WPS5279 Policy Research Working Paper 5279 Trade and Financial Sector Reforms Interactions and Spillovers Ashley Taylor The World Bank East Asia and Pacific Region Poverty Reduction & Economic Management Sector Department April 2010 Policy Research Working Paper 5279 Abstract The allocation of production across firms is a potentially interaction effects between reforms appear qualitatively important explanation of the productivity gap between important. Trade and domestic financial sector reforms rich and poor economies. Reforms to trade policy and the have complementary effects on the average productivity domestic financial sector are often both key elements of and size of domestic producers. However, if much policy packages aimed at reducing productive distortions. reallocative work has already been done through a well- However, the impact of each reform in reallocating functioning financial sector, the marginal benefits of trade production within an economy is usually analyzed liberalisation for wages and household utility are reduced. independently. This paper asks how do such general Improvements in the ability to use exports as pledgeable equilibrium effects of trade and domestic financial sector collateral enhance both the wage and productivity reforms interact in terms of their effects on productivity, effects of trade reforms. The model also highlights the wages and utility. Motivated by recent firm-level studies, potential for financial sector reforms in one economy to I add two-way linkages between firms' production and be exported via the trade channel, affecting decisions to exporting decisions and their financial constraints to a produce or export in the foreign economy and putting general equilibrium heterogeneous firm trade model. The downward pressure on foreign real wages. This paper--a product of the Poverty Reduction & Economic Management Sector Department, East Asia and Pacific Region--is part of a larger effort in the department to examining regional growth and integration. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at ataylor2@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Trade and financial sector reforms: interactions and spillovers Ashley Taylor World Bank / LSE 30 September 2009 Abstract The allocation of production across firms is a potentially important explanation of the productivity gap between rich and poor economies. Reforms to trade policy and the domestic financial sector are often both key elements of policy packages aimed at reducing productive distortions. However, the impact of each reform in reallocating production within an economy is usually analyzed independently. This paper asks how do such general equilibrium effects of trade and domestic financial sector reforms interact in terms of their effects on productivity, wages and utility. Motivated by recent firm-level studies, this paper add two-way linkages between firms' production and exporting decisions and their financial constraints to a gen- eral equilibrium heterogeneous firm trade model. The interaction effects between reforms appear qualitatively important. Trade and domestic financial sector re- forms have complementary effects on the average productivity and size of domestic producers. However, if much reallocative work has already been done through a well-functioning financial sector, the marginal benefits of trade liberalization for wages and household utility are reduced. Improvements in the ability to use ex- ports as pledgeable collateral enhance both the wage and productivity effects of trade reforms. The model also highlights the potential for financial sector reforms in one economy to be exported via the trade channel, affecting decisions to produce or export in the foreign economy and putting downward pressure on foreign real wages. This paper was drafted during my PhD studies at LSE. I am particularly grateful for discussions with Gianluca Benigno, Kosuke Aoki and Danny Quah and for comments from Enrica Detragiache and e Hubert Kempf (discussants) and from participants at the BETA / Universit´ Louis Pasteur Workshop on "Cycles and Crises", May 2008, the IMF Conference On the Causes and Consequences of Struc- tural Reforms, February 2008, the 2008 Royal Economic Society Annual Conference, the 2007 Money Macro and Finance Meeting, the LSE Money-Macro work-in-progress workshop and at seminars in the IMF Research Department and the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies. I thankfully acknowledge research funding from ESRC Research Studentship PTA-030-2004-00632 and support under "Stability of the Global Financial System: Regulation and Policy Response", World Economy and Finance, ESRC Research Programme Phase I, Grant Ref. No.: RES-156-25-0026. Email: ataylor2@worldbank.org. 1 1 Introduction The efficient allocation of production across firms matters for aggregate total factor pro- ductivity (TFP). Distortions which shift resources from more to less productive firms can have a sizeable impact on TFP and hence on average output per worker and welfare. For example, it is estimated that removing such resource misallocations could increase TFP in China by 25-40% and in India by 50-60% (Hsieh & Klenow, 2007).1 Improvements of such magnitudes are equivalent to substantial reductions in the relative productivity gaps compared to the US, moving relative TFP in both countries from around 40% to 60% of the US level (based on the 2004 aggregate TFP estimates of Jorgenson & Vu, 2007). Many of the wide-ranging structural reforms across developing and transition economies in recent decades have been focused on reducing distortions to the allocation of production. Although reforms to trade and domestic financial sectors are often both key elements of such policy packages, the respective related empirical and theoretical literatures have generally abstracted from the potentially important reallocative effects of contemporaneous reforms in the other sector. Thus, a fundamental policy question of how reforms interact in terms of their impact on aggregate productivity, wages and welfare cannot be addressed. The objective of this paper is to develop a theoretical framework to analyze this is- sue through adding financial constraints to a two-country (non-symmetric) heterogeneous firm trade model. In order to do so I add a number of novel, empirically relevant, features to a baseline heterogeneous firm trade model adapted from Melitz (2003). The first is to consider intermediate production as owned and operated by heterogeneous entrepreneurs whose borrowing is subject to credit constraints due to agency problems. The second is to allow these agency problems to vary with the composition of the entrepreneur's production between domestic output and exports. This introduces a two-way linkage between a firm's export decision and its financial constraints as suggested by firm-level survey data. I then examine the steady state general equilibrium interactions of the real- locative impacts of trade and domestic financial sector reforms (considered as reductions in variable trade costs and relaxations in credit constraints respectively). The interaction effects between trade reforms and domestic financial sector reforms appear qualitatively important. On the one hand, trade and domestic financial sector reforms can have complementary effects in increasing the average productivity and size of producing entrepreneurs. If entrepreneurs face less restrictive credit constraints as a result of financial sector reforms then investment can increase more in response to a lowering of variable export costs. With fixed factor supplies, a greater reallocation from low to high productivity entrepreneurs is thus required in order to maintain factor market equilibrium. As a result, the positive effects of trade liberalization on average productivity and producer size are enhanced if domestic financial sector reforms are more advanced. On the other hand, in such a case the marginal gains for wages and household utility as a result of trade liberalization are reduced. If credit constraints are less restrictive then effective borrowing costs are lower, intermediate prices are reduced and real wages 1 These estimates are derived from a movement to `US efficiency' based on the distribution of marginal products of capital for plants within sectors. In turn, in a model calibrated to US data, Restuccia & Rogerson (2007) find similar order aggregate TFP effects of distortions to prices faced by individual plants. 2 are higher. Thus, the marginal benefits of trade liberalization in lowering prices and increasing real wages are reduced if much reallocative work has already been done through a well-functioning domestic financial sector. In terms of the potential linkage between exports and credit constraints, improvements in the relative ability to pledge exports to creditors amplify the benefits of trade liberalization. A further insight of the paper is that even in financial autarky the financial development of not just the domestic economy but also its trading partner can play a role in determining the real wages and the efficiency of domestic production. In particular, domestic financial sector reforms in one economy can be exported via the trade channel putting downward pressure on foreign real wages. The value added of the approach adopted below is to provide a framework which allows analysis of the macroeconomic implications of reforms in one area, for example the domestic financial sector, conditional on other policy variables, for example the degree of access to international goods markets. Using this modeling approach to assess whether the interactions between these different reform measures have quantitatively important empirical effects is an important next step. In the rest of the paper, Section 2 first discusses the motivation and related literature. Section 3 then provides an overview of the modeling approach focusing on the credit constraints that entrepreneurs face. Section 4 provides details of the model with Section 5 analyzing the steady state in trade and financial autarky to emphasize the key mechanisms in the model. Section 6 then opens up the economies to international goods trade. Section 7 concludes including a discussion of further research and empirical implications. 2 Motivation and related literature 2.1 Motivation The modeling approach which I adopt is driven by two main features: first, the importance of addressing firm heterogeneity in any analysis of trade and domestic financial sector reforms and, second, the importance of analyzing the interactions of these two reforms. As surveyed in, for example, Bernard et al. (2007a), recent heterogeneous firm models of international trade are motivated by the observation that exporters tend to differ from non-exporters in important ways, for example being larger and more productive. Surveys indicate that only a limited subset of plants export, for example around 20% in the 1991 US Census of Manufactures (Bernard et al., 2003). There is also empirical support for the self-selection of higher productivity firms into exporting rather than a causality running from exporting to higher productivity, eg Clerides et al. (1998). At the same time, financial constraints vary across firms and recent firm-level data suggests that the degree of financial constraints faced by firms depends on their export status. For example, using Spanish data Campa & Shaver (2002) find exporters to be less liquidity constrained whilst for UK data Greenaway et al. (2007) show that being an exporter improves a firm's liquidity and lowers its leverage.2 This linkage from export status to a firm's financial constraints is in addition to the growing empirical evidence on the effects of financial constraints on export levels and patterns.3 Indeed, the analysis of 2 Also, using World Bank survey data from developing and emerging economies Beck et al. (2006) find that the problem of bank corruption as a constraint to finance is less of a problem for exporters. 3 See, for example, the sector-level analysis in Manova (2006). 3 Greenaway et al. (2007) suggests that the stronger financial health of exporters can be seen as `an outcome rather than a determinant of entry' into exporting. The importance of analyzing the interaction of trade and domestic financial sector reforms can be illustrated by observed patterns of policy indicators or by the joint presence of both reforms in many of the policy packages implemented by developing and emerging economies.4 As an example of the association between the two reforms, Figure 1 plots five-year averages for the trade and banking sector transition indicators for Central and Eastern European countries compiled by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD).5 As expected, the levels of the two policy indicators are positively associated with the second panel highlighting the often contemporaneous progress on both trade and financial sector reforms.6 In addition, reforms in one sector can take place at a range of initial values for policies in the other sector. Indeed, based on a new IMF dataset of de jure reform indicators covering a wider sample of 91 countries over the period 1973-2005, Hauner & Prati (2008) find that trade reforms tend to lead domestic financial reforms. Thus analysis of trade reforms assuming perfect credit markets would appear to be often inappropriate. Whilst summary indicators of policy stance are clearly not perfect, for example due to the lack of information on enforcement or their aggregate nature, the above patterns serve to highlight the empirical importance of analyzing the potential trade-offs and complementarities in the effects of trade and financial sector reforms. Such analysis can provide insights into the appropriate design of reform packages in individual countries and can also shed light on the political economy implications of different combinations of reforms. 2.2 Related literature This work is related to three main strands of literature. The first concerns the reallocative effects of trade reforms in the presence of heterogeneous productivity firms as analyzed in a growing theoretical literature (see, for example, the theoretical models of Melitz, 2003; Baldwin & Forslid, 2006). In such models trade liberalization increases investment and the demand for labor. With a fixed labor supply this leads to a rise in the minimum productivity of producers, shifts production towards higher productivity firms and results in an increase in average productivity. This reallocative process is supported in empirical studies such as Bernard et al. (2006) in relation to the US, Pavcnik (2002) for Chile and Fernandes (2007) for Colombia. The second strand of related literature concerns the reallocative effects of financial sec- tor reforms. Theoretical models, such as Almeida & Wolfenzon (2005) and Caselli & Gennaioli (2006), illustrate how domestic financial development (for example, contract enforcement or investor protection) can promote aggregate productivity through reallocating resources 4 See, for example, the chronology provided by Henry (2000) of reforms across 12 major emerging markets in the 1980s and early 1990s or the analysis of IMF programme conditionalities provided in IMF (2001). 5 The transition indicators represent an assessment of a country's policies and institutions in each area against specific criteria with scores assigned from 1 to 4.33 such that higher values indicate improvements in the policy areas towards the levels in advanced economies. Appendix A provides further details on the transition indicators and the sample coverage. 6 As shown in Appendix Figure 12, similar associations are present when controlling for country and period fixed effects. 4 Figure 1: EBRD transition indicators, 5 year averages: levels and changes (a) Levels (b) Change compared to previous period Change in trade and FX transition indicator 3 KGZ GEO GEO KGZ ROU MNG ALB ARM MNG MKD ALB MDA BGR SVN CZE LVA HUN SVKSVN LTU LVA BGR HRV HUN SVK EST ROU POL POL CZE MDA SVK SVN POL HRV EST LTU CZE Trade and FX transition indicator ARM MKD LVA EST HRV ALB BGR MKD LTU 4 AZE ROU KGZ LTU LVA KGZ MDA KAZ MDA BIH KAZ ROU MNE UKR ARM EST 2 MNG KAZ AZE ARM TJK RUSKAZ HUN MNG ALB GEO RUS SRB MNE CZE TJK UKR BIH GEO UKRBGRRUS SVK AZE POL BIH HRV MKD SVN 3 TJK SVNRUSPOL GEO SRB AZE SRB 1 MKDHRV MNECZE SVK TJK UZB MNE MNG HUN UKR BGR ARM BLR UZBAZE UKR KGZROU MDA BLRRUS BLRBLR BIH UKR ALB SRB AZE MKD ARM KAZ EST HRV ALB LVA LTU MDA BGR MNE SRB BIH EST SVNSVKHRV 2 TJK BLR UZBUZB GEO LTU POL ALBCZE TJK TKMMKD EST MNG KAZ SVN HUN KGZ ROU HUN LVA BGR POLCZE SVK 0 RUS ROU BIH BIH MNGLTU LVA ARMMDA KGZ BLR UZB RUS UZB KAZ -1 GEO MNE TKM UKR SRB UZB BLR AZE TJK SRB MNE 1 1 2 3 4 -.5 0 .5 1 1.5 Banking transition indicator Change in banking transition indicator Note: Values of the transition indicators range from 1 to 4.33 with higher values representing standards moving towards those of advanced industrial economies. Averages taken over 1989-1993, 1994-1998, 1999-2003 and 2004-2007 (four year average). Lines represent lowess smoother (locally weighted regression) with 95% confidence intervals. to more productive firms.7 From an empirical perspective the beneficial impacts of fi- nancial sector reforms on allocative efficiency are supported in studies such as Wurgler (2000), Galindo et al. (2007) and Abiad et al. (2007). For example, the latter paper finds domestic financial sector liberalization to be associated with an improvement in the effi- ciency of the allocation of production (indicated by a fall in the dispersion of Tobin's q) in a sample of emerging economies.8 The third strand of related literature concerns the impact of financial frictions on trade. This work builds on the analysis of Kletzer & Bardhan (1987) which provides one of the earliest theoretical papers to emphasize the impact of financial institutions on patterns of comparative advantage. Subsequent empirical papers, most recently using sector-level data, such as Beck (2003), Hur et al. (2006) and Manova (2006), support the view that financial frictions are an important determinant of trade flows. As the trade literature has moved towards heterogeneous firm models such as Melitz (2003) so a number of recent papers have used such frameworks to analyze the role of financial frictions in determining export patterns, for example Chaney (2005), Manova (2006) and Suwantaradon (2008).9 Chor et al. (2007) extend this approach to consider how financial frictions in host economies affect exporting and foreign direct investment patterns within a three-country model. Whilst based on a similar broad modeling framework, this paper differs from these related papers in a number of important features. First, the focus 7 Also, in the context of international financial sector reforms, Aoki et al. (2006) emphasize that the impact of capital account liberalization in shifting production across high and low productivity entrepreneurs is dependent on the development of the domestic financial sector. 8 Abiad et al. (2007) also find that trade openness improves the allocation of production across firms but the issue of the interaction of the two reforms is not addressed. 9 Suwantaradon (2008) highlights how financial frictions lead to selection into exporting and production based on both a firm's net worth and productivity, compared to solely productivity in the standard Melitz set-up. 5 here is on the general equilibrium macroeconomic effects of the interaction of trade and financial reforms rather than solely the role of financial frictions in determining selection decisions into exporting or foreign direct investment.10 Second, in line with the empirical evidence, I allow for two-way interactions between exporting and financial constraints (ie exporting decisions play a role in the credit constraints which in turn influences the decision whether to export). Third, I solve for a non-symmetric rather than symmetric equilibrium to allow for the more realistic and policy-relevant case where the level of financial development and trade costs may vary across countries.11 3 Overview of modeling approach There are two economies in the model, home and foreign, who may trade intermediate goods. The primary feature of the model is the set of heterogenous entrepreneurs in each economy which produce, with varying productivity, intermediate goods using labor inputs.12 As in the standard set-up of Melitz (2003), depending on her productivity an entrepreneur may choose to produce output for the domestic market or to pay additional costs to access also export markets. However, as the entrepreneur's investment is subject to financial constraints, her production decisions link domestic financial conditions and international trade. In order to capture the effects of financial frictions on the productive sector I consider intermediate producers as entrepreneurs who maximize their own utility and operate and own their own projects. For simplicity, as in Chaney (2008), I abstract from entry and exit decisions which can be analyzed within the standard Melitz model through the assumption of perfect competition in the productive sector and a fixed cost of entry. Agency problems, such as inalienability of human capital or ex post moral hazard etc., limit a firm's access to finance. The extent of these borrowing constraints may differ with a creditor's nationality. This may be due to different legal systems or different informational and transaction costs. The degree of borrowing constraints may also vary with the type of pledgeable output, namely output for domestic or export markets. This might reflect the differential ability of lenders to recover export output or to monitor exporting activities relative to domestic output or activities respectively. Agents in each country can access domestic credit markets consisting of one-period risk-free debt contracts (with the underlying contracting problem assumed to yield zero default in equilibrium). Borrowing of one unit of the home consumption good from home creditors at time t requires a gross repayment of Rt+1 units of the time t + 1 home consumption good. Similarly, borrowing a unit of time t foreign consumption from foreign creditors requires a gross repayment of R,t+1 of the time t + 1 foreign consumption good. 10 Related work by Hsu (2006) also examines the productivity effects of trade liberalization in the presence of financial frictions but with symmetric economies and within a different modeling framework based on the transfer of ownership across dynasties. 11 The three-economy model of Chor et al. (2007) also solves for a non-symmetric equilibrium where two countries in the North are identical whilst the South country is subject to financial frictions. However, in this model Southern producers are restricted to domestic output only and financial frictions only affect fixed costs of production. 12 It is straightforward to extend the approach to encompass capital or other factor inputs but for simplicity I focus on the labor input case. 6 I now turn to the form of the borrowing constraints. 3.1 Domestic borrowing constraint Domestic creditors face costs relative to the entrepreneur in recovering output which has been pledged to them. This may be due to the inalienability of human capital as emphasized in Hart & Moore (1994) or could reflect costs (in terms of output) of recovery when there is ex post moral hazard such as in Aghion et al. (1999) or costs of expropriation in the case of ex ante moral hazard. As in, for example, Kiyotaki (1998) and Aoki et al. (2006), these financial frictions restrict an entrepreneur's borrowing so that debt repayments do not exceed the value to the creditor of pledged output.13 Creditor recovery costs may differ with the creditor's nationality and the type of pledged receivables: Assumption 1 Creditors in the home economy can recover a fraction 0 < 1 of the domestic intermediate output which has been pledged to them by a home entrepreneur. The corresponding fraction for domestic intermediate output pledged by foreign entrepreneurs to foreign creditors is 0 < 1. The differential ability of home and foreign lenders to recover domestic outputs pledged by entrepreneurs in their respective economies can be thought to represent both the legal or judicial features of the economy and efficiency of the respective financial systems. Assumption 2 The recovery rate on export output pledged to a domestic creditor is a fraction µ times the recovery rate on domestic output in home and µ in foreign with µ 1 and µ 1. Assumption 2 is motivated by the firm-level empirical evidence from emerging and developing economies of the linkage between exporting and credit constraints.14 On the one hand any additional organizational or informational problems in recovering exports may reduce the relative ability of a creditor to recover exports compared to domestic out- put. On the other hand, certain institutional features, such as requirements to repatriate export revenues, could work in the opposite direction increasing the relative recovery rate on exports. Thus I allow µ to take values greater than or less than one subject to the restriction that the export recovery rate µ is bounded in the unit interval (and similarly for µ ). The creditor will only lend an amount such that gross repayments are less than or equal to the recovery value of output pledged to them. Thus the domestic credit constraint for a home entrepreneur indexed by can be expressed as: 13 Extending the model to add tangible assets, for example, capital or land, to the production function would provide an additional form of collateral that could be pledged to creditors. The creditor's recovery rates on these assets would then affect the optimal ratio of factor inputs. However, if creditors were unable to recover pledged output and could only recover pledged capital or land then financial constraints would only affect relative export to domestic prices if domestic and exporting activities had different production functions. 14 The requirement to pay the additional fixed exporting cost could also, in a situation of hidden information over entrepreneurial productivity, act as a signalling device of higher productivity which could facilitate lending. 7 Rt+1 bt+1 () revd,t+1 (yd,t+1 ()) + revx,t+1 (µyx,t+1 ()) (1) where Rt+1 bt+1 () are gross repayments made by the entrepreneur in time t + 1 do- mestic consumption goods for borrowing bt+1 () at time t. The creditor can recover a fraction of next period's domestic output by the entrepreneur yd,t+1 () . This pro- vides revenues of revd,t+1 (yd,t+1 ()) in units of the home consumption good. Similarly revx,t+1 (µyx,t+1 ()) represents the maximum value to the creditor, in units of the home consumption good, of the pledged export output yx,t+1 ().15 Thus exporting increases the potential pledgeable output to a creditor but, as detailed below, requires additional investment. In this set-up all investment is subject to the borrowing constraint. In contrast, in Chaney (2005) and Manova (2006) borrowing constraints only affect the fi- nancing of exporting costs. However, domestic production costs may also be subject to constraints and, due to the fungibility of funds, applying different constraints to the two types of costs may not be appropriate.16 4 Model Each economy is populated by two sets of infinitely-lived agents, households and en- trepreneurs, of mass L and M respectively (L and M in foreign).17 Both sets of agents maximize expected utility over a final consumption good which is produced using in- termediate goods. These intermediate goods are themselves produced by entrepreneurs using entrepreneurial and household labor inputs (with entrepreneurs not restricted to working on only their own projects). As mentioned above, agents are able to access do- mestic credit markets only. In the subsections below I first introduce the final goods and household sectors which provide the context for the subsequent analysis of entrepreneurs' optimal decisions. 4.1 Final goods sector The non-traded final consumption good in each country is produced using a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) combination of domestic and imported intermediate goods which are produced by home and foreign entrepreneurs respectively. For example, home final good production, Yt , is given by: [ ]/(-1) -1 -1 Yt = yd,t () d + yx,t () d (2) d,t x,t where yd,t () is the home final goods sector demand for an intermediate variety produced by a home entrepreneur; yx,t () is the demand from the home final goods sector for a variety produced by a foreign entrepreneur and exported to home; d,t 15 The subscripts d and x will be used throughout to denote domestic and exporting variables respec- tively. 16 In Antras & Caballero (2007) financial frictions (which apply in one sector) also apply to all pro- duction costs although the nature of revenues does not affect the credit constraint (which in their case limits total investment to a fraction of capital). 17 Foreign variables are denoted throughout by . 8 denotes the set of available domestically produced intermediate goods in home at time t; and, is the set of available intermediate goods in home which were produced by x,t foreign entrepreneurs and exported to home. The elasticity of substitution in production between different intermediate good varieties is > 1. For simplicity I assume that the elasticity of substitution between individual intermediates does not vary between foreign or home intermediates.18 A corresponding expression holds in the foreign economy with common substitution elasticities in both countries. Due to selection effects into exporting, the set of home-produced inputs available in home, d,t , may differ from the set of home- produced intermediate inputs available in foreign, x,t (and similarly for the set of foreign produced intermediate inputs available in foreign and home, and respectively). d,t x,t The final goods technology is open to all agents and takes place under perfect compe- tition. Intermediate goods are purchased to maximize profits given the final consumption good price (Pt at home and Pt in foreign) and the prices of individual intermediate goods. Profit maximization yields the standard domestic and export demand schedules for each intermediate good produced in home: ( )- pd,t () Domestic demand: yd,t () = Yt (3) Pt ( ) pX,t () - Export demand: yx,t () = Yt (4) Pt where pd,t () is the domestic price of variety produced by the home entrepreneur with px,t () the price charged for that variety when exported to the foreign country. With zero profits earned on final goods production, the aggregate price indices in home and foreign are given respectively by: [ ] 1- 1 1- 1- Pt = pd,t () d + p () x,t d (5) d,t x,t [ ] 1- 1 1- 1- Pt = p () d,t d + px,t () d d,t x,t With no money in the model the real exchange rate is equal to the ratio of aggregate prices indices in the foreign and home country, RERt = Pt /Pt . 4.2 Household sector The representative household in each economy gains utility from consumption of the non- traded final consumption good. In each economy the household labor endowment (L in home and L in foreign) is supplied inelastically in the domestic economy and receives a 18 Relaxing this assumption does not change the results substantively if the elasticity between home and foreign produced intermediates is above unity and less than the elasticity between varieties from the same country. Similarly, I abstract from any bias in final goods production towards home-produced intermediates. 9 l per unit household real wage in terms of the respective country consumption good (wt l in home and wt in foreign). Domestic borrowing by the household (denoted by bl for t+1 the home household ) is chosen to maximize expected utility given wage income and debt repayments. Household sector borrowing is assumed to be unconstrained. Whilst this is clearly an abstraction it greatly simplifies the analysis since the steady state interest rates are then determined from the household euler equation. The preferences of the home household are given by: ( ) Utl = s-t ln cl t (6) s=t where is the household discount rate (common to home and foreign households) and cl is the household's consumption of the home final good at time t. Consumption and t gross debt repayments (Rt bl in units of home consumption good) are funded from wage t income and new borrowings giving the household sector flow of funds as: l cl + Rt bl = wt L + bl t t t+1 (7) The first order conditions with respect to domestic borrowing give standard uncon- strained Euler equations (with corresponding equations for the foreign household). With log utility the household consumes a fraction (1 - ) of wealth in each period (ie the return on last period savings plus the discounted present value of future wage income). 4.3 Entrepreneurial sector Similar to households, entrepreneurs maximize expected utility over consumption and supply one unit of entrepreneurial labor in each period for which they receive an en- e e trepreneurial real wage (wt in home and wt in foreign). An entrepreneur's labor can be supplied to any producer, ie it is not restricted to use in the operation of the en- trepreneur's own production project.19 However, a number of crucial characteristics dis- tinguish entrepreneurs from households. First, they have access to an investment project by which they can produce intermediate goods for domestic and export markets. Second, entrepreneurs are heterogeneous in the productivity with which they produce interme- diate goods indexed by . The productivity distribution is invariant with cumulative distribution function G() and density function g (). Third, as discussed in Section 3, entrepreneurs face credit constraints which are affected by their choice over investment projects. Finally, entrepreneurs are more impatient than households. 4.3.1 Investment projects In each period the entrepreneur can choose to invest in a variety of projects. First, the entrepreneur may choose not to produce and simply save through domestic savings yielding a gross rate of return of Rt . Second the entrepreneur can invest in the production of intermediate goods for the domestic market. Third, the entrepreneur may choose to invest in production for both the domestic and export markets (given the cost structure detailed below an entrepreneur will never produce for domestic markets only). 19 Entrepreneurial labor income is required so that those entrepreneurs who do not produce in the steady state and are constrained to zero borrowing have positive consumption levels. 10 Similar to the multiple factor version of Melitz (2003) developed in Bernard et al. (2007b), intermediate goods production by home entrepreneurs requires a composite labor input of entrepreneurial and household labor which incorporates both a per period fixed cost, f , and a variable cost equal to 1/ per unit of next period output. There is a one period lag in production with next period's output requiring composite labor input today, lt (): yd,t+1 () lt () = +f (8) where yd,t+1 () is next period's production. The composite labor input is a con- stant returns-to-scale, Cobb-Douglas aggregate over household and entrepreneurial labor l e inputs, lt () and lt () respectively: lt () = lt () lt ()1- l e (9) where 0 < < 1. Cost minimization gives a composite wage wt which represents the cost ( l ) e per unit of composite labor input, wt = wt / (wt / (1 - ))1- . Producers of the final consumption good value a variety of intermediate inputs and so, given the fixed cost, each entrepreneur produces a differentiated intermediate good under monopolistic competition. If the entrepreneur wishes to export she must pay an additional fixed composite labor cost of fx per period. Exporting also incurs a variable iceberg transportation cost > 1 per unit exported. Since the fixed cost of production f is incurred whether or not the firm produces for the domestic market then the firm will always be better off producing for both the domestic and export markets than for the export market alone. In the former case an entrepreneur's total composite labor demand is given by: yd,t+1 () yx,t+1 () lt () = + + f + fx (10) 4.3.2 Entrepreneurial equity investment The entrepreneur's cost of composite labor investment in production projects, wt lt (), is financed by borrowings,ie external funds, of bt+1 (), and own equity investment, ie inter- nal funds. The level of equity investment is equal to At time t, the entrepreneur's equity investment is equal to her net worth entering the period, at (), plus the entrepreneurial wage received minus her consumption expenditure ct (). Thus the entrepreneur's flow of funds is: at () - ct () + wt + bt+1 () = wt lt () e (11) An entrepreneur's net worth entering time t + 1, at+1 (), is composed of the gross returns on the equity investment made in the previous period, at () - ct () + wt . I e define the gross rate of return on this investment realized at time t + 1 in units of home consumption good as Ft+1 (). Thus the transition of net worth is given by: at+1 () = Ft+1 () (at () - ct () + wt ) e (12) 11 The gross return varies with the entrepreneur's investment choice. Consider the case where the entrepreneur chooses to produce for domestic and export markets. In this case, the gross return represents total real revenues from production minus gross debt repayments: at+1 () = yd,t+1 () pd,t+1 () + yx,t+1 () px,t+1 () (13) - Rt+1 bt+1 () where the relative domestic and export prices compared with the aggregate price level in the producer's country of residence are given by pd,t () = pd,t () /Pt and px,t () = px,t () /Pt respectively. Given the flow of funds and the transition of net worth, the entrepreneur must choose how to allocate her net worth state variable at between consumption ct () and equity investment to maximize discounted utility: ut () = s-t ln (ct ()) (14) s=t The entrepreneurial discount rate, , is assumed common across countries with en- trepreneurs assumed to be more impatient than households ie < where is the house- hold discount rate.20 The first order condition with respect to borrowing is: ( ) 1 Ft+1 () = (15) ct () ct+1 () Combined with the net worth transition equation this yields the standard results with log utility that current consumption is a fixed fraction (1 - ) of current wealth (defined as net worth plus the value of future entrepreneurial labor income discounted by gross project returns). Using the Euler equation (15) and net worth transition (12), the entrepreneur's utility maximizing investment project choice is that with the highest return Ft+1 (). 4.3.3 Optimal investment project choice The returns from the different investment projects are derived from the entrepreneur's optimal choices over borrowing levels and production levels. This maximization is subject to the flow of funds (11), the net worth transition (12) and definition of the gross equity investment return (13), domestic borrowing constraints (1), the demand from domestic and overseas final goods producers (3 and 4 respectively). For the home entrepreneur, the first order condition with respect to domestic borrow- ing bt+1 () is : 20 A lower effective discount factor for entrepreneurs can equivalently be rationalized by assuming a death probability such that = and that a new generation of entrepreneurs are born each period such that the total population of entrepreneurs remains constant. The assumption of a lower discount rate for entrepreneurs is widely adopted in the related literature on financial constraints to ensure that the entrepreneur can never fully self-finance her investment. 12 ( ) 1/ct () = /ct+1 () + 1 () Rt+1 t (16) where 1 () is the multiplier on the domestic borrowing constraint (with correspond- t ing complementary slackness condition holding). The first order conditions with respect to domestic production, yd,t+1 (), and export production, yx,t+1 (), give the following relative pricing conditions:21 wt 1/ct () pd,t+1 () = (17) ( - 1) /ct+1 () + -1 1 () t -1 px,t+1 () /ct+1 () + 1 ()t = -1 (18) pd,t+1 () /ct+1 () + (µ) 1 () t How do prices differ from the case with no credit constraints? First, credit constraints introduce an additional pricing wedge vt+1 () > 1 over the standard unconstrained marginal cost plus fixed mark-up pricing rule. For example, for domestic production, the unconstrained relative price of a home entrepreneur pd,t+1 () = wt Rt+1 . The additional (-1) wedge added to domestic prices due to credit constraints is increasing in the cost of finance and the extent to which the constraint binds and is decreasing with the credit multiplier: ( ( -1 ) )-1 vt+1 () = 1 - Rt+1 1 - 1 ct () t () (19) A similar additional pricing wedge applies to export prices whose value also depends on the relative recovery rate on export output µ. Second, compared to the case without credit constraints, export prices differ from domestic prices due not only to the variable trade costs but also the differences in their respective pricing wedges. In turn these pricing wedges depend on the different treatment of export revenues to domestic revenues by creditors.22 Given the above optimal decisions of the entrepreneur it is possible to define the dif- ferent possible values of the gross return Ft+1 () associated with the different investment options. Comparison of these returns yields the optimal entrepreneurial choice between 1 no production (yielding return Ft+1 () = Rt+1 ); domestic only production (yielding re- 2 3 turn Ft+1 ()), and; domestic and export production (yielding return Ft+1 ()). Let the set of entrepreneurs in home and foreign be denoted and respectively. The set of home entrepreneurs who produce goods for domestic final goods producers, d,t+1 (where d,t+1 ), are the subset for whom Ft+1 () Ft+1 () and the set who also export 2 1 to foreign final goods producers, x,t+1 (where x,t+1 d,t+1 ), are those for whom 21 In the absence of aggregate uncertainty and given the CES demand functions which the entrepreneur faces, the choice of investment in the intermediate output project is equivalent to a decision on relative prices. 22 Interestingly, if export revenues confer a particularly strong financing advantage relative to domestic revenues, ie if µ is relatively high, then it could be the case that "dumping" occurs, ie export prices are below domestic prices, despite the presence of iceberg trade costs. 13 Ft+1 () Ft+1 () > Rt+1 . The investment decisions of foreign entrepreneurs can be 3 2 characterized in a similar manner. 4.4 Aggregate conditions In equilibrium, in each period market clearing conditions must hold in both economies for domestic entrepreneurial and household labor markets, credit markets, intermediate and final consumption goods markets. Funds market clearing implies that total borrowings within each economy are equal to zero (Bt+1 = B,t+1 = 0). For each intermediate good, total demand from final goods producers must equal entrepreneurial production. Final goods consumption also must equal final goods output in each country, ie Ct = Yt and Ct = Yt and the value of final goods output equals the value of inputs (by the zero profit condition for final goods producers). In addition to these market clearing conditions, the home and foreign aggregate pricing equations (Equation 5) must be satisfied. Finally, to close the model the balance of payments must be in equilibrium, ie with financial autarky net exports must equal zero: N Xt px,t () yx,t () d - RERt p () yx,t () d = 0 x,t (20) x,t x,t 4.5 Equilibrium definition To summarize, given household and entrepreneurial debt repayments and production levels entering period t, an equilibrium is defined by a path of aggregate relative prices {RERt , wt ,wt , Rt+1 , R,t+1 }, aggregate quantities {Yt ,Yt ,Ct , Ct ,Bt+1 ,B,t+1 }, individual entrepreneurial investment choices as reflected in intermediate goods relative prices {pd,t+1 (), px,t+1 (), p d,t+1 (), px,t+1 ()}, entrepreneurial credit constraint multipliers {t (), 1 1 t () }, final goods producer intermediate input demands {yd,t (), yx,t (),yd,t () ,yx,t ()}, household and entrepreneurial consumption levels {cl , ct (), cl , c ()} and t t t borrowing by home and foreign households and entrepreneurs {bl , bt+1 (), bl , t+1 ,t+1 b ,t+1 () } which are consistent with the optimal choices of households, entrepreneurs and final goods producers described above and which satisfy the above aggregate equilibrium conditions. In the sections below I focus on the properties of the steady state equilibrium given my interest in the long-run impact of the interactions between financial sector and trade reforms. 5 Domestic financial reforms with trade autarky In order to illustrate the channels through which domestic financial reforms affect ag- gregate productivity I first analyze the properties of the steady state equilibrium with financial and trade autarky. Each entrepreneur's productivity is invariant and so, with stable aggregate variables, the entrepreneurial project choice decision (and hence ag- gregate value of production) will be constant provided each entrepreneur's net worth is stable. In this case, each entrepreneur's consumption is also stable and so aggregate con- sumption will be stable if household consumption is unchanging. This gives the familiar 14 condition from the household Euler equations R = R = 1/. Given the assumption that entrepreneurs are more impatient than households then from the entrepreneurial first order conditions all entrepreneurs will be constrained by their respective domestic bor- rowing constraints. I can now pin down entrepreneurial prices and production decisions which, along with aggregate relative prices, can be used to specify the equilibrium. 5.1 Entrepreneurial production decisions Substituting the steady state multiplier on the borrowing constraint 1 () = (1/R - )/c () > 0 into the optimal relative prices expressions (17 and 18) gives steady state entrepreneurial relative prices in home (if an entrepreneur produces) of: w pd () = (21) d -1 where d = + ( - ) and = ( - 1) /. The term d can be thought as the reciprocal of the effective borrowing rate faced by entrepreneurs (as credit constraints fall the effective borrowing rate falls to the unconstrained rate of 1/). Thus, with a common , in the steady state the pricing wedges are constant across entrepreneurs. Using the intermediate good demand functions these prices determine entrepreneurial production levels and revenues. The comparison between an entrepreneur's gross returns from saving and from produc- tion of intermediates for domestic sale gives the familiar condition that the entrepreneur will only produce if her revenues exceed the borrowing costs associated with production. This is the case provided that the entrepreneur's productivity is sufficiently high, d where d is defined by: fw w f (d )1- pd (d ) yd (d ) = -1 = (22) ( - d ) d Y ( - d ) Entrepreneurs who have a productivity lower than d do not produce and, given that their credit constraints still bind, end up in the steady state just consuming their entrepreneurial wage each period. The mass of producing entrepreneurs is given by M (1 - G (d )). Following Melitz (2003), aggregate productivity, (d ), can be defined as a weighted average of the productivities of producing entrepreneurs:23 1/(-1) 1 (d ) = -1 g () d (23) 1 - G (d ) d A tightening of the credit multiplier on domestic revenues (ie fall in ) has two partial equilibrium effects on the cutoff through raising the entrepreneur's cost of production and hence price. On the one hand the higher price charged by the entrepreneur reduces revenues, increasing the term (d )1- . On the other hand higher prices are reflected in 23 As detailed in Melitz (2003), (d ) is the weighted harmonic mean of producing entrepreneurs' productivities with the weights given by their relative output shares. 15 reduced investment needs and hence repayments (increasing the term ( - d )). Whilst the former would tend to increase the productivity cutoff the latter may reduce the cutoff. In partial equilibrium, the net effect of these two forces is such that the former effect dominates and the partial derivative of the domestic productivity cutoff with respect to the domestic financial development is negative: d d (1 - ) ( - )2 =- <0 d ( - d ) Note that these comparative statics ignore the general equilibrium effect of financial development on the cutoff via aggregate prices and quantities. This is an important omission since, as shown below, the general equilibrium effect will tend to mean that higher financial development leads to a higher domestic production productivity cutoff. 5.2 Properties of the steady state autarky equilibrium Using the properties of the intermediate demand functions, the autarky equilibrium can be defined by a system of five equations in the real wage, domestic interest rate, domes- tic production cutoff, aggregate borrowing and final goods output. The corresponding equations are the household euler equation, the productivity cutoff definition, labor and credit market clearing conditions and the aggregate pricing equation. Proposition 1 In financial and trade autarky, there exists a unique steady state equilib- rium in home referenced by relative prices {w, R}, the domestic production cutoff {d } and aggregate quantities {Y, B} from which all other endogenous variables can be derived. With domestic financial sector reforms (ie increases in the credit multiplier ) the steady state comparative statics are as follows: · Average productivity of intermediate output rises through a reallocation of produc- tion towards more productive firms as the domestic production productivity cutoff, d , increases. · Real wages increase. · Aggregate consumption of the final good rises. Proof. See Appendix B.1. Thus by adding a simple credit constraint within this heterogeneous firm model, financial sector reforms increase real wages and average productivity through a realloca- tive process very similar to that emphasized in relation to trade liberalization. With households unconstrained, all the reallocative work is done by the wage rate and labor markets.24 If the credit multiplier is relaxed then, for a given wage, entrepreneurs lower their prices, increasing revenues and profits. The rise in has an intensive margin effect increasing investment of existing producers. Ceteris paribus, in partial equilibrium there 24 The comparative static results for average productivity and real wages with respect to the credit multiplier are similar to those in Aoki et al. (2006) when the credit constraint binds. However, in their model, with households also constrained, as the credit multiplier rises there is adjustment of the real interest rate as well as the real wage. 16 would also be an extensive margin effect since, with profits higher, more firms are induced to produce (see Figure 2). However, with lower prices and more varieties the real wage rate rises. This reduces revenues and raises costs. With profits reduced, lower productiv- ity firms exit production. As illustrated in Figure 2, the overall effect is an increase in the productivity required for entrepreneurs to make positive profits from domestic produc- tion.25 Equivalently for labor market clearing to hold the mass of producing firms must fall if the rise in induces greater labor demand across firms. Although the variety of intermediate inputs falls and the wage rises, the beneficial effects on unit costs of higher and higher average productivity lead to an overall rise in final goods production and consumption. Figure 2: Impact of credit multiplier on entrepreneurial production in trade au- tarky 6 Domestic financial reforms with trade openness The two economies are now open to trade in goods and entrepreneurs can choose whether to export intermediates in addition to selling them to domestic final goods producers. 6.1 Entrepreneurial production decisions When the economies are open to trade the relative price of exports to domestic output for a given entrepreneur is defined as follows: 25 Interestingly, in the model of Chor et al. (2008) the effect of a rise in financial development for a country affected by credit constraints is to reduce the productivity cut-off for domestic production. This is because in their set-up the wage rate is pinned down by the exogenous productivity of a homogenous good sector. Thus, absent the general equilibrium wage effects, there is no requirement for the productivity cut-off to rise to ensure that labor market clearing still holds. Instead there is an adjustment via the free-entry condition in their model whereby the level of aggregate demand in the economy must fall to ensure that the value of entry is still equal to the exogenously determined entry cost. 17 px () d = (24) pd () x -1 where x = + ( - ) (µ) is the reciprocal of the effective borrowing rate when export output is pledged as collateral. Compared to the standard model, the relative price of exports now depends not just on the trade costs but how export and domestic pledged output are treated by domestic creditors. If the relative pledgeabilty of export output, µ, rises then the relative price of export to domestic sales falls. As the overall domestic financial development rises the relative price of exports rises if µ < 1, ie if the fall in the pricing wedge is greater for domestic production, and falls if µ > 1. Again the comparison between an entrepreneur's gross returns to domestic production versus those for domestic and export production gives a productivity cutoff x above which the additional revenues from exporting as well as producing for domestic sales exceed the additional costs. The exporting productivity cutoff is defined by: fx w w RER- fx ( /x )-1 px (x ) yx (x ) = x = -1 ( - x ) Y ( - x ) The partial equilibrium effect of greater overall financial development and the ability to lend against export output, µ, is to reduce x , ie increase the propensity of intermediate producers to export. The ratio of the exporting to domestic production cutoff is given by: ( )-1 ( )-1 ( ) x -1 fx RER- Y d - d = (25) d f Y x - x The relative magnitudes of the exporting to domestic only productivity cutoff (and hence the likelihood of exporting given domestic production) can be decomposed into three terms. First, as variable and relative fixed trade costs increase, ie as -1 fx /f rises, - the relative level of the exporting cutoff increases. Second, the terms RER Y reflect Y the relative scale of demand from foreign compared to domestic final goods producers. The higher relative foreign demand the lower the cutoff ratio x /d . The third term, reflecting financial constraints in the pledging of both domestic and export output, is the novel feature compared to the related literature. Focusing on this third effect, if the relative ability of creditors to recover exports compared to domestic output, µ, rises then the partial equilibrium effect is to increase propensity of producers to export. However, the impact of changes in overall financial development, , is ambiguous. This is because, in contrast to Chaney (2005) and Manova (2006), domestic production is also subject to credit constraints. Thus, a rise in will reduce both the domestic and export production cutoffs in partial equilibrium. For µ less than one, a rise in overall financial development from a low level initially will tend to increase the relative exporting cutoff since it has a greater effect on the domestic production cutoff. As financial development rises the elasticity of the relative cutoff with respect to falls. If the relative recovery rate µ is greater than one then the effects are in the opposite directions. 18 In line with firm-level empirical evidence which suggests a partitioning of producing firms into exporters and non-exporters I focus on situations where x /d > 1. Given this ordering of the production cutoffs, home entrepreneurs can be partitioned into those who do not produce ( < d ), those who produce for domestic markets only (d < d ) and those who produce for export as well as domestic markets (x ). Similar expressions can be derived in foreign for and . The average productivity of d x intermediate production with trade, T , can be expressed as a weighted sum of the average productivity of domestic production, (d ), and export production, (x ), where the weights take into account the relative mass of exporters to total producers and the relative level of export production (including iceberg trade costs) to domestic production for a given entrepreneur.26 6.2 Properties of non-symmetric financial autarky steady state equilibrium The symmetric case can be shown to be unique without the need for specific distributional assumptions. However, given that financial reforms in particular are undertaken in a domestic economy without the need for corresponding reforms in trading partners, it is of more interest to focus on the non-symmetric equilibrium. Following the related literature I adopt the empirically plausible Pareto distribution for the numerical solutions where G() = 1 - (min /)a with min > 0 the lower-bound productivity and a is the distribution shape parameter.27 Under this distributional assumption the non-symmetric steady state equilibrium under financial autarky is uniquely defined. Proposition 2 In financial autarky with entrepreneurial productivity following a Pareto distribution, there exists a unique steady state equilibrium with costly goods trade which can be uniquely defined by a system of thirteen equations in relative prices {w, w , R, R , RER}, domestic market production and exporting cutoffs {d , x , , } and aggregate quanti- d x ties {Y, Y , B, B } from which all other endogenous variables can be derived. The cor- responding equations are the home and foreign household euler equations, the definitions of the four productivity cutoffs, labor and credit market clearing conditions at home and abroad, the balance of payments condition (ie balanced trade given financial autarky) and the two countries' aggregate pricing equations. Proof. See Appendix B.2. 6.2.1 Numerical parameter values In the numerical examples below I focus solely on the impact of differences in credit multipliers between countries with all other parameters identical. For the production and productivity distribution parameters I follow Bernard et al. (2007b) in setting the elasticity of substitution between different varieties = 3.8 based on the estimates from US data of Bernard et al. (2003), the shape parameter of the Pareto distribution at 26 See Appendix C.1 for details. 27 For simplicity the shape parameter a is common across countries (although the lower bound produc- tivity can be different across countries). Helpman et al. (2004) illustrate the empirical fit of the Pareto distribution and note that the assumption that a > -1 is required to ensure finite variances of revenues. 19 a = 3.4 and the minimum productivity min = 0.2. The discount factors of households and entrepreneurs are set at = 0.96 and = 0.92 respectively (yielding a steady state annual real interest rate of 4%). The share of household labor costs in total labor costs is set at = 0.985 following Bernanke et al. (1999) since entrepreneurial production rather than their labor income is the focus of the model. For simplicity the fixed costs of domestic and export production are set equal to one composite labor unit in both countries. Labor endowments are identical across countries with the masses of labor and entrepreneurs which rescale the results set at L = L = 100 and M = M = 20 giving an export propensity of producers of around 30% when variable trade costs = 1.4.28 This compares, for example, to estimates of around 21% of plants in the 1991 US Census of Manufactures Bernard et al. (2003). In developing economies, Aitken et al. (1997) find that around 27% of a 1986 and 1989 sample of Mexican manufacturing plants were exporters whilst the samples of Clerides et al. (1998) have 35% of Moroccan plant as exporters (1984-1991), 9.5% of Colombian plants (1981-1991) and a comparable number of 23% for Mexican plants (1986-1990). 6.2.2 Impact of reforms to home financial sector Before considering trade and financial reform interactions I first illustrate how home financial sector reforms affect both the home and the foreign economy for given trade costs. This aids understanding of the mechanisms through which the different reform policies interact. I compare the steady state equilibria with goods trade (subject to symmetric iceberg trade costs = = 1.4) under different values of home financial development (ie varying the credit multipliers and µ) with foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Entrepreneurial propensity to produce and export As illustrated in Figure 3, as the home credit multipliers rise the domestic production productivity cutoff in home rises via the same channels as in autarky (ie increasing investment via the intensive margin with the resulting real wage rise increasing costs and causing lower productivity firms to drop out of production).29 The higher wage costs also cause the export production productivity cutoff in home to rise. In the foreign economy the impact of changes in all take place via the trade channel. In particular in this general equilibrium set-up home financial development affects not just home export propensity (which has been emphasised in, for example, Chaney, 2005; Manova, 2006) but also the export propensities of foreign firms, as is also the case in the three-country analysis of Chor et al. (2008). In the home economy the rise in affects the export propensity (ie the ratio x /d ) through two channels. The first is an ambiguously signed partial equilibrium effect via the relative financing constraints on domestic and export revenues. The second effect is through the general equilibrium effect via the real exchange rate in reducing the relative demand for foreign relative to home intermediates . In the home economy the net effect in this illustration is that the propensity to export increases with home financial development 28 Such trade costs are of similar order to the 44% estimate of border-related trade barriers in the representative trade costs outlined in Anderson & van Wincoop (2004). 29 It can also be shown analytically that the domestic production productivity cutoff in the home economy rises with an increase in the relative pledgeability of exports, µ. 20 if the relative pledgeability of export output µ is low but falls with for low µ. In the foreign economy it is only the general equilibrium effect that is at work with a rise in home financial development causing a fall in relative demand for foreign intermediates resulting in a reduction in the foreign entrepreneurs' propensity to export. This reduces overall labor demand and the domestic production cutoff in foreign falls slightly to ensure market clearing. Whilst these results are illustrative they indicate a potential channel through which the financial development in one economy can spill over to the production and export patterns of trading partners. Figure 3: Impact of home overall financial development on entrepreneurial produc- tion cutoffs and propensity to export (a) Domestic sales cutoff (b) Exporting cutoff Home Foreign Home Foreign 0.316 0.316 0.44 0.44 0.314 0.314 0.312 0.312 0.435 0.435 0.31 0.31 Productivity, Productivity, Productivity, Productivity, 0.308 0.308 0.43 0.43 0.306 0.306 0.304 0.304 0.425 0.425 0.302 0.302 0.3 0.3 0.298 0.298 0.42 0.42 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 (c) Entrepreneurial conditional ex- port propensity Home Foreign 0.34 0.34 Conditional probability of exporting Conditional probability of exporting 0.335 0.335 0.33 0.33 0.325 0.325 0.32 0.32 0.315 0.315 0.31 0.31 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 Note: Home and foreign identical except credit multipliers. Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Variable iceberg trade cost = = 1.4. The varying lengths of the plots against for different values of µ reflect the restriction that µ 1 as detailed in Assumption 2. Real wages and real exchange rate As in the trade autarky case the home real wage rises with the home credit multiplier (Figure 4), ie the home final good price falls. This reflects a combination of lower mark-ups for existing producers and a rise in the average productivity of domestic and imported inputs which more than offset the reduction in varieties of inputs. In the foreign economy, the direct mark-up effect is not present with the result being that the lower variety of imports contributes to a fall in the foreign real 21 wage as the home credit multiplier increases. Thus the real exchange rate rises with the home credit multipliers as home and foreign final goods prices fall and rise respectively. Figure 4: Impact of home overall financial development on composite real wages and real exchange rate under financial autarky (a) Real wages (b) Real exchange rate Home Foreign 1.03 0.79 0.8 1.02 0.785 0.79 1.01 Real exchange rate 0.78 1 0.775 0.78 0.99 Real wage Real wage 0.77 0.77 0.98 0.765 0.97 0.76 0.76 0.96 0.755 0.75 0.95 0.75 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 : Home credit multiplier 0.745 0.74 µ=0.67 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 µ=1 : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier µ=1.33 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 Note: Home and foreign identical except credit multipliers. Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Variable iceberg trade cost = = 1.4. Intermediate output productivity and firm size As the home credit multiplier rises lower productivity domestic producers and exporters exit in the home economy. This increases the weighted average home productivity of intermediate goods producers and the average size of producing entrepreneurs (Figure 5). In the foreign economy there is a slight fall in the aggregate intermediate productivity and firm size reflecting the slight decrease in the domestic production cutoff. Exports From the properties of the demand functions for intermediate inputs, the relative value of exports to total intermediate sales (both in units of domestic final con- sumption good) at the entrepreneurial level is a function of the exporting and domestic production cutoffs and is identical across entrepreneurs. For a home entrepreneur this ratio is given by: ( ( )-1 )-1 f ( - x ) x exrat = 1 + (26) fx ( - d ) d The impact of changes in on a home entrepreneur's export ratio combines two effects. First there is the impact on x /d which, as detailed in Equation 25, embodies relative de- mand from home and foreign final goods producers, financing differences between exports and domestic revenues and trade costs. Second, there is the impact on relative net profits per variable unit sold between export and domestic sales (ie ( - x ) / ( - d )). The overall effect depends on the relative ability of entrepreneurs to pledge exports compared to domestic output to creditors. In the home economy, the illustrations suggest that 22 Figure 5: Impact of home overall financial development on intermediate output productivity and average size of producing entrepreneurs (a) Intermediate output average productiv- ity (b) Intermediate producer average size Home Foreign Home Foreign 0.6 0.6 11 11 Intermediate output per producing entrepreneur Intermediate output per producing entrepreneur Weighted average intermediate productivity Weighted average intermediate productivity 0.595 0.595 10.5 10.5 0.59 0.59 0.585 0.585 10 10 0.58 0.58 9.5 9.5 0.575 0.575 0.57 0.57 9 9 0.565 0.565 8.5 8.5 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 Note: Home and foreign identical except credit multipliers. Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Variable iceberg trade cost = = 1.4. Figure 6: Impact of home overall financial development on firm- and aggregate-level export to total intermediate revenue ratios under financial autarky (a) Entrepreneurial export ratio (b) Aggregate export ratio Home Foreign Home Foreign 0.285 0.285 0.246 0.246 0.284 0.284 0.245 0.245 Entrepreneur export ratio Entrepreneur export ratio Aggregate export ratio Aggregate export ratio 0.283 0.283 0.244 0.244 0.282 0.282 0.243 0.243 0.281 0.281 0.242 0.242 0.28 0.28 0.241 0.241 0.279 0.279 0.24 0.24 0.278 0.278 0.239 0.239 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 : Home credit multiplier : Home credit multiplier Home credit multiplier Home credit multiplier µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 Note: Revenues in units of domestic consumption good. Home and foreign identical except credit multipliers. Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Variable iceberg trade cost = = 1.4. 23 an entrepreneur's export ratio increases with if µ is high enough but has an inverted U-shaped response if µ is relatively low as illustrated in Figure 6. Changes in home only affect a foreign entrepreneur's export ratio in financial autarky via the impact on the propensity to export, ie via the direct trade channel. With the foreign propensity to export falling (ie / rising) with this implies a decrease in a foreign entrepreneur's x d export ratio as its trading partner's financial development improves. In the home economy the positive intensive margin effect on exports of improved home financial development combines with a generally positive extensive margin effect (for all but high levels of relative pledgeability of exports µ) to give an overall increase in the ratio of aggregate intermediate exports to total sales. In the foreign economy, the ratio of aggregate intermediate exports to total sales falls as . This reflects both an intensive margin effect (through lower relative demand from home final goods producers for foreign intermediate exports) and an extensive margin effect through the rise in the exporting production cutoff. Household and entrepreneurial utility Household steady state consumption is dependent upon household wage income and the net return on steady state house- hold savings (which, from domestic funds market clearing, are defined by aggregate en- trepreneurial borrowing). Thus the effects of changes in home financial development on household utility can be split into a household wage effect and entrepreneurial borrowing effects. The latter can be categorized as a direct pledging effect whereby a rise in for given revenues will increase entrepreneurial borrowing capacity, an intensive margin ef- fect on output via the wage and an extensive margin effect on the mass of producing and exporting entrepreneurs who are able to borrow. In the home economy a rise in leads to a rise in wages and a positive direct pledging effect which more than offsets the extensive margin effects of higher production cutoffs and thus increases household utility (Figure 7). In the foreign economy, with financial autarky, there is no direct pledging effect from changes in and the wage effect via the trade channel leads to a fall in household utility. Turning to entrepreneurs, the steady state consumption of non-producing entrepreneurs, who are constrained and hence cannot borrow, is solely their entrepreneurial wage income. The consumption of producing entrepreneurs depends on both their entrepreneurial wage income and their profits from total sales (which are increasing in entrepreneurial produc- tivity).30 Focusing on the home economy, as rises wages increase which unambiguously increases the utility of non-producing entrepreneurs. However, for given productivity higher implies lower profits from production as wages and production costs rise. Thus, for low productivity entrepreneurs utility rises with but for higher productivity produc- ing entrepreneurs the negative profit effect more than outweighs the positive income effect and utility falls with (see Figure 7). This feature can be viewed as similar in nature to the interest group theory proposed by Rajan & Zingales (2003) whereby incumbent producers may oppose financial sector reforms because it reduces their profits. 6.2.3 Interaction of reforms to trade and to the domestic financial sector Having illustrated how changes in home financial development affect both the home and foreign economy in the presence of trade I now turn to the interaction of financial sector 30 Appendix C.2 provides further details on the composition of entrepreneurial steady state utility. 24 Figure 7: Impact of home overall financial development on steady state utility under financial autarky (a) Household utility (b) Home entrepreneurial utility Home Foreign 110 110 -35.2 109.5 109.5 -35.4 Entrepreneurial utility Household utility Household utility -35.6 109 109 -35.8 -36 108.5 108.5 -36.2 0.5 1 0.4 0.8 108 108 0.6 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0.3 0.4 Home credit multiplier Home credit multiplier 0.2 Productivity, 0.2 0 µ=0.67 µ=0.67 : Home credit multiplier µ=1 µ=1 µ=1.33 µ=1.33 Note: Home and foreign identical except credit multipliers. Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Variable iceberg trade cost = = 1.4. and trade reforms. In particular I consider the level and marginal effects on the home economy of symmetric changes in the iceberg variable trade costs and how these effects vary with the home credit multipliers (with the foreign credit multipliers set at = 0.5 and µ = 1).31 In doing so it is convenient to define a trade freeness measure T F = 1- which lies between zero and one with T F = 0 as tends to infinity and T F = 1 for = 1. Home entrepreneurial propensity to produce and export: trade liberalization For given credit multipliers, the impact of trade liberalization between two economies who are already open to trade follows a similar pattern to that in the original Melitz (2003) setup. A rise in trade freeness leads to a rise in the domestic production cutoff, a fall in the exporting cutoff and rise in the propensity of producers to export in both countries. However, as illustrated in Figure 8, the magnitude of the marginal impact on the domestic production cutoff of these changes in trade freeness appears to increase with home financial development. When home financial development is relatively high the intensive and extensive margin effects of trade liberalization on labor demand are am- plified leading to a greater required rise in the domestic production cutoff to ensure labor market clearing. Whilst the marginal fall in export prices through trade liberalization is reduced at higher levels of financial development the marginal impact on overall labor demand is higher due to the looser borrowing constraint. Although not illustrated, as in the standard model greater trade freeness increases export propensity and aggregate- and firm-level export ratios. The impact of the level of the credit multiplier is of unclear 31 Although asymmetric changes in trade costs can be analyzed within the model I focus on symmetric changes in trade costs to reflect, for example, the implementation of bilateral trade agreements involving common tariff liberalization or the effect of common reductions in transport costs. 25 direction. Figure 8: Impact of symmetric changes in variable trade costs on home en- trepreneurial production cutoffs (a) Domestic sales cutoff (b) Exporting cutoff Level Derivative wrt trade freeness Level Derivative wrt trade freeness 0.36 // 0.07 0.48 -0.05 0.35 -0.1 0.46 Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness 0.34 -0.15 0.44 0.33 0.065 Productivity, Productivity, -0.2 0.32 0.42 -0.25 0.31 0.4 -0.3 0.3 0.06 0.38 -0.35 0.29 0.36 -0.4 0.28 0.27 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.055 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0.34 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 -0.45 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 Note: Home and foreign identical except overall credit multipliers and . Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Home real wages and real exchange rate: trade liberalization Trade liberaliza- tion increases the variety of imported inputs used in final goods production. Whilst the rise in the domestic production cutoff reduces the variety of domestic inputs they are of a higher productivity. The net effect is a fall in the aggregate price level and increase in home real wages. The real wage gains from trade opening appear to be greater if over- all financial sector development is lower and, for given , if the relative pledgeability of export output is higher (Figure 9). The intuition is that with high the aggregate price level at home is relatively low and thus the less the impact of any additional fall in prices due to the trade liberalization. The rise in trade freeness also increases the real wage in the foreign economy with the marginal impact also greater if home financial development is relatively low. The interplay of these two relative price changes suggests that if home development is lower than that in foreign then the real exchange rate is less than one and is falling with greater trade freeness. Home intermediate output productivity and firm size: trade liberalization Additional labor demand stimulated by increasing investment in export production as trade freeness rises leads to a rise in the domestic production productivity cutoff. This contributes to a rise in intermediate productivity and average size of producing en- trepreneurs (Figure 10). Reflecting the corresponding greater marginal effect of trade liberalization on the domestic production productivity cutoff these effects are enhanced at higher levels of financial development (and at higher levels of relative export pledge- ability for given ). Thus, in contrast with their impact on real wages trade and financial sector reforms appear to have complementary effects on aggregate productivity and firm- size. 26 Figure 9: Impact of symmetric changes in variable trade costs on home composite real wages and the real exchange rate (a) Real wages (b) Real exchange rate Level Derivative wrt trade freeness Level Derivative wrt trade freeness 0.9 // 0.175 1.04 // 0.04 1.03 0.03 Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness 0.85 0.17 1.02 0.02 Real exchange rate 1.01 0.01 Real wage 0.8 0.165 1 0 0.99 0.75 0.16 -0.01 0.98 -0.02 0.7 0.155 0.97 0.96 -0.03 0.65 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.15 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0.95 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 -0.04 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 Note: Home and foreign identical except overall credit multipliers and . Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Figure 10: Impact of symmetric changes in variable trade costs on home interme- diate productivity and average size of producing entrepreneurs (a) Intermediate output average productiv- ity (b) Intermediate producer average size Level Derivative wrt trade freeness Level Derivative wrt trade freeness // // Intermediate output per producing entrepreneur 0.68 0.15 16 10 Weighted average intermediate productivity 0.66 0.14 14 Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness 0.64 9.5 0.13 0.62 12 0.6 0.12 10 9 0.58 0.11 0.56 8 0.1 8.5 0.54 0.09 6 0.52 0.5 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.08 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 4 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 8 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness Trade freeness =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 Note: Home and foreign identical except overall credit multipliers and . Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. 27 Figure 11: Impact of symmetric changes in variable trade costs on steady state home household utility under financial autarky Level Derivative wrt trade freeness 113 // 6 112 5.8 Derivative w.r.t. trade freeness 5.6 111 Household utility 5.4 110 5.2 109 5 108 4.8 107 4.6 106 0 // 0.4 0.6 0.8 4.4 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Trade freeness Trade freeness =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=0.75 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.25, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=0.75 =0.75, µ=1.25 =0.75, µ=1.25 Note: Home and foreign identical except overall credit multipliers and . Foreign credit multipliers constant at = 0.5 and µ = 1. Home household and entrepreneurial utility: trade liberalization In terms of household utility, lower trade costs increase wage income. They also affect household saving (ie constrained entrepreneurial borrowing) via intensive and extensive margin ef- fects on total pledgeable output for exporters and domestic producers. As rises the real wage gains fall whilst the extensive margin effects increase (as the change in cutoffs rises). Overall, these effect combine to reduce the benefits to household utility from trade opening as rises for given µ (see Figure 11). This result is intuitive - using one policy tool, ie trade opening, to improve the allocation of production leads to less utility gain for consumer households if the resource allocation is more efficient in the first place through stronger financial development. However, the utility gains from trade liberalization are enhanced if, for given , the relative ability to pledge export output compared to domestic output is increased. Although not illustrated, for a given level of financial development, entrepreneurial utility increases with trade openness. Entrepreneurial wage income rises whilst produc- ers gain from increased demand and a greater propensity to export (despite the rise in production costs through higher wages). In terms of the interaction of trade reforms and financial reforms, the picture is somewhat complex combining the relative effects on both wages and intensive and extensive productive margins. However, the utility loss for higher productivity entrepreneurs in moving from low to higher financial development (ie increasing ) which was illustrated in Figure 7 appears to be reduced when trade open- ness is higher. This is consistent with the interest group theory of financial development outlined in Rajan & Zingales (2003) whereby the opposition of incumbent producers to financial reforms is weakened when an economy is open to international trade.32 32 Rajan & Zingales also argue that opposition to domestic financial reforms will be reduced when the economy is open to international finance, a feature from which the current model abstracts. 28 7 Conclusions This paper provides a tractable extension of a two-economy heterogeneous firm model to incorporate financial constraints affecting both domestic and export production. In doing so it enables analysis of trade and domestic financial sector policy changes across countries in a non-symmetric setting and provides some important insights into the mechanisms through which the two reforms can reallocate production within the two economies, their potential similarities and their interactions. In particular, numerical illustrations suggest that on the one hand domestic financial sector reforms, in facilitating greater investment, can enhance the marginal effects of trade liberalization in increasing average productivity and firm size. On the other hand, at higher levels of financial development the marginal benefits of trade liberalization in reducing aggregate prices and raising real wages and household utility may be reduced. The numerical illustrations also highlight the role of exports as collateral in amplifying the benefits of trade liberalization and the channels through which domestic financial sector reforms may be transmitted to trading partners. The analysis of the macroeconomic impact of the interactions of trade and domestic financial sector reforms within a general equilibrium heterogeneous firm setting provides a novel addition to the existing theoretical literature and is complementary to a growing empirical literature on the impact of financial constraints on trade and FDI. However, it also highlights the need for additional empirical research on the quantitative significance of these interaction effects since, as noted by Banerjee & Duflo (2005), the question of whether there are potential gains from adding multiple sources of inefficiency to models to explain productivity differences across countries is dependent upon their empirical relevance. The evidence from existing studies on these interactions is limited. At the macro level, Chang et al. (2005) provide support for the complementary effects of financial development and trade openness on growth. At the firm-level, Topalova (2004), for example, considers whether the impact on productivity of trade reforms in India varies across states by financial depth and finds that although the point estimates are similar in states with high or low credit to GDP they are only significant in the former. Further empirical analysis on the interaction of the reallocative effects of trade and financial reforms and their joint impact on aggregate productivity levels is of particular interest. A focus for future work is thus to extend the model to a multi-sector set-up to derive empirically testable predictions on the effects of reform interactions to be applied to sectoral data on average firm-size and labor productivity. In addition to these important empirical steps there is the potential to modify the model to address other policy relevant issues. For example, to extend the analysis beyond the steady state in order to examine the transitional impact of reforms or to incorporate the potential reallocative effects of international financial liberalization emphasized by Aoki et al. (2006). 29 A EBRD transition indicators Full details of the EBRD transition indicator score methodology are available at www.ebrd.com. The transition indicators cover up to 29 Eastern European and former Soviet Union economies from 1989 to 2007: Albania, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Bosnia and Herze- govina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, FYR Macedonia, Georgia, Hun- gary, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldova, Mongolia, Montenegro, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Serbia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, and Uzbekistan. The transition indicator scores are based on a judgement of an economy's progress rel- ative to defined classifications. Scores range from 1 (little change from centrally planned economy) through to 4+ (defined as 4.33) which represents norms of advanced industrial economies. Trade measure also includes restrictions to current account convertibility. In addition to the banking sector measure indicated in the figures below there is also an indicator for non-bank financial institutions and securities markets. The trade and foreign exchange (FX) indicator ranges from a value of 1 through to 4+ (graded by the EBRD as 4.33) with "1: Widespread import and/or export controls or very limited legitimate access to foreign exchange; 2: Some liberalization of import and/or export controls; almost full current account convertibility in principle, but with a foreign exchange regime that is not fully transparent (possibly with multiple exchange rates); 3: Removal of almost all quantitative and administrative import and export re- strictions; almost full current account convertibility; 4: Removal of all quantitative and administrative import and export restrictions (apart from agriculture) and all signifi- cant export tariffs; insignificant direct involvement in exports and imports by ministries and state-owned trading companies; no major non-uniformity of customs duties for non- agricultural goods and services; full and current account convertibility; 4+: Standards and performance norms of advanced industrial economies: removal of most tariff barriers; membership in WTO." The corresponding definitions for the banking reform and interest rate liberalization transition indicator are "1: Little progress beyond establishment of a two-tier system; 2: Significant liberalization of interest rates and credit allocation; limited use of directed credit or interest rate ceilings; 3: Substantial progress in establishment of bank solvency and of a framework for prudential supervision and regulation; full interest rate liberal- ization with little preferential access to cheap refinancing; significant lending to private enterprizes and significant presence of private banks; 4: Significant movement of banking laws and regulations towards BIS standards; well-functioning banking competition and effective prudential supervision; significant term lending to private enterprizes; substan- tial financial deepening; 4+: Standards and performance norms of advanced industrial economies: full convergence of banking laws and regulations with BIS standards; provi- sion of full set of competitive banking services." 30 Figure 12: EBRD transition indicators, 5 year averages: levels and changes after removing country and period fixed effects (a) Levels (b) Change compared to previous period Change in trade and FX transition indicator MNE 2 KGZ LVA LTU 1 GEO AZE Trade and FX transition indicator MDA KAZ SRB BIH TJK ROU ARMSRB MNE EST SRB TKM MNG ALB GEO MNG RUS 1 MNE UZB AZE BIH CZE UKR BGR UKR SVK BLR UZB MDA ARM RUS UKR KGZ ROU ARM KAZ POL HRV MKD SVN GEO BLR MKD AZE GEO BIH 0 HUN BLR KAZ MNE MDA EST LTU TJK TJK MNG RUS RUS KGZ AZE LTU SRB LVA SVN HUN TKM ALB ALB HRV BGR LVA GEO POL CZE SVK HRV KGZ ROU EST AZE MNGBGR LTU LVA CZE CZE EST KGZ MDA ALB ARMARM SVN UKR ROU UZB BIH LVA MKD SVK HRV SVN SVK MDA EST ROU POL TJK MKD MDALTULTU BGR HRVMNG POL KGZ UKRARMHUN TJK TKM MKD UZB POL SVN HUN HUN ALB BGR SVK LVA BLR UKR KAZ MNG CZE SVKCZE HRV ROU BIH 0 BGR MNE TKMEST BGR TJK KAZ MKD RUSPOL KAZ ALB MKD ALB SVN HRV SVK EST BLR SVN BLR CZE UZB UKR POLGEO AZE HUN ROU KAZ HUN TJK SRB BLR UZB -1 TKM RUS UZB AZE MNG RUS ARM TKM LTU LVA GEO MDA KGZ BIH TKM -1 SRB BIH MNE -2 -2 SRB MNE -1 -.5 0 .5 1 -1 -.5 0 .5 1 Banking transition indicator Change in banking transition indicator Note: Values of the transition indicators range from 1 to 4.33 with higher values representing standards moving towards those of advanced industrial economies. Averages taken over 1989-1993, 1994-1998, 1999-2003 and 2004-2007 (four year average). Plots indicate residuals from regressions controlling for country and period fixed effects. Lines represent lowess smoother (locally weighted regression) with 95% confidence intervals. B Proofs B.1 Steady state equilibrium with trade and financial autarky - Proof of existence and uniqueness The steady state equilibrium in home can be defined by the following system of five equations in relative prices {w, R}, domestic market production cutoff {d } and aggregate quantities {Y, B} from which all other endogenous variables can be derived: Household Euler equation: R = 1/ ( )1- Domestic production cutoff: -1 = w f(-d ) d Y d Funds market clearing: B = 0 Labor market clearing: L M - /f = H (d , d ) where H (d , d ) = -d A (d )+1- d G (d ) and A (d ) = (/d )-1 g () d. H (d , d ) is increasing in d and decreasing d in d . -1 -1 Aggregate Pricing equation: w = M (d ) -1 g () d d To prove existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium first consider the labor market clearing condition. H (d , d ) is continuously differentiable (provided g (d ) is defined) and tends to zero as d and tends to infinity as d 0. There is thus a unique value of d for which the labor market clearing condition holds. Substituting the equilibrium value of d into the aggregate pricing equation uniquely defines the real wage. The 31 domestic production cutoff then uniquely defines final goods output Y . The real interest rate and aggregate borrowing are defined by the euler equation and funds market clearing respectively. Comparative statics with respect to : · d > 0: From the labor market clearing condition, using the implicit function theorem the equilibrium cutoff value can be shown to be increasing in . · w > 0: Using the definition of the real wage from the aggregate pricing equation and the expression for d / it can be shown that the real wage is increasing in . · Y > 0: In the productivity cutoff equation substitute in for wages from the ag- gregate pricing equation. Using the labor market clearing condition with some manipulation one obtains final goods output as a function of d independent of giving Y / d / > 0. B.2 Non-symmetric steady state equilibrium with financial au- tarky - Proof of existence and uniqueness ( )-1 pd (d )yd (d ) Using the fact that pd ( )yd ( ) = plus the domestic production productivity d ( )-1 d fw cutoff then pd (d ) yd (d ) = (-d ) . Similar expressions can be used to define d exporting revenues in relation to x and also for variable labor demand. The steady state equilibrium can be defined by the following system of thirteen equations in relative prices {w, w , R, R , RER}, domestic market production and exporting cutoffs {d , x , , } d x and aggregate quantities {Y, Y , B, B } from which all other endogenous variables can be derived: Household Euler equations: R = 1/; R = 1/ (27) Domestic production cutoff definitions: w f (d )1- -1 = (28) d Y ( - d ) w f ( )1- -1 d = (29) d Y ( - ) d Relative cutoffs x / and /d (which cancel out foreign and domestic final goods d x production): ( )-1 ( )- x RER w = (30) d w ( )-1 ( ) x RER w = (31) d w 32 where: ( )-1 ( ) ( )-1 ( ) fx - f d - d d d ; x f x - x f x - x Composite labor market clearing conditions: -a = 1 - 2 -a d x (32) -a -a d = 1 - 2 x (33) where: L M - fx (1 + kx / ( - x )) 1 ; 2 (1 + kd / ( - d )) f min a f (1 + kd / ( - d )) with k = a/(a - + 1). and are correspondingly defined using foreign variables. 1 2 Funds market clearing conditions: B = B = 0 (34) Balance of trade conditions: ( )a w x RER = (35) w x ( )a where M ffx(-xx)) min . M x (- min Aggregate pricing equations in home and foreign respectively: 1 = w1- -1-a 1 + (RER w )1- -1-a d x 2 (36) 1- -1-a + (RER/ w)-1 x -1-a 1=w d 1 2 (37) where: 1 (d )-1 kM a ; 2 ( / )-1 kM a min x min ( )-1 kM a ; (x / )-1 kM a 1 d min 2 min Noting that the labor market clearing conditions define the domestic productivity cutoffs as functions of exporting cutoffs in each country and using the balance of trade condition to substitute out for RER the relative cutoff equations define a system in the two exporting cuts: ( )-1 (( ) ) - a x x ( ) -a -1/a = x (38) - 1 2 x ( )-1 (( )a ) ( x -a )-1/a = x (39) 1 - 2 x x 33 Each of these equations describe an upward sloping locus in { , x }. Dividing the two x equations gives a downward sloping curve which can be shown to intersect (38) uniquely at positive values of the two exporting cutoffs. As mentioned I focus on the case for which x / > 1 and / > 1 which implies that parameter values must satisfy > 1. x For the equilibrium values of x and the wages can be uniquely obtained from the x aggregate pricing equations (again once the real exchange rate has been substituted in): ( )1- -1 (( )a )-1 -1 -a a -1-a w = 1 - 2 x +1 x x 2 (40) x (( )a )1- ( ) -1 -a 1- a x -1-a w -1 = 1 - 2 x 1 + x 2 (41) x Domestic production cutoffs can be obtained from the labor market clearing conditions given the equilibrium values of x and which combined with equilibrium wages then x determine equilibrium output from the domestic production productivity cutoffs. From these variables all other individual steady state choice variables can be determined. Given the existence of a unique equilibrium the model can be solved numerically using standard techniques. C Trade steady state C.1 Weighted average productivity As in Melitz (2003) the home average productivity of intermediate production with trade, T , can be defined as a weighted harmonic mean over of productivity levels reflecting the additional production (inclusive of iceberg transport costs) of those firms who choose to export. The productivity levels are weighted by an entrepreneur's output relative to the domestic output of the average productivity level.yd (T ) . 1 1 yd () -1 x 1 yx () -1 -1 = g () d+ g () d T 1 + x 1 - G (d ) yd (T ) 1 + x 1 - G (d ) yd (T ) d d (42) 1-G(x ) where x = 1-G(d ) is the conditional probability of a producer exporting. This expression can be simplified using the definitions of )(d )(and (x ) from Equation 23 ( ) plus the relation between output levels yd () /yd = / and between relative export to domestic output: [ ] 1 -1 yx ( (x )) -1 -1 T = (d ) + x (x ) (43) 1 + x yd ( (x )) [ ] 1 -1 1- Y -1 = (d ) + x RER (x ) 1 + x Y Thus, if the two economies are non-symmetric, the weighted productivity includes a relative demand term RER Y / Y reflecting the differences in demand for intermediates from export and domestic markets. 34 C.2 Entrepreneurial utility In the steady state, an entrepreneurs utility u () = ln (c ()) / (1 - ) where the steady state consumption level is equal to: c () = we + (1 - ) a () (44) The entrepreneur's steady state net worth is given by: a () = yd () pd () + yx () px () - Rb () (45) If the entrepreneur does not produce then, as she has no collateral, her borrowing is zero and she consumes all her wage income, ie a = 0. If the entrepreneur producers then her borrowing is pinned down by the binding borrowing constraint and so her net worth is given by: ( -1 ) ( -1 ) a () = 1 - yd () pd () + 1 - (µ) yx () px () ( )-1 [ ] fw ( -1 ) ( -1 ) f ( - ) ( )-1 x d = 1 - + 1 - (µ) d d ( - d ) f ( - x ) x References Abiad, A., Oomes, N., & Ueda, K. (2007). The quality effect: Does financial liberalization improve the allocation of capital? mimeo, revised version of IMF Working Paper 04/112. Aghion, P., Banerjee, A., & Piketty, T. (1999). Dualism and macroeconomic volatility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), 1359­1397. Aitken, B., Hanson, G. H., & Harrison, A. E. (1997). Spillovers, foreign investment, and export behavior. Journal of International Economics, 43(1-2), 103­132. Almeida, H. & Wolfenzon, D. (2005). The effect of external finance on the equilibrium allocation of capital. Journal of Financial Economics, 75(1), 133­164. Anderson, J. E. & van Wincoop, E. (2004). Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3), 691­751. Antras, P. & Caballero, R. (2007). Trade and capital flows: A financial frictions perspec- tive. mimeo. available at http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/caball/papers. Aoki, K., Benigno, G., & Kiyotaki, N. (2006). Adjusting to capital account liberalization. Work in progress. Baldwin, R. E. & Forslid, R. (2006). Trade liberalization with heterogenous firms. NBER Working Paper No. 12192. 35 Banerjee, A. V. & Duflo, E. (2005). Growth theory through the lens of development economics. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, volume 1 chapter 7, (pp. 473­552). Elsevier. Beck, T. (2003). Financial dependence and international trade. Review of International Economics, 11(2), 296­316. Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2006). Bank supervision and corruption in lending. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(8), 2131­2163. Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a quan- titative business cycle framework. In J. B. Taylor, M. Woodford, J. B. Taylor, & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, volume 1 of Handbook of Macroeco- nomics chapter 21, (pp. 1341­1393). Elsevier. Bernard, A., Jensen, J. B., Redding, S., & Schott, P. (2007a). Firms in international trade. forthcoming Journal of Economic Perspectives. Bernard, A. B., Eaton, J., Jensen, J. B., & Kortum, S. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. American Economic Review, 93(4), 1268­1290. Bernard, A. B., Jensen, J. B., & Schott, P. K. (2006). Trade costs, firms and productivity. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(5), 917­937. Bernard, A. B., Redding, S. J., & Schott, P. K. (2007b). Comparative advantage and heterogeneous firms. Review of Economic Studies, 74(1), 31­66. Campa, J. M. & Shaver, J. M. (2002). Exporting and capital investment: On the strategic behavior of exporters. IESE Research Papers D/469. Caselli, F. & Gennaioli, N. (2006). Dynastic management. CEP Discussion Paper dp0741. Chaney, T. (2005). Liquidity constrained exporters. mimeo, available at http://home.uchicago.edu/ tchaney/research. Chaney, T. (2008). Distorted gravity: the intensive and extensive margins of international trade. forthcoming American Economic Review. Chang, R., Kaltani, L., & Loayza, N. (2005). Openness can be good for growth: The role of policy complementarities. NBER Working Paper No. 11787. Chor, D., Foley, F., & Manova, K. (2008). Host country financial development and MNC activity. mimeo. Chor, D., Manova, K., & Watt, S. B. (2007). Host country financial development and MNC activity. mimeo. Clerides, S. K., Lach, S., & Tybout, J. R. (1998). Is learning by exporting important? Micro-Dynamic Evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 903­947. 36 Fernandes, A. M. (2007). Trade policy, trade volumes and plant-level productivity in Colombian manufacturing industries. Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 52­ 71. Galindo, A., Schiantarelli, F., & Weiss, A. (2007). Does financial liberalization improve the allocation of investment?: Micro-evidence from developing countries. Journal of Development Economics, 83(2), 562­587. Greenaway, D., Guariglia, A., & Kneller, R. (2007). Financial factors and exporting decisions. Journal of International Economics, 73(2), 377­395. Hart, O. & Moore, J. (1994). A theory of debt based on the inalienability of human capital. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), 841­879. Hauner, D. & Prati, A. (2008). The interest group theory of financial development: Evidence from regulation. forthcoming IMF Working Paper. Helpman, E., Melitz, M. J., & Yeaple, S. R. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300­316. Henry, P. B. (2000). Stock market liberalization, economic reform, and emerging market equity prices. Journal of Finance, 55(2), 529­564. Hsieh, C.-T. & Klenow, P. J. (2007). Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. NBER Working Paper No. 13290. Hsu, T. (2006). Financial market imperfections, firm heterogeneity and the impact of trade on entrepreneurial selection and industry productivity. mimeo. Hur, J., Raj, M., & Riyanto, Y. E. (2006). Finance and trade: A cross-country empirical analysis on the impact of financial development and asset tangibility on international trade. World Development, 34(10), 1728­1741. IMF (2001). Structural Conditionality in IMF-Supported Programs. Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Jorgenson, D. W. & Vu, K. (2007). Information technology and the world growth resur- gence. German Economic Review, 8, 125­145. Kiyotaki, N. (1998). Credit and business cycles. Japanese Economic Review, 49(1), 18­35. Kletzer, K. & Bardhan, P. (1987). Credit markets and patterns of international trade. Journal of Development Economics, 27(1-2), 57­70. Manova, K. B. (2006). Credit constraints, heterogeneous firms and international trade. mimeo. Melitz, M. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695­1725. Pavcnik, N. (2002). Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improvement: Evidence from Chilean plants. The Review of Economic Studies, 69(1), 245­76. 37 Rajan, R. G. & Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: The politics of financial devel- opment in the 20th century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(1), 5­50. Restuccia, D. & Rogerson, R. (2007). Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with heterogeneous plants. NBER Working Paper No. 13018. Suwantaradon, R. (2008). Financial frictions and international trade. mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota. Topalova, P. (2004). Trade liberalization and firm productivity: The case of India. IMF Working Paper No. 04/28. Wurgler, J. (2000). Financial markets and the allocation of capital. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 187­214. 38