αi + λt + εijt. Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES risk risk risk size 0.223** 0.277** 0.274** (0.109) (0.121) (0.120) leverage -1.408 -2.106 -1.959 (1.232) (1.509) (1.512) mb -0.980** -1.215** -1.416*** (0.447) (0.505) (0.507) deposits -0.057 -0.250 -0.243 (0.461) (0.515) (0.515) provision -0.176 -0.229 -0.194 (0.153) (0.180) (0.178) roa 9.709* 12.810** 12.124* (5.541) (6.452) (6.402) loggdppca 0.363 -0.675 -1.156 (1.136) (1.258) (1.283) vargdpgr -0.053 -0.040 -0.069 (0.035) (0.043) (0.045) logpop 1.293 9.152*** 9.243*** (1.973) (2.657) (2.643) trade_gdp -0.003 0.013* 0.011 (0.003) (0.007) (0.007) stmktcap -0.055 -0.628** -0.681*** (0.165) (0.260) (0.257) pcrdbofgdp 0.333 0.151 0.141 (0.261) (0.286) (0.286) crisis 0.214* 0.083 0.040 (0.114) (0.124) (0.124) log_nbank 1.399*** 1.399*** 1.418*** (0.213) (0.241) (0.242) lerner 1.179*** 1.116*** -0.016 (0.303) (0.328) (0.453) covratio 0.143*** 0.091* (0.052) (0.051) lerner_x_covratio 0.535*** (0.166) Constant -35.831 -172.131*** -168.682*** (39.272) (52.515) (52.319) Observations 11,332 10,177 10,177 R-squared 0.424 0.418 0.419 34 Table 6: Bank supervision and systemic risk Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×competitionijt-1×regulationjt- 1 + αi + λt + εijt. Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.223** 0.248** 0.251** 0.227** 0.227** 0.232** 0.224** 0.227** 0.230** (0.109) (0.110) (0.110) (0.111) (0.111) (0.111) (0.111) (0.110) (0.110) leverage -1.408 -1.447 -1.350 -1.262 -1.267 -1.246 -1.240 -1.166 -1.281 (1.232) (1.252) (1.265) (1.250) (1.252) (1.250) (1.253) (1.248) (1.239) mb -0.980** -0.901** -0.838* -1.021** -1.020** -0.947** -0.951** -0.984** -1.051** (0.447) (0.456) (0.456) (0.451) (0.452) (0.450) (0.451) (0.450) (0.457) deposits -0.057 -0.069 -0.101 -0.093 -0.090 -0.119 -0.058 -0.169 -0.149 (0.461) (0.463) (0.464) (0.464) (0.468) (0.462) (0.465) (0.464) (0.463) provision -0.176 -0.147 -0.171 -0.159 -0.159 -0.156 -0.113 -0.165 -0.120 (0.153) (0.158) (0.159) (0.157) (0.158) (0.158) (0.155) (0.158) (0.164) roa 9.709* 9.972* 10.740* 10.163* 10.118* 9.984* 9.556* 9.964* 9.858* (5.541) (5.621) (5.660) (5.641) (5.732) (5.641) (5.620) (5.645) (5.648) loggdppca 0.363 0.173 0.210 0.086 0.087 0.082 0.144 -0.040 0.036 (1.136) (1.172) (1.173) (1.167) (1.169) (1.162) (1.163) (1.186) (1.191) vargdpgr -0.053 -0.055 -0.052 -0.048 -0.048 -0.049 -0.045 -0.038 -0.041 (0.035) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (0.037) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036) logpop 1.293 2.055 2.064 1.637 1.649 2.166 2.451 1.480 1.280 (1.973) (2.057) (2.058) (2.067) (2.077) (2.129) (2.154) (2.033) (2.057) trade_gdp -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.002 -0.003 (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) stmktcap -0.055 0.111 0.115 0.043 0.043 0.065 0.074 0.062 0.065 (0.165) (0.179) (0.179) (0.178) (0.178) (0.180) (0.181) (0.180) (0.179) pcrdbofgdp 0.333 0.200 0.195 0.214 0.215 0.289 0.309 0.147 0.126 (0.261) (0.268) (0.267) (0.269) (0.271) (0.270) (0.273) (0.266) (0.267) crisis 0.214* 0.208* 0.208* 0.225* 0.226* 0.208* 0.227* 0.209* 0.214* (0.114) (0.117) (0.117) (0.116) (0.116) (0.117) (0.116) (0.116) (0.116) log_nbank 1.399*** 1.394*** 1.373*** 1.470*** 1.470*** 1.432*** 1.431*** 1.574*** 1.596*** (0.213) (0.214) (0.214) (0.216) (0.216) (0.215) (0.215) (0.226) (0.227) 35 lerner 1.179*** 1.185*** 2.294*** 1.157*** 1.229 1.159*** -0.555 1.154*** 2.253*** (0.303) (0.306) (0.669) (0.306) (0.983) (0.307) (1.088) (0.306) (0.594) activity_restriction -0.058** -0.033 (0.027) (0.030) lerner_x_activity_restriction -0.151* (0.086) capital_stringency -0.027 -0.025 (0.046) (0.055) lerner_x_capital_stringency -0.014 (0.179) supervisory_power -0.051* -0.077** (0.029) (0.034) lerner_x_supervisory_power 0.154* (0.089) diversification_index -0.188** -0.014 (0.088) (0.107) lerner_x_diversification_index -0.875** (0.384) Constant -35.831 -47.927 -48.691 -39.751 -40.004 -49.144 -54.733 -36.077 -33.212 (39.272) (40.744) (40.671) (40.991) (41.312) (42.103) (42.711) (40.318) (40.623) Observations 11,332 11,178 11,178 11,178 11,178 11,178 11,178 11,178 11,178 R-squared 0.424 0.425 0.425 0.424 0.424 0.425 0.425 0.425 0.426 36 Table 7: Private monitoring and systemic risk Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×competitionijt-1×regulationjt- 1 + αi + λt + εijt. Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.223** 0.677* 0.593 0.661** 0.684** 0.234** 0.234** (0.109) (0.387) (0.401) (0.316) (0.320) (0.109) (0.110) leverage -1.408 -0.238 -0.466 0.015 -0.564 -1.399 -1.385 (1.232) (2.878) (2.801) (2.807) (2.733) (1.229) (1.233) mb -0.980** -0.992 -0.585 -1.307 -1.136 -1.000** -0.990** (0.447) (1.042) (1.047) (0.907) (0.897) (0.445) (0.445) deposits -0.057 -1.065 -0.852 -0.958 -0.849 -0.056 -0.057 (0.461) (0.998) (0.993) (0.926) (0.912) (0.463) (0.463) provision -0.176 -1.561*** -1.397*** -1.149*** -1.146*** -0.187 -0.190 (0.153) (0.423) (0.406) (0.327) (0.313) (0.154) (0.154) roa 9.709* 27.948** 29.788*** 25.210** 27.997*** 9.724* 9.600* (5.541) (12.107) (11.423) (9.837) (9.280) (5.566) (5.596) loggdppca 0.363 7.171 6.356 0.920 1.469 0.621 0.631 (1.136) (4.598) (4.515) (3.064) (3.153) (1.161) (1.163) vargdpgr -0.053 -0.221 -0.153 -0.102 -0.075 -0.051 -0.050 (0.035) (0.136) (0.120) (0.104) (0.106) (0.035) (0.035) logpop 1.293 -11.121 -7.234 -1.927 -3.281 1.680 1.685 (1.973) (9.422) (8.996) (8.263) (8.348) (1.982) (1.982) trade_gdp -0.003 -0.004 0.002 0.006 0.006 -0.002 -0.002 (0.003) (0.014) (0.014) (0.011) (0.011) (0.003) (0.003) stmktcap -0.055 0.166 0.083 0.674*** 0.725*** -0.089 -0.091 (0.165) (0.314) (0.319) (0.244) (0.244) (0.167) (0.168) pcrdbofgdp 0.333 -0.426 -0.386 -0.315 -0.466 0.287 0.290 (0.261) (1.203) (1.180) (0.803) (0.794) (0.268) (0.269) crisis 0.214* 0.063 -0.011 0.061 0.120 0.209* 0.208* (0.114) (0.218) (0.215) (0.188) (0.185) (0.115) (0.114) log_nbank 1.399*** 2.247*** 2.309*** 0.231 0.295 1.385*** 1.384*** (0.213) (0.780) (0.785) (0.600) (0.593) (0.214) (0.214) 37 lerner 1.179*** 0.118 -7.768*** 0.579 -4.462*** 1.185*** 1.279** (0.303) (0.745) (1.779) (0.554) (1.381) (0.305) (0.500) invest_protection -0.381 -0.359 (0.350) (0.427) lerner_x_invest_protection 1.073*** (0.244) credit_info_depth -0.184* -0.480*** (0.107) (0.139) lerner_x_credit_info_depth 0.916*** (0.243) private_bureau -0.296* -0.281 (0.164) (0.183) lerner_x_private_bureau -0.112 (0.478) Constant -35.831 124.167 59.929 20.398 41.547 -45.171 -45.427 (39.272) (187.084) (178.070) (164.333) (166.765) (39.725) (39.745) Observations 11,332 3,126 3,126 4,243 4,243 11,308 11,308 R-squared 0.424 0.659 0.668 0.587 0.591 0.424 0.424 38 Table 8: Concentration, regulation and systemic risk Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank controlsijt-1 + Θ×country controlsjt-1 + β1×concentrationjt-1 + β2×regulationjt-1 + β3×concentrationjt-1×regulationjt-1 + αi + λt + εijt. Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the bank level. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. Panel A: Baseline results (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES risk risk risk size 0.250** 0.322*** 0.507*** (0.108) (0.107) (0.062) leverage -0.961 -1.267 -1.902*** (1.134) (1.125) (0.652) mb -1.154*** -0.968** -0.575 (0.406) (0.403) (0.361) deposits -0.014 0.102 0.843*** (0.429) (0.422) (0.183) provision -0.183 -0.145 -0.389 (0.126) (0.126) (0.247) roa 21.395*** 21.824*** 17.158*** (3.954) (3.939) (4.059) loggdppca -1.130 -0.490 -0.601 (1.054) (1.033) (1.572) vargdpgr -0.042 -0.041 -0.036 (0.033) (0.033) (0.066) logpop -2.259 -1.741 -1.139 (1.561) (1.558) (2.833) trade_gdp -0.010*** -0.013*** -0.012** (0.003) (0.003) (0.005) stmktcap 0.233 0.124 0.060 (0.155) (0.155) (0.290) pcrdbofgdp -0.764*** -0.777*** -0.690 (0.197) (0.204) (0.542) crisis 0.116 0.041 0.050 (0.105) (0.106) (0.185) log_nbank 1.375*** 1.405*** 1.221*** (0.195) (0.194) (0.441) concen 2.882*** 2.912*** (0.441) (0.917) Constant 46.067 28.352 17.063 (28.765) (28.978) (53.118) Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Bank fixed effects Yes Yes No Country fixed effects No No Yes Observations 12,530 12,493 12,493 R-squared 0.437 0.440 0.287 39 Panel B: Competition policies (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.322*** 0.321*** 0.320*** 0.377*** 0.374*** 0.332*** 0.344*** 0.358*** 0.359*** (0.107) (0.109) (0.109) (0.116) (0.116) (0.109) (0.109) (0.110) (0.110) leverage -1.267 -1.135 -1.127 -1.278 -1.255 -1.363 -1.391 -1.178 -1.079 (1.125) (1.141) (1.141) (1.344) (1.345) (1.144) (1.144) (1.155) (1.153) mb -0.968** -1.040*** -1.042*** -0.882** -0.881** -1.161*** -1.135*** -1.341*** -1.370*** (0.403) (0.403) (0.402) (0.412) (0.411) (0.405) (0.406) (0.402) (0.402) deposits 0.102 0.121 0.122 -0.153 -0.161 0.103 0.101 -0.149 -0.167 (0.422) (0.428) (0.428) (0.478) (0.476) (0.422) (0.420) (0.427) (0.427) provision -0.145 -0.127 -0.127 -0.156 -0.156 -0.111 -0.110 -0.120 -0.120 (0.126) (0.128) (0.128) (0.135) (0.135) (0.127) (0.126) (0.129) (0.129) roa 21.824*** 21.993*** 21.998*** 23.265*** 23.231*** 21.565*** 21.478*** 22.128*** 21.963*** (3.939) (3.982) (3.979) (4.333) (4.335) (3.924) (3.920) (3.977) (3.957) loggdppca -0.490 -0.732 -0.809 -0.738 -0.718 -0.002 0.188 1.174 1.121 (1.033) (1.053) (1.069) (1.139) (1.143) (1.030) (1.054) (1.084) (1.066) vargdpgr -0.041 -0.034 -0.033 -0.101*** -0.103*** -0.031 -0.023 0.012 -0.001 (0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (0.038) (0.037) (0.033) (0.032) (0.034) (0.034) logpop -1.741 -1.621 -1.702 2.021 1.855 -3.533** -3.717** -1.061 -1.361 (1.558) (1.589) (1.598) (1.950) (2.030) (1.552) (1.546) (1.786) (1.790) trade_gdp -0.013*** -0.011*** -0.012*** -0.006 -0.006 -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.021*** -0.020*** (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) stmktcap 0.124 0.224 0.220 0.005 0.009 0.212 0.220 0.116 0.067 (0.155) (0.164) (0.163) (0.192) (0.193) (0.162) (0.162) (0.181) (0.186) pcrdbofgdp -0.777*** -0.835*** -0.858*** -0.968*** -0.960*** -0.846*** -0.861*** -1.532*** -1.484*** (0.204) (0.204) (0.203) (0.224) (0.225) (0.206) (0.205) (0.213) (0.215) crisis 0.041 0.065 0.073 0.036 0.038 0.071 0.064 0.283*** 0.252** (0.106) (0.106) (0.106) (0.111) (0.111) (0.106) (0.106) (0.106) (0.108) log_nbank 1.405*** 1.493*** 1.524*** 1.394*** 1.392*** 1.509*** 1.498*** 1.539*** 1.444*** (0.194) (0.196) (0.202) (0.204) (0.205) (0.195) (0.194) (0.202) (0.205) concen 2.882*** 2.942*** 1.611 3.036*** 2.880*** 2.736*** 3.228*** 2.714*** 3.336*** (0.441) (0.458) (1.939) (0.502) (0.579) (0.456) (0.475) (0.474) (0.552) entry_bar -0.069 -0.187 (0.083) (0.182) 40 concen_x_entry_bar 0.184 (0.254) ap_denied 1.112*** 0.709 (0.256) (0.964) concen_x_ap_denied 0.766 (1.709) gov_own 1.324** 4.117* (0.630) (2.283) concen_x_gov_own -4.634 (3.466) foreign_own -0.358 1.833* (0.438) (1.005) concen_x_foreign_own -3.561** (1.611) Constant 28.352 28.379 31.429 -39.346 -36.372 56.214* 57.431** 0.385 6.496 (28.978) (29.338) (30.097) (36.437) (37.646) (29.321) (29.125) (33.354) (33.244) Observations 12,493 12,337 12,337 11,658 11,658 12,279 12,279 11,848 11,848 R-squared 0.440 0.441 0.441 0.448 0.448 0.444 0.444 0.454 0.454 41 Panel C: Deposit insurance (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES risk risk risk size 0.322*** 0.387*** 0.386*** (0.107) (0.118) (0.118) leverage -1.267 -2.093 -2.056 (1.125) (1.385) (1.388) mb -0.968** -1.046** -1.054** (0.403) (0.453) (0.453) deposits 0.102 -0.025 -0.035 (0.422) (0.477) (0.478) provision -0.145 -0.222 -0.224 (0.126) (0.143) (0.144) roa 21.824*** 22.967*** 22.945*** (3.939) (4.569) (4.569) loggdppca -0.490 -1.280 -1.276 (1.033) (1.142) (1.141) vargdpgr -0.041 -0.040 -0.041 (0.033) (0.038) (0.038) logpop -1.741 5.662*** 5.743*** (1.558) (2.028) (2.027) trade_gdp -0.013*** 0.003 0.003 (0.003) (0.007) (0.007) stmktcap 0.124 -0.362 -0.365 (0.155) (0.229) (0.229) pcrdbofgdp -0.777*** -0.996*** -0.989*** (0.204) (0.231) (0.230) crisis 0.041 -0.086 -0.088 (0.106) (0.113) (0.113) log_nbank 1.405*** 1.365*** 1.374*** (0.194) (0.220) (0.220) concen 2.882*** 3.612*** 3.709*** (0.441) (0.502) (0.507) covratio 0.000 0.020** (0.002) (0.009) concen_x_covratio -0.032** (0.013) Constant 28.352 -101.243*** -102.906*** (28.978) (37.862) (37.830) Observations 12,493 11,214 11,214 R-squared 0.440 0.439 0.439 42 Panel D: Supervision (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.322*** 0.334*** 0.332*** 0.321*** 0.318*** 0.329*** 0.329*** 0.324*** 0.323*** (0.107) (0.108) (0.108) (0.109) (0.109) (0.109) (0.109) (0.108) (0.108) leverage -1.267 -1.191 -1.193 -1.086 -1.048 -1.125 -1.167 -1.021 -1.038 (1.125) (1.140) (1.140) (1.137) (1.137) (1.138) (1.127) (1.137) (1.140) mb -0.968** -0.985** -0.988** -1.063*** -1.055*** -0.984** -0.868** -0.980** -0.999** (0.403) (0.407) (0.406) (0.404) (0.405) (0.404) (0.405) (0.405) (0.406) deposits 0.102 0.103 0.105 0.090 0.098 0.077 0.058 -0.002 0.020 (0.422) (0.424) (0.424) (0.422) (0.425) (0.423) (0.422) (0.423) (0.424) provision -0.145 -0.127 -0.127 -0.129 -0.129 -0.130 -0.132 -0.143 -0.148 (0.126) (0.129) (0.129) (0.128) (0.128) (0.129) (0.129) (0.129) (0.129) roa 21.824*** 21.955*** 21.996*** 22.120*** 22.033*** 21.832*** 21.761*** 21.760*** 21.415*** (3.939) (3.987) (3.999) (3.982) (3.988) (3.984) (3.991) (3.994) (4.014) loggdppca -0.490 -0.731 -0.716 -0.680 -0.487 -0.774 -0.349 -0.816 -1.123 (1.033) (1.059) (1.047) (1.055) (1.050) (1.061) (1.076) (1.073) (1.089) vargdpgr -0.041 -0.039 -0.038 -0.044 -0.051 -0.038 -0.043 -0.026 -0.033 (0.033) (0.034) (0.034) (0.034) (0.034) (0.033) (0.034) (0.033) (0.033) logpop -1.741 -1.336 -1.267 -0.593 -0.223 -1.081 -0.401 -1.264 -1.398 (1.558) (1.614) (1.611) (1.689) (1.671) (1.686) (1.673) (1.604) (1.618) trade_gdp -0.013*** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.010** -0.011*** -0.011*** -0.010** -0.010** (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) stmktcap 0.124 0.262 0.260 0.198 0.178 0.247 0.249 0.237 0.261 (0.155) (0.163) (0.163) (0.162) (0.161) (0.165) (0.163) (0.163) (0.163) pcrdbofgdp -0.777*** -0.832*** -0.833*** -0.826*** -0.782*** -0.775*** -0.719*** -0.849*** -0.840*** (0.204) (0.208) (0.207) (0.203) (0.206) (0.206) (0.209) (0.199) (0.199) crisis 0.041 0.050 0.056 0.070 0.083 0.051 0.024 0.057 0.046 (0.106) (0.107) (0.106) (0.106) (0.107) (0.106) (0.107) (0.106) (0.107) log_nbank 1.405*** 1.436*** 1.447*** 1.463*** 1.507*** 1.441*** 1.416*** 1.582*** 1.518*** (0.194) (0.195) (0.203) (0.195) (0.197) (0.195) (0.192) (0.205) (0.207) concen 2.882*** 2.888*** 3.080*** 2.912*** 0.291 2.890*** -1.626 2.770*** 3.430*** (0.441) (0.451) (0.945) (0.450) (1.291) (0.453) (1.447) (0.448) (0.638) activity_restriction -0.022 -0.009 (0.026) (0.061) 43 concen_x_activity_restriction -0.024 (0.095) capital_stringency -0.089** -0.404*** (0.045) (0.151) concen_x_capital_stringency 0.505** (0.227) supervisory_power -0.030 -0.308*** (0.028) (0.095) concen_x_supervisory_power 0.412*** (0.130) diversification_index -0.234*** 0.011 (0.083) (0.162) concen_x_diversification_index -0.459 (0.283) Constant 28.352 22.871 21.321 8.972 1.542 18.671 5.112 21.871 27.345 (28.978) (29.822) (29.412) (31.201) (30.862) (31.104) (31.150) (29.274) (29.688) Observations 12,493 12,337 12,337 12,337 12,337 12,337 12,337 12,337 12,337 R-squared 0.440 0.441 0.441 0.441 0.442 0.441 0.442 0.442 0.442 44 Panel E: Private monitoring (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.322*** 0.657* 0.625* 0.858*** 0.855*** 0.338*** 0.345*** (0.107) (0.367) (0.367) (0.299) (0.298) (0.106) (0.106) leverage -1.267 0.549 0.607 0.716 0.727 -1.267 -1.414 (1.125) (2.908) (2.878) (2.655) (2.655) (1.118) (1.111) mb -0.968** -0.780 -0.677 -1.103 -1.113 -0.976** -0.935** (0.403) (1.083) (1.090) (0.766) (0.764) (0.400) (0.400) deposits 0.102 -1.231 -1.259 -1.277 -1.280 0.112 0.132 (0.422) (0.980) (0.967) (0.882) (0.882) (0.421) (0.422) provision -0.145 -1.183*** -1.179*** -0.637** -0.635** -0.153 -0.162 (0.126) (0.361) (0.361) (0.298) (0.298) (0.127) (0.127) roa 21.824*** 28.080*** 28.084*** 32.778*** 32.757*** 21.964*** 21.947*** (3.939) (10.116) (10.041) (7.605) (7.605) (3.953) (3.954) loggdppca -0.490 6.308 4.295 0.842 1.190 -0.090 -0.013 (1.033) (4.223) (4.411) (2.673) (2.821) (1.073) (1.067) vargdpgr -0.041 -0.200 -0.211* -0.256*** -0.254*** -0.040 -0.026 (0.033) (0.122) (0.123) (0.083) (0.083) (0.033) (0.032) logpop -1.741 -13.713* -14.028* 6.112 6.607 -1.159 -1.569 (1.558) (7.550) (7.948) (5.879) (6.124) (1.602) (1.586) trade_gdp -0.013*** -0.008 -0.009 0.011 0.011 -0.012*** -0.013*** (0.003) (0.013) (0.013) (0.011) (0.011) (0.003) (0.003) stmktcap 0.124 0.108 0.202 0.549** 0.571** 0.065 0.118 (0.155) (0.302) (0.331) (0.256) (0.264) (0.158) (0.159) pcrdbofgdp -0.777*** -0.872 -1.262 0.083 0.105 -0.827*** -0.846*** (0.204) (1.074) (1.094) (0.793) (0.793) (0.207) (0.207) crisis 0.041 0.110 0.053 0.254 0.260 0.042 0.035 (0.106) (0.194) (0.199) (0.169) (0.170) (0.106) (0.106) log_nbank 1.405*** 2.584*** 2.489*** 0.940* 0.961* 1.386*** 1.435*** (0.194) (0.736) (0.741) (0.517) (0.520) (0.194) (0.196) concen 2.882*** 3.297*** 9.068*** 6.194*** 5.275** 2.930*** -0.050 (0.441) (1.124) (3.020) (0.967) (2.437) (0.444) (1.011) invest_protection -0.564** 0.382 (0.222) (0.527) 45 concen_x_invest_protection -1.156** (0.568) credit_info_depth -0.243** -0.346 (0.098) (0.283) concen_x_credit_info_depth 0.206 (0.525) private_bureau -0.397** -2.123*** (0.158) (0.550) concen_x_private_bureau 3.185*** (0.976) Constant 28.352 178.374 199.160 -136.202 -148.357 14.058 22.333 (28.978) (145.284) (151.803) (113.199) (120.212) (30.584) (30.352) Observations 12,493 3,484 3,484 4,719 4,719 12,474 12,474 R-squared 0.440 0.679 0.680 0.614 0.614 0.441 0.442 46 Table 9: Alternative regression specifications Regression results of model riskijt = β0 + Ω×bank_controlsijt-1 + Θ×country_controlsjt-1 + β1×competitionijt-1 + εijt, Definitions of all variables are listed in Appendix I. Standard errors are reported in parentheses below their coefficient estimates and adjusted for both heteroskedasticity and within correlation clustered at the country level in columns (1), at the country-year level in column (2), and at the bank level in columns (3)-(6). Column (3) excludes banks in USA and Japan. Column (4) includes bank observations in 2010. Column (5) excludes bank-year observations prior to 2001. Column (6) drops countries with fewer than seven banks. *** (**) (*) indicates significance at 1% (5%) (10%) two tailed level, respectively. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) VARIABLES risk risk risk risk risk risk size 0.486*** 0.496*** 0.077 0.212** 0.365*** 0.215* (0.062) (0.044) (0.163) (0.103) (0.132) (0.116) leverage -1.947** -2.203*** -1.127 -1.763 -1.716 -1.250 (0.893) (0.716) (1.588) (1.135) (1.451) (1.214) mb -0.666* -0.378 -0.608 -0.977** -0.691 -1.122** (0.377) (0.344) (0.505) (0.434) (0.540) (0.476) deposits 0.591*** 0.552*** 0.538 -0.084 -0.495 -0.223 (0.184) (0.193) (0.595) (0.436) (0.525) (0.482) provision -0.274 -0.366 0.103 -0.078 -0.391* -0.289* (0.315) (0.246) (0.114) (0.142) (0.204) (0.159) roa 8.009* 5.419 7.748 10.956** 6.160 8.657 (4.254) (3.711) (4.928) (5.176) (6.107) (5.905) loggdppca -0.211 1.924 0.449 1.183 -1.302 (1.729) (1.174) (0.987) (1.610) (1.150) vargdpgr -0.048 -0.079** -0.051 0.021 -0.047 (0.071) (0.035) (0.034) (0.044) (0.041) logpop 2.146 2.210 1.956 0.668 0.683 (3.170) (2.042) (1.892) (2.583) (2.098) trade_gdp -0.002 0.001 -0.001 0.006 -0.003 (0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) stmktcap -0.052 0.042 -0.063 -0.069 0.113 (0.304) (0.165) (0.120) (0.222) (0.154) pcrdbofgdp 0.164 0.564* 0.675*** 0.826** 0.382 (0.436) (0.295) (0.240) (0.411) (0.274) crisis 0.260 0.074 0.203* 0.008 0.218* (0.225) (0.181) (0.113) (0.138) (0.120) log_nbank 1.236** -2.071 1.234*** 1.248*** 0.118 1.499*** 47 (0.503) (1.729) (0.232) (0.192) (0.238) (0.244) lerner 0.994*** 0.809** 0.740** 0.924*** 1.181*** 1.303*** (0.222) (0.389) (0.375) (0.268) (0.345) (0.319) Constant -47.620 4.564 -60.258 -48.726 -28.664 -9.127 (63.372) (7.877) (37.965) (36.981) (50.358) (42.235) Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Bank fixed effects No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Country fixed effects Yes No No No No No Country x year fixed effects No Yes No No No No Observations 11,332 11,332 5,238 12,131 9,020 10,510 R-squared 0.277 0.418 0.447 0.419 0.450 0.430 48 Appendix I. Variable definitions Time Variables Definitions Source period Dependent variables Logistic transformation of rsq (i.e.. log(rsq/(1-rsq))) , where rsq is r-squared Authors' calculation using bank from a regression of weekly change in distance to default on country data from Bankscope and stock risk 1997-2010 average weekly change in distance to default (excluding the bank in return information from question) by year. Compustat Global Bank level control variables Authors' calculation using bank size Log value of total assets in millions of US dollars. 1996-2010 data from Bankscope Authors' calculation using bank leverage Total liabilities divided by total assets. 1996-2010 data from Bankscope Authors' calculation using bank Market value of equity plus book value of debt, divided by book value of data from Bankscope and stock mb 1996-2010 total assets. return information from Compustat Global Authors' calculation using bank provision Loan loss provisions divided by net interest income. 1996-2010 data from Bankscope Authors' calculation using bank deposits Total deposits divided by total assets. 1996-2010 data from Bankscope Authors' calculation using bank roa Net income divided by total assets. 1996-2010 data from Bankscope Competition variables Financial Structure Dataset, concen Assets of three largest banks as a share of assets of all commercial banks. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt and 1960-2009 Levine (2010) Lerner index is equal to the difference between asset price and marginal Authors' calculation using bank lerner 1996-2010 cost, normalized by asset price. data from Bankscope Country level variables Competition Requirement on entry into banking, which is a variable constructed based 1999 on eight questions regarding required submission to obtain a banking Barth, Caprio, and Levine entry_bar ,2002, license. The variable ranges from zero (low entry barrier) to eight (high (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 entry barrier). 1999 The percentage of applications to enter banking denied in the past five Barth, Caprio, and Levine ap_denied ,2002, years. (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 49 1999 Barth, Caprio, and Levine gov_own The fraction of banks that are 50% or more owned by the government. ,2002, (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 1999 Barth, Caprio, and Levine foreign_own The fraction of banks that are 50% or more owned by foreign investors. ,2002, (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 1999 Deposit insurance ,2002, 2005 Deposit insurance coverage ratio, which is deposit insurance coverage Demirguc-Kunt, Kane, and covratio 1960-2003 divided by GDP per capita. Set to 1 if a country offers full coverage. Laeven (2008) Supervision A variable that ranges from zero to twelve, with twelve indicating the 1999 Barth, Caprio, and Levine activity_restriction highest restrictions on bank activities. (Unrestricted=1, Permitted=2, ,2002, (2000, 2003, 2008) Restricted=3, and Prohibited=4). 2005 A variable that captures both the overall capital stringency and the initial 1999 Barth, Caprio, and Levine capital_stringency capital stringency. It ranges from zero to eight, with a higher value ,2002, (2000, 2003, 2008) indicating higher capital stringency. 2005 1999 A variable that ranges from zero to fourteen, with fourteen indicating the Barth, Caprio, and Levine supervisory_power ,2002, highest power of the supervisory authorities. (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 1999 A variable that ranges from zero to two, with higher values indicating more Barth, Caprio, and Levine diversification_index ,2002, diversification. (2000, 2003, 2008) 2005 Private monitoring A variables that ranges from zero to ten, with higher values indicating World Banking Doing Business invest_protection 2004-2011 stronger investor protection. Survey A variable that ranges from zero to six, with higher values indicating deeper World Banking Doing Business credit_info_depth 2004-2011 credit information. Survey Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer An indicator variable that is equal to 1 if a private bureau operates in the private_bureau (2007) and World Banking 1978-2011 country and 0 otherwise. Doing Business Survey Country level control variables Authors' calculation using bank Log number of banks used to calculate country average weekly change in data from Bankscope and stock log_nbank 1996-2010 distance to default. return information from Compustat Global 50 A dummy variable that equals 1 if a country is experiencing a crisis in the Laeven Banking Crisis crisis 1976-2010 year and 0 otherwise. Database loggdppca Log value of GDP per capital in nominal constant US 2000 dollars. WDI 1960-2010 Author's calculation using WDI vargdpgr Variance of GDP growth for the previous five years. 1960-2010 data. logpop Log value of population in millions. WDI 1960-2010 trade_gdp Imports plus exports of goods and services as a percentage of GDP. WDI 1960-2010 Financial Structure Dataset, stmktcap Stock market capitalization divided by GDP. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and 1960-2009 Levine (2010) Financial Structure Dataset, Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions to pcrdbofgdp Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and 1960-2009 GDP. Levine (2010) 51