WPS5433 Policy Research Working Paper 5433 The Economic Impact of International Remittances on Poverty and Household Consumption and Investment in Indonesia Richard H. Adams, Jr. Alfredo Cuecuecha The World Bank East Asia and Pacific Region & Development Economics Department Development Prospects Group September 2010 Policy Research Working Paper 5433 Abstract This paper analyzes the impact of international with what they would have spent on this good without remittances on poverty and household consumption the receipt of remittances. Third, households receiving and investment using panel data (2000 and 2007) from remittances in 2007 spent less at the margin on one the Indonesian Family Life Survey. Three key findings important investment good--housing--compared with emerge. First, using an instrumental variables approach what they would have spent on this good without the to control for selection and endogeneity, it finds that receipt of remittances. Households receiving international international remittances have a large statistical effect remittances in Indonesia are poorer than other types on reducing poverty in Indonesia. Second, households of households, and thus they tend to spend their receiving remittances in 2007 spent more at the margin remittances at the margin on consumption rather than on one key consumption good--food--compared investment goods. This paper--a product of the East Asia and Pacific Region and the Development Prospects Group, Development Economics Department--is part of a larger effort in the department to understand the impact of remittances on poverty and economic development in the developing world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank. org. The author may be contacted at radams@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team The Economic Impact of International Remittances on Poverty and Household Consumption and Investment in Indonesia* Richard H. Adams, Jr.** and Alfredo Cuecuecha*** **Development Prospects Group (DECPG), MC2-622, World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433 E-Mail: radams@worldbank.org ***Universidad Iberoamericana Puebla, Economia y Negocios Blvd. Del Niño Poblano 2901, Unidad Territorial Atlixcayotl, CP 72430, Puebla, Puebla, México, E-Mail: 1lfredo.cuecuecha@iberopuebla.edu.mx *We would like to thank Ahmad Ahsan, Daniel Mont, Trang Nguyen, Ririn Purnamasari and participants at the June 2010 Meeting on "Cross-Border Labor Mobility in East Asia" in Singapore for useful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. 2 Remittances refer to the money and goods that are transmitted to households by migrant workers working outside of their origin communities, either in urban areas or abroad. At the start of the 21st century these resource transfers represent one of the key issues in economic development. While the total level of internal remittances in the developing world is unknown, in 2007 international remittances to the developing world amounted to US $239 billion (World Bank, 2008b). In that year the level of international remittances was about 50 percent larger than the level of official development aid to the developing world. From the standpoint of economic development, two key questions surround these large remittance flows: (a) What is the impact of international remittances on poverty and inequality in the developing world? and (b) How are these remittances spent or used by households in origin countries? Answers to these two key questions seem central to any attempt to evaluate the overall effect of migration and remittances on the developing countries of Latin America, Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa. In the past, a number of studies have found that international remittances tend to reduce poverty in developing countries. For example, using data from household surveys in 71 developing countries, Adams and Page (2005) find that, on average, a 10 percent increase in international remittances in a developing country will lead to a 3.5 percent decline in the share of people living in poverty. In a similar study using household survey data from 10 Latin American countries, Acosta et al (2006) find that international remittances reduce poverty by 0.4 percent for each percentage point increase in the remittances to GDP ratio. Finally, at the country level, 3 Lopez-Cordova (2005) in Mexico, Lokshin et al (2010) in Nepal and Adams, Cuecuecha and Page (2008) in Ghana all find that international remittances reduce poverty. On the issue of how international remittances are spent or used by households, the literature is not as clear. There are at least three views on how remittances are spent and their effect on economic development. The first, and probably most widespread, view is that remittances are fungible and are spent at the margin like income from any other source. In other words, a dollar of remittance income is treated by the household just like a dollar of wage income, and remittance income is spent just like any other source of income. The second view argues that the receipt of remittances can cause behavioral changes at the household level and that remittances tend to get spent on consumption rather than investment goods. For example, a review of the literature by Chami, Fullenkamp and Jahjah (2003:10-11) reports that a "significant proportion, and often the majority" of remittances are spent on "status-oriented" consumption goods. A third, and more recent, view arising out of the permanent income hypothesis is that since remittances are a transitory type of income households tend to spend them more at the margin on investment goods -- human and physical capital investments ­ than on consumption goods, and that this can contribute positively to economic development (Adams, 1998). For instance, in a study of remittances and education in El Salvador, Edwards and Ureta (2003) find that international remittances (mainly from the USA) have a large positive impact on student retention rates in school. In a similar study in the Philippines, Yang (2008) reports that positive exchange rate shocks lead to a significant increase in remittance expenditures on education. The purpose of this paper is to extend the debate concerning the impact of international remittances on poverty and how remittances are spent or used by households by analyzing the results of a large, panel household budget survey in Indonesia. Indonesia represents a good case 4 study for examining these issues because the country produces a large number of international migrants to Malaysia, Saudi Arabia and other countries.1 Also, the presence of panel household data from Indonesia makes it possible to overcome several of the methodological problems ­ simultaneity, reverse causality, and omitted variable bias ­ that bedevil any economic work on international remittances. At the outset it should be emphasized that even with the presence of panel data this analysis of the impact of remittances on poverty and household expenditures is not without certain methodological problems. One obvious issue is that of selection, that is, households receiving remittances might have unmeasured characteristics (e.g. more skilled, able or motivated members) which are different from households not receiving remittances. If these unmeasured characteristics are constant through time, the use of panel data methodologies can eliminate the bias that they produce in estimating the impact of remittances. But if the unmeasured characteristics change over time, then it is still important to address the problem of selection in unobservable characteristics. We meet this concern by using a three-stage nested logit model to test for selection bias in the household receipt of remittances. The identification of this model is based on the use of instrumental variables. Since past research has found that historical distance to railroad lines and changes in rainfall patterns are important in the receipt of international remittances (e.g. Adams and Cuecuecha, forthcoming; Woodruff and Zenteno, 2007; Munshi, 2003), our identification strategy focuses on these variables. This instrumental approach enables us to control for selection and to do two things. First, we use the third-stage of the nested logit model to predict two types of income for households receiving remittances: a) the income conditional on their household characteristics and their receipt of remittances (predicted income); and b) the income conditional on their household 5 characteristics and on the hypothetical condition where they do not receive remittances (counterfactual incomes). We then use these predicted and counterfactual household incomes to compare the level of poverty and inequality in Indonesia with and without remittances. Second, we use the model to rigorously compare the marginal spending behavior of two groups of households: those with no remittances and those receiving international remittances. Since all survey households are separated into one of these two groups, it becomes possible to compare how remittance- and non-remittance receiving households spend at the margin on a broad range of consumption and investment goods, including food, education and housing. The paper proceeds in eight further parts. Section 1 presents the data. Since the problems of selection and identification are so important, Section 2 presents the three-stage nested logit model and discusses the various identification issues involved in estimating this model. Section 3 estimates the selection model using an instrumental variables approach, employing variations in historical distance to the nearest railroad station and changes in rainfall patterns. Section 4 estimates the selection-corrected predicted and counterfactual expenditure functions, and Section 5 uses these expenditure functions to analyze the impact of international remittances on poverty and inequality in Indonesia. Section 6 presents the model for comparing the marginal spending behavior of remittance and non-remittance receiving households, and Section 7 presents the results of this model. Section 8 concludes. 1. Data Set The data come from the Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS), an on-going panel household survey in Indonesia. The IFLS Survey includes four waves of surveying, IFLS 1 (1993), IFLS 2 (1997), IFLS 3 (2000) and IFLS 4 (2007). However, since this paper is on 6 remittances, and consistent definitions of remittance variables could not be developed for all four waves of the IFLS survey, the focus here is on the last two waves of the survey, IFLS 3 (2000) and IFLS 4 (2007). These two waves include a total of 5,301 urban and rural households. While the IFLS Survey was never designed to be nationally representative, the last two waves of the survey do include households from 19 of Indonesia's 33 provinces. In terms of data collected, the IFLS Survey was comprehensive, collecting detailed information on a wide range of topics, including expenditure, education, health, nutrition, financial assets, household enterprises and remittances. It should, however, be emphasized that the IFLS Survey was not designed as a migration or remittances survey. In fact, it collected very limited information on these topics. With respect to international migration, the survey collected only limited information on migrants who have been gone from the household for more than one year: their age, education or income earned away from home.2 This means that limited data are available on the characteristics of most international migrants who are currently living outside of the household. With respect to international remittances, the IFLS Survey only contains information from three types of questions: (1) Does your household receive remittances from spouse, parents or children? (2) Where do these people sending remittances live? and (3) How much (remittance) money did your household receive in the past 12 months? The lack of data on individual migrant characteristics in the IFLS survey is unfortunate, but the presence of detailed information on remittances and household expenditures makes it possible to use responses in the survey to examine the impact of remittances on poverty, inequality and household expenditure behavior. Since the focus here is on remittances, it is important to clarify how these income transfers are measured and defined. Each household that is recorded as receiving international 7 remittances is assumed to be receiving exactly the amount of remittances measured by the survey. This means that households which have migrants who do not remit are not recorded in this study as receiving remittances; rather these households are classified as non-remittance receiving households. This assumption seems sensible because migration surveys in other countries generally find that about half of all migrants do not remit.3 Because of data limitations, the focus throughout this study is on the receipt of international remittances by the household rather than on migration or the type of person sending remittances. Finally, international remittances include both cash and in-kind remittances. The inclusion of in-kind remittances (food and non-food goods) is important because it leads to a more accurate measure of the actual flow of remittances to households in Indonesia. Table 1 presents summary data from IFLS 3 (2000) and IFLS 4 (2007). It shows that the number of households receiving international remittances in Indonesia is fairly small: in 2000, 169 households (3.2 percent of all households) receive remittances, and in 2007, 179 households (3.3 percent of all households) receive remittances.4 According to the table, households receiving international remittances in Indonesia have older household heads, have fewer household members with high school and university education, and are more likely to be located in rural areas. Households receiving international remittances also tend to have lower mean per capita expenditures than households without remittances. For households receiving remittances, remittances represent 26.0 percent of total household expenditures in 2000 and 29.0 percent of expenditures in 2007. However, since households receiving international remittances in Indonesia also have low levels of expenditure, the absolute amount of remittances received in annual per capita terms by households is quite low: not exceeding US $30 in either year.5 8 Table 2 shows the distribution of households receiving international remittances by province in Indonesia. The data show that the share of households receiving remittances is fairly small in all provinces except for one rural province: West Nusa Tenggara. In terms of mean annual per capita household expenditures, West Nusa Tenggara province is also one of the poorest provinces in the sample. 2. An Econometric Model of Household Incomes with Selection Controls Since most poverty economists use expenditure rather than income data to identify poverty,6 it is tempting to use the mean per capita expenditure figures from Tables 1 and 2 to conclude that households receiving international remittances in Indonesia are more likely to be poor.7 However, it is important to realize that these expenditure figures are "naïve" and cannot be used to evaluate the "real" effect of remittances on poverty in Indonesia. Households have both observed and unobserved characteristics. Since the expenditure results in Tables 1 and 2 may be caused by the unobserved characteristics of households (e.g. skills, motivation, ability), it is important to use special econometric techniques to identify the impact of these unobservables in order to pinpoint the "real" impact of remittances on expenditures and poverty in Indonesia. Specifically, it is necessary to estimate a counterfactual scenario in which we estimate the expenditures for households that receive international remittances, and then compare these expenditures with an unobserved scenario in which these households do not receive remittances. Constructing such a counterfactual can be done by treating households with no remittances as a random draw from the population, estimating a mean regression of incomes for these no- remittance households, and then using the resulting parameter estimates to predict the incomes of households with international remittances. However, this approach becomes problematic if 9 households with and without remittances differ systematically in their unobservable characteristics (e.g. skills, motivation, ability), because then the regression results will be biased. The approach followed in this paper is to estimate an equation for households receiving international remittances, taking into account in the estimation the selection bias. This kind of approach is based on a selection model developed by Dubin and McFadden (1984) and Bourguignon, Fournier and Gurgand (2004).8 The estimation strategy of this paper is to use a three-stage model to estimate counterfactual expenditures for households receiving remittances taking into account selection bias. The first-stage uses a nested logit with instrumental variables to estimate the probability of households receiving remittances. The second-stage uses a generalization of the Dubin and McFadden model (1984) to estimate selection-corrected household expenditures with and without remittances. The third stage estimates the value of the fixed effects and undifferenced selection terms. More specifically, our estimation strategy can be developed as follows. Our panel data from Indonesia is for two years (2000 and 2007) and this gives us certain advantages over simple cross-sectional data. For example, we know whether households have chosen to receive remittances in each of four states: (1) no remittances in either year; (2) remittances in 2000 but not in 2007; (3) remittances in both years, 2000 and 2007; and (4) remittances in 2007 but not in 2000. Moreover, some of the characteristics of our households are fixed, and thus do not change according to their remittance situation, while other unobservable characteristics change depending on how the households choose between the four states. For example, assume that in time period 1, households can select between two states (r): (1) receive no remittances; (2) receive remittances. Once households have chosen their state, they decide their level of expenditure ytr, where ytr is the optimal expenditure for households that 10 chose r=r. At time period 2, conditional on their state (r), they can again select between two states (r): (1) receive no remittances; (2) receive remittances. Once households have chosen their state, they decide their level of expenditure ytr. We assume that this decision tree is represented by a nested logit process. Moreover, we assume that at time 1 there are two expenditure equations: Ytri = r(1-d2) + arX1i+i+utri (1) Where d2 is a dummy that is 1 for time period 2, and it is zero for time period 1. i represents the individual fixed effect. From this point on, we will not mention the subscript for household i in the paper. For time period 2, this decision structure generates the four types of households mentioned above: (1) those that never receive remittances; (2) those that switch from not having remittances in 2000 to receiving remittances in 2007; (3) those that always receive remittances; and (4) those that switch from receiving remittances in 2000 to not receiving them in 2007. For households that do not switch in their remittance state between 2000 and 2007 (i.e. households (1) and (3)) we can obtain the first difference and get: Yr = r +a rX + ur (2) Under the assumption of a nested logit, it can be shown that ur can be represented as a linear combination of all available possibilities at the final stage of the nested logit tree: Yr = r +a rX + +vr (3) Where the represent the probabilities of all final possibilities at the final stage of the nested logit tree, with the exception of option r. Equation (3) implies that we can estimate the coefficients for the expenditure equation of households that select option r and never switch their remittance state based only on the observations of such households. 11 For households that switch their remittance state between 2000 and 2007 we can write the first difference as: Y2r- Y1r' = - r' +arX2i-ar'X1i +ur -ur' (4) There are only k=2 transitions that can be made in the model: (1) from receiving no remittances in 2000 to having remittances in 2007; and (2) from receiving remittances in 2000 to not receiving them in 2007. Finally, and given that ur -ur' represents one of the final possibilities in the nested logit, we represent our equation as: Yk = k + kX + +vk (5) Consequently, we can estimate how the switches in remittance states are correlated to the characteristics of the households. Moreover, the levels of expenditures for households in 2000 can be obtained as follows: E(Y1r |X) = r+ arX1+i+E(u1r |X) (6) For the case of households that do not switch their remittance state (that is, never receive remittances or receive remittances in both years), the equation for their expected income in 2007 is: E(Y2r|X) = arX1+i+ E(u1r |X) + a rX + (7) For the case of households that switch their remittance state (that is, switch from not receiving remittances to receiving remittances, or vice versa) the equation for their expected income in 2007 is: E(Y2k|X) = arX1+i+ E(u1r |X) + kX + (8) Notice that equations (6), (7) and (8) give us two elements that need to be determined simultaneously i and E(u1r |X). This is done using a search procedure where we use the fact 12 that we have a nested logit to express E(u1r |X) =rpr. The search procedure consists in finding a set of r and i that simultaneously satisfy equations (6), (7) and (8). To implement our estimation, the first stage model consists in estimating the probabilities to be in any part of the decision tree in 2000 and 2007, using a nested logit specification. To identify this part of the model, we need instrumental variables that enter the first stage model, but not the second stage. In our case, these instrumental variables are three: (1) the distance from kabupaten (district) to railroad station in 1930; (2) the level of rainfall in 1995-1999; and (3) unexpected rainfall in 2000.9 Our rationale for using these three instrumental variables is as follows. The first railroad line in Indonesia opened in 1867. A continuous railroad line between Jakarta and Surabaya, the two largest cities in Java, opened in 1894. Between 1900 and 1930 smaller railroad lines were constructed in Madura, Sumatra and South Celebes. In Indonesia distance to railroad lines in 1930 represents a good instrumental variable because it is related to migration costs in the past and to the need for sending migrants in the past, and therefore to the development of present day migrant social networks, but it is not correlated with the expenditure patterns of households at the time of the 2000 and 2007 IFLS Surveys. We calculated distance to railroad lines for each household using the distance from the kabupaten (district) to the nearest railroad station in 1930, using historical maps from the Indonesian Railway Authority, and then cross-checking this information with the IFLS Surveys. This type of instrument has been used before in the literature by Woodruff and Zenteno (2007) for the case of Mexico, and Adams and Cuecuecha (forthcoming) for the case of Guatemala. Changes in rainfall have also been used before in the literature as an instrumental variable in the cases of Mexico, the Philippines, and Guatemala (Munshi, 2003; Yang and Choi, 2007; 13 Adams and Cuecuecha, forthcoming). The argument here is that rain is closely correlated with agricultural production and income, and so too little rain in one or several years may cause people to migrate out of rural areas. For this reason, changes in historical rain are correlated with the formation of migrant networks and with the receipt of remittances, but changes in historical rain are not correlated with unobserved changes in consumption patterns. We obtained historical rainfall information at the meteorological station level in Indonesia from the IFLS data. We then calculated the average level of rainfall for the year 2000 and the average level of rainfall for the period 1995 to 1999 by district. From this information we estimated a model in which the level of rainfall for the year 2000 is related to the level of rainfall for the period 1995 to 1999. We then used the residuals from this model as the unexpected rainfall shock in 2000. Our argument here is that changes in migration patterns and the receipt of remittances are influenced by both the unexpected part of rainfall in 2000 as well as the actual level of rainfall for 1995 to 1999, since both variables are exogenous at the beginning of the decision process estimated with our data. For the three instrumental variables, our claim is that conditional on the set of human capital, household and district characteristics included in our specification, the unobserved components in the expenditure equation of the households are uncorrelated with the three instruments. The second stage of our model estimates equation (3) and (5) using a generalization of the Dubin and McFadden method, assuming a nested logit specification for the probabilities needed in estimation. The third stage of our model consists in estimating the values of the fixed effects. To obtain the fixed effects we implement a search method using the following three steps. First, we 14 use the values of equations (3) and (5) in equations (6), (7) and (8) to obtain values for the fixed effects and to obtain the average. In this first step we assume that =1. Second, we obtain r and i from the regressions (9), (10) and (11): Y1ri - r - arX1i = i0 + pri +1 (9) Y2ri - arX1 - a rX - = i0 + rpri + 2 (10) Y2ri - arX1 - kX - = i0 + rpri + 2 (11) We then re-estimate the fixed effect for the above equations and obtain a new average i1, and compare it to the previous fixed effect. If the difference between i1 and i0 is above a threshold, we repeat the procedure. Third, once differences are lower than a threshold (i.e. convergence is achieved) we declare our estimations for the fixed effects and r to be our final estimations for those parameters. On the basis of the preceding, our estimated expenditure for households that do not switch their remittance state (that is, never receive remittances or receive remittances in both years) is given by: E(Y2r|X) = arX1+i+ rpri + a rX + (12) For the case of households that switch their remittance state (that is, switch from not receiving remittances to receiving remittances, or vice versa) the equation for their expected income in 2007 is: E(Y2k|X) = arX1+i+ rpri + kX + (13) In the third stage of the model we also obtain the following two counterfactuals:10 1. The first counterfactual compares households receiving remittances in both years (2007 and 2000) with their counterfactual income should they have switched from 15 receiving remittances in 2000 to not receiving remittances in 2007. Therefore, we use for the counterfactual the equation for households that receive remittances in 2000, but not in 2007. 2. The second counterfactual compares households receiving remittances in 2007 but not in 2000 with their counterfactual income should they have not have received remittances in 2007. Therefore, we use for the counterfactual the equation for households that did not receive remittances in 2000, and that did not receive remittances in 2007. 3. Estimating the Econometric Model with Selection Controls Table 3 shows the results for the first-stage nested logit. The tree structure for the nested logit assumes that households plan first whether or not to receive international remittances in 2000 and then conditional on their choice in 2000, choose their remittance state in 2007. In the initial tree branch it is assumed that all variables are the ones shown in the table plus a dummy variable for urban/rural areas and dummy variables for four Indonesian regions. The only variable in the bottom branch of the nested logit is the instrumental variable, distance from kabupaten (district) to railroad in 1930. The nested logit is estimated by partitioning the data by the variable, age of household head, to help the equation converge. In Table 3 two of the household characteristics are significantly related to the receipt of remittances in 2007: age of household head and sex of household head. The sign on the age of household head variable suggests that as the age of head increases, households are less likely to receive remittances. The sign on the sex of household head variable suggests that female-headed households are more likely to receive remittances. 16 In Table 3 one of the instrumental variables, distance from kabupaten (district) to railroad, is also negatively and significantly related to the receipt of remittances in 2007. This suggests that households living further away from a railroad in 1930 are less likely to receive international remittances in 2007. Table 4 shows the results for the second-stage expenditure equation. This table is based on a fixed-effects estimation and partitions the households into the previously-discussed four groups: (1) households never receiving remittances; (2) households receiving remittances in 2000 but not in 2007; (3) households not receiving remittances in 2000 but receiving in 2007; and (4) households receiving remittances in both years. With respect to the household characteristic variables, many of the coefficients are statistically significant and suggest (as expected) that households with older household heads and more children under age 5 have lower per capita expenditures. The selection term in Table 4 is the variable. This selection term is statistically significant only for households that never receive remittances. This result suggests that some unobserved household characteristics change over time for households that never receive remittances.11 4. Estimating Predicted and Counterfactual Expenditure Functions This section discusses how counterfactual expenditure estimates for households can be developed by using predicted expenditure equations to identify the expenditures of households with and without international remittances. The methodology for obtaining these estimates follows the literature on the evaluation of programs for the case in which instrumental variables are available (Maddala, 1983; Wooldridge, 2002). 17 The methodology includes three steps. First, we start with observed expenditures, meaning the levels of expenditures reported by households in the survey. Second, we obtain predicted expenditures for households receiving remittances conditional on their household characteristics and their choice of receiving remittances. Third, we obtain counterfactual expenditures for households receiving remittances conditional on their household characteristics and the hypothetical condition in which they do not receive remittances. We then use pairwise Average Treatment Effects on the Treated (ATT) to compare counterfactual expenditures for households receiving remittances using the following two steps. 1. The first ATT compares households receiving remittances in both years (2007 and 2000) with their counterfactual expenditure should they have switched to not receiving remittances in 2007. Therefore, we use for the counterfactual the equation for households that receive remittances in 2000, but not in 2007. The counterfactual equation in this case is given by:12 E(YCF2k|X) = arX1+i+ rpri + kX + (14) Therefore, the effect of remittances on income, conditional on X is given by (that is, by subtracting equation 14 from equation 12): E(Y2r|X) - E(YCF2k|X) = (a r- k)X + (15) 2. The second ATT compares households receiving remittances in 2007 but not in 2000 with their counterfactual expenditure should they have not received remittances in 2007. Therefore, we use for the counterfactual the equation for households that did 18 not receive remittances in 2000, and did not receive remittances in 2007. The counterfactual equation in this case is given by: E(YCF2r|X) = arX1+i+ rpri + a rX + (16) Therefore, the effect of remittances on expenditure for these households is given by (that is, subtracting equation 16 from equation 13): E(Y2k|X) - E(YCF2r|X) = ( k- a r)X + (17) 5. Expenditures, Remittances and Poverty Table 5 reports observed, predicted and counterfactual expenditures for the four groups of households: households never receiving remittances, households receiving remittances in 2000 but not in 2007, households not receiving remittances in 2000 but receiving in 2007, and households receiving remittances in both years. On the basis of these expenditure levels, the table also reports levels of poverty based on a 2007 national poverty line for Indonesia of 308,000 rupiah/person/year at 2000 prices for urban households, and 235,500 rupiah/person/year at 2000 prices for rural households.13 Three different poverty measures appear in Table 5. The first measure -- the poverty headcount -- shows the percent of the population living beneath the poverty line. However, this headcount index ignores the "depth of poverty," that is, the amount by which the average expenditure of the poor fall short of the poverty line. The table therefore reports a second measure, the poverty gap. This index measures in percentage terms how far the average expenditures of the poor fall short of the national poverty line. The third poverty measure -- the squared poverty gap ­ shows the "severity of poverty." The squared poverty gap index possesses useful analytical properties, because it is sensitive to changes in distribution among the poor. In 19 other words, while a transfer of expenditures from a poor person to a poorer person will not change the headcount index or the poverty gap index, it will decrease the squared poverty gap index.14 Columns (1) and (2) of Table 5 show that households which never receive international remittances have mean per capita expenditures that situate them in the middle of the expenditure distribution of Indonesia. For this reason, households which never receive remittances have the lowest amount of observed poverty on average in the table. By contrast, columns (8) and (9) show that households which receive international remittances in both years (2000 and 2007) have the lowest mean per capita expenditures in the table and the highest rates of observed poverty on average in the table. In Table 5 it is possible to identify the impact of remittances on poverty by comparing the results for predicted poverty values with those for counterfactual poverty. Specifically, for households receiving remittances in 2007, but not in 2000, it is possible to compare predicted poverty in column (6) with counterfactual poverty in column (7), and for households receiving remittances in both years (2000 and 2007) columns (9) and (10) can be compared. Results suggest that for households receiving remittances in 2007, but not in 2000, the receipt of remittances increases the poverty headcount by 35.3 percent, but that for households receiving remittances in both 2000 and 2007 the receipt of remittances decreases the poverty headcount by 75.9 percent. While these results may appear contradictory and inconclusive, when we calculate overall Average Treatment Effects on the Treated (ATT) the effect of receiving remittances on poverty becomes clearer.15 In calculating the overall ATT we average the poverty results for households receiving remittances in both years with the poverty results for households receiving remittances 20 only in 2007. This overall ATT uses the ATT for households receiving remittances in 2007 and compares it to the counterfactual that would occur if these households did not receive remittances in 2007. Results for the overall ATT in column (11) in Table 5 show that all three of the poverty measures ­ poverty headcount, poverty gap and squared poverty gap -- show a large and statistically significant decrease. According to column (11), the poverty headcount declines by 26.7 percent, the poverty gap falls by 55.3 percent and the squared poverty gap falls by 69.9 percent. On the basis of these findings, international remittances appear to have a large, statistical effect on reducing poverty in Indonesia However, Table 5 shows that international remittances increase income inequality in Indonesia. For households receiving remittances in 2007, but not in 2000, the Gini coefficient of inequality falls by 3.5 percent with the receipt of remittances, while for households receiving remittances in both years (2000 and 2007) the Gini coefficient rises by 1.7 percent. In column (11) the overall ATT for the Gini coefficient shows that the Gini increases by 2.3 percent, and that this increase is statistically significant. 6. Estimating the Marginal Expenditure Behavior of Households Since we want to examine the impact of remittances on expenditures, it is important to present the type of expenditure data contained in the IFLS Survey (2000 and 2007). Table 6 shows that the survey collected detailed information on five major categories of expenditure, and on several subdivisions within each category. While the time base over which these expenditure outlays were measured varied (from last 7 days for most food items, to last year for most durable goods), all expenditures were aggregated to obtain yearly values. For household durables (stove, refrigerator, automobile, etc), annual use values were calculated to obtain an estimate of the cost 21 of one year's use of that good. Annual use values were also calculated to obtain an estimate of the one year use value of housing (rented or owned). Table 6 also shows the average budget shares devoted to the five categories of goods for each of the four groups of households. On average, each of the four groups of households spends over 53 percent of their budgets on one key consumption item ­ food ­ and less than 6 percent of their budgets on education. The purpose of this section is to analyze the marginal expenditure patterns of remittance- receiving and non-receiving households, and to do this it is necessary to choose a proper functional form for the econometric model. The selected functional form must do several things. First, it must provide a good statistical fit to a wide range of goods, including food, housing and education. Second, the selected form must mathematically allow for rising, falling or constant marginal propensities to spend over a broad range of goods and expenditure levels. A model specification that imposes the same slope (or marginal budget share) at all levels of expenditure would not be adequate. Third, the chosen form should conform to the criterion of additivity (i.e. the sum of the marginal propensities for all goods should equal unity). One useful functional form which meets all of these criteria is the Working-Leser model, which relates budget shares linearly to the logarithm of total expenditure. This model can be written as:16 Ci /EXP = i + ai /EXP + i (log EXP) (18) where Ci /EXP is the share of expenditure on good i in total expenditure EXP. Adding up requires that Ci / EXP = 1. Equation (18) is equivalent to the Engel function: Ci = ai + i EXP + i (EXP) (log EXP) (19) 22 To estimate the marginal expenditure shares of households we begin with the equation: (20) Where represents expenditure on good i in time t, is the total expenditure of the household, represents the jth characteristic of the household in time t, represents the fixed effect for each household, which is independent of time and the good i consumed, is assumed to be a random variable which is not necessarily uncorrelated to the unobservable characteristics of the individuals. To estimate equation (20) we obtain the first difference of equation (20) to eliminate the fixed effect as follows: (21) Where we have that . Because we have a time lag of seven years and migration is known to be a dynamic process, we include selection controls in equation (21) for each of our four types of households. Consequently, the equation estimated for households of type k that consume good i becomes: (22) To estimate equation (22) we follow a two-step procedure: first we use our estimation of obtained from the nested logit procedure explained previously; second, we use constrained ordinary least squares on equation (22).17 The marginal budget shares can be shown to be equal to: 1 (23) Notice that our estimation of the MBS comes out cleanly from the parameters obtained in equation (22). Therefore, with equation (22) we can calculate all MBS needed to construct 23 counterfactuals. Specifically, we calculate the counterfactual that compares households that do not receive remittances in 2000 and received remittances in 2007 (k=2), and compare them to households that never receive remittances (k=1). Consequently, the Average Treatment Effects on the Treated (ATT) in this case is: ATT(1)= 1 (24) The second ATT that we obtain is the difference between households that receive remittances in 2000 and 2007 (k=4) and compare them to households that receive remittances in 2000 and stop receiving them in 2007 (k=3): ATT(2)= 1 (25) 7. Remittances and Marginal Budget Shares Tables 7-10 show the results of estimating the marginal expenditure behavior of households for each expenditure category and for each type of household: (1) those that never receive remittances; (2) those with no remittances in 2000 but receive remittances in 2007; (3) those with remittances in 2000 but no remittances in 2007; and (4) those that receive remittances in both years (2000 and 2007). The most important variable in these four tables is the selection term, which is the II variable. For households that never receive remittances (Table 7), the II term is significant for one expenditure category. For households that receive remittances in 2000, but not in 2007 (Table 9) and for households that receive remittances in both years (Table 10), this term is significant for two expenditure categories. These results suggest that selectivity in unobservable 24 components matters for households receiving international remittances in Indonesia. In other words, estimations ignoring the selectivity part of the model would be biased. Table 11 takes the coefficients from Tables 7 to 10 and calculates the estimated and counterfactual marginal budget shares for the five categories of expenditure for each type of household. This table also shows the overall Average Treatment Effects on the Treated (ATT), which averages the ATT for all households receiving remittances in 2007 and compares it to the counterfactual of what would have happened if these households did not receive remittances in 2007.18 Three of the ATT results in Table 11 (column 7) are noteworthy. First, compared to a counterfactual situation in which they did not receive international remittances in 2007, households receiving remittances in 2007 spend more at the margin on one key consumption good: food. Households receiving remittances in 2007 spend 8.5 percent more at the margin on food than what they would have spent on this good without the receipt of remittances. Second, compared to a counterfactual situation in which they did not receive international remittances in 2007, households receiving remittances in 2007 spend less at the margin on one important investment good: housing. Households receiving remittances in 2007 spend 39.1 less at the margin on housing than what they would have spent on this good without the receipt of remittances. Finally, compared to a counterfactual situation in which they did not receive international remittances in 2007, households receiving remittances in 2007 spend more at the margin on education, but this result is not statistically significant. 8. Conclusion This paper has used data from a large, panel household survey in Indonesia to analyze 25 the impact of international remittances on poverty and household consumption and investment. The paper has three key findings, and two of these findings merit comment. First, using an instrumental variables approach to control for selection and endogeneity, the paper finds that international remittances have a large, statistical effect on reducing poverty in Indonesia. When we compare households receiving international remittances in 2007 with a counterfactual situation in which these households did not receive remittances in 2007, we find that the poverty headcount falls by 26.7 percent and the squared poverty gap declines by 69.9 percent. These results are much larger than those produced by broader, cross-national studies on the relationship between remittances and poverty. For example, Adams and Page (2005) find that a 10 percent increase in international remittances in a country will lead, on average, to a 3.5 percent decline in the poverty headcount and a 2.8 percent decline in the squared poverty gap. Second, when we compare households receiving remittances in 2007 with a counterfactual situation in which they did not receive remittances in 2007, we find that households receiving remittances increase their marginal expenditures on one key consumption good ­ food ­ by 8.5 percent. Third, when we compare households receiving international remittances in 2007 with a counterfactual situation in which they did not receive remittances in 2007, we find that households receiving remittances reduce their marginal expenditures on one key investment good ­ housing ­ by 39.1 percent. The second and third findings of this paper deserve comment because they are at odds with recent research on the impact of remittances on consumption and investment in other countries. For example, using a large, nationally-representative household data set and a similar instrumental variables approach in Guatemala, Adams and Cuecuecha (forthcoming) find that 26 since remittances are a transitory type of income, that households tend to spend them more on the margin on human and physical investment goods ­ like education and housing ­ than on consumption goods ­ like food. The difference between these two sets of findings ­ Guatemala and Indonesia ­ can be explained as follows. In Guatemala households receiving international remittances receive much more in annual per capita terms from remittances than those in Indonesia (US $365 vs. US $30 per year). As a result, mean annual per capita expenditure levels for remittance-receiving households in Guatemala are much higher than those in Indonesia.19 Remittance-receiving households in Guatemala thus have more income and are able to devote more of their marginal expenditures to investment in human and physical capital: education and housing. By contrast, households receiving international remittances in Indonesia are much poorer and thus the focus of their marginal expenditures is on improving their consumption of basic goods ­ like food ­ rather than second-order investment goods, like education and housing. In the future, as remittance-receiving households in Indonesia continue to raise their average per capita expenditures through the receipt of international remittances, it is likely that they will devote more of their marginal expenditures to these second-order investment goods. 27 Table 1. Summary of Data on Non-Remittance and Remittance-Receiving Households, Indonesia, 2000 and 2007 2000 2000 2000 2007 2007 2007 t-test t-test Receive no Receive (Receive Receive no Receive (Receive Variable remittances remittances remittances vs. remittances remittances remittances vs. no remittances) no remittances) Mean age of 50.17 55.03 2.19*** 52.80 56.53 4.26*** household head (29.13) (14.22) (12.82) (15.26) (years) Number of 0.38 0.40 0.37 0.28 0.35 1.93* children below (0.59) (0.65) (0.53) (0.60) 5 years in household Number of 1.38 1.22 -1.63 1.03 1.05 0.33 children (1.22) (1.17) (1.08) (1.06) between 6 and 18 years old in household Number of 1.46 1.20 -0.07 1.32 1.33 0.12 household (1.15) (.82) (1.10) (1.06) members with primary education Number of 0.74 0.59 -2.16** .93 0.61 -3.78*** household (1.17) (.93) (1.25) (0.93) members with high school and university education Area (0=rural, 0.33 0.21 -3.15*** 0.38 0.28 -3.26*** 1=urban) (0.47) (0.41) (0.48) (0.45) Mean annual 702.5 614.2 -1.34 1007.8 931.3 -.032 per capita (861) (471) (3573) (1240) household expenditures (000 Indonesian rupiah) at 2000 prices Remittances as NA 26.0 NA NA 29.0 NA percent of total (42) (63) per capita household expenditure N 5132 169 5122 179 Notes: N=5301 households. Standard deviations are in parentheses. In 2000, 8422 Indonesian rupiah= US$1.00; in 2007, 9141 Indonesia rupiah=US$1.00. Source: Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS), 2000 and 2007. *Significant at the 0.10 level. **Significant at the 0.05 level. ***Significant at the 0.01 level. 28 Table 2: Distribution of Households Receiving Remittances by Province, Indonesia, 2000 and 2007 Province Percent of Mean annual Percent of Mean annual households per capita households per capita receiving household receiving household remittances, expenditures remittances, expenditures 2000 in province 2007 in province (000 rupiah), (000 rupiah), 2000 2007, at 2000 prices North 670 1168 Sumatera 1.5 (949) 1.9 (6671) West 742 1038 Sumatera 3,6 (891) 2.5 (1082) Riau 683 822 --- (438) (508) South 594 830 Sumatera 0.3 (669) 0.8 (2001) Lampung 571 735 1.4 (772) 1.7 (664) Bangka dan 1109 1386 Belitung --- (1007) 2.5 (838) Riau Islands 902 671 --- --- --- DKI Jakarta 1300 1640 1.4 (1481) 1.2 (2197) West Java 782 993 2.3 (862) 4.5 (1555) Central Java 699 1129 2.7 (877) 3.6 (5424) Diyogyakarta 845 1333 0.9 (1023) 1.1 (8214) East Java 588 784 4.8 (719) 4.8 (1708) Banten 608 923 1.3 (601) 5.9 (798) Bali 780 1599 0.4 (763) 0.8 (6018) West Nusa 489 592 Tenggara 9.4 (498) 11.7 (735) Central 881 1453 Kalimantan --- --- -- South 778 1128 Kalimantan 2.6 (1002) (1231) South 632 1018 Sulawesi 4.5 (571) 4.7 (3270) West 477 657 Sulawesi --- (447) (551) Notes: N = 5301 households. Standard deviations are in parentheses. In 2000, 8422 Indonesian rupiah=US$1.00; in 2007, 9141 Indonesian rupiah=US$1.00. 29 Table 2: Distribution of Households Receiving Remittances by Province, Indonesia, 2000 and 2007 Source: Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS), 2000 and 2007. Table 3. Nested Logit Model for Indonesia 30 Household head is Household head is Household head is between between 51 years of age 16 and 30 years old 31 and 50 years old or older Coefficient sd Coefficient Sd Coefficient sd Variable Tree Branch: Bottom Distance from kabupaten (district) to railroad in 1930, adjusted 0.180*** 0.045 0.049*** 0.003 0.018*** 0.001 Tree Branch: Initial Human Capital Number of household members over age 15 with primary education 0.453 1.005 0.044 0.156 0.184* 0.102 Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary to university education 0.253 1.212 0.119 0.134 0.194** 0.093 Household Characteristics Age of household head 0.142 0.170 0.089*** 0.025 0.032*** 0.010 Sex of household head (1=male) 2.142 1.721 1.090*** 0.325 0.528** 0.240 Number of children below 5 years 0.635 0.899 0.495 0.273 0.491*** 0.179 Number of children between 6 and 18 years old 0.900 0.932 0.072 0.128 0.117 0.094 Instrumental variables Rainfall, 0.0004 0.0016 1.97E06 2.62E04 0.0001 0.0002 Table 3. Nested Logit Model for Indonesia 31 1995- 1999 Unexpected rainfall in 2000 0.002 0.002 0.001** 0.0004 0.0003 0.0003 Log -56.27 N/A -1426 N/A -1773 N/A likelihood Likelihood 283.92*** N/A 4744*** N/A 3406*** N/A ratio test for model Chi squared 16.88*** N/A 303.69*** N/A 198.29*** N/A test for unexpected rainfall and distance to railroad Likelihood 36.75*** 112.38*** 861.80*** ratio test for IIA hypothesis N 219 N/A 2583 N/A 2499 N/A Notes: Table reports the coefficients of a variable on the probability of household receiving international remittances in 2007. The tree structure assumes that households plan first whether or not to receive remittances in 2000, and then conditional on their choices in 2000, choose their remittance situation in 2007. It is assumed that all variables in the initial tree branch are the variables shown in the table plus a dummy for urban/rural areas and dummies for four Indonesia regions. The only variable in the bottom branch is the distance from kabupaten to railroad variable. The distance to railroad variable is adjusted in the following manner: for households that never receive remittances the variable is the simple distance to railroad; for households that receive remittances in 2007 but not in 2000, it adds 3 to the distance to railroad variable; for households that receive remittances in 2000 but not in 2007, it adds 2 to the distance to railroad variable; and for households that receive remittances both in 2000 and 2007, it adds 4 to the distance to railroad variable. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 32 Table 4. Per Capita Household Expenditure Estimates (Selection Corrected) for Indonesia, 2000-2007 (Fixed Effects estimation) No remittances in No remittances in Remittances in Remittances in Variable 2000, no remittances 2000, remittances 2000, no remittances 2000, remittances in 2007 in 2007 in 2007 in 2007 Human Capital Number of household members over age 15 with primary -0.065*** -0.091 -0.099 -0.067 education (0.011) (0.067) (0.088) (0.076) Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary -0.044*** 0.014 0.035 0.057 education (0.012) (0.078) (0.117) (0.136) Number of household members over age 15 with senior secondary -0.042*** -0.022 0.059 -0.130 and above education (0.010) (0.061) (0.121) (0.131) Household Characteristics -0.003*** -0.011** -0.008 -0.009 Age of household head (0.001) (0.004) (0.006) (0.008) -0.078*** -0.020 0.164 -0.062 Sex of household head (1=male) (0.026) (0.145) (0.188) (0.223) -0.232*** -0.212** -0.461*** -0.266** Number of children below age 5 (0.014) (0.091) (0.115) (0.130) Number of children between 6 and -0.097*** -0.058 -0.121* -0.095 18 years old (0.008) (0.055) (0.072) (0.072) 0.032* -0.184* -0.048 -0.039 Bank in the village (1=yes) (0.018) (0.110) (0.180) (0.182) 0.001 0.003 -0.003 1 NA (0.001) (0.005) (0.012) -0.023** 0.060 -0.033 2 (0.012) NA (0.063) (0.065) -0.025** 0.003 0.005 3 (0.013) (0.009) NA (0.014) 0.026** 0.011 -0.069 4 (0.012) (0.033) (0.073) NA 0.216*** 0.214 0.560* -0.083 Constant (0.035) (0.203) (0.314) (0.282) Adjusted R2 9.74 6.43 9.36 16.04 2.4* Test of joint significance (F) .97 .34 .25 5023 N 132 99 47 33 Table 4. Per Capita Household Expenditure Estimates (contd) Notes: Dependent variable is the log of annual per capita household expenditure (including remittances). The regression included a dummy for area and a dummy for region. Figures in parentheses are standard errors. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 34 Table 5. Effects of Remittances on Poverty for Non-Remittance and Remittance-Receiving Household, Indonesia, 2007 No remittances in Remittances in 2000, no No remittances in 2000, remittances in 2007 Percent Remittances in 2000, remittances in 2007 Percent ATT 2000, no remittances remittances in 2007 Difference Difference Overall in 2007 % difference Observed Predicted Observed Predicted Observed Predicted Counterfactual Observed Predicted Counterfactual (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (6) vs (7) (8) (9) (10) (9) vs (10) (11) 7.27 12.1 10.78 3.15 7.98 22.15 16.37 35.3*** 11.05 16.18 67.03 -75.9*** -26.7*** Poverty (3.09) (-8.42) (-4.58) headcount (%) 1.54 2.52 1.85 .15 1.39 4.28 2.86 49.7** 2.33 2.39 27.58 -91.3*** -55.3*** Poverty gap (%) (2.20) (-4.31) (-3.72) 0.51 0.79 0.45 0.01 0.40 1.47 0.74 98.6** 0.63 0.59 15.94 -96.3*** -69.9*** Squared poverty (1.82) (-3.12) (-2.78) gap (%) .4890 .3477 .5728 .245 .5033 .3674 .3807 -3.5*** .3718 .3272 .3217 1.7*** 2.3*** Gini coefficient (-345) (36.26) (7.02) 1041 579 1166 1408 1010 503 567 -11.3 676 540 243 122.2 19.5 Mean annual per (-.002) (.002) (.17) capita household expenditure (000 rupiah) at 2000 prices N 5023 5023 99 99 132 132 132 47 47 47 Notes: Columns (1), (3), (5) and (8) show observed household per capita expenditure. Columns (2), (4), (6) and (9) show predicted household expenditures, using the equation that corresponds to each type of household. Columns (7) and (10) show counterfactual expenditures using the method explain in section 2 of the paper.. Column (11) shows the Average Treatment Effect of remittances on indicator i. It is calculated as the weighted average of two ATT that are calculated subtracting column (7) from (6) and column (10) from (9). T-statistics shown in parenthesis. T-tests conducted using clustered standard errors and weighting observations. Poverty calculations made using a national poverty line for Indonesia in 2007 of 308,000 Indonesian rupiah/person/year at 2000 prices for urban households and 235,500 Indonesian rupiah/person/year at 2000 prices for rural households. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 35 Table 6. Expenditure Categories and Average Budget Shares, Indonesia, 2000 and 2007 Expenditure category Description No remittances in 2000, no Remittances in 2000, no No remittances in 2000, Remittances in 2000, remittances in 2007 remittances in 2007 remittances in 2007 remittances in 2007 2000 2007 2000 2007 2000 2007 2000 2007 Food Purchased food 0.600 0.551 0.609 0.535 0.615 0.550 0.627 0.563 Non-purchased food Education Educational expenses 0.049 0.051 0.049 0.051 0.045 0.056 0.029 0.049 Housing Housing value 0.100 0.112 0.091 0.157 0.092 0.114 0.093 0.110 Health Health expenses 0.018 0.020 0.024 0.030 0.010 0.020 0.017 0.052 Other Household durables, Transport, 0.232 0.266 0.227 0.226 0.238 0.260 0.234 0.225 Communications, Legal 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 Notes: N=5301 households. All values are weighted. International remittances include remittances received from spouse, parents and children. Source: Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS), 2000 and 2007. 36 Table 7. Estimated (Selection Corrected) Per Capita Household Expenditure in Good i for Indonesia, 2000-2007 (Fixed Effects estimation) for households with no remittances in 2000 and no remittances in 2007 Variable Food Education Housing Health Other Expenditure 1.472*** 0.157** 0.245** 0.167*** 0.559*** (0.174) (0.072) (0.108) (0.055) (0.149) Expenditure*logExpenditure 0.180*** 0.019** 0.029** 0.017*** 0.064*** (0.020) (0.008) (0.012) (0.006) (0.017) Human Capital 16.699*** 4.924** 5.877 0.169 5.566 Number of household members over age 15 with primary education (5.794) (2.411) (3.588) (1.823) (4.946) Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary education 16.429* 2.544 10.190* 4.046 28.258*** (9.350) (3.890) (5.789) (2.942) (7.981) Number of household members over age 15 with senior secondary and above education 11.052 17.279*** 19.404*** 0.594 41.968*** (8.566) (3.564) (5.304) (2.695) (7.312) Household Characteristics 0.361 0.058 0.361 0.231 0.664* Age of household head (0.407) (0.169) (0.252) (0.128) (0.347) Sex of household head (1=male) 10.035 16.805*** 20.849*** 0.853* 44.877*** (12.345) (5.137) (7.644) (3.884) (10.538) Number of children below age 5 22.928** 13.663*** 5.970 2.760 23.137** (10.771) (4.482) (6.669) (3.389) (9.194) Number of children between 6 and 18 years old 1.258 2.494 6.758* 3.302* 27.341*** (6.163) (2.564) (3.816) (1.939) (5.261) Bank in the village (1=yes) 9.911 6.441* 10.748** 5.472** 6.514 (7.992) (3.325) (4.948) (2.515) (6.822) 2 1.472 2.231** 1.218 0.034 2.217 (0.174) (1.065) (1.585) (0.805) (2.185) 3 0.180 1.920* 0.433 0.141 2.946 (0.020) (1.011) (1.504) (0.764) (2.073) 4 16.699 2.656** 1.003 0.067 2.741 (5.794) (1.185) (1.763) (0.896) (2.431) Adjusted R2 .35 .29 .11 .05 .29 Test of joint significance (F) 10.14*** 4.63*** 5.53*** .88 1.35 N 5023 5023 5023 5023 5023 Notes: Dependent variable is the change in expenditure in good i. All variables shown are introduced as changes, except for selection controls. The equation includes interactions between expenditure and each characteristic. Figures in parentheses are standard errors. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 37 Table 8. Estimated (Selection Corrected) Per Capita Household Expenditure in Good i for Indonesia, 2000-2007 (Fixed Effects estimation) for households with no remittances in 2000 and remittances in 2007 Variable Food Education Housing Health Other Expenditure 1.997 0.162 1.780* 0.037 2.474* (1.822) (0.680) (1.070) (0.475) (1.363) Expenditure*logExpenditure 0.137 0.023 0.213* 0.007 0.287* (0.206) (0.077) (0.121) (0.054) (0.154) Human Capital 73.074 46.816** 62.713* 11.906 17.659 Number of household members over age 15 with primary education (56.202) (20.986) (32.999) (14.665) (42.068) Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary education 19.148 34.750 46.412 2.406 6.224 (76.151) (28.434) (44.712) (19.871) (57.000) Number of household members over age 15 with senior secondary and above education 78.931 2.629 39.839 8.189 3.611 (63.939) (23.874) (37.541) (16.684) (47.859) Household Characteristics 11.515** 0.822 4.505 0.753 2.982 Age of household head (5.783) (2.159) (3.396) (1.509) (4.329) Sex of household head (1=male) 127.758 63.256 43.619 54.118* 2.804 (119.912) (44.775) (70.405) (31.290) (89.756) Number of children below age 5 177.953 0.948 29.893 29.242 45.031 (116.449) (43.482) (68.372) (30.386) (87.164) Number of children between 6 and 18 years old 39.626 12.166 27.720 5.204 19.964 (52.493) (19.601) (30.821) (13.698) (39.292) Bank in the village (1=yes) 37.246 39.081 76.398* 7.522 4.923 (71.536) (26.711) (42.002) (18.667) (53.546) 1 0.281 0.086 0.295 0.087 0.548 (0.592) (0.221) (0.348) (0.155) (0.443) 3 1.181 0.848 0.605 0.077 1.674 (1.973) (0.737) (1.158) (0.515) (1.477) 4 9.730 2.610 5.336 1.178 3.461 (7.940) (2.965) (4.662) (2.072) (5.944) Adjusted R2 .35 .41 .23 .03 .34 Test of joint significance (F) .84 .96 .53 .23 1.57 132 132 132 132 132 N Notes: Dependent variable is the change in expenditure in good i. All variables shown are introduced as changes, except for selection controls. The equation includes interactions between expenditure and each characteristic. Figures in parentheses are standard errors. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 38 Table 9. Estimated (Selection Corrected) Per Capita Household Expenditure in Good i for Indonesia, 2000-2007 (Fixed Effects estimation) for households with remittances in 2000 and no remittances in 2007 Variable Food Education Housing Health Other Expenditure 2.227 0.053 0.491 0.200 1.532 (1.642) (0.676) (1.040) (0.507) (1.166) Expenditure*logExpenditure 0.307 0.032 0.005 0.008 0.188 (0.203) (0.084) (0.129) (0.063) (0.144) Human Capital 32.447 14.377 48.064 19.670 21.119 Number of household members over age 15 with primary education (41.382) (17.031) (26.211) (12.769) (29.397) Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary education 6.950 14.611 55.690 1.199 20.710 (116.352) (47.886) (73.696) (35.903) (82.653) Number of household members over age 15 with senior secondary and above education 98.396 24.738 11.765 13.122 40.761 (82.532) (33.967) (52.275) (25.467) (58.629) Household Characteristics 3.454 1.832 1.551 0.380 4.256** Age of household head (2.813) (1.158) (1.781) (0.868) (1.998) Sex of household head (1=male) 10.106 48.110 91.611 49.734 182.202** (127.052) (52.289) (80.473) (39.205) (90.254) Number of children below age 5 69.517 0.198 32.842 10.680 34.801 (96.430) (39.687) (61.078) (29.756) (68.501) Number of children between 6 and 18 years old 22.954 5.332 21.636 3.165 63.015 (55.366) (22.786) (35.068) (17.085) (39.330) Bank in the village (1=yes) 47.211 35.713 41.541 33.589 3.353 (100.951) (41.547) (63.941) (31.151) (71.713) 1 1.954 1.953*** 0.545 0.074 0.618 (2.003) (0.824) (1.269) (0.618) (1.423) 2 32.666*** 11.165*** 0.976 1.124 5.655 (11.807) (4.859) (7.479) (3.643) (8.388) 4 39.393*** 12.237*** 2.798 1.048 5.470 (12.599) (5.185) (7.980) (3.888) (8.950) Adjusted R2 .44 .38 .20 .01 .37 Test of joint significance (F) 4.35*** 10.85*** .21 .03 .45 99 99 99 99 99 N Notes: Dependent variable is the change in expenditure in good i. All variables shown are introduced as changes, except for selection controls. The equation includes interactions between expenditure and each characteristic. Figures in parentheses are standard errors. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 39 Table 10. Estimated (Selection Corrected) Per Capita Household Expenditure in Good i for Indonesia, 2000-2007 (Fixed Effects estimation) for households with remittances in 2000 and remittances in 2007 Variable Food Education Housing Health Other Expenditure 4.940 4.558** 2.843 6.654** 3.967 (6.409) (1.863) (2.577) (2.683) (4.769) Expenditure*logExpenditure 0.722 0.687** 0.322 0.728* 0.721 (0.859) (0.250) (0.345) (0.360) (0.639) Human Capital 24.809 27.402 38.348 3.837 36.312 Number of household members over age 15 with primary education (56.792) (16.508) (22.837) (23.777) (42.256) Number of household members over age 15 with junior secondary education 107.382 19.525 52.695 5.453 130.552 (216.564) (62.950) (87.085) (90.669) (161.136) Number of household members over age 15 with senior secondary and above education 137.513 13.719 175.450** 76.114 23.327 (173.639) (50.473) (69.824) (72.698) (129.198) Household Characteristics 13.822 8.054** 0.533 4.064 4.907 Age of household head (11.385) (3.309) (4.578) (4.767) (8.471) Sex of household head (1=male) 204.317 50.289 72.546 170.091 50.023 (248.725) (72.298) (100.018) (104.134) (185.065) Number of children below age 5 191.222 126.109* 67.996 34.774 320.102 (214.891) (62.464) (86.412) (89.969) (159.891) Number of children between 6 and 18 years old 71.899 25.523* 14.925 56.387** 70.325 (49.614) (14.422) (19.951) (20.772) (36.916) Bank in the village (1=yes) 172.797 277.775*** 417.637*** 188.018 202.967 (343.143) (99.744) (137.985) (143.665) (255.317) 1 0.057 2.474 6.342 3.342 1.220 (9.307) (2.705) (3.742) (3.896) (6.925) 2 1.968 23.779** 9.614 2.026 18.111 (31.089) (9.037) (12.502) (13.016) (23.132) 3 2.320 5.049** 6.538** 2.934 8.390 (7.376) (2.144) (2.966) (3.088) (5.488) Adjusted R2 .34 .45 .33 .07 .25 Test of joint significance (F) .03 5.01*** 2.67* .56 1.12 47 47 47 47 47 N Notes: Dependent variable is the change in expenditure in good i. All variables shown are introduced as changes, except for selection controls. The equation includes interactions between expenditure and each characteristic. Figures in parentheses are standard errors. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 40 Table 11. Marginal Budget Shares for Non-Remittance and Remittance-Receiving Household, Indonesia, 2007 No remittances Remittances No remittances in 2000, Percent Remittances in 2000, Percent ATT in 2000, no in 2000, no remittances in 2007 Difference remittances in 2007 Difference Overall remittances in remittances % difference 2007 in 2007 Predicted Predicted Predicted Counterfactual (3) vs (4) Predicted Counterfactual (5) vs (6) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Food 8.9*** 7.4** 8.46* 0.432 0.460 0.479 0.440 (7.0) 0.470 0.438 (2.29) (1.72) Education 11.0 78.9 9.76 0.084 0.041 0.075 0.085 (1.1) 0.051 0.028 (0.64) (0.30) Housing 25.8*** 84.7*** 39.11*** 0.121 0.178 0.088 0.118 (2.75) 0.028 0.183 (5.4) (3.3) Health 5.6 46.1* 6.37 0.034 0.064 0.033 0.035 (0.50) 0.094 0.064 (1.75) (1.45) Others 0.8*** 24.7* 6.31 0.328 0.257 0.325 0.322 (4.45) 0.357 0.286 (1.97) (1.68) 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 Notes: Column (7) shows the Average Treatment Effects (ATT) of remittances on indicator i. It is calculated as the weighted average of two ATT that are calculated subtracting column (4) from (3) and column (6) from (5). T-statistics shown in parenthesis. T-tests conducted using clustered standard errors and weighting observations. *** Significant at the 0.01 level. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. * Significant at the 0.10 level. 41 References Acosta, P., Calderon, C., Fajnzylber, P. and Lopez, H. 2006. Remittances and Development in Latin America. World Economy 29, pp. 957-987. Adams, Jr., R. 1998. Remittances, Investment and Rural Asset Accumulation in Pakistan. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 47, pp. 155-173. Adams, Jr., R. and Cuecuecha, A. Forthcoming. Remittances, Household Expenditure and Investment in Guatemala. World Development, forthcoming November 2010. Adams, Jr, R., Cuecuecha, A. and Page, J. 2008. The Impact of Remittances on Poverty and Inequality in Ghana. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4732. World Bank, Washington, DC. Adams, Jr., R. and Page, J. 2005. Do International Migration and Remittances Reduce Poverty in Developing Countries? World Development 33, pp. 1645-1669. Bourguignon, F., Fournier, M., and Gurgand, M. 2004. Selection Bias Corrections Based on the Multinomial Logit Model: Monte-Carlo Comparisons. Unpublished DELTA working paper, France. Chami, R., Fullenkamp, C. and Jahjah, S. 2003. Are Immigrant Remittance Flows a Source of Capital for Development? IMF Working Paper 03/189, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. de la Briere, B., Sadoulet, E., de Janvry, A., and Lambert, S. 2002. The Roles of Destination, Gender and Household Composition in Explaining Remittances: An Analysis for the Dominican Sierra, Journal of Development Economics 72, pp. 309-328. Dubin, J. and McFadden, D. 1984. An Econometric Analysis of Residential Electric Appliance Holdings and Consumption. Econometrica, 52, pp. 345-362. 42 Edwards, A. and Ureta, M. 2003. International Migration, Remittances and Schooling: Evidence from El Salvador. Journal of Development Economics 72, pp. 429-461. Lokshin, M., Bontch-Osmolovski, M., and Glinskaya, E. 2010. Work-related Migration and Poverty Reduction in Nepal. Review of Development Economics 14, pp. 323-332. Lopez-Cordova, E. 2005. Globalization, Migration and Development: The Role of Mexican Migrant Remittances. Economia, 6, pp. 217-256. Maddala, G. 1983. Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Munshi, K. 2003. Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the US Labor Market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, pp. 549-597. Prais, S. J. and Houthakker, H. S. 1971. The Analysis of Family Budgets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ray, D. 1998. Development Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Schmertmann, C. 1994. Selectivity Bias Correction Method in Polychotomous Sample Selection Models. Journal of Econometrics 60, pp.101-132. Wooldridge, J. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Woodruff, C. and Zenteno, R. 2007. Migration Networks and Micro-enterprises in Mexico. Journal of Development Economics 82, pp. 509-528. World Bank. 2008a. The Malaysia-Indonesia Remittance Corridor. Working Paper No. 149. Washington, DC. World Bank. 2008b. Migration and Remittances Factbook, 2008. Washington, DC. Yang, D. 2008. International Migration, Remittances and Household Investment: Evidence from Philippine Migrants' Exchange Rate Shocks. Economic Journal 118, pp. 591-630. 43 Yang, D. and Choi, H. 2007. Are Remittances Insurance? Evidence from Rainfall Shocks in the Philippines. World Bank Economic Review 21, pp. 219-248. 44 Notes 1 According to the World Bank (2008a: 8), 85 percent of the Indonesians that were approved to work abroad in 2006 went to Malaysia and Saudi Arabia. 2 The IFLS Survey contains detailed information on international migrants who are listed on the household roster (that is, migrants who have been gone for less than one year), but it does not contain any information on migrants who are not listed on the household roster (that is, those who have been gone for more than one year)/ 3 For example, in their study in the Dominican Republic, de la Briere, Sadoulet, de Janvry and Lambert (2002) find that fully half of all international migrants do not remit. 4 By contrast, recent household surveys in Guatemala (2000) and Ghana (2005/06) show that the share of households receiving international remittances was 7.1 percent in Guatemala and 5.4 percent in Ghana. For details on these surveys, see Adams and Cuecuecha (forthcoming) on Guatemala and Adams, Cuecuecha and Page (2008) on Ghana. 5 By contrast, the household surveys cited in note (4) show that the absolute amount of international remittances received in annual per capita terms by remittance-receiving households was US $365 in Guatemala and US $417 in Ghana (nominal terms). 6 This paper will follow the convention of using expenditure rather than income data to examine poverty in Indonesia for the following reasons. First, since households tend to use savings to smooth fluctuations in income, many economists believe that expenditures provide a more accurate measure of household welfare over time. Second, in developing country situations like Indonesia, expenditures are typically easier to measure than income because of the many problems inherent in defining and measuring income for the self-employed in agriculture, which represent such a large proportion of the labor force. 7 The simple correlation between poverty and the receipt of international remittances by a household in Indonesia is positive in both 2000 and 2007. 8 See Schmertmann (1994) for a more formal and detailed explanation of the nested logit selection model. 9 In a simpler version of the model, one in which the effect of receiving remittances is modeled as a change in intercept in the expenditure equation, the three instruments are tested for under-identification, weakness and over- identification. The three instruments are significant at the 1% level in the first stage, the instruments reject the null hypothesis of under-identification, the instruments present a Cragg-Donald F statistic that demonstrates that they are not weak, and the tests do not reject the null of valid instruments. 10 More details about the counterfactuals are presented in section 4 of the paper. 11 When we estimate these regressions in levels, all of our selection terms are statistically significant for all types of households and for both 2000 and 2007. It is only when we control for fixed effects that the significance of selection terms vanishes for all types of households except for those that never receive remittances. 12 The coefficients that multiply the probabilities for the counterfactual equation are available from the authors upon request. 13 Data on the 2007 national poverty line for Indonesia (urban and rural) are from the World Bank. 14 This characteristic is called the weak transfers principle. The squared poverty gap does not possess a third characteristic that is also desirable in poverty measures. That characteristic is called the principle of transfer 45 sensitivity, which establishes that a given regressive transfer between two poor people must increase the poverty index more when the persons involved are poorer (Ray, 1998). 15 The ATTs reported in this section average out the effect of remittances for the two types of counterfactual experiments that we perform. We obtain a weighted average in which each type of household involved in the comparison is weighted according to their importance in the population studied. Standard errors reported in this section also adjust for these weights. 16 The functional form used in this analysis differs from the Working-Leser model because it includes an intercept in equation (18). In theory, Ci should always equal zero whenever total expenditure EXP is zero, and this restriction should be built into the function. But zero observations on EXP invariably lie well outside the sample range. Also, observing this restriction with the Working-Leser model can lead to poorer statistical fits. Including the intercept term in the model has little effect on the estimation of marginal budget shares for the average person, but it can make a significant difference for income redistribution results. For more on the Working-Leser model, see Prais and Houthakker (1971). 17 To normalize the changes in expenditure shares over time we employ the following reasoning: all changes in the five expenditure goods should add up to the aggregate change in expenditure observed for each household. Therefore, all changes in expenditure are expressed as a fraction of the total change in expenditure per household. Moreover, we constrained the estimation to guarantee that the sum of the different MBS adds to one. 18 The ATTs reported in this section average out the effect of remittances for the two types of counterfactual experiments that we perform. We obtain a weighted average in which each type of household involved in the comparison is weighted according to their importance in the population studied. Standard errors reported in this section also adjust for these weights. 19 Mean annual per capita expenditures for households receiving international remittances in Guatemala (in 2000) were 47.3 percent higher than those for households receiving international remittances in Indonesia (in 2007): US $1,127 in Guatemala vs. US $765 in Indonesia (nominal terms)