THE WORLD BANK Glob al Ja25305 January 2003 I =2oonomic :Prosp ects and the Developing Countries 4 .............. -p , - - *........:i a . ... r ;!;, t''r' ~- . - 2 'L's, et':s ; 1p' a ,~~~ft." ' ' t 'iZ!' L..~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~P 1s' > -- 4't ,^0-i Investing to UrI-ock Global Opportunities vjn n A Investing to -Utlock Global Opportunfities203 lo bal Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries 2003 ( 2003 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, NW Washington, DC, USA 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org E-mail: feedback@worldbank.org All rights reserved. 1 2 3 4 04 03 02 This volume is a product of the staff of the World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of the World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA, telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-7S0-4470, www.copyright.com All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA, fax 202-522-2422, e-mail pubrights@worldbank.org ISBN 0-8213-5338-1 ISSN 1014-8906 Library of Congress catalog card number: 91-6-440001 (serial) Contents Foreword ix Acknowledgments xi Summary xiii Abbreviations and Data Notes xxi Chapter 1 The International Economy and Prospects for Developing Countries A recovery constrained by major risks 4 Investment cycles in developing countries 23 Growth and poverty to 2015: coming changes in savings and investment patterns 28 Notes 41 References 42 Chapter 2 Changes in Global Business Organization 45 The surge in trade and FDI 46 The rise in service sector FDI 52 Global production networks 55 Good policies attract FDI 66 Notes 69 References 71 Chapter 3 Domestic Policies to Unlock Global Opportunities 77 Investment climate and investmenit policies 78 Promoting efficient private investment: harnessing competition 85 Public investment in infrastructure and human capital 103 Policies to promote competition 107 Notes 109 References 110 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Chapter 4 International Agreements to Improve Investment and Competition for Development 117 International efforts to promote investment 119 International agreements to promote competition and competition policy 133 Conclusions 145 Notes 146 References 147 Appendix 1 Regional Economic Prospects 151 Appendix 2 Global Commodity Price Prospects 175 Appendix 3 Global Economic Indicators 199 Figures 1.1 The recovery was initiated in a typical fashion 6 1.2 A brief rebound in industrial countries was underway 6 1.3 Rebound in industrial countries boosted production in East Asia 6 1.4 Non-oil commodities are recovering but stand well below previous peaks 7 1.5 Private sector creditors have cut debt exposures so far in 2002 9 1.6 FDI flows to emerging Asia are proving to be quite resilient 10 1.7 Investment recovery is still uncertain 10 1.8 World trade rebounds along with GDP, 1998-2004 13 1.9 2002 marks the start of a moderate recovery 15 1.10 LAC and MENA are not experiencing the recovery 15 1.11 Low case: world trade and other indicators will be much lower than the baseline 20 1.12 G-7 investment falls sharply 21 1.13 Investment growth and net capital flows into Latin America are strongly correlated 22 1.14 Oil prices spike 23 1.15 Investment is more volatile than GDP in East Asia 23 1.16 Investment is more volatile than GDP in Latin America 23 1.17 Central Europe and Turkey experience greater volatility in investment than in GDP 24 1.18 Investment volatility declines with income 24 1.19 A better investment climate reduces volatility of investment cycles 25 1.20 Impact of policy climate on investment volatility after correcting for income remains strong 25 1.21 Growth of working-age population decelerates 33 1.22 Productivity has not been the dominant source of growth in regions 35 1.23 Productivity is expected to be more significant in the longer term 35 1.24 Major structural shifts in investment and savings behavior have occurred 37 1.25 Youth dependency ratio will fall everywhere except Japan 39 1.26 Elderly dependency ratios will rise in some regions 39 2.1 Exports-to-GDP ratios have increased since the 1970s 47 2.2 All regions have benefited from rising FDI flows 47 2.3 FDI is concentrated in large countries, but many small countries receive large amounts relative to GDP 48 iv C O N T E N r s 2.4 The service sector dominated the 1990s mergers and acquisitions boom 49 2.5 Cross-border mergers and acquisitions are small compared with stock market capitalization 49 2.6 U.S. aggregate concentration has held steady 50 2.7 Global concentration has not increased significanitly 51 2.8 Share of FDI in the service sector increased in major industrial countries 52 2.9 U.S. cars are produced in many countries 55 2.10 Cross-border networks capture increasing shares of production and trade 56 2.11 The role of production networks continiued to increase through most of the 1990s 56 2 12 Tariff rates fell in the last two decades 57 2.13 Reforming countries boosted exports through production networks 58 2.14 Parts and components exports grew rapidly, 1981-2000 61 2.15 Developing countries' share of global parts and component exports rose between 1981 and 2000 61 2.16 Developing countries' parts and component exports are highly concentrated, 2000 62 2. 17 Strong rule of law attracts foreign investors 66 2.18 Foreign investors have been shifting away from weaker investmenlt climate locations 67 2.19 Private iiifrastructure investmiient surged in the 1990s 68 3 1 Domestic capital is the largest source of investmenit in developing countries 78 3.2 Incentives for FDI are varied and numerous 80 3.3 Competition and ease of entry are associated with higher growth 86 3.4 Competition from imports checks markups in concentrated markets 87 3.5 High tariffs are correlated with lower productivity 88 3.6 High entry costs inhibit FDI inflows 90 3.7 Barriers to entry can become barriers to exit 92 3.8 Barriers to entry and exit allow inefficient firms to stay in the market 94 3.9 Difficulties in obtaining licenses and permits discourage FDI 94 3.10 Inefficient customs hurt Indian exports 95 3.11 Inefficient ports raise India's transport costs far above competitors' transport costs 95 3.12 Privatization revenues soared in the 1990s 96 3.13 Granting monopoly rights brings in revenues 98 3.14 More competition means more phones 98 3.15 Better infrastructure means higher growth 105 3.16 Greater literacy is associated with higher growth 106 3.17 Education raises the productivity of FDI, which leads to higher growth 107 4.1 Countries are increasingly liberalizing their investmiient regimes 123 4.2 South-South FDI is rising 123 4.3 Share of South-South FDI in total FDI is rising 124 4.4 Revealed preferences: governments shield services more often than manufacturing from the winds of investment competitiol 126 4.5 FDI is growing faster than exports and output 128 4.6 OECD countries spent $230 billion in 2001 to support agrictiltural producers 135 4.7 Imports affected by cartels rose from 1981 to 2000 for both rich and poor countries 138 v G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Tables 1.1 Global conditions affecting growth in developing countries and world GDP growth 3 1.2 External environment for developing countries, 1991-2004 14 1.3 Global effects in a low-case scenario, 2003-04 20 1.4 Low case: contributions to global effects in 2003 21 1.5 Relative volatility of investment is high in developing countries 24 1.6 Upturns can be financed abroad and domestically 26 1.7 Capital inflows lead investment in middle-income countries: correlation between investment ratios and (past or future) capital flows 26 1.8 Long-term prospects are projected to be stronger for most regions 29 1.9 Large poverty reductions in EAP and SAR partially offset by poverty increases in SSA 30 1.10 Savings fall in high-income countries, but increase in most other regions 38 2.1 FDI inward stocks in services and manufacturing, 1988-99 52 2.2 Growth of exports of parts and components, 1981-2000 55 2.3 Export activity for product groups with the fastest growth in world exports, 1980-98 62 2.4 Rapid growth and structural change experienced by network participants 65 3.1 Profitability on equity, concentration, and market share (percent): Brazil, 1971-78 99 3.2 Cartel enforcement in selected developlng countries 101 4.1 Many antidumping investigations were initiated during the 1995-2001 period 136 4.2 International cartels can be expensive: estimates of sales and overcharge 138 4.3 National exemptions to competition law for exporters 141 4.4 Breaking up floating cartels could help developing countries 142 Boxes 1.1 Is Latin America going against the rising tide? 8 1.2 Integration pays off where policies are supportive 12 1.3 The terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001 had an economic impact 16 1.4 Consumption in low- and middle-income countries is smoothed over the business cycle 27 1.5 Is the World Bank overestimating global poverty? 31 1.6 Technological progress is an important determinant of growth 34 2.1 Intra-firm trade increases worldwide 59 3.1 Trade restrictions shield MNCs from competitive forces at enormous cost: the case of Argentina 89 3.2 Competition policy and competition law share similar objectives across countries 102 3.3 Does public investment "crowd out" or "crowd in" private investment? 104 VI C O N r E N T S 4.1 What is a BIT? 120 4.2 The Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI) 122 4.3 South-South flows: who invests and who receives? 125 4 4 Do BITs increase investment flows? Only a bit 129 4.5 Disciplines on corporations can also improve the investment climate 132 4.6 The lysine cartel, 1995-2001 139 4.7 International cooperation aids competition policy 144 \'11 Foreword Productivity increases and efficient investment are essential conditions for rapid growth and poverty reduction. The key to accelerating technological improvement and increasing in- P vestment is improving the "investment climate " In the broadest sense, this term encom- passes the policy and institutional environment that fosters entrepreneurship, learning, and pro- ductive investment. In this report, we argue that the investmlient climate for developing countries has both a global dimension and a national dimension. The global investment clinate, although less amenable to policy initiatives of developing countries, nonetheless presents opportunities, risks, and at times obstacles for developing countries. In this report, we focus on1 two aspects of the global invest- ment climate: the current state of the world economy as it affects developing countries' financial outlook, exports, and growth prospects (chapter 1) and the organization of global business, notably the proliferation of multinational companies and associated production networks (chap- ter 2). In previous reports we have studied other aspects of the global investment climate, in- cluding the world trading system (Global Economzic Prospects 2002) and aspects of the global financial system (Global Development Finance 2002). The national dimension of the investment climate for developing countries is discussed in chapter 3. This dimension is composed of the policy and institutionial environment that fosters entrepreneurship-and that strongly influences the pace of productivity growth and the rate of investment. Differences in national policies help explain why some countries grow rapidly and others do not, even though all operate within the same international investment climate In short, policymakers have considerable scope for choosing policies that influenice the amounit and pro- ductivity of investment. For the purposes of this report, we focus on two types of national policies that affect how countries use globalization to grow. The first type is investmenit policies-for example, tax in- centives, tariffs, subsidies, and policies to channel investmlient into particular activities, as well as public iivestmenit. The second type is policies that promote or limit competition-for example, tariffs, entry restrictions, and state monopolies as well as conventionally defined competition policy. We chose these policy areas for three reasons. First, these policy areas directly link the do- mestic policy dimensions of the investment climate with the global economy. Second-in contrast to macroeconomic policies, property rights, and other institutional features that primarily affect the quantity of investment-policies fostering investnment and competition work instead through microeconomic incentives to influence the quality of investment (as measured by its productivity). Finally, these policies are at the center of global debate, figuring prominently in discussions of the G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Doha Development Agenda launched at the World Trade Organization (WTO) Ministerial Meet- ing in November 2001. To inform that debate, the final chapter of this report asks how the international community can support developing countries in their quest for better investment climates, both global and national. The chapter focuses on synergies that can emerge from developing countries' participa- tion in internationial agreements on investment and competition policies, topics that are not only central to the WTO Doha Development Agenda but that also figure prominently in many regional trade negotiations around the world. Nicholas Stern Chief Economist and Senior Vice President The World Bank x Acknowledgments T his report was prepared by the Development Prospects Group in the World Bank, draw- ng on resources throughout the Development Economics Vice Presidency and the World Bank's operational units. Richard Newfarmer was the lead author and manager of the report, under the direction of Uri Dadush. The principal chapter authors were Hans Timmer (chapter 1), William Shaw (chapter 2), Jeffrey Lewis and Scott Wallsten (chapter 3), and Richard Newfarmer and Pierre Sauve (chapter 4). We are grateful for the ideas and insights of Bernard Hoekman, Michael Klein, and Theodore Moran (Georgetown University). The report was pre- pared under the general guidance of Nicholas Stern. Many staff from insidc and outside the World Bank contributed to the report. In chapter 1, Caroline Farah, Himmat Kalsi, Robert Keyfitz, Aniette I. Dc Kleine, Robert Lynn, Fernando Martel Garcia, Mick Riordan, and Bert Wolfe contributed to the global trends; Dominique Van der Mensbrugghe provided the long-term analysis; and Shaohua Chen and Martin Ravallion contributed to the poverty analysis; Kathlecn Rollins was the staff assistant. Chapter 2 benefited from background papers and other inputs from Gary Gereffi, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Shafiq Islam, Frances Ng, Matthcw Slaughter, Lawrence Whlite, and Yong Zhang. Similarly, in chapter 3, Claudio Frischtak, Rughvir Khemani, Kamal Saggi, Luis Villela, and Alberto Barreix as well as Mary Hallward-Driemeier provided background papers that became building blocks for the sections on incentives, investmenit, competition, and foreign investment, and Denis Medvedev provided valuable written inputs and rcsearch assistance. Chapter 4 was based on background papers by Simon Evenett and Benno Ferrarini (competition), Bijit Bora (performance requirc- ments), and Mary Hallward-Driemeier (bilatcral investment treaties and investor protections) as well as inputs from Aaditya Mattoo and Shweta Bagai (various). Beata Smarzynska and Jacques Morisset provided helpful guidance and comments on various aspects of the report. The regional appendixes benefited from the written inputs of the Regional Chief Economists around the Bank and their staff. John Baffes, Betty Dow, Donald Mitchell, and Shane Streifel prepared the com- modity appendix. The staff assistant for the report was Awatif Abuzeid. Mark Felge provided ed- itorial assistance. Yinne Yu and Yong Zhang as well as Jonathan Koh provided valuable research assistance at various stages of the report's preparation. Dorota Nowak coordinated publication and disseminatioii activities Several experts provided written comments that immeasurably improved the quality of the rc- port at various stages: Pierre-Richard Agenor, Robert Anderson, Milan Brahmbhatt, Jean-jacques Dethier, Simeon D;ankov, Richard Eglin, Antonio Estache, Shahrokh Fardoust, Alan Gelb, Coralic Gevers, Ian Goldin, Rughvir Khemani, Aart Kraay, Ernesto May, Mustapha Nabli, Anne xi G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 McGuirk, Ashoka Mody, Ijaz Nabi, John Panzer, Guillermo Perry, Guy Pfeffermann, Karl Sauvant, Todd Schneider, Mark Sundberg, and Roberto Zagha. We are also grateful for the many substantive comments we received from governments around the world through their Executive Directors on the World Bank's Board. Melissa Edeburn, Susan Graham, and lIma Kramer managed the production for the World Bank's Office of the Publisher. Xii Summary The global recovery is fragile, because and middle-income countries as it is in high- investment spending is insufficient to income countries. But the volatility of invest- underpin continuing growth- ment is greater in developing countries than in Strong cyclical dynamics, together with an rich countries. Countries with sound invest- easing of macroeconomic policies in the ment climates experience far less volatility United States and elsewhere, have boosted than countries with deficient policies and large parts of the global economy into the mi- institutions. tial phase of a recovery in 2002. The driving Capital flows to developing countries have forces behind the initial phase of the recovery proved to be procyclical. But the direction of were strong, but they have proved short-lived causality between investment and capital in- because inventory and high-tech cycles are flow appears to differ significantly between short and appear to have peaked. Though rich and poor countries. In rich countries, a consumption spending has held firm, this is boom in domestic fixed investment tends to precisely the time when investment demand attract foreign capital, while in middle-income should pick up and boost recovery onto a countries it is the acceleration of capital higher trajectory. So far it has not. Financial inflows that typically stimulates domestic imbalances, evident in different forms investment. Similarly, a fall in rich countries' throughout the world economy, seem to be investment tends to reduce net capital inflows, weighing down growth. Wide-ranging uncer- while for middle-income countrics reduced net tainty in financial markets may jeopardize the capital inflows (or increased capital outflows) needed rebound in fixed investment and may are the driving forces behind contractions in thus diminish prospects for projecting the domestic investment. This dependence on cap- global recovery into the future. Falling and ital flows makes the middle-income countries volatile stock markets, accounting scandals, especially vulnerable to tensions in global fi- accumulated debts (domestic and foreign, pri- nancial markets. Low-income countries, with vate and public), and reassessments of long- greater reliance on official aid and with lim- run profitability keep investors cautious, if ited access to private capital markets, do not not jittery, throughout the world. For these exhibit either of these patterns. reasons, growth in 2003 seems certain to be weaker for almost all developing regions than -but long-term prospects remain we anticipated as recently as six months ago. promising Analysis of long-tern trends indicates that Over the long run, new opportunities for the investment cycle as a determinant of over- technological advances (often driven by all cyclical behavior is as important in low- globalization), together with more stable xii G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 macroeconomic policies and an improved 1990s, rising from $331 billion in 1995 to business climate, have the potential to acceler- $1.3 trillion in 2000, before falling off to an ate growth and to increase investment ratios estimated $725 billion in 2001. Most of these in developing countries that currently lag flows are destined to rich countries. behind. The outlook for reductions in global FDI flows to developing countries are poverty, while generally positive and of the about $160 billion. This amount is still rela- same order of magnitude as in our previous tively small compared with all domestic in- report, is marginally dimmer because of the vestment in developing countries, now about absence of a robust recovery today. $1 trillion. Nonetheless, in virtually every re- At the same time, demographics are likely gion, FDI is a driving force of globalization to alter existing savings and investment pat- and has risen relative to total capital expen- terns and will tend to push countries to be- ditures during the 1990s. It has doubled in come more interdependent through capital middle-income countries and has tripled in flows. Major demographically driven shifts in low-income countries. However, recently FDI current account balances-particularly in flows have fallen. They peaked in 1999 at Japan, which is moving toward reduced sur- $184 billion and are experiencing their most plus, and in middle-income countries, which sustained fall since the global recession of are moving toward increased surplus-are 1981-83. likely to accelerate financial integration. These trends over the past decade have in- Underneath large swings in net flows are even creased competition in most markets around larger movements of gross capital flows, as the world. Despite a sharp increase in mergers foreign direct investment (FDI) expands into and acquisitions, the share of global economic growing markets in developing countries and activity accounted for by the largest compa- as financial agents in developing countries nies does not appear to have risen over the seek to diversify their portfolios in rich coun- 1990s. The profits of the top 50 companies ac- tries. However, because international financial counted for 0.8 percent of world GDP in flows have at times fluctuated widely, they 2001. Although their share of aggregate prof- have sometimes proved damaging to growth its amounted to 3.3 percent of global savings and poverty reduction. The international com- in 2000, up from 1.8 percent in 1994, this in- munity and developing countries have to crease is likely to be the result of the boom in search for mechanisms to provide greater sta- the United States and the overstatement of bility in integration. Developing countries can earnings of some large U.S. corporations. do much on their own. Improving the domes- These factors point to a pattern of stability tic investment climate, particularly through rather than a trend of increases. Similar pat- sound macroeconomic policies and gover- terns exist for the largest 500 companies. nance, can reduce the volatility of capital Four changes in the organization of busi- flows and attract less-volatile FDI. ness are particularly important for developing countries. First, the rise of foreign investment Global competition is creating new in services is creating a new source of compe- opportunities for developing countries tition-and potential productivity gains-in Cross-border trade and direct investment have developing countries, where staid state com- expanded rapidly over the past three decades. panies have often monopolized production for Global exports of goods and services in- decades. Recent efforts to privatize these com- creased from 14 percent of output in the early panies and to open industries to competition 1970s to 23 percent by the late 1990s, while have allowed some developing countries to global FDI flows have more than doubled rel- harness this competition for gains. In many ative to the gross domestic product (GDP). developing countries, restrictions on services The surge in FDI flows accelerated in the late still remain high, because some countries have xiv S U M M A R Y privatized only slowly and others have priva- in global risk premiums has reduced investors' tized badly, creating private monopolies still appetite for risk and for projects with long ges- insulated from competition. tations. Adversity to such projects is reflected Second, production networks that span the not only in the average spreads over U.S. Trea- globe, once barely a dot on the horizon of in- sury interest rates that developing countries ternational business, have now become a cen- must pay to their bondholders in the Emerging tral feature. That so many large firms have Market Bond Index (even excluding country chosen to outsource production of parts and "outliers" in crisis) but also more generally in equipment or to otherwise locate production spreads of high-risk corporate bonds in the facilities offshore offers new opportunities United States. Both have more than doubled for developing countries. Firms choosing to from under 500 basis points to more than "deverticalize" production through outsourc- 1,000. The recent collapse of the telecommu- ing create new opportunities for suppliers and nications sector, as well as difficulties experi- create a foundation for a steady increase in enced by major power companies associated trade for participating developing countries. with the Enron scandal, has diminished the The downside is that this production and the number of players and enthusiasm among associated high rates of export growth are potential long-term financiers. Second, many highly concentrated geographically, and so projects have suffered payment problems this door into a greater share of the global because of the inability of contracts to weather economy has, to date, opened only for rela- sharp contractions in demands. From tively few countries. Taking advantage of Argentina to Indonesia, the string of defaults networks requires a strong policy environ- associated with infrastructure projects and re- ment that fosters private investment and pro- structurings has left in its wake a severe re- vides complementary public investmenits (see trenchment. Thus, governments throughout below). the developing world will have to do more to Third, with growing concerns about risk, offset this risk-principally through better investors are becoming increasingly sensitive policies, and perhaps through a slowing of the to investment climates in developing coun- retreat from government financing of infra- tries, and the result is that money is moving to structure that has occurred under the banner the countries with large, rapidly growing, and of privatization. relatively stable economic environments. Countries such as China, the Republic of Harnessing globalization requires Korea, and Mexico benefited from the largest reducing barriers to competition- inflows in 2000. As a share of domestic in- To raise the productivity of both foreign and vestment, however, small-market countries are domestic investment, developing countries proving they can keep pace-provided that have to harness the full force of competition they protect property rights, have stable inherent in globalization. Too often they have macroeconomic environments, and have good not done so. In many countries, policy barri- institutions. Poor countries that fall short on ers to competition-whether they are im- policies and institutions compound the disad- pediments to trade, restrictions on incoming vantages they already experience from having foreign investment, administrative barriers to small markets. Hence, they may be virtually competition, or monopolies granted to state shut out from foreign investment flows in any enterprises-have channeled domestic as well sector other than natural resources. as foreign investment into less-productive Finally, long-term private investment fi- activities that dampen productivity improve- nancing for infrastructure has fallen off to ment and hobble growth. Import competition, levels that may prove persistent. This retrench- for example, can limit what would otherwise ment has two origins. First, the post-1997 rise be the shared monopoly pricing of a few local xv G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 producers. In a wide sample of developing broader reform packages, either to catalyze countries, decreasing imports in concentrated support for emerging opportunities (such as industries from 25 percent of domestic sales to clusters) or to create transitional mechanisms zero is associated with increases of 8 percent and initial constituencies for reform that can in oligopolistic markups on sales. be progressively expanded (such as EPZs). But Competition-impeding regulations in re- more broadly, investment incentives will gen- cently privatized industries have undermined erally not make up for serious deficiencies potential benefits from privatization and have in the investment environment or generate insulated new owners-frequently foreign sustained growth. To encourage productive companies-from efficiency-improving com- investment and benefit from globalization, petition; the result has been slow growth and governments must tackle the challenges of resource misallocation. In Africa, for example, promoting competition and entrepreneurship telephone services in countries with private and of undertaking complementarily pro- monopolies have expanded growth only one- ductive public investment in areas such as third as fast as telephone services in countries education. with competitive networks. Over time, firms in countries with lower -and therefore sound public investments barriers to trade and to investment competi- are essential tion tend, as a general rule, to enjoy signifi- Public investment also plays a crucial role in cantly higher productivity of investment, both enhancing growth. Some countries get both foreign and domestic, and with it more rapid the levels and the composition of investment growth. This fact does not imply a single pre- right, and their growth rates are high. Other scription for all countries irrespective of their countries invest too much through the public stage of development. As the experience of sector and crowd out private investment. China-among others-has shown, reforms Because these effects are also associated with have to be tailored to country circumstances investments in state enterprises that enjoy mo- and integrated into sustainable development nopoly positions protected from competition, strategies. The analysis does imply, however, the composition effects of public investment that countries wishing to increase their oppor- are negative. Other countries invest too little tunities from globalization would do well to through the public sector. This problem is usu- look first at the incentive features of their ally manifested in poor education, poor in- investment climate, with special attention to frastructure, and poor public institutions barriers that impede competition. generally-all of which reduce profitable in- vestment opportunities for both domestic and -and using targeted interventions foreign companies. Investing in effective pub- with care- lic institutions has an especially high return. Governments may hope to make up for an unfriendly investment environment through in- International agreements on investment centive mechanisms. But while there are clearly and competition policies can provide examples in which targeted interventions- benefits through reciprocity- such as fiscal incentives, export processing Countries get most of the positive growth zones (EPZs), or support for economic clus- stimulus from domestic unilateral reforms ters-may indeed lead to higher investment tailored to local strategy and conditions, and levels (and the jobs and related spillovers that these reforms should not be held hostage to go along with them), there is, unfortunately, international agreements. Nonetheless, re- little evidence that such initiatives can be forming governments may be able to obtain systematically successful. Instead, they tend to additional benefits from international agree- work best when they work in support of ments. Benefits can take several forms. For S U M M A R Y investment policies, participating in interna- reinforce sound domestic policies and can tional agreements that are linked to greater contribute to better performance. Since most market access may elicit more investment by of the remaining restrictions are on services, signaling to investors that changes are perma- governments around the world can increase nent. Also, participating in international nego- market access by using the existing multilat- tiations may strengthen the hand of domestic eral framework rather than creating a new reformers by holding out the prospect of mar- one. The General Agreement on Trade in Ser- ket access abroad in exchange for new domes- vices (GATS) provides an as-yet-underutilized tic policies; simultaneously, negotiations can arrangement to negotiate reciprocal market prompt reciprocal reforms among partners access in services. To date, the coverage of that would not otherwise occur. For competi- commitments for a large number of countries non policy, international agreements may lead is limited. About two-thirds of the World to the removal of restraints that inhibit com- Trade Organization membership has sched- petition, thereby unleashing new price compe- uled 60 or fewer sectors (of the 160 or so spec- tition that benefits all countries. ified in the GATS list). Moreover, in many cases, commitments do not reflect the actual -but agreements on investment policy are degree of openness. Finally, in some countries, likely to have strong development effects the commitments that have been made serve only if they deal with the big issues facing only to protect the privileged position of in- developing countries- cumbents rather than enhance the contestabil- The purposes of coordinating investnent ity of markets. To remedy these problems, policy are to expand the flow of investment governments must take greater advantage of around the world, to minimize policy exter- the opportunity offered by the GATS to lend nalities that hurt neighbors, and to help credibility to reform programs by committing improve economic performance. Agreements to maintain current levels of openness or by might contribute to achieving these goals precommitting to greater levels of future through three main channels: protecting openness. To advance the process of services investors' rights, which increases incentives to reforms beyond levels undertaken indepen- invest; liberalizing investment flows, which dently and to lead to more balanced outcomes permits enhanced access and competition; and from the developing-country point of view, curbing policies that may distort investment countries could better harness the power of flows and trade at the expense of neighbors. reciprocity by devising negotiating formulas International agreements that focus on es- that widen the scope for tradeoffs across sec- tablishing protections for investors cannot be tors (both in goods and in services) and across expected to expand markedly the flow of in- modes of delivery, particularly the temporary vestment to new signatory countries. This is movement of workers. While difficult, such ef- because many protections are already con- forts may prove easier than designing a whole tamed in bilateral investment treaties (BITs). new international investment arrangement. Even the relatively strong protections in BITs Similarly, curbing policy externalities that do not seem to have increased flows of in- "beggar thy neighbor" can benefit developing vestment to signatory developing countries. countries, especially if the countries focus These facts suggest that expectations for new on two critical issues. The first is to reduce flows associated with protections emerging investment-distorting trade barriers. By de- from any multilateral agreement should be priving developing countries of market access kept low. and by discouraging their exports, many trade International agreements that allow coun- barriers also lessen the attractiveness of oppor- tries to negotiate reciprocal market liberaliza- tunities to invest in developing countries' ex- tion and to promote nondiscrimination can port industries for both foreign and domestic xvu G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 investors. In Canada, the European Union Restrictions on competition in the global (EU), Japan, and the United States, average ad marketplace that most hurt development take valorem-equivalent tariffs for manufactures three forms. The first form consists of policy are roughly twice as high for developing coun- barriers in markets abroad that limit competi- tries as they are for members of the Organisa- tion among developing countries in these tion for Economic Co-operation and Develop- markets. These barriers, like those discussed ment. The ad valorem-equivalent tariffs on above, discourage investment and create ob- agriculture (to say nothing of subsidies) in stacles to competition. Particularly harmful those countries are also more than three times are the $311 billion in agricultural subsidies higher than such tariffs on manufactures. Re- and textile quotas, as well as the correspond- ducing trade barriers among developing coun- ing high border protection, tariff distortions tries themselves is as important as reducing (that is, tariff peaks and escalation), and pro- trade barriers in rich countries. Developing tectionist use of antidumping. These practices countries import from each other at average ad are only too common in all countries, rich and valorem-equivalent rates comparable to EU poor alike. All of these trade restrictions limit rates for imports from developing countries. the ability of exporters in developing countries This level of protection dampens investment- to compete in international markets. both domestic and foreign-in affected export Second, private restraints on competition industries, and removal of these barriers can adversely affect prices for consumers and would have significant development effects. producers in developing countries-much as The second critical issue is to curb the they can in industrial countries. For example, emerging competition among countries to lure cartel practices among companies based in foreign investment through investment incen- high-income countries taxed consumers in tives. Unfortunately, information on the ex- developing countries by up to $7 billion in the tent of investment incentives is inadequate to 1990s. Actions that facilitate prosecution of assess their effects, and so a high priority for cartels should be high on the priority list. Such international collaboration is to systematically actions can range from developing more sys- compile this information. tematic arrangements to exchange informa- Finally, participation in international agree- tion among competition agencies, to granting ments on investment may also have benefits standing for developing countries to sue under over and above unilateral reforms if the agree- foreign antitrust laws when their trade is ad- ments include reciprocal market access in versely affected. Indeed, both developing and areas of importance to developing countries. industrial countries would benefit from much These benefits can become clear only in the greater efforts to identify and document re- course of negotiation. strictive business practices that adversely af- fect prices of their trade. -and thus competition agreements should Third, many governments in high-income focus on restraints to competition that countries officially sanction trade restraints hurt developing countries through antitrust exemptions for their compa- Greater competition is associated with more nies in domestic law. For example, many gov- rapid development, and lowering policy barrn- ernments permit their companies to cartelize ers to trade and foreign investment in devel- exports. Shrouded in the secrecy of government oping countries, as shown in chapter 3, is a registries, these national export cartels may powerful procompetitive force. Beyond unilat- well raise prices to developing countries. Ef- eral actions, international agreements on com- forts should be made to make information on petition policy might also bring benefits, pro- national export cartels transparent. Everyone vided they address the major restrictions that would benefit from a decrease in cartels that adversely affect developing countries. have damaging price effects. Similarly, antitrust xviii S U M M A RY exemptions for ocean transport have given rise adoption of best practices in developing coun- to price-fixing arrangements that systematically tries can pay high dividends. hurt consumers everywhere, including those in Unlocking global opportunities begins with developing countries. These restraints are esti- the efforts of developing countries to improve mated to cost developing countries more than their investment climates. Deployed well, in- $2 billion per year and entail similar costs to vestment policies and policies to unleash com- consumers in industrial economies. petition can accelerate economic growth and Finally, competition policies in developing reduce poverty. This report offers a general countries themselves can in many cases be framework and lessons, but each country has improved through increased transparency, to formulate its own development strategy. nondiscrimination, and procedural fairness. Nonetheless, the international community, However, international cooperation in this working together, can help through develop- complex area of regulation has to recognize ment assistance, voluntary collaboration, and that countries have different capacities and well-conceived international agreements. For institutional settings, warranting caution in these efforts to have greatest effect, they have recommending-much less in mandating- to tackle the most pressing investment and across-the-board policies. In this area, volun- competition problems-and that is the chal- tary programs that facilitate the learning and lenge ahead. xix Abbreviations and Data Notes ADB Asian Development Bank ASCM Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures BITs Bilateral Investment Freaties EPZ Export processing zone EU European Union FDI Foreign direct investmenit FSAP Financial Sector Assessment Program GATS General Agreemcnt on Trade in Services GPA Government Procurement Agreement HIV/AIDS Human immunodeficiency virus/acquired immune deficiency syndrome lCC International Chamber of Commerce ICN International Competition Network ICSID Internatioial Center for Settlement of Investment Disputes IMF International Monetary Fund ITO International Trade Organization LDC Least developed countries M&A Mergers and acquisitions MAI Multilateral Agreement on Investmiient MERCUSOR Latin America Southern Cone trade bloc (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay) MFN Most favored nation MNCs Multinational corporations NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement NGO Nongovernmental organization OAS Organizationi of American States OECD Organisatloni for Economic Co-operation and Devclopment ROSC Reports on the Observance of Standards and Codes SOEs State-owned enterprises xxt G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS P E C I 5 2 0 0 3 TNCs Transnational corporations TRIMs Trade-Related Investment Measures TRIPS Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights U.S. BEA U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis UNCITRAL United Nations Commission on International Trade Law UNCTAD United Nations Conference for Trade and Development UNDP United Nations Development Programme USAID U.S. Agency for International Development WTO World Trade Organization Data notes The "classification of economies" tables at "developing countries" as used in this vol- the end of this volume classify economies by ume covers all low- and middle-income coun- income, region, export category, and indebt- tries, including countries with transition edness. Unless otherwise indicated, the term economies. All dollar figures are U.S. dollars. xxii N~ The International Economy and Prospects for Developing Countries Developments in early 2002 showed a the second phase is in jeopardy because of ten- cyclical rebound- sions in fiancial markets, which reflect accu- Macroeconomic stimulus, a rebound from a mulated financial imbalances and significanit record trough in the high-tech sectors and uncertainties. These pressures have made the a bottoming-out of inventory cycles, brought recovery in 2002 less uniform, and they are large parts of the global economy onto a re- likely to moderate growth in 2003. covery path at the end of 2001. Lower interest In Japan, deflation and high and rapidly rates helped keep consumers' demand for growing government debt have placed severe durable goods strong. Together with fiscal eas- limits on both monetary and fiscal stimuli. ing, that demand provided support for the Combined with the fragility of the banking rebound in the United States and, to a lesser sector, which is burdened by bad loans and extent, in some East Asian and European diminishing capital caused by lower equlty countries. High-tech markets-in which tech- values, financial uncertainty prevents the nologies quickly become obsolete-returned spread of recovery fromi export sectors to to strong growth by creating replacements for those that produce for the domestic market. old products. Inventory selloffs ceased, thereby The accounting scandals in the United Statcs contributing to an acceleration of gross do- have undermined the trust in reporting sys- mestic product (GDP) growth in early 2002. tems. Investors, who have come to rely on The driving forces behind the initial phase continuously rising equity prices, nlow find it of the recovery were strong, but short-lived, as difficult to assess the profitability of firms. business confidence remained weak. Inventory That difficulty sharply pushed up risk premi- and high-tech cycles typically are short, and ums in equity markets. European financial in- both appear to have peaked toward the middle stitutionis were forced to adjust their balance of 2002. The effects of fiscal stimulus and sheets in the wake of large-scale defaults, monetary easing can also, under current cir- notably by Argentina and several major cumstances, dissipate quickly. U.S. firms, which probably played a role in suppressing a nascent recovery in European -but uncertainty in financial markets has economies. In Europe and elsewhere, tclecom- sapped momentum municationi sectors still suffer from overin- In the second phase of a typical recovery, the vestment and high debt burdens, making a upturn spreads to other sectors and other speedy recovery of capital spending in those regions, and the driving force shifts from in- sectors unlikely. ventory dynamics to accumulation of fixed Uncertainty is keeping investors cautious, investment. In the current upswing, however, if not skittish, throughout the world. While G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 investors in high-income countries take their -and the outlook for 2003 is losses and replenish their reserves, they limit for tepid growth their exposure to developing countries and Reflecting financial uncertainty and the dis- concentrate their assets in investment-grade appointing recovery of business confidence, borrowing countries.1 Capital flows into large prolected growth for 2003 has been marked parts of Latin America dropped sharply, re- down for almost all developing regions, be- flecting the aftermath of Argentina's default cause a robust rebound in industrial coun- and the vicious combination of global uncer- try growth-driven by strong advances in tainty, domestic problems in some large coun- investment-has become less likely. In line tries, and intra-regional contagion. The reversal with these revisions, inflation, interest rates, of capital flows-with the accompanying rise and non-oil commodity prices are also likely in spreads and depreciation of currencies- to be lower. The sole exception to this pattern when combined with vulnerable balance- is the Middle East and North Africa region, sheet characteristics triggered a dangerous where oil exporters have benefited from high worsening of debt dynamics in some Latin oil prices during 2002. Several of these coun- American countries. In such an environment, tries are seeing increased government expendi- average per capita income in Latin America ture, financed by rapidly mounting surpluses has fallen in 2002 for the second year in of oil revenues. succession. Investment cycles in developing countries The rebound in 2002 was less uniform are more volatile than in rich countries than anticipated- With the sharp fall in global investment in Rapid recovery in the beginning of 2002, 2001 and the uncertainty surrounding a re- driven in part by sharp increases in the U.S. bound in capital expenditure, investment government's expenditure in the aftermath of behavior has become a key element of the terrorist attacks, has resulted in upward revi- outlook. A closer look at investment cycles in sions of 2002 growth for the United States, developing countries suggests the following East Asia, and Japan, relative to forecasts conclusions: prepared in February (table 1.1). At the other extreme, growth in Latin America has been * Investment behavior in low- and middle- lowered by 1.6 percentage points for the income countries is a determinant of year. This decrease reflects not only the crisis overall volatility that is even more in Argentina, but also the major contrac- important than it is in high-income tions of GDP in Uruguay and the Repiblica countries. Bolivariana de Venezuela, plus slow growth * Those developing countries with a in Brazil, Chile, and Mexico. Those events stronger policy environment exhibit made the 2001-02 period the worst for the lower volatility in investment. region since the debt crisis of the early 1980s. * Although in rich countries domestic Consistent with higher-than-anticipated fixed investment tends to drive foreign global growth, non-oil commodity prices in capital inflows, in middle-income coun- 2002 have risen more than anticipated. tries the opposite tends to occur (that is, Nonetheless, the present rebound in com- capital inflows typically drive domestic modity prices is modest froin an historical investment). perspective, thus highlighting the continuing downward pressures on prices tied to strLc- These conclusions imply that the middle- tural factors. Higher commodity prices have income countries are especially vulnerable to supported modestly improved performance in the current jitters in financial markets. Such Sub-Saharan Africa. countries are exposed to sudden reversals in 2 r H E I N T E R N AI I O N A L E C O N 0 M Y A N D P R O S P l C T S I O R D E V E l O P I N G C O U N I R I E S Table 1.1 Global conditions affecting growth in developing countries and world GDP growth (percenttage cbange front previouis year, except interest rates anid oil price) Global Developm>ent Currcnt estinate Current forecasts Finance 2002 forecasts 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2002 2003 Global conditions World trade (volume) 13 1 -0.5 2.9 7.0 8.0 1.8 8 3 Inflation (consumer prices) G-7 OECD countriesa 1 9 1 7 0 9 1 2 1 5 0 9 1 6 United States 3 4 2 8 1 5 2.1 2 3 1 5 2.4 Commodity prices (nominal $) Commodity prices, except oil ($) -13 -91 5 0 5 8 4 4 1 3 7 3 Oil price ($, weighted average), $/bbl 28 2 24 4 25 0 23 0 20 0 1 20 0 21 0 Oilprice(%change) 562 -137 27 -80 -130 -179 50 Manufactures export unit value ($)' -21 -1.4 0 5 3 0 2 2 -0 5 3 6 Interest rates LIBOR, 6 inonths (US$, percent) 6 6 3 6 18 1 5 3 1 2 3 4 0 EURIBOR, 6 months (euro, percenit) 4 5 4 2 3 4 3.2 3 8 3 0 4 0 GDP (growth)d World 3 8 1.1 1.7 2.5 31 1.3 3.6 Menio iteni World GDP (ppp)' 4 5 2.1 2 8 3 4 4 0 2,4 4 3 High-income countries 3.5 0.7 1.5 2.1 2 7 0 9 3.3 OECD countriesf 3 4 0 8 14 2 1 2 6 0 8 31 United States 3 8 0 3 2 3 2 6 31 1.3 3 7 Japan 21 -0 3 00 08 1 3 -15 1 7 Euro Area 3 7 1.5 0 8 1 8 2 6 1 2 3.3 Non-OECD countries 6.8 -0.7 2 3 3 7 5 3 2 7 5 3 Developing countries 5 2 2.9 I 2.8 3.9 4.7 3.1 4.9 East Asia and Pacifict 70 S 5 6 3 61 6 4 5.6 7.1 Europe anid Central Asia 6.6 2.3 3 6 3 4 36 3 2 4 3 Transition countries 6.4 4 6 3 5 3 3 35 3 4 4 0 Latin America and the Canribbean 3 7 04 -1 1 1 8 3 7 0 5 3.8 ExcIliding Argentina 4.5 1.2 0 7 1.9 3 6 2 1 4 3 Middle East anid North Africa 4 2 3 2 2 5 3 5 37 2 7 3 3 Oil exporters 3.6 2.4 2 4 3 7 3 6 2.2 2 8 Diversified economies 3 7 4.3 2 2 2 7 36 1 31 4 4 South Asia 4.8 4.4 4 6 5 4 58 4 9 5 3 Sub-Saharais Africa 3.2 2.9 2 5 3 2 3 8 2 6 3.6 Memorandums items Developing countriesI Excludinig the tiansitioni countries 5.0 2 6 2 7 4 0 4.9 3 1 5 1 Excluding Chitia atid India 4 6 1 7 1 5 2.8 3.8 2 0 4.1 Note OECD = Organization for Economic Co-operation and Developnenit, hbl = barrel, EURIBOR = European interbank offered rate, LIBOR London interhank offered rate, ppp = purchasing piower parity a Caniada, France, Germany. Italy, Japani, the Utmited Kingdom, anid the United States. b In local cuirrency, aggregated using 1995 GDI' weights c. Unit value index of matsufactsires exports fioii the G-5 coLuitries to developimg countries, expressed in U S dollars d GDP itt 1995 constanit dollars 1995 prices and irnirket exch.ange rates e GDP measured at 1995 puirchasing power parity (itnrernatoiial dollar) weights. f Republic of Korea iticome classificationi chaniged from middle to sighi in comie (July 2002). Bioth forecassts were adijisted for this revision Souirce World Bank, November 2002 anid Glrbal Developmenit Fiiance 2002 projectiois of Febiuary 2002 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 capital flows, which can dampen investment quarter of 2001. Accumulated financial im- sharply and can undermine growth momen- balances that had built up during the 1990s tum. Countries with strong policy environ- emerged as a critical factor that clouded the ments are more likely to avoid or smoothly economic outlook. In the United States, the absorb potential external financial shocks. bursting of the equity bubble and cumulated private sector debt kept investors cautious and In the long term, faster growth resulted in a continuous flight to quality, can be achieved in most whlich moved the yield on government bonds developing regions to a 40-year low while hampering the recovery Market reforms and trade liberalization dur- in private investment. In Japan, banking prob- ing the 1990s have opened opportunities for lems and the lack of scope for monetary eas- accelerating technological advances through- ing and fiscal stimulus limited the spillover out the developing world for the next 15 years. from an export-driven recovery to a rebound An exception is emerging East Asia, where in domestic investment. In Europe, weakness some moderation of technological progress was concentrated in the highly indebted is anticipated, reflecting in part the extra- telecommunications sector and in financial ordinarily rapid catching-up that occurred dur- sectors that had to absorb sharp devaluations ing the 1980s and 1990s. The acceleration of of their assets. growth in many of the other regions is likely Bankruptcies and reductions in investment to coincide with increasing savings and invest- during the global downturn of 2001 and the ment rates. Demographic transitions are anti- subsequent first phase of recovery in early cipated to boost saving rates in developing 2002 had not reduced corporate debt nor re- countries, while reducing them in high-income stored profitability sufficiently. In a number of countries. cases, the downturn has generated new imbal- On balance, the declining availability of ances. Throughout the world, fiscal balances savings in the aging populations of high-ilconme deteriorated and balance sheets of financial countries and the increased savings in the institutions weakened. Continued tension in developing world-set against investment financial markets made the recovery less uni- patterns needed to accommodate potential form in 2002-as well as probably less robust growth-imply that more and more develop- In 2003-than would have been the case ing countries will move toward surplus on the under more normal circumstances. Vulnerabil- current account and that the recent shift from ity to adverse shocks has increased, and even debt accumulation to debt reduction is likely the potential for a "double-dip" recession sce- to continue. As long as domestic credit mar- nario in the industrial countries cannot-at kets continue to mature and public savings this juncture-be entirely ruled out. do not deteriorate, domestic savings can be Three distinct phases characterize recent expected to rise, and the required reduction in developments. The first phase portrays the debt levels will not conflict with the required driving forces behind the initial phase of the investment. recovery that started in late 2001, a recovery that was more robust in the United States and East Asia. These forces range from the end of A recovery constrained inventory adjustment, monetary easing, and by major risks fiscal stimulus to a technical rebound in the During the summer of 2002, investor risk high-tech industrial sectors. This picture nor- D perceptions increased and market senti- mally would be characterized as a favorable ment deteriorated across large parts of the environment for developing countries. That world's economy, thereby jeopardizing the environment includes low inflation and inter- global recovery that had started in the fourth est rates, plus a significant recovery in global 4 T HE IN TERN AT IO NA L EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR D EVE LO PING C O U N F R I E S trade and commodity prices, albeit a recovery annual rate, despite a drag of nearly 1.5 per- from low levels. During the second phase, a centage points stemming from a deterioration recovery typically broadens to other regions of net exports. In contrast, output in Japan in- and other sectors. Therefore, a recovery of creased by 2.5 percent, of which foreign trade profits and strong growth in fixed investment contributed 1.8 percentage points, while in the becomes the driving force that sustains or even Euro Area, GDP growth of 1.6 percent was accelerates growth. In the absence of such supported bv almost 1 percentage potnt from broadening and deepening, driving forces that positive net exports contributions. underpin the initial phase would suddenly appear to become short lived, which is the -inventory dynamics- situation today. Finally in the third phase- Inventory dvnamics played a pivotal role in typically the shift from "recovery" to eco- the recovery, thus complementing macro- nomic expanision-implications of the set of economic stimulus efforts. The same reduction opposing forces (cyclical rebound and finan- in the inventory stock that led to a negative cial turbulence) for the medium-term global contribution of stock building to CDP growth outlook (2003-04) are analyzed. The lack of in 2001 implied a positive contribution of uniformity in growth performance during stock building to GDP growth in 2002. Once 2002, following an almost synchronized slow- the lower level of desired inventories was ing of growth across regions in 2001, is par- achieved, stock building shifted from sharply ticularly notable. The growth projections for negative to close to zero. The slowing of inven- 2003 are more uniform across regions, but tory liquidation significantly shifted the con- are distinctly weaker than would have been tributLion to GDP growth from the second half anticipated in a strong, synchronized global of 2001 to the first half of 2002t that shift recovery. added 1.2 percentage points to the accelera- tion of GDP growth in both Japan and the The first phase of the global Euro Area, and a full 2.2 percentage points in recovery was driven the United States (figure 1.1). by policy stimulus- In the wake of the terrorist attacks in Septem- -a high-tech rebound- ber 2001, forceful monetary easing in the Recovery in global high-tech markets was an United States-and to a lesser extent in equally powerful stimulant. After demand for Europe-helped prevent a deepening of the semiconductors and related equipment plum- global downturn. U.S. consumers benefited meted during 2001, markets were anticipated from historically low interest rates to boost to rebound sharply, but the scope of recovery their purchases of durable goods. Combined exceeded expectations. There are several with double-digit growth in government natural limits to declines at rates of up to spending-mainly driven by security, defense, 50 percent. The nature of the product-the and reconstruction efforts-the stimulus was technology of which becomes obsolete sufficient to turn U.S. GDP growth positive, to quickly-warrants a periodic return to high 2.7 percent (annlualized), in the fourth quarter growth, as old products are replaced by new of 2001. One quarter later, Japan, which suf- ones and as the introduction of advanced fered steep output declines for three quarters technologies generates new and growing mar- in succession, and Europe, having experienced kets. Defensc- and security-related spending in only a modest fall in GDP, broke away from the United States also played a role in bolster- negative growth rates as well. ing demand (U.S. manufacturing orders for The importance of U.S. domestic demand computers and communications equipmenlt in this recovery is striking. During the first ratcheted to annual rates of 40 and 90 per- half of 2002, GDP advanced at a 3 percent cent, respectively, in early 2002). As the 5 G LO BA L ECON OM IC PROS PE CTS 2 0 03 Figure 1.1 The recovery was initiated in a typical fashion (growth in percent) 5 4 GDP growth 4 Japan 3 2 |l * / ~~~~Stock contribution I2 -1 -2 United States Euro Area -3 -4 -5 -6 03 04 01 02 Q3 04 Q1 02 03 04 01 02 2001 2001 2002 2002 2001 2001 2002 2002 2001 2001 2002 2002 Sousrce U S. Departmenit of Commerce, Japan Econiomic Statistics and Research Institute (ESRI) and Eurostat rebound intensified, a strong boost was given for a broader global recovery through the to manufacturing output in industrial coun- traditional channels of international transmis- tries, and especially to production and exports sion. With world trade increasing, commodity from East Asia (figures 1.2 and 1.3). prices firming, and interest rates-fostered by Macroeconomic stimuli, inventory dynam- low inflation-standing at historically low ics, and a powerful turnaround in high-tech markets in the industrial countries set the stage Figure 1.3 Rebound in industrial - .* countries boosted production in East Figure 1.2 A brief rebound in industrial Asia countries was underway Semiconductor dollar sales and Industrial Manufacturing production productlon (percent change, 3m/3m saar) (percent change, 3m/3m saar) 20 125 - 50 100 J.Sem~~~~~~~~~Siconductor sales j 15 (let axis) 40 10 ,,~~Japan 75 A30 10 EUzE U -1S tt 250 - Industrial production 20 0 ~~~~A25 \ 10 -5 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 0 -10 -25 -10 United States -15 . -0 -20 Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul -20 2000 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 Jan May Sep Jan May Sep Jan. May Sep 2000 2000 2000 2001 2001 2001 2002 2002 2002 Note. Through July 2002 'Republi of Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, aiid Taiwan, China. Note 3m/3m saar refers to 3-morith/3-month seasonially Souirce Semiconductor Iindustry Associataon (SIA) and adiLsred annualized rate national souirces through Datastream, World Bank staff Souirce Datastream. estimiates 6 T HE IN T ER N AT IO NA L EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP CC TS F OR D EVE LO PING CO UN r RI ES levels, developing countries faced a broadly crisis, such as Argentina and Turkey, have favorable environment during the early part of posted inflation peaks of just 20 to 40 percent. 2002. The second phase of the recovery -and a recovery of global trade is on uncertain footing World trade began to grow at near double- Notwithstanding the positive environment digit annual rates, recovering from a fall to taking shape in early 2002, it became appar- negative territory during 2001. The World ent before the middle of the year that financial Bank's non-oil commodities price index strains were clouding the outlook. In the gained 19.2 percent between October 2001 wake of large corporate bankruptcies and and October 2002 (figure 1.4), while the rele- the accounting scandals in the United States, vant index for Sub-Saharan African (SSA) stock markets still seemed overvalued and countries rose further-by 30 percent. How- debt levels seemed underestimated. Falling ever, commodity prices are still one-third equity prices further eroded the capital base below their peak levels, which occurred during of Japanese commercial banks and other the summer of 1997, and sevcral exporters, financial instltutLions. The growth outlook notably those in Caribbean countries that for Latin America deteriorated noticeably. specialize in coffee and sugar, did not benefit Following Argentina's default, Uruguay and from the rebound in average prices during the Paraguay were also hit hard through financial first half of 2002. Historically low inflation and trade linkages. Political uncertainty in the characterized not only the high-income Repiiblica Bolivariana de Venezuela triggered economies, but also those in the majority of capital flight, and in several other countries developing countries. The median inflation debt dynamics worsened as a result of a coIll- rate in developing countries is presently one- bination of domestic problems and increased third of that during the 1990s, despite rela- risk aversion in international capital markets tively high oil prices and more widespread (box 1.1). In Europe, financial institutionis adoption of flexible exchange rates. Indeed, were hit hard by defaults in the United States double-digit inflation rates have become an and in Argentina, as well as by falling equity exception, and countries experiencing recent prices and a weakening of the dollar. And the Figure 1.4 Non-oil commodities are recovering but stand well below previous peaks (index, Sept lOct 2001 = 100) 190 180 /\g/ Agriculture 170 160 150 rC\ /Sub-Saharan African 10 _ commodities 130 120 metals/minerals 110 100 Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Oct 1997 1997 1998 1998 1999 1999 2000 2000 2001 2001 2002 20022002 Souirce World Baunk sraff 7 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Box 1I1 Hs Latin America going against the rising tide? E conomic activity in Latin America and the Argentina, and of expanding political uncertainties ECaribbean (LAC) has fallen behind production in the run-up to the October elections all con- trends in other developing countries (box figure). tributed to a weakening in financial market senti- The region's per capita gross domestic product ment toward the country. The combination also re- (GDP) is estimated to have dropped by 2.6 percent sulted in a sharp reduction in private financing in 2002, the only developing region where per capita flows, which, in turn, led to a deterioration of public output contracted during the year. This decline was debt dynamics. the second consecutive year of contraction in per With financial markets increasingly averse to capita incomes-the worst performance since the taking risks through financial flows to the major beginning of the debt crisis in the early 1980s. Why LAC countries over the course of the year, other is LAC going against the tide of rising global income countries in the region were unable to obtain signif- growth? icant new financing from international capital The crisis in Argentina and the spillover markets at reasonable terms. This lack of financing effects on Southern Cone Comrnon Market limited growth in high-debt countries with significant (MERCOSUR) countries (particularly Uruguay financing requirements. Political instability in and Paraguay) clearly contributed the most to the Rep6blica Bolivariana de Venezuela-an aborted decline in regional output during 2002. In Brazil, coup in March that came on top of poor economic the combination of rising public debt, of declining management in previous years-led to a large export revenues tied to the collapse of demand in contraction in GDP of some 6 percent. The crisis in Argentina and its fallout is a classic example of a vicious circle of instability in interna- Latin America falls.behind tional financial markets and domestic vulnerabilities: (Ldustnalproduction, fdex, 1995=100, 3-month high levels of debt; large financing requirements; moving average) and, in some countries, fixed exchange rates, politi- cal uncertainties, and weak banking systems. Once 135 a crisis erupts, the vicious circle turns into a brutal 130 A downward spiral in which a depreciation of the 125 countries currency, debt burdens, a deterioration of dollar 120 returns, a rise in spreads, and a reversal of capital 115 /6c 2 flows reinforce each other. Argentina's peso lost 11 t_Latin America more than two-thirds of its value in the year to 110 { September. In a comparative perspective, stock 105 prices increased over the same period by 20-30 per- 100, , , I I I I C cent in several countries in East Asia and Central Feb Feb Feb Feb Feb Feb Europe, currencies were stable and spreads did not 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 increase substantially. Source National statistics, World Bank staff Source- World Bank staff. plight of European telecommunications sec- dards, have reduced some of the corporate tors continued to deepen under the weight of debt, but they have also led to a deterioration overinvestment and mounting debt loads. of the balance sheets of financial institutions. Bankruptcies and sharp reductions in in- To improve their reserves and to decrease their vestment expenditure, driven by the erosion of risk exposure, these financial institutions, in equity values and a tightening of credit stan- turn, sold part of their equity assets. In doing 8 T HE IN T E RN ATI O NA L EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING C O U N T R I E S so, they further fueled the fall in stock prices interest rates seems still likely, especially in and amplified new imbalances. Similarly, the Euro Area. The limited scope for macro- the drop in capital flows has increased debt economic policy makes the risks surrounding problems in several vulnerable middle-income the recovery even more severe. Policy solutions countries. in the industrial world may best be focused Another example of new or deteriorating on eliminating bad debts and restoring in- imbalances is the public sector deficit across vestor's sentiment by strengthening institu- the industrial countries. The U.S. general gov- tional oversight. ernment deficit deteriorated from a surplus position of 2.3 percent of GDP in calendar Capital flows to emerging markets year 2000 to a deficit of 2.5 percent in 2002, are declining with 2.5 percentage points of that shift attrib- Also important for middle-income coun- uted to structural deterioration. In turn, the tries was a continued decline in international United States has not taken advantage of the market-based capital flows, despite low inter- recession to narrow its deficit on current ac- national interest rates and the initial phase of count. Despite increases in the household sav- recovery in the industrial world. New gross ings rate and declines in the private investment capital market flows fell from $228 billion in rate, the current account deficit widened to 2000 to $175 billion in 2001, falling further a watershed mark of S percent of GDP as of to near $140 billion during 2002 (figure 1.5), the second quarter of 2002. with bank lending showing the steepest falloff. In the Euro Area as well, fiscal deficits have The latter point highlights the cautious posi- deteriorated from a 0.9 percent surplus to a like tion that international banks have adopted level of deficit, though this deterioration re- following financial crises in Turkey and flects mainly the work of automatic stabilizers. Argentina and following defaults by several Unlike the U.S. fiscal deficit, it is not a struc- large U.S. corporations. These capital flow fig- tural deterioration. France, Germany, Italy, ures suggest that total external debt in the and Portugal are now approaching the current developing world continues to contract. limits of a 3 percent of GDP deficit, limits Net foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows that were imposed by the European Monetary to developing countries also trended down- Union Growth and Stability Pact. The original plan to eliminate deficits by 2004 has been abandoned and replaced by an agreement to Figure 1.5 Private sector creditors have reduce structural deficits by at least O.S per- cut debt exposures so far in 2002 centage points per annum over the coming (gross market-based monthly flows in billions of dollars) years. Japanese fiscal deficits remain extra- 25 2001 monthly average = $143 ordinarily high, at levels above 7 percent of 2002 monthly average = $121 GDP. And East Asian emerging economies, on 20 average, continue to run relatively high deficit levels-above 4 percent of GDP-contrasted 15 with a deficit of 1 percent before the 1997 crisis. In other parts of the developing world, primary 1 1 surpluses are increasing, but improvement of s the overall deficit remains difficult to achieve, given the burden of debt service. 0 Deteriorated government deficits, com- J F M A M J J A S O N D J F M A M J J A bined with low nominal interest rates, have 2001 2002 left little room for further fiscal stimulus or Souirce Euromoney and World Bank staff estimates monetary easing, although some lowering of 9 G LO BA L EC ON OM IC PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 financial strains currently battering corporate Figure 1.6 FDI flows to emerging Asia sectors are likely to have a restraining effect are proving to be quite resilient on investment. Falling equity prices, concerns Net infiows of FDI by region about corporate debt, uncertainty about prof- (billlons of dollars. half yearly rate) itability, and cautious commercial bank lend- 50 ing in high-income countries tend to curtail 45 \ Lat nAmerica financing for investment. Moreover, current 40 business uncertainty regarding future demand 35 t growth serves as an additional restraining 30 force on capital spending. Reduced capital 25 20 Emerging Asia flows to emerging markets place a damper 15 Emerging Europe \ on investments in the developing world. If 10 one looks further ahead, large and increas- s ing public sector deficits carry the potential 1S 2nd I s I l to "crowd out" private investment in high- ts in si 2nd 1si 2nd 1si half half hall half half half half income and developing countries alike, al- 1999 2000 2001 2002 though low interest rates on government Source World Banik staff estimates bonds show that such crowding out is not yet a problem. -and driving forces for the initial phase ward, from about $170 billion in both 2000 could be short-lived- and 2001, to an estimated $145 billion during Without a solid upswing in investment and 2002 (figure 1.6). The decline can be almost a concomitant broadening of recovery, the wholly attributed to reduced flows into Latin forces driving the first phase of the rebound America, as FDI into Central Europe and East Asia retained a resilient tone. That resilience underscored the importance of the course of integration into global and neighboring mar- Figure 1.7 Investment recovery is still kets that China [recently gaining membership uncertain in the World Trade Organization (WTO)] and (4-quarter moving average, percentage change in the World Trade Organization (WTO)] and qlq, sear) Central European countries [anticipating 15 European Union (EU) accession] are following Developing countries at present. 10 \ /Industra Financial strains may inhibit s $ oun corporate investment- During the fall months of 2002, investment o was still declining in both high-income and developing countries, although the declines -5 V were bottoming out, which indicated the be- ginning of a turnaround (figure 1.7). In a typ- -10 01 01 Q1 Q1 Q1 ical recovery, once investment growth returns 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 to positive territory, the recovery gets new Note q/q refers to quarter over quarter impetus, because a virtuous circle of adjust- *Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Czech Republic, Poland, Turkey, Indonesia, Rep of Korea, Malaysia, ments in the capital stock and in expected Philippines, Thailand, and South Africa (4s% of market growth may easily generate double- developing cointry total) Souirce Datastream and WVorld Bank staff estimates digit advances n capital spending. However, 10 T HE IN T ER NAT IO NA L E CON OM Y A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING C O U N T R I E S could well become short-lived. Widening pub- appears to be dependent on (and exposed to) lic sector shortfalls limit the range of options global demand and financial conditions. for fiscal policy. As France, Germany, and Growth was disappointing in the first half of Italy approach Maastricht limits; as the U.S. 2002, and expectations for only a sluggish deficit widens; and as Japan remains encum- advance in output during the second half of the bered by continuing massive fiscal imbalance, year have now become more widespread. opportunities for further fiscal stimulus in the industrial world have indeed become quite -implying a much less supportive scarce. Moreover, it appears that several other external environment for developing driving forces for the initial recovery could countries quickly run out of momentum while their Against this background-particularly the stimulative properties dissipate. Official inter- lack of a rebound In fixed investment across est rates now standing at historically low industrial countries and the intensification of levels (particularly in Japan and the United financial uncertainties-the environment for States) leave little prominent role for further developing countries is much less favorable. monetary easing. And the inventory and International interest rates may remain low, high-tech cycles-typically of short duration- but borrowing costs have risen in step with in- probably reached peak levels by mid-2002. creases in interest rate spreads. Trade volumes Japanese output growth is now largely and commodity prices may be on the rise, but grounded in export growth, although con- they are still at low levels, and momentum is sumers have begun to spend at more rapid weakening. Metal prices started to decline rates-despite softening labor market condi- again in the middle of 2002, adding to the tions. Japan's strong export performance doubts about the strength of the global recov- stands at risk and could fade quickly should ery. The further rise in agricultural prices was foreign demand conditions worsen, should the mainly due to specific supply disruptions-as yen resume its appreciation against the dollar, civil strife in C6te d'lvoire jeopardized cocoa or both. In the United States, considerable un- production and as droughts in Australia, certainty is attached to the outlook for con- Canada, and the United States boosted wheat sumer spending. Following robust purchases prices-and was not a sign of rising demand. of durable goods during the third quarter- Inflation remains low, but the danger of particularly automotive sales that were in- outright deflation has emerged in parts of duced by zero interest incentives-questions developing and industrial East Asia-China, arise concerning the tenor of growth into the Hong Kong (China), Singapore, Taiwan final quarter of the year. Incentives cannot con- (China), and Japan. Stable and low inflation is tinue indefiniitely, and massive equity-based a prerequisite for solid growth and creates a wealth losses of the past two years could play favorable environment for effective monetary a larger role in households' consumption deci- policy. However, In several cases, a sharp drop sions. Though low interest rates have spurred in inflation has increased real interest rates mortgage refinancings and "cash outs," which and has worsened debt problems. Although are anticipated to place some $100 billion to deflation limits the options for monetary pol- $200 billion of additional liquidity into the icy, it tends to depress investment and demand hands of consumers during 2002, this trend for durable goods. could prove limited if the recovery falters seri- With market emphasis on financial strains ously. U.S. business remains cautious in invest- and risk perceptions, it is important not to ing or rehiring, in part because of the clouded lose sight of several brighter spots in the outlook for growth in final demand. And in developing world. Market reforms, including the Euro Area, especially in Germany, domes- a diminution of trade barriers and an open- tic demand is lackluster, and near-term growth ing up to foreign competition achieved in G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 many countries during the 1990s, are note- China and several Central European countries worthy. These changes have contributed to are examples of successful reforming econo- faster growth in trade and in welfare gains, and mies that are preparing for even further inte- the process continues across many countries. gration into foreign markets. This integration Box 112 EIntegration pays off where po]licies are supportive T he recent global downturn has depressed export inregration with global markets largely through the T growth across the developing world, leading to EU accession process, association agreements, and a contraction in aggregate volume from the third lower trade barriers, which will culminate with full quarter of 2001 through the first quarter of 2002. menmbership in the EU, which appears now on track However, several countries-notably China, the for 2004. Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland-have been Reduction of trade barriers is but one factor able to record impressive export volume growth that has made these coLntries successful and able (box figure). They have done so by increasing their to take advantage of trade opportunities. Macro market share, which has allowed them to partially stability, rapid institutional reforms toward liberal- offset the dampening effect of the global downturn. ization of domestic markets, good or adequate This increase in market share, in turn, reflects a levels of education, and competitive wages (relative continuing pattern of their intensifying integrationi to productivity growth) all contribute to the into the global economy and of attendant inflows success. of FDI. These four countries have benefited from Greater integration with world markets has strong and sustained inflows of FDI from Western been achlieved by China, for example, through its investors that have been building production recently gained membership (December 2001) in capacity and transferring management skills and the WTO, after years of negotiations and efforts to technical know-how, in addition to financing, such comply with WTO rules and standards. The three that these countries can gain additional market Central European countries have raised their trade share as integration deepens. FDI inflows help ex- pand production capacity and raise productivity (that is, they help to improve the recipient country's Several developing countries competitiveness). All four countries have posted show solid export performance liigh FDI inflows according to various measures. (volumes, 3-month moving average, percent y/y) For example, using the ratio of the economy's share of world FDI inflows to the economy's share of 0 Chia world GDP, China, the Czech Republic, Hungary, 30 and Poland all posted ratios of above t (or the world Eastem Europe average) for 1998-2000-of 1.3, 2.7, 1.2, and 1.5, 20 / respectively. As a share of gross fixed capital forma- ro 1 0 h JF tlt nt 3;>V \N, j V tion, FDI inflows to these countries have also been 1l l l ll 111 1f l i X - high, particularly in China, where FDI inflows aver- o Ti " 4t * * l msI 1 1 l aged 13 percent of gross fixed capital formation dur- Oiherdeveloping countnesWoU@World ing 1990-99. In the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul Poland, FDI inflows averaged 25, 19, and 16 per- 2000 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 cent, respectively, as a share of gross fixed capital formation during 1997-99. Note y/y refers to year over year Souerce Datastream and World Bank staff estimates So__rce__World_Bank_staff 12Source: World Bank staff. 12 r HE IN T ER N ATI ON AL EC ONO MY AND P R O S P E C I S F O R D E V E L O P I N G C O U N T R I E S not only pays off in the long run, but also has * Growth in 2003-04 is anticipated to be assisted these countries in absorbing or even moderate. World GDP reflects a combi- avoiding short-term shocks and fluctuations, nation of a more gradual recovery in by promoting business confidence and by facil- Latin America, an emergence of modest itating export-oriented FDI. Perhaps more growth in Japan, and a generally sub- important, through relatively large inflows of dued rebound in other parts of the global FDI, these countries have become less vulner- economy. The average outturn does not able to turmoil in internationial financial mar- follow the typically strong patterns of kets (box 1.2). recovery and expansion that is concurrent across regions and reinforced by accom- The medium-term outlook calls modating macro policies. for modest growth in the global * Downside risks to the baseline forecast economy-third phase are substantial. The global recovery The baseline forecast reflects the interaction appears vulnerable to additional shocks. of strong opposing forces: the stimulative (These points are discussed after we policies and the intrinsic recovery in stock review the external environimilent and building and high-tech production that work outlook for developing countries.) to accelerate global growth on the one hand, and the financial strains-high and rising debt The external environment is mixed levels, falling equity prices, and uncertainty The driving forces may be found in expecta- about profitability-on the other hand. These tions for growth of global trade volumes driving and restraining forces affect the out- 2.9 percent in 2002 and an average of 7.5 per- look in three ways: cent in the following two years (figure 1.8 and table 1.2). The restraining forces make a sub- Global growth in 2002, the initial year stantial rise in capital flows unlikely over the of the forecast, shows little resemblance medium term. The modestly firming trends in to the uniform recovery that one would non-oil commodities prices-5 percent in 2002 normally expect after an almost synchro- and averaging 5 1 percent in the following nous downturin in 2001. Instead, it dis- years-reflect the subdued recovery. The 5 per- plays quite diverse patterns of activity cent gains in commodity prices remain far across industrial as well as developing below historical patterns during booms. In- countries. creases in real commodity prices are expected Figure 1.8 World trade rebounds along with GDP, 1998-2004 (percentage change) 1 4 10 /Worldtrade 6 /World GDP \I 6 4 2 . .l__ 0_ 0 -2 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Soutrce IBF, OECD, World Banik. anid WXorld Banik prolctloris 13 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 Table 1.2 External environment for developing countries, 1991-2004 (percenttage change from previous year, except tinterest rates and oil price) Current estimate Currenit forecasts Growth rates/ratios 1 1991-2000 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2002-04 Industrial country GDP growth 1 2.4 2 9 3 4 0.8 1 4 2 1 2 6 2 0 World trade growth' 7.2 5.6 13 1 -05 2.9 6 7 7.7 5 7 Industrial country import demand 6 9 8.5 11.6 -1 0 1 3 5.3 6.8 4 4 United States 9 4 12.4 13.7 -3.6 4 4 8.1 8 0 6 8 Japan 5 6 6 6 10.7 -2.8 -2.0 7 7 8 6 4 7 Euro Area 6.6 6 4 11.2 0 8 -0.5 4 0 6.6 3.3 Developing-country import demand 8.2 -1 3 16.9 45 56 10.1 100 8.0 1 Market growth for developing countricsb 10.7 5.3 13.1 0 2 2 6 7.0 8.4 6.0 Non-oil commodity prices (nominal) -1.4 -11 2 -1.3 -9.1 5.0 5 8 4 4 5 1 Agriculture -1.3 -13 9 -5 5 -9 1 8 4 8 5 4 8 7.0 Metals and minerals -1 8 -2 3 12 6 -9 6 -3.5 5.6 5 7 2.5 Real non-oil commodity pricesc -1 1 -11.0 0.8 -7 8 4.5 2 8 2.2 3.2 Oil price ($, weighted average), $/bbl 19.1 18 1 28 2 24 4 25.0 23.0 20 0 22 7 Manufactures unit value indexd 1 -0.3 -02 -2.1 -1 4 0.5 3.0 22 1 9 Developinig-country terms of trade 0.1 3.3 2 8 0 3 -3 2 -1.4 -1.3 -2.0 Terms of trade/GDP ('.), 0.1 0.7 0.6 0 1 -0 8 -0 4 -0 4 -0 5 LIBOR (US$, 6 months) 5.6 5 5 6 6 3.6 1.8 1.5 3 1 2.2 EURIBOR (euro, 6 months) 5 4 3.1 4.5 4 2 3.4 3 2 3 8 3.5 Note bbl = barrel, LIBOR = London interbank offered rate, EURIBOR = European interbank offered rate a Goods and nontfactor services b. Weighted average growth of import demand in export markets c Deflated by manufactures unit value index d Dollar-based export prices of manufactures in the G-5 countries e Chanige in terms of trade, measured as a proportion to GDP (percent) Source World Bank, November 2002 to be even more moderate, about 2.5 percent sipates and that increased supply, both from per year. Most of the increase in commodity Organization of Petroleum Exporting Coun- prices in 2002 was due to a surge in agricul- tries (OPEC) and non-OPEC sources, can eas- tural prices, which bounced off cyclical lows: ily meet moderate increases in demand. This the agricultural index had dropped 40 percent forecast would imply oil prices of around below its peak, which was reached in 1997. $20 per barrel by 2004. The lack of strength The recent surge is to a large extent induced in the recovery is also reflected in the interest by supply factors: for example, droughts in rate projections. The London interbank of- Australia and the United States have boosted fered rate (LIBOR) and European interbank grain prices, and supply disruptions in Cote offered rate (EURIBOR) are anticipated to d'Ivoire and Ghana did the same for cocoa drop modestly further during 2003, but to in- prices. Conversely, the rally in metal prices that crease in step with firming economic activity started in October 2001, which is normally by 2004, at rates below 4 percent. strongly correlated with the business cycle, The recovery in global markets is shaped stalled in the second quarter of 2002. The fore- primarily by developments in industrial coun- cast for metal prices is one of decline in 2002, tries. At 1.4 percent in 2002 and an average of and of a return to 5-6 percent gains thereafter. 2.3 percent in the following years, growth re- This trend is another indication that the tenor mains at or below potential, which is a rare of global recovery is anticipated to be modest. phenomenon during a recovery (figure 1.9). In The base forecast assumes that the current this forecast, inflation will accelerate little, re- risk premium in the oil market gradually dis- maining below 2000 or 2001 levels. 14 I H E I N T E R N A T I O N A L E C O N O M Y A N D P R OS P E C T O r o R D E V 1: L O P I N G C O U N I R I E S Figure 1.9 2002 marks the start of a moderate recovery (GDP growth rate in percent) 6 Developing countries Forecast 5 S ~~~~~Industrial countr e\> 4 3 2 0 _/_ 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Source World Banik data and projections An outlook for moderate growth across 12 percent, and growth in the region slowed developing regions- from 1.2 percent in 2001 to 0.7 percent in What does this environment imply for output 2002). The region's per capita income fell growth in the developing countries? In 2002, 2.6 percent after a drop of 1.2 percent in 2001, a strong recovery in East Asia coincides with a which was the worst performance across two disappointinig performance in Latin America, years since the debt crisis in the early 1980s where GDP declined by 1.1 percent (excluding (figure 1.10). Oil exporters, particularly in Argentina, where GDP plummeted by nearly the Middle East and North Africa (MENA), Figure 1.10 LAC and MENA are not experiencing the recovery (developing countnes GDP growth, percent change) 7 6 5 4~~~~~~~~~~20 3 2~~~~~~~~~20 -1 2002 -2 East Asia South Asia Laiin Eastern Middle East Sub-Saharan and Pacitic America and Europe and and North Africa the Caribbean Central Asia Africa Source World Banik projections 15 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 follow an independent growth pattern, which, fit of hindsight, it is quite difficult to disentan- to some extent, is the same for developing gle the set of recent shocks and their effects on countries that are rapidly integrating into for- developing countries. Yet the downward revi- eign markets (for example, Central European sions do not contradict the assessment made countries, China, and Mexico), where exports in the fall of 2001 that adverse effects stem- were recently able to outperform world trade ming from the terrorist attacks of September growth as a whole (see box 1.2). 2001 would not be limited to the United Average growth in 2002 for developing States, but would spread to developing coun- countries is anticipated to be 2.8 percent, tries as well (box 1.3). 0.3 percentage points lower than was expected Sharply different growth patterns are likely in the February 2002 forecast and 0.8 per- to characterize economic activity across coun- centage points lower than was projected in the tries and regions in the short run, as jittery December 2001 forecast. Even with the bene- financial markets affect the vulnerable and ]3ox 113 The terrorist attacks of September 119 2001 had an economic effect Shortly after the terrorist attacks of September 11, of accounting scandals in the United States, compli- V2001, the World Bank concluded that the eco- cate the picture. nomic effects would be most severe in the United The fiscal stimulus and rapid monetary easing States but would be significant in developing coun- in the United States probably prevented a serious tries. The main transmission mechanisms were delay in the U.S. recovery and in world trade growth. thought to be: Non-oil commodity price increases have slightly out- performed forecasts made in the fall of 2001. How- • Tourism revenues would decline, especially in South ever, the steep decline in tourism revenues and the Asia, the Middle East, and the Caribbean. increase in risk perceptions did materialize, and the o Increased risk perceprions in international markets outlook for developing countries has further deterio- would make oil prices more volatile, foreign capital rated, especially for Latin America. This observation less readily available, and transportation more costly. suggests that 9/11 did exert strong ifluence in shap- o There would be delayed recovery in the United States, ing ensuing economic trends in developing countries, where immediately after the attacks air traffic was albeit reinforced by other factors. constrained, equity prices had declined sharply, and Following continuous and robust growth over consumer confidence had plummered. That delay the past decade, global tourism arrivals declined would also hamper the recovery In world trade, com- by 0.6 percent in 2001, tied in large measure to the modity prices, and financial flows, effect of the terrorist attacks. The most-affected Of the developing world, Latin America was developing regions were South Asia (down 6 per- thought to be the hardest hit because of its proximity cent), Latin America (down 4 percent), and the Mid- to the United States, its dependence on tourism rev- dle East (down 3 percent). enues and commodity prices, and its vulnerability Business and consumer confidence across the to financial shocks. Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa industrial centers fell abruptly in the aftermath of were also vulnerable because they have limited the attacks. Although the losses evaporated within options to absorb adverse shocks. 2 months as the recovery took shape, the tenor of Even with the hindsight of a year, it still remains business and financial market confidence has contin- quite difficult to assess the independent effect of 9/11 ued to be exceptionally fragile (box figure). This fac- on the global economic environment. Not only are tor was one underlying the decline of capital market the counterfactuals unkinown but new shocks, such flows to emerging market recipients in 2002, as well as the financial crisis in Argentina or the emergence as the rise in bond markets. 16 T HE IN r ER NAT IO NA L EC ONO MY AND PRO SP EC TS F OR Dr v EL O PING CO UN TR IE S Box 1.3 (continued) U.S. confidence plummets (ISM and Conference Board business and consumer sentiment indices) 60 120 :0 - \ / Consumer confidence 110 ISM index \ / 100 50 - 45 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~90 80 Jan Apr Jul Oct Jan Apr Jul Oct 2001 2001 2001 2001 2002 2002 2002 2002 Soiurce Iinstitute for Suppl) Managenient and Coniferenice Bloard, throig/i Datastream Developing countries' GDP growth in 2002 has thesc developments took form under the influence of been limited to 2.8 percent-about 0.8 percentage a global environment that was highly unsettled by point below that expected onc year ago (notably, the destruction of the New York World Trade figures that included an assessment of the 9/11 ef- Center. fects). Although not all barriers to stronger growth are linked directly to the terrorist attacks, most of Soutrce World Bank staff highly indebted developing countries more together with the pursuit of policies geared to- severely than countries with lower debt ratios. ward reducing financial strains. Mexico and Though the forecasts for 2003-and espe- sorine Central American and Caribbean coun- cially for 2004-display accelerationi of tries are in position to benefit most from the growth that tends toward more uniformity expected upswing in the United States, and across regions, that acceleration is weaker Mexico's growth in particular is anticipated to than one would expect in a strong, synchro- exceed that of most Latin American countries. nized global recovery.2 The forecast for Latin America and the -has the strongest growth evident in Caribbean (LAC) assumes some rebound in East Asia- Argentina, where output has fallen some Prospects for developing East Asia and Pacific 20 percent below 1998 levels, but the rebound (EAP) appear more buoyanit than those for is insufficient to return to carlier prevailing other regions, as growth is expected to reach levels within the time horizon of this forecast. 6.4 percent by 2004. Continiued solid expan- Modest growth rates are anticipated for Brazil sion in China and recovery in most other and most other countries of the region. That countries-albeit with growth rates that re- growth is grounded in a recovery in global main below the robust performance of 2000- trade and an end to the freefall in Argentiiia, underpin this view. Favorable prospects do 17 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 not imply that risks are negligible, however. infrastructure and other development activities, East Asia remains vulnerable to oil price especially in Algeria, the Islamic Republic of spikes, to uncertain demand conditions in the Iran, and Saudi Arabia. Growth among the di- United States, and to the fragile state of the versified exporters should increase to an aver- Japanese commercial banking system and age of 3.2 percent, as drought conditions ease growth prospects there. Moreover, the dy- in Morocco and Tunisia and as fiscal deficits namics in high-tech markets remain volatile. are brought under tighter control and business Options for domestic stimulus are more lim- confidence returns in Egypt-as the govern- ited than in previous years because in most ment there sets an appropriate interest rate and countries fiscal deficits have widened and in- pushes ahead with policies, such as privatiza- terest rates stand at low levels. tion, that will increase international investor In Europe and Central Asia (ECA), growth confidence. Risks to this outlook are substan- is expected to remain strong, but it will be tial, however, with political tensions mounting grounded in a highly differentiated outlook during apparent preparations for military between the Central and Eastern European action in Iraq. At this juncture, the baseline (CEE) group of countries and the hydrocarbon does not explore these potential developments, exporters that dominate growth trends in the but rather focuses on the country-specific and Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS- region-specific economic fundamentals, as well Russian Federation, Kazakhstan, and several as global factors that contribute to shape the smaller states). For the former group, output outlook. growth is projected to accelerate from 2.3 per- cent in 2002 to 3.1 percent and 4.3 percent -and South Asia in 2003 and 2004, respectively. Activity is A forecast of consistent growth in the South expected to be driven by increased import Asia region (SAR) of well above 5 percent demand from the EU and by intensification over 2003-04 comes after a significant cycli- of the EU's accession process. For Turkey cal downturn in 2001, when manufacturing (included in this group), assuming that there output in India and Pakistan stopped growing is relative political stability and that the new and when GDP growth mainly reflected con- government continues to pursue the current re- tinued expansion in the service sectors. The form path, recovery is expected to strengthen main challenge for the subcontinent remains in 2003. In contrast, growth is anticipated to fiscal reforms to curb over-large government ease in the CIS subregion in the years through deficits and to promote further trade liberal- 2004 (through fiscal and trade linkages to the ization. With almost-balanced current ac- hydrocarbon exporters in particular), assum- counts and with substantial capital flows into ing a significant medium-term decline in the Pakistan, external financial tensions remain oil price. CIS GDP is anticipated to decelerate limited at present. But, it is expected that the from 4.4 percent in 2002 to 3.5 percent and effects of accumulated fiscal debt will, at some 3 percent in 2003 and 2004. These divergent future point become an obstacle to achieving trends combine to shape the path of growth the acceleration in growth required for sub- for the broader region, from 3.6 percent in stantial alleviation of poverty levels. 2002 to an average of 3.5 percent in the years Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) re- following. mains restrained by unfavorable domestic con- Growth in the Middle East and North Africa ditions, ranging from civil strife, to droughts, (MENA) region is expected to revive in to macroeconomic imbalances, and to the AIDS 2003-04 to average 3.6 percent, as hydrocar- epidemic. Elements of the external environ- bon output increases in line with global energy ment should, however, provide some support demand, and as accumulated oil-surplus funds for a modest acceleration of growth over the are progressively committed and expended on next years. Despite a relatively sluggish pickup 18 T I1 E IN FE RN Al IO NA 1. EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR I) E V EL O PING C O U N T R I E S in world GDP growth in 2003-04, a robust markets, thereby heightening tensions in sev- recovery is anticipated for African trade vol- eral vulnerable middle-inconie countries; and umes, ratcheting from growth of 3 percent in (c) the risk of higher oil prices, which are as- 2001 toward 6 percent by 2004. That recov- sociated with prospective developments in the ery should be accompanied by generally Middle East. firmer non-oil commodity prices (exceptions The base case presents a moderate but are cocoa and gold, where prices have surged steady recovery in investment; it effectively to unsustainable levels). The resulting terms of rules out finaicial crises in middle-income trade gains should support relatively buoyant countries and foresees a gradual decline In oil external performances by African non-oil cx- prices. If downside risks materialize, adverse porters. For oil exporters of the region, the outturns in these domains could easily occur price of crude is expected to weaken in the at the same time or could, in sequence, rein- medium term. Even so, oil sectors will remain force cumulative effects on the economy. To profitable, and production and export vol- gauge the sensitivity of economic recovery to times are anticipated to rise-from i'ligeria these risks, we have traced the possible effects and other producers in the Gulf of Guinea, as on the economic outlook of these elements. well as from Angola's offshore sector. The results underscore the set of tensionis em- In the domestic sphere, agricultural pro- bedded in the base-case forecast and can illu- duction will benefit from a return to more minmate the magnitude of potential downside normal weathier patterns in southerin Africa, risk to the projections-with particular focus thus contributing to a recovery of domestic on the implications for developing countries.3 output and expenditure. On balance, GDP growth for the region is expected to rise from Global recovery could be delayed 2.5 percent in 2002 to 3.2 percent in 2003 and until 2004 3.8 by 2004. The overall acceleration reflects Table 1.3 outlines the global effects of a low- gains by non-oil exporters, which will more case scenario in which the risks highlighted than offset modest retrenchment by oil pro- above occur essentially at the same time, but ducers. The current projection for the region each of the adverse shocks is fairly short lived. represents a sliglt deterioration of prospects The scenario reflects the joint effects of a compared with the spring 2002 forecast, temporary relapse to negative growth in the which is consistent with the overall down- industrial country's investimient cycle, of short- grading of expectations for world output and lived financial disruptions in several middle- trade growth. Nevertheless, though perfor- income countries, and of a momentary spike mance will continue to lag behind other devel- to $45 per barrel (bbl) in world oil prices The opmig regions, per capita incomes are set to scenario suggests that, rather than an acceler- resume positive growtlh following several years ation of global growth in 2003 to 2.5 percent of stagnation. as in the base case, a continuation of sluggish output advance in a range of 1.9 percent could Risks to the base case are substantial characterize the year. Contrasted with base- The world recovery is clouded by substantial case forecasts, cumulative differences over uncertainties in the immediate to near term. 2003-04 in world trade growth, OECD infla- These uncertainties carry with them implica- tion, and interest rates are fairly substantial. tions for medium-term developments in global The latter element reflects a strong monietary growth and financial flows. Among critical policy response to the financial and real dis- factors in the outlook are (a) continued finan- turbances of the scenario. OECD output cial turbulence in high-income countries that growth is dampened by 1 percentage point, could jeopardize a rebouncl in investment; and for developing countries, it is dampened (b) a reversal in capital flows to emerging by 0.8 point over the period (figure 1.11). G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Table 1.3 Global effects in a low-case scenario, 2003-04 2003 2004 2003-04 Scenario Diff. lbase) Scenario Diff (base) Cum. diff GDP growth (%) World 1 9 -0.6 2 7 -0 4 -1.0 industrial countries (OECD) 1 5 -0 6 2.2 -0 4 -1 0 Developiiig countries 3.0 -0 9 4 8 0 1 -08 Consumer price index inflation (%) Industrial counitries 2 2 0 1 1 2 -0 6 -0.5 Developing counitries (median) 5 0 0 6 4.4 0.0 0.6 Short-term interest rates (%) Industrial counitries 2.9 -0.3 3.3 -0 8 -1.1 Trade volumes (%) OECD imports 5 5 -1 3 7 5 -0 4 -1 7 Developing-country exports 9 3 -1 0 9.2 -0 3 -1 3 Source World Bank, Noveinber 2002 Among industrial countries, growth pro- falling substantially below baseline), but it files in the United States and Japan are more will rebound wsth some vigor as conditions adversely affected. This is linked to the relapse equilibrate in 2004. East Asia-with strong of fixed investment spending during 2003, links to export markets in all three industrial with less room for monetary easing than exists centers-will also suffer a sharp falloff in in the Euro Area. Among developing regions, growth, but less so than Latin America. Latin America will feel the initial brunt of Initially, inflation increases slightly in reac- diminished capital inflow during 2003 (growth tion to the rise in oil price. However, when oil prices start falling again and the effect of lower growth becomes noticeable, inflation Figure 1.11 Low case: world trade and will drop in high-income countries, thereby other indicators will be much lower than triggering substantial monetary easing com- the baseline pared with the baseline. In developing coun- (cumulative difterences,2003-04, ow-case scenano tries, inflation will remain on average above versiusbase-case scenano, percent) its base-case level, as higher oil prices are com- Developing- plemented by devaluation of several curren- World Interest OECD OECD country trade rates inflation growth growth cles in reaction to financial tensions. o0 * * Table 1.4 breaks out for 2003 the contri- butions of the individual risk scenarios (out- -0 5 lined below) to the overall low-case simula- I -oUs - tion. A relapse of investment in the industrial -1C0 - -08 countries carries the largest downside poten- -1 1 -0 tial to the global outlook, which affects output -1 5 growth, world trade, and interest rates most acutely. Developing-country growth is more -1 7 affected under the restraint of capital flow -20 scenario, but is equally diminished by devel- Soutrce World Bqi,k opments under the G-7 investment scenario and by higher oil prices. The latter scenario 20 T H E I NT ER NAT IO NA L EC ONO MY AN D P R O S P IiC r S F O R D E V r L o P I N G C O U N I R I E S Table 1.4 Low case: contributions to global effects in 2003 - -| Diar kiu-j 1-- - L. I.i Flu.." uJ p;.J GDP growth - . World 19 -0.6 -0 3 -0 1 4 2 Inidustrila countries (OECD) 1.5 -0 6 -0 3 -0 1 -0 2 l)eNelopinig counitries 3 ( . -0.9 -0 .2 -0 5 -0.2 Consumer price index inflation (%) Inidustrial countries 2.2 0 1 -0 I 0 0 0 2 Devcloping countries (mediani) 5.0 0 6 -0 1 0 1 0 6 Short-term interest rates 2.9 - -0.3 -0.3 -0.1 0 1 World trade 5.8 -1.3 -0.9 -0,1 .0.3 OECD imports 5.5 -1.3 -1 0 0 0 -03 Developinig exports 9 3 -1 0 -0 6 -0 2 -0 2 Source World Banik, November 2002 prospectively could hamper a fuller easing of monetary policy across the industrial centers, Figure 1.12 G-7 investment falls sharply with growth suffering commensurately. (base-case scenario and low-case sceonanos, voliume growth, percent saar) Financial market turbulence in high- s income countries could trigger a relapse in the investment cycle- Base-case \ /scearraio Though investment growth momentum is now o building in selected sectors and countries, the potential for relapse looms large as imbal- ances and uncertainties remain acute through- Low-case out the industrial world. The low-case sce- socnsrio nario assumes that the growth of real business -10 investmiient in industrial countries drops to 04 02 04 Q2 04 Q2 Q4 02 Q4 negative territory (-0.7 percent) during 2003, 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 2004 which would be 3.5 percentage points of Souirce Natnoiial statistics. World Basik proiectio,,s growth below the baseline path. Spillovers into 2004 carry cumulative growth differences in capital spending to 6.5 percentage points (figure 1.12). 0.4 percent in 2003 and by a further 0.3 per- If one examines the scenario environment cent during 2004, as multiplier effects place among the industrial countries, cumulative pressure on household consumption. With inflation over 2003-04 is reduced by 0.5 per- the compression of imports, adverse growth cent. At the same time, the profile of short- effects in the major industrial countries are term interest rates reflects reductions that are transmitted to smaller advanced economies, more than the improvement in inflation per- while weakened demand for commodities formance, which represents a substantial places downward pressure on1 nonenergy easing of monetary policy in the wake of de- prices, thus affecting developing countries' velopments. The rate of unemployment rises terms of trade adversely. On balance, GDP by 0.4 percentage points in OECD countries. growth in developing countries will decline Among prominent growth effects, industrial by 0.3 percentage points relative to the base country output gains are dampened by figures during 2003-04. 21 G LO BA L EC ONO M IC PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 -while financial tensions pose difficulties for emerging markets- Figure 1.13 Investment growth and net Under a scenario of substantially lower in- capital flows* into Latin America are flows of private capital into countries with strongly correlated weak r deciningcredi ratigs an withlarge (4-quarter movwng (4-quarter moving weak or declining credit ratings and with large average. percent GOP) average, percent saar) financing requirements, interest rates rise, ex- 25 change rates depreciate, or both, which raises Investment 20 the cost of servicing debt and results in diffi- 6 A 20 culties in meeting debt payments for both the 10 1 - 5 public and private sectors. To understand the 4 - possible implications of such development, we \ performed a simulation in which capital flows -5 to selected emerging market countries were 2 assumed to drop by 15 percent below the 1 Netcapdalflows - baseline forecast in 2003, while spreads on in- as percent of GOP I I I 2 ternational debt would increase substantially. 1 01 01 Q1 01 01 Q1 01 01 With these assumptions, the Latin America 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 region will suffer an average falloff in output 'Net capital flows defined as CAD-addition to growth of 1.9 percentage points compared reserves-lMrF funds with the baseline in 2003 . Rebound in re- Source Datastream and World Bank staff estimates with the baseline In 2003. Rebound In re- sponse to eventual equilibration in exchange and interest rates, as well as to falling risk spreads, should be grounded in stronger ex- prices. A so-called war premium on prices has ports, and output growth rises some 0.9 per- been estimated at up to $8-$9/bbl. The base centage point above the base in 2004. The case assumes that the oil market normalizes cumulative fall in regional growth amounts with further increases in non-OPEC supply, to 1.1 percentage points during 2003-04. This with a modest rise in OPEC quota, and with fall is a reflection of the strong dependence a dissipating of the war premium. These as- of Latin America on capital inflows, whereas sumptions might turn out to be too optimistic. reversals in capital flows tend to have far- With continued tensions in the Middle East reaching consequences for domestic economies and vith the possibility that, for example, in that region (figure 1.13). Central Europe is some 2 million barrels per day (mb/d) of Iraqi another region that is affected by the reversal oil exports would be temporarily lost to the in international capital flows, although the market, oil prices might rise well above greater diversity within the region makes the $30/bbl-partly because of low stocks and overall effect smaller than for Latin America. tight market conditions-and might peak at $4S/bbl during the height of the disruption. -and higher oil prices could temporarily However, it is likely that any loss in supply (yet moderately) dampen recovery will eventually be replaced by other OPEC Crude oil prices have risen to more than producers. They currently have about 5 mil- $29/bbl because of expectations of a supply lion barrels per day (mb/d) of spare capacity- disruption in Iraq and of increasingly tighter of which Saudi Arabia alone has some 3mb/d. market fundamental conditions. Crude oil Or supply will otherwise be replenished. Prices stocks fell sharply in the third quarter of 2002, could fall relatively quickly below $20/bbl by particularly in the United States. The drop was 2004 before OPEC begins to restrain output as due to high runs of refined products, a decline world demand increases, as the organization in Iraqi crude exports, and continued restraint attempts to bring prices back into its target by OPEC to limit exports in support of higher price band of $22-$28/bbl (figure 1.14). 22 T II r I N i E R N A T I O N A L E C O N O M Y A N D P R O S P E C I S F O R D) V E L. 0 P I N G C O U N I R I E S Figure 1.14 Oil prices spike Figure 1.15 Investment is more volatile (base-case and low-case scenanos, oil pnce $/bbl) than GDP in East Asia 36 0 (4-month moving average, percentage change qlq, saar) A 30 31 5 / ,A ,-Investment Base-case Low-case 20 scenarqo scenano GDP 270 10 18 0 0 7| 04 02 04 02 04 Q2 04 02 Q4 -20 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 2004 -30 Soturce World Bank dati, World Bank prolectionis -40 Q1 01 01 01 01 01 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Note Indonesia, Rep of Korea, Malaysia, Phiippiiies, On a cumulative basis, a $2.501bbl incrcase aid Thliailaid in oil price above baseline levels (but with dy- Sozurce Datastrearn and World Banik ctaff estimrtes namics as outlined above) will yield a moder- ate fall in global growth of 0.1 percent during 2003-04. Effects during 2003 will be some- what more pronounced, however: a drop in world output of 0.2 percentage points. Infla- than GDP in Latin America tion and interest rates in the industrial coun- (4-month moving average, percentage change q/q, saar) tries will be boosted modestly, by some 0.2 and 0.1 percentage points, respectively. 20 15/ 10 a / Investment Investment cycles in developing 5 _4GDP countries For developing countries, the risk of an F untimely interruption to the recovery in -s global investment comes after a period of sharp -10 swings in investment in the past five years. -1 _ During the East Asian crisis, investimient fell at GI Q1 Q1 01 Q1 01 an annual rate of 30 percent, three times the 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 fall in output (figure 1.15). Crises in Argentina Note Argentiia, Brazil, Chile, aid Mexico and Turkey dominated recent developments in Source Dattstrearn aid World Banik sra ff estimates Latin America and Central Europe, respec- tively, with regional investment declining at annual rates of 15-20 percent (figures 1.16 and 1.17). The dynamics of itivestment are much isons of developing with high-income more forceful than that of output.4 countries. This section looks at three important * The cffects of improvements in the in- patterns: vestment climate on the volatility of investment and output. . The volatility of investment, relative to * The role of capital flows that influence the the volatility of output, and compar- investment cycle in developing countries. 23 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 for some 160 countries over the 1990-2000 Figure 1.17 Central Europe and Turkey period.6 The volatility of the cyclical compo- experience greater volatility in nents of investment declines steeply with investment than in GDP htgher income per capita. (4-month moving average, percentage change qlq, saar) Explanations for the high volatility of in- 45 vestment in low- and middle-income countries 30 A will vary from large external shocks relative to 30 \ Investment the size of the country to a poor investment 1 5 GDP climate. Properly functioning domestic finan- cial institutions may smooth cycles by allow- o, , 1 , > ? , | t;4- /sing additional savings to be channeled to investors during downturns. -15 Poor countries, on average, tend to be rela- tively small economies. Thus, the GDP of an -30 Q Q Q Q average low-income country during the 1990s 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 was $25.6 billioon, barely 2.5 percent of the Note Czech Republic, Poland, and Turkey average high-income country. Baxter and Source Datastream and World Bank staff estimates Crucini (1993) and Crucini (1997) argue that, ,_________________ _ as a result, external shocks are relatively large in proportion to GDP, which explains reason- Table 1.5 Relative volatility of investment ably well the patterns observed in figure 1.18. Table high indevelopingcountriesFor example, international capital flows can easily be much larger from the standpoint of 1971-80 1981-90 1991-2000 a small country, and reversals in capital flows Low ncome 4.6 5 2 7.6 can have a relatively large effect. The decision MiddleIncomne 4.9 3.6 4.5 by a French multinational to invest $100 mil- Hlgh-income OECD I 2.9 3.2 ~ lion in Senegal instead of at home would re- Note This table presents tinweighted averages of country- duce France's investment spending in 2000 by specific standard deviations of investment growth as a ratio to the unweighted average of standard deviations of GDP growth Source World Bank, Figure 1.18 Investment volatility declines Investment cycles are more pronounced with income in lower-income countries than in higher- (mean and standard deviation of volatitty of investment) income countries 020 The volatility of investment growth relative to the volatility of output growth is twice as large 0 15 ard deviation in low-income countries as in high-income Mean economies-and volatility has increased over 0 10 time (table 1.5). An understanding of the in- vestment cycle is pivotal to the explanation 005 of overall cyclical behavior in developing countries. o Low Middle High income High inoome A similar picture emerges if one examines a income income non-OECD OECD different measure of the cyclical component of Note lnvestnienr volatility is defined as the srandard investment, namely the percentage deviation deviation of the deviation from (HP filtered) trend from trend.5 Figure 1.18 displays the mean Source World Bank staff estimates and standard deviation of that measure 24 T HE IN T ER NAT IO NA L EC ONO MY AND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING CO UN TR I ES just 0.04 percent, but it would raise Senegal's investment by 11.5 percent. The effects on Figure 1.19 Abetter investment climate the two economies of such a decision would reduces volatility of investment cycles be disproportionate. Similarly, idiosyncratic (standard deviation of cyclical component of investment) shocks-economic, weather-related, or the 0 4 reflection of civil strife-have a relatively large Regulation effect on smaller countries. Low levels of de- 03 velopment and small size will tend to imply i . " ar.z;Z less diversification in the output and export 02 mix but stronger dependence on commodity prices, so that poor countries' terms of trade 0 1 will tend to be more volatile than those of OECD countries. ist quarOle 2nd quartile 3rd quartile 4th quarbile Governance Improvements in the investment climate Bad > Good can reduce volatility Source World Bank staff estimates using governance The qualityof the invstment climte, exten- indicators developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and The quality of the investment climate, exten- Zoido-Lobar6n (2000) sively discussed in the following chapters of _ this report, appears to be highly correlated with investment volatility. If one examines the investment climate, several candidates are available to proxy for this environment, all of Figure 1.20 Impact of policy climate on which correlate highly with one another. Fig- investment volatility after correcting for ure 1.19 is based on the quality of governance income remains strong indicators compiled by Ka ufmann, Kraay, (standard deviation of cyclical component of investment) and Zoido-Lobat6n (2002), which have the 0 25 advantage of comprehensiveness. Six sub- 0 20- indexes attempt to capture various dimensions _ of policy and institutional quality. An un- weighted average of all six is identified in 0 10- the figure as "All." Meanwhile, two of the 0o05 - subcomponents seem especially pertinent to * * h measuring the investment climate: "regulatory oo2nd 3rd 4th burden," which reflects the incidence of market quartile quartile quartile quartile friendly policies, and "rule of law," which mea- Governance sures respect for society's rules. "Regulation" Bad o Good consists of the first of these, while "Regulation Sozurce World Bank staffestimates using governance and Law" is an average of the two. All three indicators developed by Kaufmann, Kraay, and indexes show a similar pattern of declining Zoido-Lobat6n (2000) volatility as the policy environment improves, suggesting the finding is robust. One concern about the evidence presented The independent effect of governance on in figure 1.19 is that all three indexes correlate volatility can be shown in a different way. very highly with income.7 However, in regres- Figure 1.20 repeats the analysis, but it corrects sions that explain volatility with both income for the possible influence of income by first re- and governance as explanatory variables, the gressing the governance index on income and coefficient for governance tends to be more then examining the relationship between the significant than is the coefficient for income. volatility of investment cycles and the residuals 25 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 from this regression (that is, in relation to that -but capital flows tend to trigger part of the governance indicator that is not domestic cycles in middle-income correlated with income). Investment volatil- countries ity continues to fall with a better investment Both "push" and "pull" factors are respon- climate. sible for the procyclical nature of capital inflows. In a downturn, demand for invest- International net capital inflows are pro- ment financing is reduced as firms postpone cyclical, both in developing and high- investment plans and reduce capital stocks income countries- (the pull factor). At the same time, financial Because investment cycles are more pro- investors look for less risky or risk-free invest- nounced than output cycles, investment as a ments and show little appetite to invest in share of GDP tends to rise during a boom and countries and sectors that suffer from declin- to decline during a downturn. For countries at ing growth and profit rates (the push factor). all income levels, financing of the increase in For developing countries, the push factors the investment ratio during a boom comes have often been emphasized as a major chal- from both domestic and foreign sources. Dur- lenge. Sharp increases in external finance fre- ing an upturn, domestic savings rates normally quently preceded severe crises (such as in build, while current accounts deteriorate Mexico, East Asia, and Turkey), which were (table 1.6). In other words, foreign investors triggered by sudden reversals of these flows. turn away during downturns, while domestic The dynamics of net capital inflows and the consumers reduce their savings and increase changes of official reserves over the cycle do their consumption as a share of income. indeed indicate that the push factor is more Clearly, procyclical capital flows do not pre- important for middle-income countries, while vent consumers from absorbing shocks by the pull factor dominates in high-income smoothing consumption over time (box 1.4). countries. Net foreign capital inflows actually lead the domestic investmenit cycle in middle- income countries, while they lag the cycle in Table 1.6 Upturns can be financed abroad high-income countries. For example, one-year- and domestically lagged capital inflows are correlated with in- Coreeiaulon of cyciicai High | vestment by 0.27 in middle-income countries, mwstvmentcomponenis Low. Middlc inconic. compared with a correlation of only 0.08 for with changes mn income income OEC , high-income countries. In middle-income Current account countries, one-year-lagged capital nflows are (as % of GDP) -021 -0 39 -0.43 ias strongly correlated with the domestic m- Domestic savings a (as % of GDP) 0.16 0 16 0.45 vestment cycle as they are with contempora- neous capital inflows (table 1.7). In high- Note The table shows unweighted averages of correlation coefficients of variables in individual countries income countries, a one-year lead in capital Source World Bank inflows is, by contrast, as strongly correlated Table 1.7 Capital inflows lead investment in middle-income countries: correlation between investment ratios and (past or future) capital flows 2-year lag I.ycar lag No lag or lcad 1-year Iead 2-scar lead Net capital inflows Low income -0.09 009 021 007 -001 Middle income 0.13 0.27 035 0 10 -0 11 High income (OECD) -0 20 0.08 0 32 0 35 0.25 Source World Bank staff estimates. 26 T HE IN T ER NAT IO NA L EC ONO MY AND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING CO UN TR I ES lBox 1.4 Consumption in low- and middle-income countries is smoothed over the business cycle n all country groupings, the savings rate is posi- Relative and increasing vulnerability of ltively (or the consumption rate is negatively) corre- low-, middle-, and high-income countries to lated with GDP growth in the short run (see box terms-of-trade shocks figure). The correlation is relatively weak for developing countries, but that weakness is mainly 1973-80 1981-90 1991-2000 because GDP is an inaccurate measure of income in Low income 2.1 2 2 2.8 the presence of terms-of-trade shocks. Real growth MAddle income 1 9 1.8 2.2 of gross national income (GNI), which includes High incom2e 1 15 (non-OECD) 2.8 I terms-of-trade gains and losses, is much more High Income volatile than growth of real GDP in developing (OECD) 1.4 1.3 1 3 countries. In industrial, high-income countries, the terms of trade have a much smaller effect (see box deviation of GDP growth/ table). The correlation between the savings rate and Source: World Bank data. real growth of GNI is decisively more similar across countries. The strong evidence of consumption smoothing in low- and middle-income countries is remarkable, ing fluctuations in income are less favorable than in because the conditions in such countries for absorb- high-income countries. First, domestic credit markets tend to function less smoothly, and access to interna- tional capital markets is more difficult than in high- income countries. Second, as far as fluctuations in Consumption smoothing is strongest in income are caused by terms-of-trade shocks, the high-income countries smoothing of consumption over time is less attractive (correlation of change in average propensily to consume than in the case of volume shocks, which prevail in Iand GDP growthi) andIGDP growth) high-income countries. If, for example, import prices Low Middle Hgh income High income fall, the decline in price amounts to a rise in income, income mnoome non-OECD OECD 0 1 1 1 _ _ J which could trigger an increase in the savings rate. However, a temporary price fall implies a future -o1 price rise, making future spending of current savings -O 2 less attractive. In the case of a temporary rise in the volume of income, it is more appealing to save now -0 3 and spend later, when income is back at a lower level, | -0 4 T _ _ _ v )Despite these impediments, developing countries' -0 5 consumption is being smoothed over the business | -0 6 Income growth _ GP growth cycle, providing relief for consumers and supporting domestic financing of procyclical investment ratios. Sourcc VWorld Bank staff eshiinares Soturce World Bank staff. with the domestic investment cycle as with official reserves. Some of the foreign capital contemporaneous capital inflows. inflow that precedes a domestic investment The picture of capital inflows being a push boom in middle-income countries is temporar- factor for middle-income countries is strength- ily accumulated as foreign reserves, while cap- ened when one considers the behavior of ital outflows that precede a domestic bust are 27 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 temporarily absorbed by reductions in official significant reduction of poverty. Thus, the mil- foreign exchange reserves. lennium development goal of halving poverty In low-income countries, capital inflows by 2015 could be reached on a global level, are also procyclical, but the correlation with although growth will be insufficient to achieve the domestic cycle is less significant. The poverty targets in all regions. At the same weaker correlation reflects the specific charac- time, financial imbalances and volatility in ter of these flows-official aid and FDI are less international capital flows continue to jeopar- cyclical-and also the dependence of those dize uninterrupted growth. Vulnerable coun- countries on commodity prices. Part of the fi- tries will benefit from further debt reduction nancing for investment booms comes not from in their pursuit of sustained high growth. foreign borrowing, but from increased export The acceleration of growth in developing revenues as a result of terms-of-trade gains. countries is expected to coincide with in- Similarly, investment busts are not necessarily creases in investment ratios. Saving rates are driven by a reversal of capital flows, but they also expected to increase, driven particularly can originate from terms-of-trade losses. by a declining proportion of youths and by On the basis of these relationships, it ap- the need for adults to save for retirement. Op- pears that cycles are still a prominent feature posite movements are expected in industrial of macroeconomic developments, which is countries, wvhere aging is bound to reduce even more important in developing countries savings rates and where a sharp decline in than in industrial countries, and cycles were population growth will suppress investment more pronounced during the 1990s than dur- ratios. ing earlier decades. Investment swings are The long-term forecast suggests that, on bal- financed both domestically and abroad, which ance, net inward capital flows toward develop- makes current account deficits and capital ing countries could well decline, though gross inflows strongly procyclical. A major differ- flows will continue to play an important role in ence between developing countries and high- enhancing growth potential. These changes in income countries is that middle-income global savings and investment behavior raise countries are more exposed to independent questions about the critical role of financial reversals in capital flows, while capital flows integration and the need for improvements in are more accommodating in high-income international financial intermediation. countries, and the cyclical dynamics in low- income countries are to a significant extent Long-run per capita growth is expected influenced by terms-of-trade shocks and to accelerate- idiosyncratic disturbances. Developing-country growth, on a per capita basis, is projected to more than double during the 10-year period from 2005 to 2015 when Growth and poverty to 2015: compared with the performance of the 1990s coming changes in savings and (table 1.8). This projection reflects substan- investment patterns tially improved growth prospects for Europe A fter an impressive wave of market re- and Central Asia-leaving behind sharp con- Aforms and increased openness in develop- tractions that characterized the transition to ing countries during the 1990s-both of market economies during the 1990s-and for which prompted acceleration of technological Sub-Saharan Africa. For Africa, the scenario is progress and brought about a more stable predicated as a continuation of broad trends macroeconomic environment-long-term eco- toward better governance and economic poli- nomic growth prospects for developing coun- cies, of progress toward resolving conflicts and tries are relatively optimistic. If the projections diversification away from agriculture, and of come to pass, growth patterns could lead to a export dependence on primary commodities. 28 TIf E I N T E R N A T I O N A L E C O N O M Y A N D P R O S P E C T S F O R D E V I 1 O P I N G C O U N T R I E S Table 1.8 Long-term prospects are projected to be stronger for most regions (real CDI' per capita, annuitial average percentiage change) Forecast sceniario Medium terni Long term 19805 19905 2001-05 2006-is World total 1.3 1.2 1.1 2.1 High-income countrics 2.5 1.8 1.5 2.4 OECD 2.5 1.8 1.5 2.4 United States 2.2 2.2 1.6 2.4 Japan 3.5 1.2 0.4 2.0 European Uttion 2.1 1.7 1.9 2.4 Non-OECI) counlitries 3.3 3.6 1.7 3.3 Developing countries 0.7 1.6 2.4 3.5 East Asia anid the Ilacific 5.6 6.4 5.1 5.4 Europe anid Cet,tral Asiai 0.7 -1.9 3.3 3.4 lIatini America anld the Caribbeani -0.9 1.6 0.3 2.6 ,M0iddle East anid North Africa -0.6 1.0 1.3 1.3 South Asia 3.4 3.3 3.5 4.0 Sub-Saharan Africa -1.2 -0.4 0.8 1.6 Note: Aggregationis are inovinig averages, reweighted annuially after calcUlations of growth in constant prices. Sotirce: World Bank. At the same time, a lack of humani capital, development goal of halving extreme poverty poor infrastructure, and the AIDS epidemic by 2015 from the 1990 poverty level should be remaini pressing problems. achieved on a global level, though with wide Per capita growth in Latin America is regional disparities. The revised poverty projec- expected to accelerate by I percentage point tions indicate a poverty rate of some 13.3 per- under this scenario, but as a result of slowing cent in 2015 compared with 29.6 percent in population growth, the acceleration of real :1990. The actual number of poor would GDP growth is small. Latin American coun- decline to around 809 million from 1.3 billion tries are expected to have benefited from in 1990 and 1.1 billion in 1999. Asia should reform efforts durinig recent years and from readily achieve the target, but the MENA sustained improvemiielits in macroeconomic and SSA regions will make little progress in stability. The East Asia and Pacific Region imiproving poverty incidence (table 1.9). should witness a declininig per capita growth Though the central message remains the rate from 6.4 percent in the 1990s to 5.4 per- same, the long-term outlook reflects rather cent in the longer term, as economies mature significant changes from last year's forecasts. and as options for rapid catchinig up become These changes are a combination of three less abundant. Per capita growth in the rest of factors: the world, including South Asia, the Middle East and North Africa, and highi-income couni- * The economic projections reflect recent trics, is projected to accelerate moderately. trends and a downgrading of the medium- term forecast, as detailed earlier in the -leading toward significant poverty chapter, page 5. The long-term forecast reduction has remainied relatively unchanged, but As projected in previous Global Econotnic lower growth-actual and forecast- Prospects (GEP), achieving the millennilum between 2000 and 2005 has slightly 29 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 worsened the poverty forecast, all else (that is, for the same growth rate, the being equal. rate of poverty reduction has declined). * New surveys and methodology have sig- nificantly altered the 1999 estimate of The reader should bear in mind that these poverty incidenice. For developing coun- numbers are sensitive to the poverty line cho- tries, this change has led to a 1.6 percent sen and underlying assumptions and data (see rise in the estimate of the number of box 1.5). poor living on less than $1 per day. The relation between growth and poverty However, the revisions are not uniform may not have changed in a fundamental way, across regions. There is a significant rise but the change may be a consequence of past in East Asia and in Europe and Central trends at a more disaggregated level. Recent Asia, while the estimated number of studies9 of poverty trends in India indicate poor has dropped in Latin America.8 that poverty has been successfully reduced in * The thlird factor is the change in the a number of states in which growth rates are relation between economic growtlh and high and in which the responsiveness of poverty reduction. This rclation has been povcrty reduction to growth is likcwise highcr. re-estimated using the new survey data. Moreover, the evidence suggests that these re- Overall, the relationship has weakened gions had significantly better initial conditions Table 1.9 Large poverty reductions in EAP and SAR partially offset by poverty increases in SSA Number of people livng on less than 51 per day (millions) CEI' 2002 GEP 2003 Region 1990 1999 2015 1990 1999 2015 East Asia and Pacific 452 260 59 486 279 80 | Excludinig Chinia 92 46 6 110 57 7 Europe and Central Asia 7 17 4 6 24 7 Latin America anld the Caribbean 74 77 60 48 57 47 Middle East and North Africa 6 7 6 5 6 S South Asia 495 490 279 506 488 264 Stib-Saharan Africa 242 300 345 241 315 404 Total 1,276 1,151 753 1,292 1,169 809 Excluding China 916 937 700 917 945 735 SI pcr dav hcadcount indcx (percent) GEP 2002 GEP 2003 Region 1990 1999 2015 1990 19')9 2015 East Asia and Pacific 27.6 14 2 2 8 30.5 15 6 3 9 E\cludingChina 185 79 09 242 106 1 1 Europe and Central Asia 1 6 3 6 0 8 1 4 51 1 4 Latin America atid the Caribbcats 168 151 97 11.0 I I1 75 Middle East and North AfriLa 2 4 2 3 I S 2 1 2 2 2 1 South Asia 44 0 36 9 16 7 45 0 36 6 15 7 Sub-Saharan Africa 47 7 467 39 3 47.4 49 0 46 0 Total 29 0 22 7 12 3 29 6 23 2 13 3 E\cluding Chinia 28 1 24 5 14 8 28.5 25 0 15 7 (continued oni page 31) 30 I 11 L I N I E R N A T I O N A l E C O N OM Y A N D P R OS P 1: C I S F O R D E V E L OP I N G C O U N T R I E S Table 1.9 (continued) Numbe,r Of p-ople Iving oi, le,, th-n 52 pCr dai% (milli-ns C'kl 2002 r GEP 2003 Region 1990 1999 lots 1990 1999 2015 Last Asia anid lacific 1,084 849 284 | '1,114 897 339 ExclUding Chinsa 285 236 93 295 269 120 hirope anid Ccntral Asia 44 91 42 31 97 45 Latin Amiicma and the Caribbean 167 168 146 121 132 117 ,Middle East anid North Africa 59 87 65 50 68 62 South Asia 976 1,098 1,098 1,110 1,128 1.139 Sub-Saharan Aftica 388 484 597 I 386 480 618 btoal 2,718 2,777 2,232 2.712 2,802 2,320 lxcltiding Chila 1,919 2,164 2,041 1,892 2,173 2,101 S2 per ciay head-uni midex (per,enit GCLV 2002 CEP 2003 Region 1990( 1999 201 i 199U 1999 21015 Fasr Asia anid P'acific 66 1 46 2 11 5 697 50 i 166 Excltiduig China 57 3 40 4 13 3 61.9 50 2 18 4 Eulropc and Central Asia 9 6 19 3 8 7 6 8 20 3 9 3 Latin America and the Caribbean 38 1 33 1 23 4 27 6 26 0 18 9 Minddle East and North Africa 24 8 29 9 167 210 23 3 16 0 South Asia 86 8 82 6 655 89 8 84 S 6S.0 SLub-SahAran Africa 76 4 75 3 68 0 76 0 74.7 70 4 Total 61 7 54 7 363 62 1 55 6 38 1 Excluding Chinia 58 8 56 5 41 0 58 7 57 .5 44 7 Noie The GEP 2002 figures IClUde the RepuiblI of Kiirea, which has been relaLssified ieito the high-incoiine gtruLp Soiti cc World Baiik stati estirrlit Box 1.5 Is the World Bank overestimating global poverty? A recent study (Bhalla 2002) conclLIdCs that the line, his use of seconidary data sources rather than A World Bank has overestimatecl the number of primary surveys, and consumption adjtistnlents. poor in developing countries, and that the miLlen- These differences highlight the complexity in count- nium devctopment goal ot halving extrcme poverty ing the number of poor and are described here. A by 2015 (from its 1990 level) was already achieved more cotnplete critique of the Bhalla study can be In 2000. The study estimates that the percentage found in a separate paper (Ravallion 2002). of poor in developmig countries in 2000 was only The r World Bank has chosen to use $1 per day 13.1 percent and that the World Bank's estimate is and $2 per day poverty lines for global estinations, 10 percentage points higher (see table 1.9). Three roughly spanning the ranige of national poverty lines differences between the Bhalla estimates and the in developinig countries. Bhalla uses $1.50 per day. World Bank's explain Bhalla's different conclusion. Because the cost of purchasing 2,200 calories differs Thesc differences Hiclude the choice of the poverty from country to country, each country estimates its 31 G L O B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Box IL o5 (continuted) own national poverty line. This approach also re- countries-and the calculations are properly flects the fact that the nature of poverty varies signif- weighted to reflect survey design and differences in icantly across and within countries. Moreover, household size. Consumption is deemed to be the poverty has many dimensions: inadequate consump- preferred measure to income, but income is used tion of essential commodities. as well as low life ex- when consumption is not available. pectancy, high child mortality, and low school enroll- Finally, Bhalla's study makes consumption ment rates, among other attributes related to the adjustments, which may not be warranted and could quality of life. Poverty is also a r elative and sublec- lead to a biased poverty estimiate. The headcount tive concept. What is deemed a necessity in some index (that is, the percentage of the population living countries (for example, indoor plumbing in rich at or below the poverty line) is calculated using an countries) may be a luxury in others. In Latin Amer- estimate of the per capita consumption level relative ica, the regional estimate for the percentagc of peo- to the poverty line. There can be significant discrep- ple living in extreme poverty is 17.8 percent in 1998 ancies between the survey-based mean consumption (VWodon and others 20021, compared with 11 I per- and the mean consumption as measured by the na- cent in 1999 usmig the Sl per day poverty line. The tional accounts. Part of this discrepancy is explained foIrImner is based oni national poverty lines and is from by the way consumption is estimated in the national a regional perspective. This higher number-ar- accounts (which typically includes consumption of guably a more accurate reftection of the incidence of non-household private agents such as nonprofit poverty from a social point of view-is more rele- organizations). Other discrepancies can arise from vant in determining policies for reducing poverty. measurement error (for example, misreporting of i However, for purposes of global comparisons, the consumption in surveys). Adjustments for these dis- World Bank has tried to select a level of real con- crepancies can lead to different estimates of poverty. sumption that best measures the same level of con- If, for example, the misreporting is biased toward sumption across countries so it can make aggregate high incomes-that is, if only rich households under- judgments independent of where the poor live. report consumption in the surveys-and if an tup- Unlike the Bhalla study-which relics on aggre- ward adjustment is applied to all households (includ- gate secondary data sources-the World Bank's ing the poorest), then the number of poor will clearly | poverty estimates rely exclusively on primary data be underestimated (see Ravallion 2002). The World from comprehensive household surveys. Since the Bank's poverty estimates rely on the survey-based 1980s, the World Bank and developing-country gov- consumption levels. i ernments have been actively involved in undertaking Transparency in the methodology and data used national household surveys to get an accurate picture to assess the level of poverty is critical in this debate of the distribution of consumption across individo- regarding how to count the number of poor The als. To date, more than 300 comprehensive surveys ability of different researchers to easily assess and have been collated and used to estimate the number compare results will lead to improved estimates and of poor. Currently, the surveys cover more than to a better understanding ot the nature of poverty 90 countries, with surveys available for various years and policies that accelerate poverty reduction for most counties. The surveys used all have national coverage They include consumption from own- production-a key feattire in many developing Source: World Bank staff. than did states with lower growth rates. This initial conditions in the laggard states and evidence implies that progress in the future should not rely exclusively on raising the na- will be harder to achieve with the same na- tional growth rate. tional growth rate. Poverty-reducing policies The number of poor in last year's report will, therefore, have to focus on raising the was projected to be 753 million in 2015, 32 T H E IN T E RN Al 1IO NA L EC oNO MY A N D P R O S P E C r S F O R D E V 1: L 0 P I N G C O U N F R I E S or a headcount rate of 12.3 percent. The cur- Population growth will ease rent forecast shows the number of poor will in all regions- decline to only 809 million by 2015, or a In virtually all countries, growtth of the headcount rate of 13.3 percent This change working-age population is slated to decline represents a 7.4 percent increase when com- over the next 15-year period, thereby affect- pared with last year's figure. The percentagc ing labor supply and thus contributing Icss to increase can be decomposed into two factors. GDP growth in the long run (figure 1.21). The higher initial level of the number of poor High-income countries and those in ELirope in 1999 would lcad to an increase of 2.3 per- and Central Asia are likely to see an absolute cent in the 2015 forecast, all else being equal. drop in the working-age population by 2015. The remaining 5.1 percent of the increase In Developing regions will see a slower pace of the forecast is attributed to a weakening of the decline, although East Asia is expected to see relation between growth and poverty. its growth rate halved to 0.7 perccnt per year by the end of the period.10 A slower growth Population, savings, and investment rate in the labor force means that achieving are factors underlying the long-term the same ratc of per capita growth will requirc forecast an acceleration of investniciit, a highcr level of Some developing regions will need to see a productivity, or a combination of both. reversal in performance of underlying growth factors-particularly in productivity and in -but technological progress should savings and investment-from the last decade. accelerate That reversal should show either changes to The role of total factor productivity (TFP) policies or persistence with ongoing reforms. growth in determininiig growth ratcs has bcen Assessing the factors underlying the long- the subject of significant research over the past term forecast-population and labor supply, decade (see box 1 6), but there is a growing technological progress, and savings and consensus that technological advances and investment-will elucidate some of the under- efficiency improvements are pivotal determi- lying dynamics in the long-term growth fore- nants of growth patterns. If one looks for- cast and its policy implications. ward, many countries are expected to reap the Figure 1.21 Growth of working-age population decelerates (annual growth of population for ages 15 to 65) 40 35 0 XMNA 30 ____________SSA__SAS_ 25 LAC 20 1 0 \ ~~~~EAP= 10 05 ', EGA 0 0 1 I I I I I I I I 1 1 I -05 HIY -1 0 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Note HIY refers to high-income counitries, SSA refers to Sub-Saharan Africa, EAP refers to East Asia and lPacific, SAS refers to South Asia, ECA refers to Eastern Furope and Central Asia, MNA refers to Middle East and North Africa, LAC refers to Latin Amiierica and the Caribbean Source World Baitk staff demographic projectiois 33 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Box 1.6 Technological progress is an important determinant of growth A growing conscnsus in the economic literature is sign for developing countries, because constraints on L that TFP accounts for the bulk of cross-country domestic resources and access to external financing differences in the level of income and the rate of severely limit a country's ability to raise growth rates GD1' growth (Easterly and Levine 2001).11 Whether by increasing the volume or imnproving the quality TFP or capital and labor accounted for the bulk of of physical and human capital. To the extent that income differences among countries has been an differences In TFP growth will reflect differences in issue of dispute since seminal articles by Denison technology, then developing countries (whicih are (1972) and Jorgenson and Griliches (1967, 1972). well below the technological frontier) can potentially The debate sharpened in the 1990s when a number achieve high "catch-up" rates of growth hy import- of comparative growth studies found that the success ing technology. Parente and Prescott (1994) see the of the East Asian Tigers was driven mostly by in- main source of cross-country productivity differences creases In capital and labor rather than by increases as stemminlg from policy-induced barriers to adopt- in TFP (Young 1992, 1995; Collins and Bosworth ing advanced technology. TFP growth also reflects 1996). Because capital is subject to diminishing re- other aspects of economic efficiency that are turnis, such studies implied that the highi rates of amenable to change through improving policies. For growth achieved in East Asia were not sustainable example, policies that increase competition may raise (Krugman 1994). TFP by improving the allocation of labor and capital More recently, the weight of evidence appears and by increasing the ability of the economy to re- to be moving toward the conclusion that TFP is the spond to changes In the economic environment main driver of growth. The East Asian studies have (Easterly and Levine 2001, Solow 2001; Hulten been criticized for not accounting for the role that 2000). technological progress plays in encouraging greater Critiques of using this accounting approach capital accunmulation (Hulten 2000; Barro and Sala-i- inclide the fact that it typically relies on various Martin 1992).12 Nelson and Pack (1999) emplhasize restrictive assumptions (for example, constanit that learning, technology absorption, and forceful en- returns to scale and competitive markets) that may trepreneurship were critical to the success of large in- not hold in reality (although models that incorpor-ate vestments in physical and human capital. Klenow and Rodriquez-Clare (1997) estimate that TFP made an important contribution to growth in all of the East TFP is a major contributor to growth Asian "mniacle" economies, excepr Singapore. East- (percent) erly and Levine (2001) summarize studies that show 60 TFP accounts for more than 40 percent of output 50 growth in most of the industrial countries, 30 percent 40 or more in most Latin American countries, and a wide range (from -5 percent to 30 percent) in East 30 20-- Asia (box figure). Some writers attempt to refine esti- mates of the contribution of TFP to growth by imcor- 10 porating some measuremenit of the quality of in- 0 __ puts-for example, adjusting data on labor input for -10 the degree of education or training (see Easterly and rj q, CO o Z Levine 2001 and Parente and Prescott 2000 for recent F V 4 b. contributions). In general, efforts have not been suc- b cessful In greatly reducing the amount of growth or ,° income differences that are accounited for by TFP. The evidence that growth in TFP is the maini Source Easterly anid Levinie (2001) driver of economic growth is essentially an optimistic 34 T ` E I N I E R N A T I O N A L E C O N O M1 Y A N D P R O S P E C T S F O R D E V E L OP I N G C O U N T R I E S Box 1.6 'continued) market Imperfections also confront clifficult econo- covered. Finally, growtlh accounting generally does metric prolblems; see Brock and Durlauf 2001). not reflect eithel improvements in the quality of Often, key parameters, such as the share of capital in goods or the introductioni of new products, which output, are assumed to be based on linited empirical are also Important for welfare (Hulten 2000). Those work (Senhadii 2000). Solow (2001) notes that the criticisms underscore the substantial methodological growtlh-accounting framework assumes that the and measurement difficulties involved in quantify- economy is moving along the potential output fron- ing the contiibution of inpuits and productivity to tier. In developing countries, the volatility of the growth rates. Nevertheless, as Hulten (2000) stresses, business cycle means that actual output may be con- this approach has provided a simple and internally siderably different from potential at any point in consistenit intelleCtual framework that has been used time. Thus, growth-accounting estimates using time to gain vital insights iito the process of economic series data may be biased by differences between growth. potential and actual output levels at the beginning and end points, even if a considerable time period is Source: Woild Bank ntr.ff changes in its servicc sectors, which will have Figure 1.22 Productivity has not been long-term payoffs. Both Europe and Japan, the dominant source of growth in although lagging somewhat behind the United regions States, have the opportumity to reap gains from (average percent per annum 1990-2000) improved use of information technologies. 8 The East Asia region has been the leader Productivity among developilg regions in terms of acceler- 6 _ \ ating productivity over the past two decades 4 , It has built on compositional shifts (from Capi al agriculture to mallufacturing and services), o ra_ r _ iiii-r Figure 1.23 Productivity is expected to -2 be more significant in the longer term (average percent per annum 2005-15) -4 HIY EAP ECA LAC MNA SAS SSA 8 Productivily HIY = high-inconie coitintriesi6 Souerce Wo Id taik staff estimates Capital 4 benefit of reforms undertaken during the past 2 10 years. These benefits will likely show up as an acceleration of technological progress (fig- Labor ures 1.22 and 1.23). Among industrial coun- -2 tries, those countries in Europe will see accel- -4 erating benefits from the single currency plus HIY EAP ECA LAC MNA SAS SSA greater capital and labor mobility. Japan, i-lY = high-iicome cotiiitries though still burdened with significant prob- Soure VWorld Bank staff stimates lems in its financial sector, is witnessilg 35 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 educational improvements, and productivity- Figures 1.22 and 1.23 summarize the de- enhancing policies (for example, increasing composition of the various sources of GDP openness). The region will continue to benefit growth into three broad components: the from good policies and compositional shifts. labor supply, capital accumulation and pro- After all, the largest country in the region, ductivity for the historical period 1990-2000, China, still has more than 60 percent of its and the long-term projection for 2005-15. work force in agriculture. However, as the gap The decomposition profiles projected for the with technologically more advanced countries period 2005-15 are rather similar to the closes, the opportunities for extreme advances 1990-2000 period, with the significant excep- in productivity diminish. tion of the contribution from technological Europe and Central Asia is benefiting from progress. As argued on page 38, we have pro- the substanitial reforms of the 1990s, accom- jected that most regions will see an accelera- panied by large FDI flows. Moreover, many of tion of technological progress, which will the accession countries will accelerate the re- drive the improvements in GDP growth. That form process in preparation for joining the EU progress will trigger further capital accumula- early in the forecast period. tion to accommodate and to further enhance In Latin America, progress has been visible growth prospects-hence the need for pro- regionwide. As has been positively demon- viding an enabling investment environment. strated by Chile and Mexico, openness and Capital accumulation implies an investment stability are key elements in providing sustaiin- profile-discussed in more detail below- able growth. A recent study of Latin American linked, of course, to behavioral assumptions growth over the past three decades concludes regarding savings during the coming decade. that structural reforms and stabilization poli- cies accounted for a large contributioni to the Convergence of investment ratios is likely overall acceleration in the rate of growth in to continue the 1990s compared with the "lost decade" of After a distinct divergence of investment ratios the 1980s.13 These trends are expected to con- across regions during the past decades, some tinue in the next decade, with increasing in- convergence is expected during coming vestments in infrastructure and education and decades, though disparities will remain signifi- with greater openness to trade underpinning cant. Investment rates in the developing East solid productivity growth. The key downside Asia and the Pacific region gradually increased risk includes the vulnerability of the region to from 15 percent of GDP during the 1960s to external shocks, particularly given its sizable almost 30 percent during the 1980s (fig- external debt burden, and the effects that this ure l.24a). This increase coincided with rapid debt could have on the stability of the domes- growth of the economies in the region, major tic financial sector. sectoral shifts as a result of diversification, Sub-Saharan Africa has benefited from sim- and regional and global integration, which all ilar policy reforms and stabilization. FDI has required expansion or replacement of capital been increasing, and the resolution of some stocks. During the first half of the 1990s, the long-term civil conflicts should provide a average investment rate jumped further to more enabling environment for sustained 35 percent, of which a substantial part was growth. South Asia and the Middle East and used for real estate development when foreign North Africa regions have maintained some of capital streamed in. In 1997, investors realized the highest trade barriers in the world. These that their collective behavior was based on barriers will slowly be removed under the im- overly optimistic expectations. The resulting petus of multilateral and regional trade agree- financial crisis sharply lowered investment ments, with ensuing efficiency gains. rates back to levels near 25 percent. 36 T HE I NT E RN AT IO NA L EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING C O U N T R I E S The investment rate in South Asia was ex- changes and privatization programs. One rea- tremely low until the mid-1970s, but then it soIn for the lack of a strong rebound in invest- started to rise. To a large extent, that rise is a meint was the continued low domestic savings reflection of the green revolution and industri- rate In both regions (figure 1 24b). Even with alization programs in India. Although not as low investment rates, the current account strong by far as in East Asia, the average rate showed large deficits during the 1 990s. continued to increase during the 1980s and Future investmiient trends will be influenced 1990s, and the current level is now close to by expected GDP growth, by real domestic OECD levels of around 22-23 percent. That interest rates, and by expected domestic rates level is well above rates in Latin America and of return to capital compared with the average Sub-Saharan Africa. global rate of return. If one assumes a stable Structural developments in the latter two risk environment, the last effect should tend regions (LAC and SSA) were quite different to benefit developing countries, where rates from the Asian experience. A gradual rise in of return are higher than In rich counties. investment rates during the 1970s, whiclh was Table 1.10 summarizes the changes in invest- partly financed abroad, suddenly turned into mcnt behavior betwccn the averagc of the a sharp decline when the debt crisis hit In the 1997-2001 period and the final year (2015) early I 980s. Investment rates dropped around of the basehine scenario. On average, the high- 5 percentage points. Macroeconomic imbal- income countries will see a drop in the invest- ances and hyperinflation In Latin America, as ment rate of about 2.9 percentage points (rel- well as sharp terms-of-trade losses in Africa, ative to GDP). This figure is derived largely led to extremely low growth during the 1980s. from lower projected GDP growvth rates and In this environment, investment rates contin- thus changes in the optimal capital to output tied to fluctuate around historical lows. Dur- ratio. The average investment rate in develop- ing the 1990s, investment rates showed only ing countries increases sligltly by 0.2 percent- a slight recovcry, although the composition age points, with higher investment rates in shifted significantly away from public to pri- many regions offset by lower investment in vate investmenit, following major structural East Asia. The latter region is still suffering Figure 1.24 Major structural shifts in investment and savings behavior have occurred a Investment-to-GDP ratio b. Savings-to-GDP ratio (current dollar-weighted average) (current dollar-weighted average) 35 35 1980s 30 1 - 30 197\SO /1990s 1970s 1980s 25 25 1960s 1960s190 20 _ 20 15 15 510 100 II South Labn Sub-Saharan East Asia South Latin Sub-Saharan East Asia Asia Amenca and Atrica and Pacitic Asia America and Africa and Pacitic the Caribbean the Caribbean Souirce World Batik staff estrmites 37 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table 1.10 Savings fall in high-income countries, but increase in most other regions (as a percentage of CDP) 1997-2001 2015 Capital Capital Savings Investment nflows Savngs Investment inflowsv (S) (I) (KA) (S) (I) (KA) Total 22.4 22.5 0 1 20.5 20.5 0.0 High income 22 0 21 9 -0.1 18.6 19.0 0.4 Low and middle income 24 2 24 7 0 5 26 0 24.9 -1.1 European Union 208 204 -04 17.5 174 -0.1 Japan 29 8 27 5 -2 2 26 0 25.4 -0 6 United States 17 5 19 5 2.0 14.5 16.3 1 9 Rest of high income 30 8 26 1 -4.7 24 9 23 2 -1.7 East Asia and Pacific 36.9 33 9 -3.0 35 0 29.3 -5.8 South Asia 21.3 22.2 0 9 23 7 23.5 -0.2 Middle East and North Africa 26.2 21 4 -4 8 23.1 22.2 -0.9 Sub-Saharan Africa 13.9 17 6 3.7 19 0 20 1 1 1 Europe and Central Asia 21 9 22 6 0 7 22 0 271 51. Latin America and the Caribbean 17.9 21.7 3.7 20 5 20.6 0.0 Note The columils (S), (I), and (KA) represent, respectively, the nationial saving rate, the national investmenit rate, and the capital account, all as a share of GDP The values for 2015 are simulated values from the global general equilibrium model (maintained by the Development Economics Prospects Group) The values for the 1997-2001 period represent the average observed values from the World Bank's statistical databases For thie high-income countries, these values are the 1997-99 or 1997-2000 averages, depending on data availability For the totals, the averages cover only the years 1997-99 Source. World Bank model simulations from past overinvestment, particularly in lennium. Rich countries are seeing an exten- some sectors, and will adjust its investment sion of life spans and a rapid decline in needs to a slight deceleration in growth. Most birthrates, leading to a sharply aging popula- of the other developing regions will see accel- tion. Developing countries are witnessing a eration in investment in anticipation of higher relatively sharp drop in the percentage of growth. Investment in those regions will also youths as well as modest increases in the provide relatively higher returns than in the number of elderly. Recent economic evidence more mature economies. suggests that these trends could have sigmfi- Future changes in investment rates do not cant implications on national saving rates- necessarily lead to corresponding changes in lowering them in rich countries because of current accounts. Despite capital mobility, aging, but raising them in developing coun- investment rates tend not to correlate with tries as workers save for future retirement. current account deficits in the long run, the Lower birthrates also lead to a reduction in so-called Feldstein-Horioka puzzle (1980). resource demand for the young. Also in the coming 15-year period, the savings The demographic transition with respect to rate is expected to increase in those countries the proportion of youths is largely over in the that are anticipated to enjoy an acceleration of high-income countries (figure 1.25). The over- growth, partly because of rapidly changing all average was 27.4 youths per 100 workers14 demographics. in 2000 and is expected to drop to 24.4 by 2015. Developing regions are likely to witness Changing demographics will raise much greater changes. First of all, the propor- savings in developing countries tion of youths is starting from a significantly and will lower savings in industrial higher base, wsth the dependency ratio aver- countries aging 51.0, which is nearly double the high- Global population dynamics are evolving income average. The ratio is expected to drop fairly rapidly at the beginning of the new mil- to 40.7 by 2015, twice the percentage of the 38 T HE IN I ERN ATI ON AL EC ONO MY AN D P R O S P E C I S F O R D E V E L O P I N G C O U N T R I ES Figure 1.25 Youth dependency ratio will Figure 1.26 Elderly dependency ratios fall everywhere except Japan will rise in some regions (number of youths, age 15 and under, per 100 (number of elderly age over 60, per 100 working-age worklng-age population) population) 90 2000 -T 2000 50 80 2 ~~~~~~~~~40 2015 70 2015 60 50 230 200 40 T ------215 20 _20 30 2000 20 1 10 ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 1*~~~~1 0 F77T 1 t I 0 I I RHY = rest of high inLome, TOT = global average, RHY = rest of high riicoime, TOT = global aserage, HIY = high-linctine average, LMY = low- and miiddle- I-IIY high-iiicomie average, L.\Y = lows- aiid miiddlc- inconile dvrrage iiicoine average Note Working-age popllatiotn is defined ,is those people Note \Working-age population is defined as those people betwseen the ages of 15 to 65 hetxveen the ages of 15 to 65 Soutrce World Banik staff Souerce World Batik staff fall expected iD industrial countries. This anti- alone could have major macroecononmic impli- cipated decline is the consequence of two fac- cations for Japan and have conscquences for tors: a boom in births over the past two the rest of the world, because Japan has long decades, leading to a rapid rise in the working- had largc excess savings that have been recy- age population, and, more recently, declining cled abroad. Outside the industrial countries, birthrates, which are caused by a combination the average elderly dependency ratio is not of economic growth and family-planning expected to change significantly. The average programs. was 8.9 in 2000, increasinlg to only 9.6 in The elderly dependency ratio, defined as 2015. number of members of the population who Several recent studies of private savings are older than 65 per 100 workers, is rising in behavior have linked the private savings rate almost every region (figure 1.26). The transi- to a number of different factors: demograph- tion is occurring rapidly in industrial countries ics, income levels and growtlh, interest and in- as the Baby Boom generation ages and as flation rates, and degree of finaicial mterme- life expectancy improves, but there will only diation.16 The results discussed next focus on be modest changes in developing countries only three channels affecting savings: the rate through 2015 because relatively more recent of per capita GDP growth, the youth depen- improvements in health and life expectancy dency ratio, and the elderly dependency ratio. will affect elderly demographics only further Other chaninlels may prove to be equally im- in the future.15 The elderly dependency ratio portant, however, such as improved financial average in 2000 for industrial countries was intermediation and a stable macroeconomic 21.2 per 100 workers. It is expected to rise to environment. Combining these three effects 26.9 by 2015, surpassing the youth depen- suggests that global savings may decline by dency ratio. Japan will witness the most dra- around 1 percentage point over the longer matic iiicrease, from 25 1 to 39.8. This change term, a figure that takes into accounlt a 39 G LO BA L ECO NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 2.7 percentage point decline in high-income investment ratio. Those figures would reflect countries and a 3.7 percentage point rise in no change in overall growth compared with developing countries. the 1990s because declining population With relatively large swings in domestic growth will counteract the acceleration in per savings rates, the scenario suggests a rather capita growth.19 These trends in savings and significant change in net capital flows. In investment rates will require ad]ustments to 1997, the base year of model simulations, relieve the strains on budget and other vari- industrial countries were exporting around ables. Open capital and goods markets would $67 billion in net investment to low- and facilitate the potential strains from demo- middle-income countries, some 1.1 percent of graphic transition. low- and middle-income countries' GDP. East Asia was the only developing region that was Major policy challenges are likely a net exporter of capital in the base year.17 By to emerge 2015, under these savings and investment as- While there is evidence in support of the eco- sumptions, low- and middle-income countries nomic growth projection in this long-run sce- would be significant net exporters (some nario, the degree of uncertainty regarding the 1.1 percent of their GDP), while industrial projections is high. There is recognition that countries would be net importers. Among in- these trends will require good policies, be- dustrial countries, Europe would be in ap- cause many developing countries are still sub- proximate investment-to-savings balance, but ject to major shocks. the United States could continue to be a sig- These scenarios raise important long-term nificant net importer of capital. The United policy issues. First, the changing savings and States would actually see little change in its investment patterns will have consequences capital account surplus from the base year (as for net capital flows. Several developing coun- a share of GDP), though it would experience tries that in past decades have relied on net a reversal from its present high level. Japan's capital inflows will find it harder to do so in capital account deficit would diminish sharply the coming 15 years. Indeed, the recent shift with a rapidly increasing elderly population from debt accumulation to debt reduction in leading to a decrease in savings. 8 many of these countries is likely to herald The actual magnitude of these changes a new long-term trend of further declines in savings and investment rates remains in debt. If the expected increase in private speculative-even though they are grounded in domestic savings is accompanied by further empirically validated economic theory within maturing of domestic credit markets and is a consistent accounting framework-because not thwarted by deterioration of public sav- some of the underlying behavioral relations ings, then debt reduction will not conflict with could change the savings rates, the investment the investment patterns needed to underpin rates, or both to some extent and could have growth. a noticeable effect on the balance (that is, the Underlying large swings in net capital flows capital account). Nevertheless, there is little are even larger movements of gross capital doubt regarding the broad changes in the flows, because FDI expands into growing pattern in these projections. A clear trend markets in developing countries and because emerges of further reduction in developing financial agents in developing countries seek countries' foreign debt. East Asia could con- to diversify their portfolios in rich countries. tinue to show significant surpluses on the cur- These capital movements will require further rent account, while Latin America could con- international financial integration. Because verge toward a balanced current account. The the history of financial integration has not latter would be the result of, and represent a been entirely felicitous-and at times has been rise in, the savings rate and a relatively stable damaging to growth and poverty reduction- 40 T HE IN rE RN A 1IONA L EC ONO MY A ND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING C OU N T R I E S the international community and developing have a lower magnitude because average per capita in- countries have had to search for mechanisms come in Argentina ($12,100 in purchasing power par- to provide for greater stability in integration ity terms in 2001, and $7,750 in 1995 terms) is much Developing countries can further facilitate higher thani the $2 per day level. 9 See, for example Datt and Ravallion (2002) potential growth by improving their invest- 10. The growth rates are weighted by labor value ment climates. A sound policy environment added, which may bias the regional estimates down- will trigger investment flows and, more im- ward if high-wage countries iave slower growth rates portant, will ensure that these flows go into Among other things, this method would affect a world internationially competitive activities. A sound total because industrial couLntries have sigilficantly investment climate in developinig countries higher wages than developing countries. can 11ta FIwcialII TFP is nor the same as technical progress, but instead includes all contributions to growth that are volatile capital inflow. inot captured by data on capital and labor However, the integration of more efficient techinologies into pro- duction can raise the level of TFP Notes 12 Technically, only the fraction of capital accu- 1 Examples of investment-grade borrowing coun- mulation that arises from the underlying propensity to tries are Chile, China, the Republic of Korea, invest at a constant rate of TFP growth should be Malaysia, Mexico, Thailand, and several Central viewed as capital's independenit contribution to output European countries growth Hulten (2000) found that correcting for the 2 See Appendix 1, "Regional Economic Prospects," induced capital accumulationi caused by highier TFP for detail on recent developments, policy, and prospects almost doubled estimates of the contribution of TFP for developing regions to growth for the United States 3. Simulation used the world model by Oxford 13 See Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calder6n (2002) Economic Forecasting Inc 14. We will use the term "workers" as shorthand 4 Investment is the most cyclical component of for the working population between ages 15 and 65 GDP and is the key drivinig force underlyling the emer- 15. With the significanit exception of SSA, where gence of turning points in the economy The flow of AIDS has dramatically reversed life expectancy, and to investment expenditures is volatile because investment, a lesser extent ECA, whiere health systems deteriorated unilike consumption, represents the desired change of during the transition toward market economies. a stock. As the capital stock tends to move with income 16. See, for example, Loayza, Fajnzylber, and and consumption, the change in the srock shows Calder6n (2002) and Masson, Bayoumi, and Samici sharper fluctuations than the change in income. Fur- (1998). thermore, a downturn in in vestmiienit is inherently tem- 17. Model simulations start in the base year 1997, porary and bears the seeds of subsequent recovery and net capital flows for that year are derived from the Once the lower desired capital stock has been achieved, Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP), release 5.0, the flow of investment stops falling and starts increas- database. Note that the GTAP data, though based on ing again to keep the capital stock stable at the new official statistics, are adjusted to ensure global ac- level. counting consistency (that is, the sum of the capital 5 The trends are computed witlh Hendrick-Prescott account across all regions is identically equal to zero). filters The world capital account has had a significant and 6. To reduce the potential risk of bad data contam- increasing residual over the past few years. The values mating the results, we have excluded outliers (invest- in the first three columns of table 1.10 (that is, the ment volatility more than three standard deviations average savings to investment ratios for the period above the mean). 1997-2001) are largely consistenit with the initial 1997 7. The correlation coefficient exceeds 0 75 base levels from the GTAP dataset The only region 8 The large drop in the poverty incidence in Latin where the signi of the capital account balance differs be- America comes from new surveys and from revisions to tween 1997 and the 1997-2001 average is the MENA, consumption levels The sur eys predate the recent tur- which is subject to considerable volatility because of moil in the region, particularly in Argentina, where the the price of oil, the region's main export. incidence of poverty has increased substantially after For all other regions, the sign of the observed early three years of recession. The large recent rise in poverty period capital account balance is consistent with the in Argentina reflects the national poverty line The rise 1997 base year, though the magnitude may differ The using the World Bank's $1 per day or $2 per day may difference in maginitude is easily magnified because the 41 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 capital account balance is a residual item. Thus, even Assimilation." Brookings Papers on Economic if there is little volatility in the savings and investment Activity 2: 135-91. components individually, there could be significantly Crucini, Mario J. 1997. "Country Size and Economic more variation in the capital account balance. Fluctuations " Review of International Econom- Finally, as already highlighted in the table nore, the ics 5(2): 204-20. capital account imbalance at the global level has been Datt, Gaurav, and Martin Ravallion. 2002 "Is India's large of late-and is increasing In the model simu- Economic Growth Leaving the Poor Behind>" lations, the base data are adjusted to remove the Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(3). 89-108. global imbalance, and the model itself ensures global Denison, Edward E 1972. "Some Major Issues in accounting consistency in each year of any simulation. Productivity Analysis: An Examination of the (The model could track perfectly the observed saving Estimates by Jorgenson and Griliches." Survey of and investment ratios for each country except one. Or Current Business 49(5, part II): 1-27. there would have to be a residual country in the model Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. "It's Not that would absorb any adjustments to ensure global Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth accounting consistency) Even if the global capital Models." The World Bank Economic Review 15: account imbalance is small as a share of global GDP, 177-219. squeezing out the $100 billion to 200 billion residual Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka. 1980. error is bound to have significant effects on the capital "Domestic Savings and International Capital account of individual countries, even a large one such Flows." Economic Journal 90(358): 314-29 as the United States. If the U.S. imbalance is $400 bil- Hulten, Charles R 2000 "Total Factor Productivity. A lion and the entire adjustment is forced on it, the U S Short Biography" National Bureau of Economic capital account imbalance could change by as much as Research (NBER) Working Paper no. 7471 Boston. 50 percent Jorgenson, Dale W., and Zvi Griliches. 1967. "The 18. Note that this concept is flow based. All indus- Explanation of Productivity Change." Review of trial countries have significant assets in other industrial Economic Studies 34(3) 249-83 countries as well as in developing countries. One 1972 "Issues in Growth Accounting: A Reply would anticipate, as in the case of Japan, that as the to Edward F Denison " Survey of Current Busi- population ages, the retired elderly will draw down ness 52(5, part 11): 65-94. their accumulated savings, including those funds in- Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido- vested abroad Lobat6n. 2002. "Governance Matters II' Up- 19. Table 1.10 compares the observed investment datedLndicatorsfor2000-01 "WorkingPaperno. ratios over the 1997-2001 period with the end-of- 2772 World Bank, Washington, D.C. February. period investment ratio generated by the model The Klenow, Peter, and Andres Rodriguez-Clare 1997 starting point of the model, 1997, has an investment "Economic Growth: A Review Essay." Journzal of ratio of 20.5 for Latin America. Thus, the scenario is Monetary Economics 40(3)- 597-617 forecasting virtually no change in the ratio Krugman, Paul 1994 "The Myth of Asia's Miracle." Foreign Affairs 73(6): 62-77 (November/ December). References Loayza, Norman, Pablo Falnzylber, and Cesar Barro, Robert, and Xavier Sala-i-Marnn. 1992. "Con- Calder6n 2002. "Economic Growth in Latin vergence." Journal of Political Economy 100(2). America and the Caribbean' Stylized Facts, 223-51 Explanations, and Forecasts " World Bank, Baxter, Marianne, and Mario J. Crucini. 1993. Washington, D C. June Processed "Explaining Saving-Investment Correlations." Masson, Paul R., Tamim Bayoumi, and Hossein American Economiic Review 83(3). 416-36 Samiei. 1998. "International Evidence on the Bhalla, Surlit. 2002. Imagine There's No Country: Determinants of Private Saving." World Bank Poverty, Iiequality, and Growvth in the Era of Econonmic Review 12(3): 483-501 Globalization Washington, D.C . Institute for Nelson, Richard R, and Howard Pack. 1999. "The International Economics Asian Miracle and Modern Growth Theory." Brock, William A., and Steven N. Durlauf 2001 EconomictJournal 109(July). 416-36. "Growth Empirics and Reality." The WVorld Bank Parente, Stephen L, and Edward C. Prescott. 1994. Economic Revietv 15(2): 229-72 "Barriers to Technology Adoption, Learning-by- Collins, Susan M, and Barry P. Bosworth 1996 "Eco- Doing, and Economic Growth." Journal of Polit- nomic Growth in East Asia: Accumulation versus ical Economy 102(2): 298-321. 42 T HE IN T ER NAT IO NA L EC ONO MY AND PRO SP EC TS F OR DE V EL O PING C O U N T R I E S - 2000 Barriers to Riches. Cambridge, Mass Carlos Sobrado, and Jean-Philippe Tre 2002 MIT Press. "Poverty in Latin America: Trends (1986-1998) Ravallion, Martin 2002. "Have We Already Met the and Determinants." World Bank, Washington, Millennium Development Goal for Poverty;" D C February. Processed World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Young, Alwyn. 1992. "A Tale of Two Cities Factor Senhadli, Abdelhak. 2000 "Sources of Economic Accumulation and Technical Change in Hong Growth An Extensive Growth Accounting Kong and Singapore." In 0. J. Blanchard and Exercise." International Monetary Fund Staff S. Fisher, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual Papers 47, no. 1 Washington, D.C. 1992 Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, pp. 13-53 Solow, Robert. 2001. "Applying Growth Theory . 1995 "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting across Countries." Th7e World Bank Economic the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Experi- Review 15(2). 283-88. ence." Quarterly Jouzrnal of Economics 110(3) Wodon, Quentin, Rodrigo Castro-Fernandez, Kihoon 641-80 Lee, Gladys Lopez-Acevedo, Corinne Siaens, 43 Changes in Global Business Organization T he organization of global business is networks, and the growinig importance of rapidly changing in ways that affect strong investment climates for the allocation the competitive opportunities open to of foreign investment. developing countries. A principal feature of business organizationi is the steady expansion Developing countries have benefited of multinational corporations and their related from the boonm in global trade and trade and investment activities. Multinational investment- companies, including many based in other Cross-border trade and direct investment have developing countries, are altering the compet- expanded rapidly over the past three decades. itive landscape by providing for developing Global exports of goods and services increased countries a new source of entry into markets. from 14 percent of output in the early 1970s to Moreover, by taking advantage of falling com- 23 percent by the late 1990s, whiile global FDI munication and transport costs, multiniation- flows have more than doubled relative to gross als have learned to manage different stages domestic product (GDP). The surge in FDI of production in multiple, distant locations, flows, with a large boost from cross-border thereby creating opportunities for developing mergers and acquisitions (M&A), accelerated countries to produce during those stages of in the late 1990s. FDI rose from $331 billioni production-often labor-intensive stages- in 1995 to $1.3 trillion in 2000 before falling that correspond to their comparative advan- to an estimated $725 billion in 2001. Despite tage. But tapping into this potential source the sharp increase in M&A, the share of global of competition is not automatic, and not all economic activity accounted for by the top countries have benefited. Moreover, some 50 companies does not appear to have risen observers have openly worried that the re- significanitly during the 1990s. The top 50 com- cent surge in global mergers among leading panies accounted for 0.8 percent of world multinationals might be dampening competi- GDIP, and their aggregate profits amounted to tion and creating obstacles for developing 3.3 percent of global savings in 2000. countries. This chapter reviews four recent trends in -the rise in service sector FDI- the organization of global business that affect A second change in global business organiza- developing countries' ability to harness for- tion creates an opportunity for developing eign investment for greater competition: countries to expand productivity-enihancinig changes in global business concentration, the competition. Foreign investimienit in services- rise in service sector foreign direct investment financial, wholesaling and retailing, real (FDI), the growth of global production estate, and business services-is accelerating. 45 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Today, services account for more than half -but a strong investment climate is of the FDI stock in most major industrial critical countries. The rise in service sector FDI helps The policy and institutional framework is an developing countries to introduce new tech- important determinant of whether countries nology, to boost competition in services, and have participated in the rise in FDI. During to increase the availability and quality of ser- the 1990s, countries with strong investment vices. Because many services are essential in- climates captured an increasing share of rapidly puts to production, with multiple linkages to expanding global FDI flows. The removal of virtually every dynamic part of the economy, restrictions on private investment in services increasing their efficiency directly boosts (particularly infrastructure services) has in- economy-wide productivity. However, many creased private investment and has improved countries still maintain impediments to this the quality of services available to firms in de- new source of competition and technology veloping countries. The lowering of trade bar- and, as a result, are at risk of being left tiers and reduction in restrictions on FDI has behind. facilitated developing countries' participation in cross-border production networks. External -and the growth of cross-border factors also play a role in determining access to production networks- FDI. For example, the recent deterioration of Technological progress in transport, commu- the global business environment has led to a nications, and data processing-coupled with reduction in investment in high-risk projects, policy reforms-has fueled the growth of and foreign investment in infrastructure has cross-border production networks, in which dropped all over the world. Still, those coun- multinational corporations break down the tries with macroeconomic stability, sound gov- production of final goods into stages that ernance, and healthy institutions will attract an vary in the intensity of capital, skilled labor, increasing share of available funds. unskilled labor, and other requirements, and multinationals produce each stage where it can be done at lower cost. In part, production The surge in trade and FDI through networks is accomplished by greater outsourcing of production, as multinationals Trade and FDI have grown rapidly since become less vertically integrated. In part, the 1970s- networks are established through foreign Cross-border trade and direct investment have subsidiaries. expanded rapidly over the past few decades. Developing countries' increased participa- Global exports of goods and services increased tion in production networks is seen in the by 5.5 percent per year in real terms from rapid growth in their exports of parts and 1978 to 2001, rising from just over 14 percent components, as well as in their increasing of output in the 1970s to almost 25 percent importance in intra-firm trade by multination- of output in 2001. High-income countries als. Participation in networks has generated account for the bulk of world trade and hence substantial gains for developing countries the largest increment to trade flows. Develop- through improving access to technology, thus ing countries' exports rose by just under 6 per- increasing the demand and supply of skilled cent per year in real terms from 1978 to 2001, labor, as well as providing the opportunity for and their aggregate exports-to-GDP ratio in- moving up the value chain to produce more creased by more than half over this period sophisticated products. However, production (figure 2.1). for networks is highly concentrated in coun- Global FDI flows have also expanded tries with strong policy regimes, skilled work- rapidly. The surge in FDI flows accelerated forces, and adequate infrastructure. in the late 1990s, rising from $331 billion in 46 C H A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N E SS O R G A N I Z A II 0 N sharp rise in the average ratio of FDI to invest- Figure 2.1 Exports-to-GDP ratios have ment during the 1990s (figure 2.2), with the increased since the 1970s largest increase in the industrial countries dur- (percent) ing the last years of the decadc. Low-income 35 countries have seen a five-fold rise in FDI rela- 30 tive to investment, to almost the same ratio as in lower-middle-incomile countries. FDI flows 25 High-incomecountnes to developing countries equal about $160 hil- 20 H - lion, while domestic investimlent in developinig 1 5 countries equals about $1 5 trillion. Developing countries The rise in trade and FDI has played an 10 important role in boosting the productivity of s firms in developing countries. In part, devel- oping countries may become more productive 0 o I Q, I I C I Iz , I (b I 53 because trade inmproves the allocation of re- 'A '6 g 'C' ', ' ' Ksources a nd because multinational sLubsidiaries Sorurce World Banik data Inay be more productivc than domestic firms. In addition, domestic firms may increase their productivity through participation in trade 1995 to $1.3 trillion in 2000 before falling to and contacts with local subsidiaries of foreign an estimated $725 billion in 2001 (UNCTAD firms, although the extent and channels are a 2002a). All income groups experienced a matter of considerable debate in the economic Figure 2.2 All regions have benefited from rising FDI flows (FDI-to-investment ratios, 1990-2000, in percent) 40 35 30 25 20 1 5 105 il1 0 Top 10 developing Low-income Lower-middle-ncome Upper-middle-income High-income country recipients countries countnes countnes countries Note Each set of bars repi eseists the period 1 990-2000, each bar represents onie year dtiring that period lThe data on FDI itcliUde both greenfield and M&A transactiols. wbhereas national iiiconiie account data oni itivestmient representi oiilv new inivestimienits .Top 10 developisig counitry recipienlts" refers to the 10 deselopiig counitries that received the largest inflows of FDI Souirce World Banik data 47 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 literature. Much empirical work has focused -but not all countries have participated on the potential for technological spillovers equally in the rise in FDI through importing, exporting, and FDI (see Among industrial countries, the top five recip- chapter 3 for a full discussion). On balance, ients of net FDI flows accounted for 74 per- the evidence for technological spillovers cent of total FDI. However, a few of the through imports is strong, while the evidence smaller countries (for example, Ireland and that exporting promotes technology diffusion Denmark) have the highest ratio of FDI to is less robust. Evidence for the existence of GDP. The same pattern can be seen in devel- technology spillovers from FDI is mixed. oping countries, where the top 12 recipients Many industry-level studies (for example, captured 80 percent of total FDI flows, but Blomstrom 1986) have documented a positive some smaller countries had FDI-to-GDP ratios correlation between FDI inflows and produc- that were several times the average ratio. Fig- tivity, although the causal direction is unclear. ure 2.3 compares each developing country's Some firm-level studies have failed to find evi- share of total FDI with its ratio of FDI to dence of technological spillovers in developing GDP (the countries are ordered by the share countries. The effect of FDI will depend, in of total FDI). Almost half of the 12 largest part, on the form that FDI takes. FDI directed recipients of FDI (at the far right of the distri- to heavily protected industries or attracted by bution in figure 2.3) have FDI-to-GDP ratios very costly incentives may have a low, or even that are lower than the average. According to negative, effect on growth and productivity. a more comprehensive measure developed by But FDI used to integrate domestic sub- the United Nations Conference on Trade and sidiaries in production networks could have Development (UNCTAD), FDI to developing substantial spillover effects (Moran 2001). countries is mildly concentrated: only 30 out of Figure 2.3 FDI is concentrated in large countries, but many small countries receive large amounts relative to GDP (percent share of total FDI) (FDI as a share of GDP) 25 - 45 - 40 20 -X-35 20 - Some countries with a small share of total 30 15 - Top 10 receive almost FDI have high FDI-to-GDP ratios (nght axis) 80% of total FDI 25 -flows (left axis) 20 10 15 5 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1 0 5 , «f 1 ; n n nn n n + * * * | I- 50 Mos 0D es D 0 iHnno'nnnn 0,6 0, .a. tQ ' i- Q4. Note Countries sorted by share of total FDI, l1999 Soiirce World Baiik data 48 C h AN GE S IN G LO B AL B US IN ES S OR GAN I Z AT IO N Figure 2.4 The service sector dominated the 1990s mergers and acquisitions boom Mergers and acquisitions boomed in the 1990s Services dominated the mergers and acquisitions boom from 1987 to 2000 (billions of dollars) (billions of dollars) 1200 900 1000 800 700 800 600 600 / 500 Services 600 ~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~400 _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ 400 Developing countries 300 Primary 200 High-income countries '~200 / Manuatrn ' 100 O O Soiirce UNCTAD (2001) 102 developing countries had shares of FDI Global concentration of ownership that equaled or excecded their average shares of does not appear to be increasing world GDP, employment, and exports (see box Contrary to popular perceptions, the boom In 2 2 in World Bank 2002b). Obviously, many cross-border M&A does not appear to have factors other than market size, particularly the had a major effect on the global concentra- policy and institutional framework, are impor- tnon of ownership. Cross-border M&A trans- tant In determining a country's attractiveness actions in the late 1990s represented only a to FDI.i small fraction of industrial countries' stock The takeoff in M&A transactionis among market capitalization. The dollar value of industrial countries-driven in part by extra- cross-border M&A transactions equaled less ordinarily rapid increases in the stock prices thani 3 percent of stock markets in most of of some major corporations and in part by the top seven industr-ial countries (figure 2.5).' expectations (during the boomn) that continu- ing productivity increases would fuel contin_- Lied rises in stock prices-was a driving force behid graterFDI see igur 2.4. Glbal Figure 2.5 Cross-border mergers and behind greater FDI (see figure 2.4). Global acquisitions are small compared with M&A rose more than five-fold between 1995 stock market capitalization and 2000 (after increasing by only 24 percent (average value 1997-99, in percent) In the first half of the 1990s) to a peak of 4_0 $1 1 trillionii n 2000, before dropping by some 3 5 45 percent in 2001 with the decline in stock 30 - markets and the global economic slowdown.2 2 5 This experience was not unprecedented: 25 * * * through the 1980s and 1990s, the global econ- 1 0 U * * omy experienced major waves of corporate 05 C U I ___ mergers.3 The bulk of the cross-border M&A 0 ! ! 1 1 ! M transactions was in service sectors (more than c - & , half in finance, transport, storage, and com- a niunications alone), which accelerated rapidly beginning in 1998 (see also the discussion of Souirce Evenert (21112) FDI in service sectors, page 10). 49 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Of course, the M&A boom coincided with the sharp rise in stock market valuations in the Figure 2.6 U.S. aggregate concentration late 1990s, particularly in the United States. has held steady Thus it is useful to keep in mind that both the Share of top 500 companies of U.S private sector numerator and the denominator in figure 2.5 (percent) are rising rapidly. 80 A related concern is whether the concentra- 70 ,Profits tion of global economic activity, either in mdi- 60 vidual sectors or in total, has increased for 50 _ reasons other than cross-border M&A. For 40 social and political reasons, high concentra- 30 non in an economy may be a matter of con- 20 cern. For example, 5.5 million corporations t0 are in the United States, with the largest 100 0 l,,, ,, companies accounting for about l1 percent .z W$z IR, IC' Ie@$'I'.'IC of employment and payroll.5 The fabric of the U.S. economic (and socio-political) land- Source White scape would surely be different if there were no small enterprises, no start-ups, and no alternative places (beyond a few mammoth because each firm may participate in multiple corporations) where someone with a new en- markets.9 trepreneurial idea might go to obtain financial Concentration at the global level appears support and institutional encouragement. to remain low, although one confronts enor- Similar concerns would hold for a high level of mous data problems and difficult tradeoffs in concentration in the global economy. There making such estimates. In 2001, total employ- may be an extra element of concern for devel- ment by the largest 50 global companies (as oping countries in this regard. Few of the identified by Forbes) accounted for 0.3 percent largest companies in the global economy are of the world labor force, or 1.6 percent of headquartered in and identified with a devel- employment in Organisation for Economic oping economy.f6 A global economy that is Co-operation and Development (OECD) dominated by a relative handful of giant com- countries. Those companies' profits amounted panies (if that were the case), which are head- to 0.8 percent of world GDP and 3.3 percent quartered in a relatively few industrial coun- of world gross domestic savings.10 Although it tries, may raise even greater socio-political is difficult to say what level of concentration concerns in developing countries that feel that should be viewed as a cause for concern, at they can exert little effective control over these least these aggregate data do not reflect a dom- enterprises. ination of the global or OECD economies by a Although the measurement issues involved small number of firms. are enormous, it does not appear that global Global concentration does not appear to concentration is high or has been rising signif- have risen significantly during the 1990s. The icantly during the 1990s.7 White (2001, 2002) share of the top 50 companies (as measured by reports declining or stable aggregate concen- Forbes) in the world labor force and in OECD tration in the U.S. economy from the 1980s employment has fallen slightly since 1994 (fig- through the late 1990s, depending on whether ure 2.7).11 The declining share of the large employment, payroll, or profit data are used companies' employment levels is consistent (figure 2.6).8 Note that this measure of aggre- with the trend for the United States reported gate concentration does not provide an indica- by White (2001, 2002). Despite the merger tor of market power in individual markets, wave of the 1990s, very large companies have 50 CH AN GE S IN G LO B AL B US IN ES S OR GAN I ZAT IO N Figure 2.7 Global concentration has not increased significantly Employment of the top 50 global companies, 1994-2001 Profits of the top 50 global companies, 1994-2001 (percent) (percent) 18 Share of OECD em6loymet 6 1 6 S o8 E employen Share of OECD savings T ~~~~~~~~~~~~5 14 1 0 08 \ 200d labor1force 06 2 m iii 040 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Souirce Wloite 20021, not experienced a significant expansion of A different approach to the calculation of employment relative to other companies. This global concentrationl is reported by DeGrauwe has been partly due to interinal rationaliza- and Camerman (2002), with similar conclu- tions and cost-cutting by those companies and sions. They find that sales of the top 50 in- partly due to significanit numbers of spinoffs dustrial corporations from the Fortune 500 and divestitures. list have grown slightly less rapidly than world The share of the top 50 companies' profits GDP from 1980 to 2000. Thus the 2000 sales in global savings and OECD savings has risen of the 50 largest industrial corporations were sincc the rnid-1990s (figure 2.7). The rise in slightly smaller in relation to world GDP than profits among the largest companies is also was true for the 50 largest corporations in consistent with the U.S. trend reported by 1980.12 White (2001, 2002a). However, in the United These indicators of global concenitiationi States, economy-wide profits were rising reveal nothing about the concentration of rapidly during the late 1990s; thus the ratio of market power in individual sectors. Risinig the largest companies' profits to total profits concentrationi at the sectoral level may reduce was relatively constant. Unfortunately, tinme se- competition, thereby increasing prices faced ries data on global profits, or even OECD prof- by consumers and suppliers and shifting its, are not available. Nevertheless, it is likely wealth from consumers and suppliers in that OECD profits were rising more rapidly competitive industries to producers in more than nominal GDP or savings; hence the share concentrated incustries. Unfortunately, com- of the top companies' profits may not have in- prehensive data do not exist on global sectoral creased as much as indicated by the ratios given concentration. in figure 2.7. Moreover, the recent accounting Sectoral data are available for some major scandals affecting telecommunications, energy, countries, and they do indicate a rise in coil- and other high-tech companies indicate a sig- centration ratios. The average concentration nificant overstatement of profits in many of the of industries at the Standard Industrial Classi- largest companies during the late 1990s. Thus fication (SIC) 4 level increased from 1947 to the rise in profits of the top 50 companies rela- 1992 in the United States, while concentration tive to global savings may be overstated. declined slightly from 1983 to 1992 in Japan G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 before increasing sharply in 1992-98.13 Table 2.1 FDI inward stocks in services However, sectoral concentration ratios at the and manufacturing, 1988-99 country level provide little information on the (groth rate and shares in dollars) competitiveness of markets, because most of Growth rate. 1988-99 Share, those companies face competition from im- I 1 9 change 1999 ports. Indeed, the rapid rise in world trade pr vecar) (percent) over the past two decades, coupled with the emergence of developing-country exporters, orlDi Total FDl 123 indicates that competitive pressures may have Manufacturing 12.2 41 6 increased in many industries.14 Services 13.8 503 Despite the difficulties in measuring global Industrial countries, I sectoral concentration ratios and in determin- Total FDI 9 9 ing the implications for competition, anticom- Nlanufacturing 9 1 36 4 petitive practices have clearly affected some Services i 6 555 industries. The 1990s saw the uncovering of a Developing countries, large number of international cartels, in which Total FDI 21 5 firms from more than one country made ManufaCtUring 19 6 54 5 explicit agreements to fix prices, divide up mar- _Services_28_2 _ 37_3 kets, or rig bids for contracts (see chapter 4). Note Seconid column data for France are from 1998, and seconid columin data for Japan are from 1994 Souirce UNCTFAD (2001) The rise in service sector FDI lines the importance of an effective regulatory FDI flows into services have overtaken regime, because designing and enforcing an those in manufacturing- appropriate regulatory framework is more Service sector FDI has grown rapidly over the difficult in many service sectors (such as past few decades, and services are now the natural monopolies in infrastructure) than in dominant sector for foreign investment.1s manufacturing. The stock of FDI in services was only about one-fifth of the total in the 1950s (United Nations 1989), but by the mid-1970s the share of services in the stock of outward FDI Figure 2.8 Share of FDI in the service of major industrial countries ranged mostly sector increased in major industrial between 30 and 40 percent.i6 By 1990, this countries share rose to between 45 and 60 percent, and (percent) over the past decade, FDI in services has con- -0 tinued to rise more rapidly than FDI in man- 80 ufacturing in both developing and industrial 70 1998 countries (table 2.1). By the end of the 1 990s, 60 services accounted for more than half of the 50 _ stock of inward FDI in most major industrial 40 i countries (figure 2.8). Despite the rapid 20 _ increase in service sector FDI, the global ratio 10 _ of FDI to value added in services remains less 0 than half the ratio of FDI to value added in France Germany italy Japan Unted United manufacturing, thus indicating the potential Kingdom States for further increases in service sector FDI. Sou,rce OECD (2001) and OECI) onliie database The dominance of service sector FDI under- 52 C It A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N E SS 0 R GANIZATION -reflecting the rising role of services in intensive services-research and development the global economy- (R&D), engineering, design, computing and FDI in services has increased relative to man- data processing, inventory management, qual- ufacturing, in part because of the growing ity control, design, accounting, legal services, importance of the service sector in economic personnel services, and so on-have become a activity. By the late 1 990s, the service sector critical part of the production process in the had increased from half of global output in the manufacturing sector. With moderin manufac- early 1970s to 64 percent. Income growth has turing production and distribution becoming been the driving force behind the rise in ser- increasingly dependenit on the processing and vices: cross-country comparisons show that dissemination of information, the demanld for the richest countries have the greatest share those producer services is rising rapidly. of services. Services account for 70 percent of Moreover, the growing sophistication and output in industrial countries, 55 percent variety of services, coupled with specialization in middle-income countries, and 44 percent in emerginig from economies of scale, have led low-intcomie countries. The correlation coeffi- manufacturinig firms to rely more on out- cient between income level and the share of sourcing than o1 in-house departments to services is 0.6. The relationship between provide the services necessary for production. higher income and a greater share of services The immediate consequence is a statistical in part reflects consunmer demand, because effect: the size of the service sector rises wheni luxuries such as travel and entertainmrent services that were previously classified as often have a large services component. Also, manufacturing output are suddenly counted higher incomes permit an allocation of more as services. Typical examples of these types of resources toward protecting assets (insurance services are accounting, computer services and legal services), richer and complex soci- (data processing and software), warehousing, eties require more resources devoted to educa- public relations, information technology, and tion and advisory services, and technological management information systems. advaiices associated with higher incomie widen Technological progress has greatly reduced the scope for the protection of health. Finally, the cost of some services, thus increasing the the higher labor intensity of services and rising scope of services that are feasible to supply real wages have increased the nominal value (for example, mobile telephones, complex of services relative to manufacturing. financial transactionis suclh as derivatives, and a host of other services facilitated through -technological changes that have advanced data processing). Technological increased the demand and supply progress has also generated new means of of services- deliverinig services (for example, the dissemi- Technological progress has tended to increase nation of research over the Internet). This the demanid for services connected with the process is similar to what occurred during the production of goods and to facilitate the sepa- industrial revolution, when technological ration of goods production from services pro- progress and income growth greatly increased duction.17 The larger scale of production, the the importance of manufactures when com- greater technological sophistication of goods, pared with the primiary sector. and the increased trade in goods and imianage- Both the reduced cost of some services and ment of enterprises across large distances have the increased scope of services have increased all contributed to the greater demand for ser- the tradability of services, a trend that has, vices. The importance of management, market- in part, beeii exploited through increased FDI. ing, distribution, and after-sale maintenance For example, software can be produced in has risen relative to the value of manufactured low-cost locations such as India and sold products. Many information-and-knowledge- directly to firms and consumers in the United 53 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 States over the Internet. Many multinationals provide services through subsidiaries, rather have established centers in developing coun- than other kinds of relationships, include tries, where wages are low, to handle contacts (a) financial institutions, in which much of with consumers in industrial countries. For proprietary knowledge is tacit, is expensive to example, call centers in the Caribbean manage produce, and is complex and idiosyncratic; phone calls to multinationals from U.S. clients (b) firms that require control over production (this is an example of participation of service to maximize efficiency and to protect the firms in production networks; see page 13 for quality of the end product (and thus customer an elaboration of this concept in manufactur- goodwill) for trademarks (for example, in ing). In some cases, the rising tradability of advertising, market research, construction, services may have reduced FDI by enabling business consulting, consumer-oriented ser- firms to provide services at a distance rather vices, and goods-related personal services such than establishing a subsidiary. However, in as motor vehicle maintenance and repair); and general, increased tradability has created new (c) trade-related service affiliates set up by opportunities for multinationals' subsidiaries non-service multinationals to obtain inputs to export services to home markets and, in for domestic activities or to supply markets. some cases, to operate as international hubs to supply services to firms in other countries. -and policy changes that encourage Because industrial countries are the lead con- the private provision of services sumers of tradable services, developing coun- The removal of restrictions on FDI and regula- tries have benefited from the establishment tory reforms that have improved competition of subsidiaries to service the richer markets. in service sectors have contributed to the rise in Technological advances that increase services service sector FDI. Until recently, many coun- tradability have also imparted an advantage tries (including many industrial countries) pro- in service delivery to multinationals relative to hibited foreign investment in sectors such as domestic firms, thus enabling the former to transport, communications, banking, finance, overcome the natural advantages of proximity utilities, and media. Since the mid-1980s, and knowledge of the market (Sauvant and governments in both industrial and develop- Mallampally 1996). ing countries have been gradually opening up Income growth and technological progress those service sectors to foreign investment.18 have boosted the provision of services through Multinationals can enhance the efficiency various forms of cross-border relationships of services industries in developing countries in several sectors: (a) management and fran- by providing services that developing-country chise contracts in hotels, restaurants, and car suppliers cannot provide, as well as by intensi- rentals (in which performance requirements fying competition. In particular, providing can often be adequately codified, local man- producer services (for example, managerial agerial input is desirable, and the synergistic services, engineering, finance, and marketing) advantages of global reservations and referral that are often subject to economies of scale and systems can be obtained without the risks and that have a much higher cost from a distance costs involved in an equity stake); (b) joint can generate important benefits to developing- ventures in some business services, in recre- country firms. Availability of producer services ational activities, in some accounting and legal may be an important reason to form industrial services, and in civil engineering in turnkey complexes and may explain a significant share projects (in which individual customization of the differences in economic performance and specialized knowledge of local practices among regions. Producer services are likely to are required); and (c) services in which a local be provided through FDI (rather, for example, partner is required for marketing and dist- than through training unaffiliated firms) ribution (Dunning 1981). Firms that tend to because they involve knowledge-based assets 54 C H AN GE S IN G LO B AL B US IN ES S OR GAN I Z AI IO N that are easily copied if firms lose control over the knowledge (Markusen, Rutherford, Figure 2.9 U.S. cars are produced in and Tarr 2000). FDI has surged in developing many countries countries' banking sectors, in many cases re- (percentshareinvalueadded) ducing the costs of financial intermediation, 40 increasing the scope of financial services avail- able to local firms, and transferring skills to 30 workers in developiiig countries.19 20 20 , _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ Global production networks 10 - The globalization of production has ol l _ l le, 31 ~ C',~9 helped fuel the growth in global trade 10 :'c- 4o --I'7 Rapid growth in trade and in FDI flows has ', . reflected, in part, the expansion of production networks.20 The production of many fmial goods, which formerly took place in one loca- Souirce WTO (1998) tion, has been broken down into discrete steps, with each step moved to locations where it United Kingdom, although it fell in Japan canl be performed at the lowest cost (Venables (figure 2.10). Using iIput-output tables, 1999; Kimura 2001). Thus a significant pot- Hummels, Rappaport, and Yi (1997) calculate tion of international trade and FDI has shifted'' from the exchange and production of final that the fraction of the total value of trade consumer goods to the exchange and produc- accounted for by inputs that are both consofmart anods componthe nts.hae Ts glob- imported and then embodied in exports rose tilon of parts and componentrs. This global- I ization of producing individual goods has in France, the United Kingdom, and the United States from- 1970 to 1990, while drop- progressed to the point that it can become dif- Unitd tae fo 197022 rt 1990 whe drop ficult to identify the nationality of some prod- ping slghtly In Japan. Data from the U N. ucts. For example, the World Trade Organiza- portrad databaenshow tha portscof tion (WTO 11998]) gives figures for the share parts and components-a proxy for partlcipa- ofvalue added in producing a U.S. automobile, tion in global networks-Increased by almost of vaue grouped by atomobile,- 2 percentage points faster than exports of with countries grouped by category of pro- total manufactured goods from 1981 to 2000 duction. The United States accounts for only (table 2.2).23 37 percent of value added (figure 2.9).(te.)- Thpercent is consderabled evidee that th The rise in the share of trade accounted for share of global trade accounted for by net- by global networks in part reflects the increas- works is inicreasing, although the results ing importance in global production of goods vary amonig countries and studies. Baldonie, Table 2.2 Growth of exports of parts and Sdogati, and Tajoh (2002) estimate that the components,1981-2000 share of intermediate products in total trade (averagenas,198al-perce 00tage0chatgiidollars) within the European Union (EU) rose only sligltly in the 1990s, from 17 percent in 1990 1981-90 1990-2000 to 19 percent in 1999.21 One measure of inter- ianufactured exports 10.6 7 2 national outsourcing-the ratio of imported to Parts and components exports 12 1 9 6 total intermcdiate inputs in manufacturing- Merno itern Share of parts doubled in the United States from 1974 to and colnponents 13.2 18 5 1993 and increased in Canada and the Source UN Conmtrade database 55 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 Figure 2.10 Cross-border networks capture increasing shares of production and trade Imports of intermediate inputs increased, 1974-93 Production through networks increased, 1974-93 (ratio of imported to total intermediate inputs In (percent share of trade accounted for by imported inputs manufactunng, in percent) that are embodied in exports) 25 20 2016 1 4 1c 5 12 2 199 the~~~~~~~~~~~~~~19 1990 1 0 8 6 5 4 2 0 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 Canada Japan United United France Japan United United Kingdom States Kingdom States Soerce Feenstra (1998), Campa and Goldberg (1997), Himmets, Rappaport, aid Yi (1997) such as electronics, chemicals, and transport product classes. Hanson, Mataloni, and equipment and machinery, where trade in Slaughter (2001) report that the share of U.S. components is most important. The share of multinational affiliates' imports of intermedi- those sectors in world trade rose from 27 per- ate inputs in their total sales rose significantly cent in 1986 to 43 percent in 1997 (Schive and from 1982 to 1994 in electronics, transporta- Chyn 2001). However, the increase also tion equipment, and industrial machinery and reflects a rise in components trade within the equipment (figure 2.11). Figure 2.11 The role of production networks continued to increase through most of the 1990s Use of Intermediate inputs rose, 1982-94 Exports by MNCs abroad rose, 1982-98 (percent of U S affiliates' imports of intermediate inputs as (percent of U S affiliates' exports as a share of total affiliate a share ot sales) sales) 25 70 19892 20 60 1982 ~~~~~~~~~~~50 1 5 40 10' 30 20 5 1 0 Souirce U S Bureau of Economic Analysis, as reported in Hanson, Maratoiii, and Slaughter (2001) 56 C If A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N E SS O R G A N I Z A T I O N The establishment of global networks has systems greatly reduce the costs of procure- been facilitated by technology- ment and improve the coordinationi of pro- Technological progress in transport, commu- ductron across dispersed factories by automat- nications, and data processing has fueled ing the processing of routine transactions increased FDI flows and the establishment (Chen 1996). of cross-border production networks. A nearly 70 percent decline in sea freight unit costs -policy improvements- between the early 1980s and the mid-1990s Improvements in economic policies, notably (in part caused b) a rise in the share of cargo the decline in barriers to trade, have also con- carried in containers; see World Bank 1997)24 tributed to forming cross-border production and an increased reliance on air shipments, networks. Successive rounds of multilateral plus the growth of express services (such as negotiations reduced average tariffs on manu- overnight and two-day delivery)25 have facili- factured products in industrial countries from tated the shipment of com1ponents for pro- 10 percent in 1980 to 5 percelnt by 1998. The cessing in different locations. The low cost of average tariff rate in developing countries fell long-distance telephotne rates, the develop- from between 25 and 30 percent in the early ment of fax machines, and, most recently, the 1980s to 13 percent by 1998 (figure 2.12). advent of the Internet have made it easier for Even relatively low tariff rates can have a multinationals to closely coordinate produc- significant role in deterring the formation tion at dispersed locations. Those changes of cross-border networks, because goods often have also greatly reduced the costs of finding pass through borders several timies in the and evaluating potential suppliers for more course of prodLuction (Navaretti, Haaland, arm's-length transactions (Grossman and and Venables 2000), and the gross margins Helpman 2002). Finally, an increased ability of manufacturing companies are often lower to process and analyze vast amounts of data than 5 percent.26 Hanson, Mataloni, and has facilitated the management of global Slaughter (2002) find that tariffs are an im- networks. Electronic data interchange (EDI) portant detcrminant of the size of intermediate Figure 2.12 Tariff rates fell in the last two decades Average tariff raies, 1980-98 Industrial countries' tariffs on parts and components, 1988-2001 (average tanff on nmports trom industrial countries, (percent) in percent) 35 6 / Developing countries 30 _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ 5 25 20 15 I3d E U _-___ 10 ~~~inusnaocuntr es 7710 - 0d2| OI I I I I I I I I IIIII O r' 1980 1984 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 1988-90 1991-93 1995-97 1998-2001 Note Uniweighied average of ad salorern, applied, or NtFN rates, whiichever data are available ftor a loniger period Soitrce U N Cmrntrade database 57 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 inputs from parent companies relative to the shifted to negative lists (that is, lists specifying total sales of U.S. affiliates (a direct measure a limited number of sectors from which for- of activity within production networks). eign investors are excluded or are subject to a Higher tariffs are significantly correlated with ceiling on the share of the firm that foreigners less production sharing, with estimated elas- may own).27 Often, reforms in trade, FDI, ticities in the range of 2 to 4. Multinationals and other areas work together to encourage may even lobby for reduced tariffs on their in- greater participation in global networks. The puts so they can reduce the costs of networks. export-to-sales ratio of U.S. multinational The average tariff rate that industrial coun- affiliates rose dramatically from 1982 to 1998 tries impose on imports of parts and compo- in Mexico (following trade and investment nents declined during the 1990s and was well reforms in the mid-1980s), in China (after below the overall average tariff rate by the end reforms in the early 1990s), and in Canada of the decade. (after investment reforms of the mid-1980s Steps toward greater integration between and the coming into effect of U.S.-Canada free geographically close neighbors with signifl- trade agreement in 1989) (figure 2.13). cantly different wage rates have had a particu- larly important role in stimulating the growth -and incentives of regional production networks. Before 1990, Countries may affect their attractiveness to the export of processed goods from Eastern global production networks by specific require- Europe to the EU was minimal. By 1996, such ments or incentives affecting foreign firms. exports were almost 20 percent of Poland's Moran (2001) examines case studies on the exports to the EU, 40 percent of Romania's, industries cited above as being most heavily and well over 10 percent in most other Eastern involved in global production networks (elec- European countries (Baldone, Sdogati, and tronics, machinery, and transportation). He Tajoli 2002). Kaminski and Ng (2001) report finds that affiliates in countries that impose that the value of Central Europe's total trade relatively stringent or widespread performance in parts grew almost three-fold from 1993 standards on multinationals (for example, to 1997. The maqtiiladora industry in Mexico limits on foreign ownership, domestic-content has grown spectacularly since introduction of requirements, and various technology-sharing the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Networks have been boosted by special Figure 2.13 Reforming countries arrangements. U.S. and European tariff provi- boosted exports through production sions encourage production by the subsidiaries networks of multinationals, because the tariff on a sub- (exports of US affiliates asashare of total sales, sidiaries' import is imposed only on the value in percent) added in the assembly country, not on the total 45 value of the good (Ng and Yeats 2001). 40 1998 35 Reduced restrictions on FDI in developing 30 countries have increased the participation in 25 20 international production networks. Of the 15 1982 1 0 numerous regulatory and policy changes that s have affected FDI and that werc introduced 0 by developing-country governments during the All countries Canada Mexico China OtherAsia 1990s, 95 percent were aimed at creating a Note Exports from US affiliates in all countries show more open environment for FDI (UNCTAD iso rise in the share of sales due to declines in the export shares in primary production 2001). Many developing countries have elim- Souerce Hanson, Mataloii, and Slaughter (2001) mated broad restrictions on FDI and have 58 CHANGES IN G LO BA L B US IN ES S ORGAN I ZAT ION mandates) are much less productive, use older particular products (Arndt 2001). A spectrum technology, and take longer to introduce new of choices exists, and each involves some processes and products than affiliates in coun- form of relationship between supplier and tries that do not impose such requirements. purchaser.28 The major advantage that multi- Thus, FDI to countries with strict require- nationals have over local firms is typically tech- ments is more likely to be directed at local nology, and protecting that advantage is a key markets, because participation in networks consideration in determining the structure of a often requires the latest technology. global network (Ethier and Markusen 1996).29 Because it can be difficult to maintain control Global networks can be structured over technology in arm's-length arrangements, in many ways FDI is often the preferred choice (Hoon and Global networks are achieved through a range Ho 2001).30 This preference is reflected in the of ownership structures, from conducting rise in the share of intra-firm trade in multina- arm's-length transactions (for example, trade tionals' exports, at least as far as developing in standardized parts sold in organized mar- countries are concerned (box 2.1). kets) to establishing a subsidiary for produc- There are disadvantages, however, to es- ing components that are custom-made for tablishing a network through FDI. Securing Box 2.1 Intra-firm trade increases worldwide The boom in FDI flows during the 1990s was actions rather than greenfield investments. The associated with only a small rise in the share of transfers of ownership involved in such transactions intra-firm trade in U.S. exports during the 1990s (see would not necessarily have a significant effect on box figure 1).31 By contrast, the share of intra-firm trade flows. If one looks at longer time series, there exports in Japanese trade almost doubled during this is some evidence that intra-firm trade has become period. The failure of U.S. outward FDI flows (the more important for U.S. multinationals, particularly stock of which nearly tripled in the 1990s) to result in services (box figure 2). in a sharper increase in the share of intra-firm trade probably reflects the dominance of M&A trans- Intra-tirm trade in services is becoming Intra-firm trade has increased more important (percent share of intra-firm exports in total exports) (percent share of intra-firm exports in total U.S MNC 40 1999 exports) 1999_______________________ 35250 1 5 20~~~~~~~~~~~~4 auacue SrIe 3 0 40 - 25 199 15~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 10 20 United Slates Japan 1977 1983 1993 1999 Souorce: OECD (2001). Source: OECD (2001). 59 G LO B A L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 B ox 2.1 (continued) Intra-firm trade includes production that is by U.S. multinationials have increased only slightly shared among locations in global networks, as well more rapidly than have total U.S. exports. However, as trade in finished products tor marketing and dis- a growing share of this trade is devoted to production l tribuLIoll in foreign countries There is some evidence networks, which increasmigly involve developing i that production through networ ks has become more countries. important over time. The share of exports of inter- nmediate goods to overseas manufacturing affiliates in I total Japanese exports rose from 20 percent in 1994 I to 29 percent in 1999. Products intended for further processing increased from 57 percent of U.S. multi- nationals' exports to foreigni-ownied affiliates in 1989 Trade among U.S. affiliates is rising in to 68 percent In 1999 (Mataloni and Yorgason 2002). the developing world Trade among foreign affiliates of U.S. multinationals (percent share of intra-firm exports in total U S MNC has also expanded, which probably indicates that net- exports) works have beconme more complex over time. The 70 share of intra-firm exports of foreign subsidiaries accounted for by exports to other subsidiaries (rather 6019 than to the parent company) rose from 53 percent In 50s- 1983 to 66 pcrcent in 1 999 (box figure 3). This rise 40- is almost totally due to an increase in foreign affiliate 1983 trade among developing countries, from 30 percent 30- of U.S. multinationals' intra-firm trade in 1983 to 20- 51 percent in 1999. Production networks appear to 10 be less important in intra-firm trade among industrial 0 countries, given their more similar labor costs. For o _ . . . . example, 90 percent of intra-firm exports from All Industrial Developing countries countries countries foreign multinationals to U.S. affiliates are finished goods for direct distribution to the U.S. market. The Soturce OECD (2001) picture that emerges is that total intra-firm exports intermediate inputs through contracts with ing the 1990s and now account for 20-30 per- local firms often entails lower administrative cent of total electronics production. costs than establishinig a subsidiary. The multi- national is free to specialize in providing tech- Developing countries have increased nology, marketing, and distribution services, their participation in global while a local partner may be better situated networks to handle the personnel and regulatory issues Developing couLntries have been increasingly involved in establishing a company. Moreover, involved in the international networks that some multinationals outsource a substantial manage the production and trade of interme- share of manufacturing, because contract diate goods. Differences in wage levels have led manufacturers may be better placed than firms to locate in developing countries those multinationals to absorb the risk from rapid portions of the production chain that are in- product obsolescence (Ernst 2002). Contract tensive in manual labor, while locating at home manufacturers that produce components for the technically skilled labor (such as that in- well-known multinationals grew rapidly dur- volved in R&D, management, and marketing) 60 C I1 AN GE S IN G LO B AL B US IN ES S OR GAN I Z A r I ON (Hanson, Mataloni, and Slaughter 2001; Filipe, Fontoura, and Saucier 2002). Multina- Figure 2.14 Parts and components tionals operating in developing countries arc exports grew rapidly, 1981-2000 morc likely to be part of a network (as opposed (percent per annum) to supplying the host market) than are multi- 25 nationals in industrial countries. The share of U.S. affiliate production that is sold back to 20 the United States is more than twice as high 15 for developing countries as it is for industrial 10 countries (Shatz and Vcnables 2000). Data on parts and components exports, 5 which are a proxy for participation in nct- 0 works, confirm the growing participation of High-income countries Developing countries developing countries.32 Their exports of parts Source U N Cointrade .ind World Bd.ik and componients increased by almost 1 8 per- cenit per year in the 1 980s and by 22.5 percent in the 1990s (in U.S. dollar terms), almost Access to networks among developing three timies more rapidly thaii such exports countries is highly concentrated of high-incomile countries In the latter period Developing countries' participation In global (figure 2.14). As a result, the share of develop- networks is highly concentrated, particularly ing countries in global parts and components in East Asia. The top five developing-country exports increased from 4 percent in 1981 to exporters of parts and components (China, 21 percent In 2000 (figure 2.15). By contrast, Mexico, Republic of Korea, Malaysia, and the share of developing countries in exports Thailand) accounted for 78 percent of devel- of world manufactures rose much morc oping countries' exports of parts and coplipo- slowly, from 16 percent in 1 981 to 22 percent nents, and the next five largest developing in 2000, while developing countries' share of countries accounted for about 14 percent (fig- total trade fell slightly (largely caused by the ure 2.16). Developing countries outside the top fall in commodity prices). 10 made up only about 8 percent. By contrast, Figure 2.15 Developing countries' share of global parts and component exports rose between 1981 and 2000 Percent share of parts and components trade, 1981 Percent share of parts and components trade, 2000 Other developing Developing East Asia Other developing Developing East Asia counltries rU i 3 countries 7 Souirce U N Cointrade and World Banik 61 G LO B A l EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Networks help improve the allocation Figure 2.16 Developing countries' parts of resources and component exports are highly Global production networks break the pro- concentrated, 2000 duction of a given final good into a set of coIn- (percent share of total) stituent activities that vary in the intensity of 30 capital, skilled labor, unskilled labor, and 25- other production requirements. Instead of 20 making entire products, developing countries 15 can be involved in just those stages of products 10 M L (for example, labor-intensive stages) that best 5 I I I suit their mix of endowments. This approach 0o ! ! ! ! ! ! enables developing countries to shift more cS , & a 9 Zbx resources to activities in which they have a o e} <; tg > c, soa,4comparative advantage, particularly the fast- , ^ be Co9 growing segments that require large labor inputs in one or more stages of the manufac- turing chain. Developing countries' participa- Sourrce U N Cointrade aid World Banik tion in global networks has enabled those countries to increase their share of the world's fastest-growing export products (transistors and semiconductors, computers, and computer the top 10 countries accounted for 63 percent and office machine parts) from 2.4 percent in of developing countries' total exports ancl 1980 (about the same as the share of those 75 percent of their manufactured exports. products in global exports) to 16.3 percent by Thus trade of parts and components is much 1998 (almost 7 percentage points higher than more concentrated than total or manufac- the share of such products in global exports) tures trade. All top 10 countries (except Brazil) (table 2.3). either are from East Asia or are participating Participating in networks may help dampen in regional arrangements-with the United the effect of adverse shocks. Multinationals States or the EU-that provide for low trade may have an interest in maintaining the oper- barriers and long-term arrangements to in- ations of firms with which they have close ties, crease trade integration. By contrast, countries either in the form of investment or long-term that have limited ties to major industrial coun- contracting relationships. Some authors have try markets, that lack adequate infrastructure argued that intra-firm trade is less respon- (particularly transport facilities) or a suffi- sive to changes in relative prices than is trade ciently educated work force, that are subject between firms, because multinationals will be to high risks as a result of poor governance or concerned with the effect of their production weak institutions, or that have pursued poli- cies that erode incentives for private sector Table 2.3 Export activity for product investment have minimal participation in groups with the fastest growth in world global networks. South Asia, Sub-Saharan exports, 1980-98 Africa, and the Middle East and North Africa (percent) together account for only 2 percent of devel- 1980 1998 oping countries' parts and components exports (and two-thirds of that amount is Share in world exports 2 6 9 7 from South Africa and India), compared with Share in developing-country 11 percent of developing countries' total man- exports 2.4 16.3 ufactured exports. Soturce UNCTAD (2002) 62 C HANG ES IN G LO B AL B US IN ES S OR G A N I Z A I I ( N decisions on the survival of foreign affiliates a large share of technical advances. Using in- (Cho 1990; Helleiner 1978).33 Thus niulti- ternational patent data, katon and Kortum nationals may lend funds to subsidiaries suf- (1999) find that even the major industrial fering temporary shocks or may provide the coulitries (the United States, Japan, Germaniy, backing necessary for them to access credit the United Kingdomil, aiid France) generally markets, adopt from one-half to three-fourths of their Long-term contracts that have been entered innovations from abroad, and that the United through networ-ks may help firms survive States is the only country that clerives most of severe shocks. For example, exports from the its growth from its own innovationis (see also Philippinies maintained double-digit growth Keller 2001). Because developing countries rates in 1998, while other countries in the spend a lot less than industrial coLintries on region saw outright declines in exports be- basic researchi, they are even more dependent cause of the crisis This performance was prin- on foreign sources of techniology. Thus the cipally due to the high growth In electronics potential for increasinig access to techinology exports (while exports of consunier goods as a result of participation in trade and FDI languishcd), and almost all of the Philippines' may be great (Keller 2002). electronic exports come from affiliates of In part, benefits from the tranisfer of tech- multinationals. The arrangements in place nology are directly capturcd by the local firm meant that a substantial share of the or subsidiary participating in a network. Philippines' production was booked well in Technology is transferred from the parent to advance (typically one year), which helped the a subsidiary, or a local exporter may pLirchase country maintain output growthi during the technology as a conditioni of participating downturn in demand (World Bank 1999). in a network. One piece of microeconiomilic evidence consistent with rising intra-firimi Networks may boost access to knowledge transfer is the rising share of technology- multiniationals' R&D performed by foreign Participating in global networks may improve affiliates. The U.S. Bureau of Economilic developing countries' access to technology. Analysis (BEA) reports that, in 1982, affiliates Multinationials typically possess knowlecige of U.S. multinationals performed 6.4 percent assets such as patents, proprietary technology, of worldwide R&D for these firms. By 1994, trademarks, and so forth that can be deployed that share had nearly doubied, to 11.5 per- in plants outside the parent couLitry (see cent. This form of technology transfer may Dunning 1981). Blomstrom and Kokko (1998) increase domestic productivity, but the benefit describe how multinationals typically have is fully reflected in market prices: the local proprietary technology that enables them to subsidiary or indepenidenit firm pays for the compete against local firms, which presumilably techniology through profit repatriation or have superior kniowleclge of local markets and expenditures on technology. In addition, local business practices. Approximately 90 percent firms may absorb technology from networks of the world's R&D is carried out in five coun- in ways that are not enti-ely reflected in tries (the United States, the United Kingdomii, market transactions (referred to as spillovers; France, Germany, and Japan) that are among see discussion in chapter 3). Rodriguez-Clare the largest source countries for world FDI (1996) Illustrates how multinational spillovers flows (Keller 2001). from participation in global production net- works may work: affiliates increase a host -which may be an important source of country's access to specialized varieties of growth potential intermediate inputs, the improved knowledge Access to techinology is particularly important of which raises the productivity of domestic for developing countries, which tend to import producers. 63 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 Networks may help increase the supply by inward FDI, resulted in a surge in labor and demand for skilled labor supply driven largely by the reverse migration Networks help improve access to technology, of young Irish people back to Ireland. which tends to stimulate demand for more- If the presence of multinationals raises the skilled workers relative to less-skilled workers. demand for skilled labor more than the supply, Increased capital available through FDI may then wage rates for skilled labor may increase also increase the demand for skilled workers relative to those for unskilled labor. This (see the survey in Hamermesh 1993). Feenstra change implies a widening of income inequal- and Hanson (1996) show that the transfer of ity in countries with a large pool of unskilled technology and capital accumulation associ- labor. However, multinationals' demand for ated with global networks can raise the labor is likely to raise the level of income of all demand for more-skilled labor in both indus- workers, regardless of the effect on relative trial and developing countries, and Feenstra wages. Several studies have found that multi- and Hanson (1997) estimate that FDI into nationals pay higher wages than do domesti- Mexico's maquziladoras has contributed to ris- cally owned establishments, even when con- ing demand for skilled labor. Slaughter (2002) trolling for a wide range of observable worker finds a robust and positive correlation be- or plant characteristics such as industry, tween skill upgrading and the presence of U.S. region, and overall size. The magnitudes in- foreign affiliates. This correlation is more than volved are significant. Doms and Jensen twice as large for the subsample of developing (1998) document that for U.S. manufacturing countries when compared with the subsample plants in 1987, wages in foreign affiliates ex- of industrial countries. ceeded wages in domestically owned firms by Participation in global production net- a range of 5 to 15 percent, with larger differ- works may raise the supply of skilled labor entials being enjoyed by production workers in developing countries. One channel can be than by nonproduction workers.34 The pre- the short-term activities by which individual mium could be accounted for by higher firms interact with host-country labor markets worker productivity as a result of multination- through on-the-job training or support for als' superior technology or capital. It could local educational institutions. Multinationals also be a result of other factors, such as higher might directly affect labor supplies, because worker productivity caused by unobserv- their transferred knowledge might boost the able worker qualities, or of multinationals skills of their employees (and, with labor being more profitable and therefore more able mobility, the skills of the employees of domes- to share more rents with workers. Whatever tic firms as well). They might indirectly affect the case, the bottom line is that global pro- labor supplies (for example, by influencing the duction networks are likely to present high- educational infrastructure of host countries in wage opportunities for both more-skilled and terms of curriculum choices and vocational less-skilled workers. training). As Hanson (2001) reports, Intel recently chose to establish a large assembly The benefits from networks can contribute and testing facility in Costa Rica, in part to growth and structural transformation thanks to Costa Rica's agreement to expand Improved allocation of resources, access to high school training in electronics and English technology, and increases in skilled labor can, (see also Moran 2001). Also, to the extent that in principle, make important contributions FDI inflows and trade increase the supply of to raising productivity and to facilitating the attractive employment opportunities, they transition from primary commodities to pro- may inhibit the emigration of more-educated ducing products with higher value added and workers to industrial countries. For example, greater potential for growth. However, the ex- the 1 990s boom in Ireland, caused in large part tent of benefits from participation in networks 64 C H A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N E SS O R G A N I Z A I I O N is an empirical question. Local firms may not participation in networks.37 The failure of capture the benefit from the transfer of tech- manufacturing value added to rise as a share nology and increased productivity through of GDP reflects the rapid rise in services as in- networks if multinationals have a wide choice come rises, particularly in these fast-growing of production locations and a monopsonist economies. That network participants did position in the purchase of supplies. In this achieve significanit structural change is indi- situation, competition among suppliers may cated by the rapid fall in the share of agricul- drive prices down, and the benefits of local tural value added in GDP, from 17 percent in firms' productivity improvemenits will accrue 1980 to 10 percent in 2000. These data do not to the multinational.35 demonstrate that network participation was a Some observers have argued that the bene- major cause of growth and structural change fits from network participation have been lim- in these economies, but they do indicate that ired for most countries, with the important participation in networks has been consistent exception of a few of the most successful East with such progress. Asian countries (see UNCTAD 2002b). Rising Sectoral studies indicate that networks have manufactured exports thtough networks may enabled countries to move from low-value to not be accompanied by increased value added relatively high-value activities. For example, in manufactures, and network participation the global apparel industry contains many ex- may simply mean the continued use of un- amples of industrial upgrading by developing skilled labor in low value added activities countries.38 Several countries have shifted rather than the development of the manufac- from assembling apparel from Imported in- turing sector. For the 20 developing countries puts (whlich requires only low-wage labor) to with the largest exports of parts and compo- filling orders from global buyers. This latter nents (a proxy for network participation), the role requires the ability to make samples; to average share of GDP devoted to manufac- purchase or manufacture the needed inputs for tures has shown no increase over the past garments; to meet international standards in 20 years (table 2.4).36 However, average main- terms of price, quality, and delivery; and to as- ufacturing value added (at constant prices) sume responsibility for packing and shipping has increased by more than 5 percent per year the finished items. A few East Asian countries in these countries, a very respectable perfor- made this transition in the 1970s, then began mance over a 20-year period, aiid 2.5 per- to set up their own international production centage points more rapidly than the average networks in the 1980s using low-wage of developing coun1tries with limited or no countries in Asia and elsewhere. Since then, several countries (for example, India, Mexico, Romaniia, Turkey, and Vietnani) have devel- Table 2.4 Rapid growth and structural oped expertise in managing apparel produc- change experienced by network tion chains. Their role is likely to expand participants greatly as the apparel quotas under the Multi- " -. , ,,fibre Arrangement are phased out in 2005. Global production networks have been a Share of manu ,. GD ,., . central feature in the development and upgrad- added inl GD' 2. - . Share of agricuii.wf - mig of Asia's large, dynamic electronics sec- added in GDIP - - 10 3 tor. While the East Asian newly industrializing Memotern average annual - Eeconomies-Honig Kong (China), Korea, growth rate of tmianiutactrLring valLue added, 1980-2000 5 3 Singapore, and Taiwan (China)-were the first participants, the major Southeast Asian couI1- Note Data represent the 20 developinig economies (includinig Taiwan ICIniial) with largest exports of parts and componeints tries of Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippinies, Souirce World Bank staff and Thailand have taken places directly below 65 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 them in the production chain, including work- ing in design and setting up their own1 produc- Figure 2.17 Strong rule of law attracts tion networks. More recently, China has been foreign investors cvolving from a provider of low-wage, assem- (FDI) bly operations to the leading producer of elect- 3 ronics across a wide range of industries 2 (Borrus, Ernst, and Haggard 2000). Finally, 1 S ** exporters of fresh vegetables in Kenya and o, Zimbabwe have benefited from their relation- -1* ship with U.K. supermarkets, first through -2* * y=03996x + 00117 assistance in meeting production standards, _3 (t = 1 90) and more recently in taking on higher value -1 5 -1 -05 0 05 1 1 5 added activities within the production chain. Rule of law These activities have included packaging and Note Partial correlation for developing coLntries applying barcodes; investing in state-of-the-art controll iig for size, inicome, openness, inflation, education applymg Drcoues; nvestmg n state-o-tne-art Source World Bank staff methods for cold storage; adopting just-in- Source_World_Bank_staff time management techniques (including infor- mation technology) to reduce the time between law, and effectiveness of the regulatory regime harvesting, packing, and delivery; and expand- have been shown to be significant determinants ing to joint ventures with freight forwarders to of the location of foreign investment, after con- gain more control over the distribution process trolling for other variables (Stein and Daude (Dolan and Humphrey 2000). 2002). For example, figure 2.17 shows that a Of course, participating in networks has ranking of countries according to the rule of not always been accompanied by progress to law (see Kaufman, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton higher value added activities. Survey evidence 2000) is significantly related to the level of FDI indicates that East Asian firms participating inflows, after controlling for size, income, in networks have experienced an increased openness to trade, inflation, and educational propensity to innovate as they draw on for- attainment. By this measure, increasing the rule eign expertise (as well as increased export of law by one standard deviation (for example, growth), compared with firms in the same sec- from the level of Bangladesh to that of Turkey, tors that did not participate in networks or from the level of Turkey to that of Chile) (World Bank 2002a). However, networked would raise FDI inflows by 40 percent. firms did not show faster growth in employ- Time series analysis underlines the impor- ment or value added, on average, than non- tance of governance and institutional quality networked firms. The World Bank (2002a) for the allocation of FDI. Countries with better also found that few East Asian firms were able investment climates-as indicated by the level to move up the value chain through participa- of corruption, voice (political openness), rule tion in networks. However, these observations of law, quality of the regulatory regime, gov- are consistent with countries benefiting from eniment effectiveness, and political stability- network participation through spillovers and tended to receive an increasing share of total production by multinational subsidiaries. FDI over the 1990s (figure 2.18).39 The impor- tance of each dimension of the investment climate used in figure 2.18 varies considerably. Good policies attract FDI Countries that have strong rankings for regu- T he quality of the policy regime is an latory quality, government effectiveness, or T important determinant of the allocation political instability consistently received more of FDI flows among developing countries. than half of all the FDI to developing coun- Macroeconomic stability, corruption, rule of tries, with little change in their share of FDI 66 C II A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N SS o R G A N I Z A T I o N Figure 2.18 Foreign investors have been shifting away from weaker investment climate locations (percent annual shares of total FDI to developing countnes) Anticorruption Votce 100 100 75 75 50 50 11110 Il o) ) 00 io 0) 00) Q0 00 0) 0 ) 00 () 00 0 00, 0 0 0) 0) 00) o,1 00), 0) , ,. i, '.0- Weakest Below average Above average Weakest Below average Above average Rule of law Regulatory quality 100 100 75 75 50 50 25 25 0) 0 Weakest Below average Above average Weakest Below average Above average Government effectiveness Political stability 100 100 75 75 50 50 25 rii 25 0 0 4a 00 4o 00 50 0° 0)0 4) 400 4) 4)4 4)° 4°) Weakest Below average Above average Weakest Below average Above average Soiirce World Bank staff by the late 1990s when compared with earlier shares of FDI, the shares tended to decline in tn the decade. In contrast, the extent of politi- the latter half of the 1990s. For example, coun- cal openness has not been strongly associated tries with below average anticorruption efforts with the share of FDI received. And although received 70 percent of developing-country FDI countries with relatively poor rankings for rule in 1994, but only 50 percent in 2000, while of law and anticorruption received substantial those with above-average ratings doubled their 67 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 share from 20 percent to just over 40 percent. centives. Another hypothesis is that investors If one holds other determinants of FDI alloca- became more concerned about risk in reaction tion (including market size, openness, inflation, to the crises of the late 1990s, and that coun- and education) constant, corruption is signifi- tries with weak governance were viewed as cantly related to the share of FDI in the late relatively risky. Indeed, risk premiums on junk 1990s, but not in the early 1990s. bonds and on emerging market debt jumped Why should the share of FDI going to sharply toward the end of 1998, indicating countries with better investment climates have a shift toward increasing risk in the global increased during the 1990s? Remember that environment. total FDI flows to developing countries in- The boom in private infrastructure invest- creased very rapidly during this period. One ment during the 1990s highlights the impor- possibility is that countries with high levels tance of a policy for attracting foreign invest- of corruption or weak rule of law had other ment. Private infrastructure investment in attractions (such as high tariff barriers or in- developing countries surged during the 1990s, centives programs) that made them desirable rising from $14 billion in 1990 to a peak of locations for investment In particular sectors, $117 billion in 1997, before easing to $89 bil- while they remained relatively undesirable lion by the end of the decade (figure 2.19).40 locations for FDI in general. Countries that Foreign investors were involved in some offered such attractions for FDI were unlikely 80 percent of recorded private infrastructure to share equally in the FDI boom during the transactions from 1990 to 1998, although 1990s, which generally responded to the liber- foreigners accounted for only about 30 per- alization of economic policies and improve- cent of the dollar value of total private infra- ments in macroeconomic stability in several structure financing (Sader 2000). The boom countries. That is, countries with poor gover- in private infrastructure investment responded nance may have attracted a substantial to improvements in the investment climate in amount of FDI during the 1990s because of several of the largest developing countries. costly incentives. However, they would be Privatization programs opened infrastructure unlikely to attract increasing amounts of FDI sectors to private investment, and total priva- unless they were able to continually raise in- tization proceeds in infrastructure jumped Figure 2.19 Private infrastructure investment surged in the 1990s By region By sector (billions of dollars) (billions of dollars) 140 - 140 - 120 - ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~120 - 100- LAC,X, 100°~ Telecoms 100 EA ~~~~~~~~~~~~~100 - 80 - ECA 8 0 \ - 80 Gas & electric SA ~~~~~~~~~~~~~Transpari 60- SS A, , 60 - 40- 40- 2!0 20 0 - 19901991 199219931994199519961997199819992000 19901991 199219931994199519961997199819992000 Note MENA is Middle East and North Africa, ECA is Europe and Cenitral Asia, SSA is Sub-Saharan Africa, EAI' is East Asia and Pacific, SAS is South Asia, and LAC is Latin America and the Caribbean Souirce World Bank staff 68 C H A N G E S I N G L O B A L B U S I N E SS O R GANIZATION from $10 billion in 1990 to $40 biliton in Notes 1998, before faliing off sharply to $12 billion 1 A country's location may have an important rolc in 1999 (World Bank 2001). More gener ally, in attracting FDI flows For example, Caribbean cooin- efforts in several countries to open their tries benefit from their proximity to the United States economics to trade and investmenit and to 2. Data are from UNCTAD 2001. The data on establish more stable macroeconomic environ- cross-border IMf&A already introduced are nor compa- rable to the data on FDI Fot examilple, NMl&A is re- ments encouraged the surge in inifrastructuri-e ported on a transactions basis, while actual payments investment. that are reported as FDI may be spread ovei several The decrease in foreign investment in infra- years Also, the local financing share will be reported as structure projects among developing countries part of an M&A transactioni but will not be reported since 1997 largelv reflects a reduced demand as FDI. Thus It Is not useful to compare the magnitude for infrastructure services, owing to the crises of M&A flows with FDI in East Asia, Russia, Brazil, and Argentina. 3 Documentation and discussion of those merger in East waves can be found in Golbe and White (1988, 1993), For example, in East Asia and the Pacific, pri- Black (2000), Holmstrom and Kaplan (2001), Wlhite vate infrastructure investmenit collapsed from (2001), and Pryor (200 Ia) a peak of $38 billion in 1997 to an average of 4. Analysis based on Evenett (2002) less than $15 billion per year from 1998 to 5 These data are from White (2001, 2002) The 2000. 1n Latin America, p-ivate infrastructure number of coiporations refers to 2000 The share of investment in 1999-2000 was halved from the top 100 iefers to 1999 the 1998 peak of $71 billion. The drop-off 6 In the Fortune list of the largest 500 global com- panies in 2000 (as measured by ievenues), 12 were affected all sectors, with peak-to-trough de- headquartered in Chlin (iicliding Hong Koig), 11 in cines of 63 percenit in gas and electricity, Korea, 3 in Brazil; 2 each In Mexico, Russia, and South 57 percent in transport, and 24 percent in Africa, anid I eacch in Iidia, Malaysia, and the Repliblica telecommunications. Bolivariana de Venezuela The iemaininig companiles Although comprehenisive data are unavail- were headquarteied in Japan, North America, or able, foreign investment in developing-country Westerni Eurcpe inifrastruIcture projects has likely conitinlued 7 Choosing the appropriate indicator of conceni- tration is difficult Value added is clearly the superior to declinie in the past two years. The overall all-around measure of aggregate concentration, but It deterioration in the interinationial economic is not regularly reported by companiies in their public enivironimilenit has driven a sharp decline in coil- financial statemenits or in governmenit data AccouLnt- mercial bank lending to developing countries ing profits will depend on depreciation and amortiza- (net long-term lendinig from the banks fell to noni rates that vary across firms, and on corporate a negative $32 billion in 2001), anid funids for income tax rLules that vaiy by country Data oni sales poetfiniance have dried up. Also, the key in- will signiificantly distort thie relative imiportanice of e prolect tiainfrast ried secrso, u ties k ey til firmis (with large ratios of sales to valuLe added) ver- sus manufacturing firms. Measurinig concentration in Europe and United States), equipment manu- terms of assets would imply double counting for finan- facturers, and specialized venture capitalists cial intermediaries Moreover, reported asset values have seen their profits collapse, and in some would depeid oi alternative accouniting treatments for cases the firms have gone bankrupt. Most Of \e&A, changes over time In aCCounlting and tax t[eat- those firms are under pressure to recapitalize ment of asset depreciation, amortization, and write- and are reluctant to devote their limited re- offs, and changes in the treatment of expensing verSuS write-off for various categories of costs. To avoid these sources to high-risk ventures in developing inconisistenicies and definitional problems, we tise em- countries Finally, the scandals involving en- ployment data to analyze global conicenitration, but we ergy deregulation and the spectacular losses of also look at Indicators that are based on profits privatized telecommunications firms may have 8. White (2001) also reports a rise in aggiegate reduced support for the deregulation of service concentration in manufacturing alone from the 1 940s sectors, a key step toward providing infra- to the 1980s, and then a decline in the 1990s, based , , ~~~~~~~on value added measures, a decchnc in economy-wide structure services by the private sector. aggregate concentration in the 1970s, as showni by 69 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 employment and profit data; and a decline in aggregate and retail trade; travel, transportation; storage and concentration from the 1950s through the 1980s, warehousing; telecommunications; banking, finance, based on assets Somewhat similar conclusions are and insurance; entertainment; real estate; accounting reached by Pryor (2001b). and auditing; data processing; research and develop- 9. The only antitrust concern that might be raised ment; law; health; education; public relations; personal would be that of multimarket contacts among the assistance (such as auto and house repair, haircutting, largest companies. For discussions of the potential and and laundry); and public administration. actual influence of multimarket contacts, see Feinberg 16. See UNCTAD (1992), table 1.3, p. 18. For (1985), Rhoades and Heggestad (1985), Bernheim and Germany and Japan, the initial year is 1976 Whinston (1990), and Evans and Kessides (1994). 17. Services are becoming increasingly interlinked 10. The Forbes "Super 50" list is based on a com- with goods, especially in high-tech products in which posite calculation of sales, profits, employment, and the use of hardware requires various software and market value. maintenance service contracts. 11 The time series analysis is based on the Forbes 18. Williamson and Mahar (1998) detail moves list, which provides comparable data from 1994 to toward liberalization of banking sectors. 2001. The Fortune 500 list was not used because it 19. The importance of foreign bank participation in included several government-owned businesses. In par- developing countries has been discussed by several ticular, it extended in the latter years to a few state- authors (see Roldos 2002). owned Chinese companies, thereby distorting the 20 See World Bank (1997) for a discussion of the comparison with the mid-1990s. globalization of production and the developing 12. As stated above, calculations of aggregate con- countries. centration should not be based on sales data because of 21. The share declined from 1996 to 1999 because of the wide range of ratios of sales to value added found the abolition of tariffs under the EU's Association Agree- in different corporations. But this calculation is based ments, which resulted in companies switching from EU on changes over time, and presumably differences in to Eastern European firms for intermediate inputs. the growth rates of sales and value added are not as 22. This is a narrow definition of the share of trade disparate as the levels. conducted through networks, it excludes imported 13. World Bank computations are based on data inputs that are processed and sold as a final good in from the U S Bureau of Census and the Japan Ministry the domestic market. of International Trade and Industry. 23. Hummels, Ishii, and Yi (2001) attributed one- 14. Even if data were available, global trends in the third of the growth in world trade over the past number of companies in major oligopolistic industries 25 years to trade in parts and components, rather than would provide only limited information concerning trade in final goods. changes in the degree of competition. On the one hand, 24. Containerized shipment allows for better track- declining numbers of firms may be consistent with ris- ing of cargo, more efficient and reliable port services, ing competition, as lower transportation and commu- and greater ease of switching to land transport. nication costs enable formerly regional firms to enter 25. The volume of cargo shipped by airlines global markets. On the other hand, little change in the increased by 6 percent per year from 1978 to 1998, number of firms may be consistent with reduced com- and the share of revenue from international cargo in petition (for example, resulting from strategic alliances total air shipments rose from about 40 percent to well with the goal of coordinating prices or sharing out over half (Air Transport Association 1999). markets) (OECD 2001). 26. Deardorff (1998) points out that tariffs can 15 Services are products that are to a large extent either deter or stimulate participation in global net- intangible, nonstorable, and nontransportable. Intangi- works, depending on where they are imposed and bility implies that the quality of services is uncertain whether they are on final or intermediate goods. because of their high and variable human content and 27. The easing of restrictions on FDI flows in "one-off" nature of production Therefore, services developing countries has been discussed in various generally require proximity and close interaction editions of Global Development Finance between the producer and the consumer to ensure a 28. Chen (1996) lists alternative forms of prod- satisfactory level of quality. Nonstorability and non- uction relationships, including wholly owned affili- transportability imply that services must be produced ates, joint ventures, foreign minority holdings, fading- and consumed at the same time and at the same loca- out agreements, licensing, franchising, management non However, some services can be embodied in goods contracts, turnkey ventures, contractual joint ventures, or stored and transmitted through electronic means. and subcontracting See also Grosse (1996) for an Services include such economic activities as wholesale alternative categorization. 70 C 11 A N G E S I N G l O B A L B U S I N E SS O R G A N I Z A T I O N 29. FDI requires some advantage by the multina- 37 Excludinig Korea, Malaysia, and Taiwan tional over home production to compenisate for domes- (China) from this set reduces the group's average tic firms' superior knowledge of local markets, con- growvth rate of manufacturing value added to 4.3 pei- sumer preferences, and business practices (Blomstrom cent per year, still much higher than other developing and Sioholm 1998) countiies. 30. The example is given of a Singaporeani com- 38 General information on apparel is mainly pany in which some technology was transferred to a draviv from Geieffi (1999) and the apparel chapters local subcontractor, but critical components were in Gereffi and Korzeniewicz (1994) and Gereffi and unlikely to be outsourced. Kaplinsky (2001) 31 One concern is whether these data are distorted 39. The countries are classified into three cate- because multinationals may not report "true" prices of gories the worst group (more than half a standard goods traded amonig affiliates, but they will instead deviation from the average), below average (half a stan- increase the price (and therefore profits) of goods from dard deviation oi less from the average), or above low-tax locations and will reduce the price of goods average from high-tax locations. There is some evidence that 40. Technological inn1ovation also helped boost U S firms have followed this practice; however, the investment in iifrastructure over the I 990s For exam- oveiall patterns of prices are similar to the pricing of ple, flows to the telecommunications sector rose with goods tiaded between firms (Clausing 2001) Thus the dramatic reductions in the price of long-distance these data may provide a reasonably accurate picture service. of trends in intra-firm trade 32 These data refer to product categories identified as parts and components in the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) Revised 2 svstem. This References trade is a proxy for, but is not identical to, production Air Transport Association. 1999. "Aviation Economic through networks On the one hand, such trade may Impact " http:/fwww air-transport org/public/ also reflect the export of relatively undifferentiated industry inputs to arm's-length purchasers Conversely, many Aitken, Brian, Ann Harrison, and Robert E Lipsey goods that are parts to consumer products are not 1996 "NWages and Foreign Ownership: A Coni- identified as such in the SITC system. On balance, the parative Study of Mexico, Venezuela, and the data probably understate the extent of trade through Umted States " Jottntal of International Econom- networks (see Kaminski and Ng 2001) irs 40()May) 345-71 33 Howevei, Rangan and Lawi ence (1999) argue, Arndt, Sven W 2001 "Productioni Networks in an Eco- on the one hand, that the costs of search and assess- nomically Integrated Region " ASEAN Econzomiiic ment of reliability involved in choosing suppliers and Bulletin, Singapore, 18(1): 24-34 outlets will mean that even arm's-lenigth relationshlips Baldone, S , F Sdogati, and L. Tajoh 2002 "Interna- can be relatively insensitive to changes in relative prices tional Fragmentation of Production, Trade Flows, in the short term On the orher hand, multinationials and Growvth " 53rd Conference Paris March face smaller search and assessment costs because of 14-17 gleater international experience, so they are moIC Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Michael D Whinston likely to switch pioduction iapidly in response to iela- 1990. "Multimarket Contact and Collusive tive exchange rate changes They provide some empir- Behavior," Ranid Journal of Economics ical support for this view 21 (Spring) 1-25. 34 For additional U.S. evidence, see Howenstinie Black, Bernard S. 2000. "The First International and Zeile (1994) Griffith (1999) piesents similar Merger Wave (and the Fifth and Last U S. evidence for the United Kingdom, Globerman, Ries, Wave) " Unziversitt of Miami Lawv Revierv 54 and Vertinsky (1994), for Canada, Aitken, Harrison, 799-818 and Lipsey (1996), for Mexico and the Repiblica Blomstrom, Magnus 1986 "Foreign Investment and Bolivariana de Venezuela, and Te Velde and Miorissey Productive Efficiency The Case of Mexico" (2001), for five African countries Journal of Indistrial Economics 35(1) 97-110. 35. Conceivably, all sectors may be peifectly coin- Blomstrom, Magnus, and An Kokko 1998. "Multina- petitive, and the benefits of increased productivity will tional Corporations and Spillovers " Journal of accrue to consumers Economic Surveys 12(2) 1-31 36 This calculation excludes a few network partic- Blomstrom, Magnus, and Fredrik Sloholm 1998. ipants that lack adequate time series data on maniufac- "Technology, Transfer, and Spillovers Does Local turing value added Participation vith iMtultinationals Mlatter?" 71 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 Centre for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Ernst, Dieter. 2002. Global Production Networks in Paper Series no. 2048(December): 1-16. London. East Asia's Electronics Industry and Upgrading Borrus, Michael, Dieter Ernst, and Stephan Haggard, Perspectives in Malaysia. Honolulu: East-West eds. 2000. Iiiternational Production Networks in Center. Processed. Asia. London: Routledge. Ethier, Wilfred J , and James R. Markusen. 1996. "Multi- Campa, J., and L. Goldberg. 1997. "The Evolving Ex- national Firms, Technology Diffusion, and Trade." ternal Orientation of Manufacturing Industries: Journal of International Economics 41 1-28 Evidence from Four Countries." National Bureau Evans, William N., and loannis N Kessides 1994 of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper "Living by the 'Golden Rule': Multi-Market no 5919. Cambridge, Mass. Contact in the U S. Airline Industry." Quarterly Chen, Edward K. Y. 1996. "Transnational Corpora- Journal of Economics 109(May) 341-66. tions and Technology Transfer to Developing Evenett, Simon J. 2002 The Cross-Border Mergers Countries." In Transnational Corporations and and Acquisitions Wave of the Late 1990s. Bern, World Development London Routledge (on Switzerland: World Trade Institute Processed. behalf of the UNCTAD Division on Transnational Feenstra, Robert C. 1998. "Integration of Trade and Corporations and Investment), International Disintegration of Production in the Global Thompson Business Press Economy." Journal of Econoniic Perspectives Cho, Kang Rae 1990 "The Role of Product-Specific 12(4). 31-50 Factors in Intra-Firm Trade of U S Manufacturing Feenstra, Robert C., and Gordon H. Hanson. 1996. Multinational Corporations " Journal of Interna- "Foreign Investment, Outsourcing, and Relative tzonal Business Studies 21(2): 319-30. Wages " In Robert C. Feenstra, Gene M. Grossman, Clausing, Kimberly A. 2001. "The Behavior of Intra- and Douglas A Ihwin, eds., Political Economy of Firm Trade Prices in the U.S International Price Trade Policy. Essays in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati. Data." Bureau of Labor Statistics Working Paper Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, pp. 89-127. no. 333. Office of Prices and Living Conditions, 1997. "Productivity Measurement and the Washington, D C. January. Impact of Trade and Technology on Wages Esti- Deardorff, Alan V. 1998. "Fragmentation in Simple mates for the U S., 1972-1990 " National Bureau Trade Models." School of Public Policy. Research of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper Seminar on International Economics. Discussion no 6052 Cambridge, Mass Paper no 422. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Feinberg, Robert. 1985. "Sales-at-Risk A Test of DeGrauwe, Paul, and Filip Camerman. 2002 "How Mutual Forbearance Theory of Conglomerate Big Are the Big Multinational Companies>" Behavior." Journal of Business 58(April): 225-41. United Nations Conference on Trade and Devel- Filipe, Joao Paulo, Maria Paula Fontoura, and Philippe opment Geneva Processed. Saucier. 2002 "U.S. Intra-Firm Trade: Sectoral, Dolan, Catherine, and John Humphrey. 2000. "Gover- Country, and Location Determinants in the 90s." nance and Trade in Fresh Vegetables: The Impact International Atlantic Economic Conference of U.K. Supermarkets on the African Horticulture Paris. March 13-17. Industry " Journal of Development Studies 37(2). Gereffi, Gary. 1999. "International Trade and Indus- 147-75 (December). trial Upgrading in the Apparel Commodity Doms, Mark E, and J. Bradford Jensen 1998. "Com- Chain " Journal of International Economics paring Wages, Skills, and Productivity Betveen 48(1). 37-70 (June). Domestically and Foreign-Owned Manufacturing Gereffi, Gary, and Raphael Kaplinsky, eds. 2001 The Establishments in the United States." In Robert Value of Value Chains: Spreading the Gains from Baldwin, Robert Lipsey, and J. David Richardson, Globalisation Special issue of the IDS Bulletin eds., Geography and Ownership as Bases for 32(3). Econoniic Accounting. Chicago: University of Gereffi, Gary, and Miguel Korzeniewicz, eds. 1994. Chicago Press, pp. 235-55. Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism. Dunning, John H. 1981. International Production and Westport, Conn Praeger the Multinational Enterprise. London- George, Globerman, Steven, John C. Ries, and Ilan Vertinsky. Allen, and Unwin. 1994. "The Economic Performance of Foreign Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. 1999 "Interna- Affiliates in Canada." Canadian Journal of Eco- tional Technology Diffusion: Theory and Mea- nomics 27(1): 143-56 surement " InternationalEconomic Review 40(3): Golbe, Devra L., and Lawrence J. White. 1988 "A 537-70. Time Series Analysis of Mergers and Acquisitions 72 C H A N G E S I N G L O B A B U u S I N E SS O R C. A N I Z A 1I 0 N in the U.S Economy." In Alan J. Auerbach, ed , facturing Establishments." Survey of Current Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences Business 74(1). 34-59 (January) Chicago University of Chicago Press, pp 265- Hummels, D, J Ishii, and K.-M. Yi. 2001 "The 302. Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in 1993 "Catch a Wavc The Time Seties Behav- World Trade." Journal of International Econom- ior of Mergers " Review of Econonics and Statis- ics 54 75-96. tics 75(August). 493-99. Hummels, D., D Rappaport, and K.-M. Yi 1997 Griffith, Rachel 1999 "Using the ARD Establishmenit "Verical Specialization and the Changing Nature Level Data to Look at Foreign Ownership and of World Trade." Federal Reserve Bank of New lroductivity in the U K " Econonic journal York Economic Policy Reviewv (June): 79-99. 109(June). F416-F442. Kamioiski, Bartlomiel, and Francis Ng 2001. "Trade Grosse, Robert. 1996 "International Technology and Production Fragmentation Central European Transfer in Services." Journal of International Economies in EU Networks of Production anid Business Stidies Fourth Quarter 781-800 Marketing." World Bank Policy Research Work- Grossman, Gene M, and Elhanana Helpinan. 2002. ing Paper no 2611. Washingtoni, DC "Outsourcing in a Global Econonmy." National Kaufman, Daniel, Art Kraay, and Pablo Zoido- Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Lobaton 2000 "Governance Matters, from Paper 8728. Cambridge, Mass. January. Measuremcnt to Action." Finance and Develop- Hamernicsh, Daniel S. 1993 Labor Demand. Princeton, nient 37(2) (June) N J Princeton University Press. Keller, Wolfgang 2001. "The Geography and Hanson, Gordon H 1996. "Localization Economies, Channels of Diffusion at the World's Technology Vertical Organization, and Trade." Amierican Frontier" National Bureau of Economic Research Economic Review 86(5): 1266-78 (December) (NBER) Workinig Paper 8150. Cambridge, Mass 2001. "Should Countries Promote Foreign March Direct Investment?" United Nations Conference . 2002. "International Technology Diffusion." on Trade and Development G24 Discussion Paper University of Texas, Austin Processed. Series No. 9. Geneva. Kimura, Fukuniari. 2001 "Fragmentation, Internaliza- Hanson, Gordon H., Raymond J. Mataloni Jr., and tion, and Interfirm Linkages. Evidence from the M4atthew J Slaughter 2001 "Expansion Strate- Micro Data of Japanese Manufacturing Firms In gies of U.S. Multinational Firms " In Dani Rodrik Leonard K Cheng, and Henryk Kierzkowski, and Susan Collins, eds , Brookings Trade Forum eds , Global Production and Trade in East Asia 2001. Washington, D C. Brookings Institution, Boston, Dordrecht, and London: Kluwer Acade- pp 245-94 mic Publishers 2002 "What Drives Production Sharing Markusen, James, and Anthony Venables 1998 Within Multinational Firms?" Processed. "Multinationial Firms and the New Trade Helleiner, Gerald K. 1978. "Transnational Corpora- Theory." Journal of International Economics 46 tions and Tradc Structure: The Role of Intra-Firm 183-203. Trade." In Herbert Giersch, ed., Oni the Economn- Markusen, James, Thomas F Rutherford, and David ics of Intra-lndustry Trade Tubingen, Germany Tart. 2000. "Foreign Direct Investmenit in J C B. Mohr, Paul Siebeck, pp. 159-81 Services and the Domestic Market for Exper- Holmstrom, Bengt, and Steven N. Kaplan 2001. "Cor- rise." National Bureau of Economic Research porate Governance and Merger Activity in the (NBER) Working Paper no 7700. Cambridge, United States Making Sense of the 1980s and Mass. May 1990s " Journal of Economic Perspectives Mataloni, Raymond J., and Daniel R. Yorgason. 2002 15(Spring). 121-44 "Operations of U.S. Multinational Companies Hoon, Hian Teck, and Kong Weng Ho. 2001 "Arm's- Preliminary Results from the 1999 Benchmark Length Transactions versus Affiliates: A Study of Survey." Survey of Current Btusiness. Washington, Two Electronic Component Firms in Singapore." D C: U S Department of Commerce March. In Leonard K. Cheng and Henryk Kierzkowski, Moran, Theodore 2001. Parental Supervision' The eds., Global Production anid Trade in East Asia. Netv Paradignm for Foreign Direct Investment Boston, Dordrecht, and London' Kluwer Acade- anid Development. Washington, D.C.. Institute for mic Publishers International Economics August Howenstine, Ned G., and William J. Zeile. 1994. Navaretti, Giorgio Barba, Jai 1. Haaland, and Anthony "Characteristics of Forcign-Owned U.S. Manu- Venables 2000. Multinationzal Corporations and 73 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Global Production Networks. The Implications Slaughter, Matthew. 2002. U.S. Trade and Investment for Trade Policy. Report prepared for the Euro- Policy and the Growth of Infornation Technol- pean Commission Directorate General for Trade. ogy. Washington, D.C.. Emergency Committee London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. for American Trade Ng, Francis, and Alexander Yeats 2001. "Production Stein, E., and C. Daude. 2002. Institutions, Integra- Sharing in East Asia Who Does What for Whom tion, and the Location of Foreign Direct Invest- and Why?" In Leonard K. Cheng, and Henryk ment. Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Devel- Kierzkowski, eds., Global Production and Trade opment Bank Research Department. Processed. in East Asia. Boston, Dordrecht, and London: Te Velde, Dirk Willem, and Oliver Morrissey. 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers "Foreign Ownership and Wages: Evidence from OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Five African Countries." Centre for Research in Development). 2001. New Patterns of Industrial Economic Development and International Trade Globalisation: Cross-Border Mergers and Acqui- Discussion Paper University of Nottingham, sitions and Strategic Alliances Paris. United Kingdom. Pryor, Frederick L. 2001a. "Dimensions of the World- UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and wide Merger Wave." Jour,zal of Economic Issues Development). 1992. World Investnient Report. 35(4). 825-40. New York. - 2001h. "Will Most of Us Be Working for 2001 World Investmnent Report. New York. Giant Enterprises by 2028?" Journal of Economic . 2002a "FDI Downturn in 2001 Touches Behavior and Organization 44(April). 363-82. Almost All Regions " January 21. Press Release. Rangan, Subramanian, and Robert Z. Lawrence. . 2002b. Trade and Development Reports. 1999. "Search and Deliberation in International Geneva. Exchange: Learning from Multinational Trade United Nations. 1989. Foreign Direct Investment and about Lags, Distance Effects, and Home Bias " Transnational Corporations in Services. New National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) York, p. 8. Working Paper 7012. Cambridge, Mass. Venables, Anthony 1999. "Fragmentation and Multi- Rhoades, Stephen A., and Arnold Heggestad. 1985 national Production " European Economic Re- "Multimarket Interdependence and Performance view 43(5): 935-45. in Banking- Two Tests." Antitrust Bulletin 30: White, Lawrence J. 2001. "What's Been Happening 975-95. to Aggregate Concentration? (And Should We Rodriguez-Clare, Andres. 1996 "Multinationals, Care?)" Working Paper no. EC-02-03. Stern School Linkages, and Economic Development " American of Business, New York University. December 3 Economic Review 86(4): 852-73 (September) . 2002a. "Trends in Aggregate Concentration in Roldos, Jorge. 2002 "FDI in Emerging Market the United States " Journral of Economic Perspec- Banking Systems." International Monetary Fund, tives 16(Summer) Washington, D.C. Processed . 2002b. "Trends in Global Aggregate Concen- Sader, Frank. 2000 "Attracting Foreign Direct Invest- tration." Background paper for Global Econom- menlt Inlto Infrastructure Why Is It so Difficult?" ics Prospects 2002. Processed Foreign Investment Advisory Service Occasional Williamson, John, and Molly Mahar. 1998. "A Survey Paper no 12. World Bank, Washington, D.C. of Financial Liberalization." Princeton Essays in Sauvant, Karl P., and Padma Mallampally. 1996. International Finance no 211. Princetoni Univer- "Transnational Corporations in Services." In sity, Princeton, N.J. Transnational Corporations and World Develop- World Bank. 1997. Global Economic Prospects. Wash- ment Geneva: Routiedge (on behalf of the UNC- ington, D C TAD Division on Transnational Corporations and . 1999. Philippines- The Challenge of Econoniic Investment), International Thompson Business Recovery. East Asia and Pacific Regional Office. Press Washington, D.C. Schive, Chi, and Regina Yeu-Shyang Chyn 2001. . 2001 Global Developmeent Finanice 2001 "Taiwan's High-Tech Industries." In Leonard K. Washington, D.C. Cheng, and Henryk Kierzkowski, eds., Global Pro- - 2002a. East Asia's Future Economy duction and Trade in East Asia. Boston, Dordrecht, Washington, D C. and London: Kluwer Academic Publishers . 2002b. Global Developmieiit Finance 2002. Shatz, Howard, and Anthony J. Venables. 2000. "The Washington, D.C. Geography of International Investment." World WTO (World Trade Organization). 1998. Annual Bank Research Paper. Washington, D C. Report. The World Trade Organization. Geneva. 74 Domestic Policies to Unlock Global Opportunities Globalization makes it increasingly spected property rights-encourages invest- important to get the "investment ment and promotes economic growth. Many climate" right- countries try to use specific investment poli- Expanding global scrvice and production net- cies, such as tax incentives, to attract invest- works can accelerate growth in developing ment or to channel it in particular directions. countries that successfully harness competition Such schemes are often poorly designed, mad- to encourage efficient investment. Efficient in- equately implemented, and costly, and may vestment does not simply mean more invest- largely benefit investors who would have in- ment. In fact, recent research demonstrates vested anyway. surprisingly little short-run correlation be- tween investment levels and growth (Easterly -and promoting competition that will 1999). Instead, investment and its productivity increase the productivity of private are inextricably linked to domestic policies investment that, taken together, broadly make up the local In many countries, policy and private barriers investment climate. either have discouraged private investment or Sound enabling policies-including good have channeled it into less-productive activi- governance, institutions, and property rights- ties that reduce economic growth. Promoting can help attract more private investment, both a positive investment climate, however, does domestic and foreign. Policies that promote not imply a laissez-faire approach to the econ- competition and entrepreneurship increase the omy. Rather, it requires active government efficiency of that investment. Complementary efforts to reduce barriers that stifle entrepre- public investment, mcanwhile, further con- neurship and competition. Four policy barri- tributes to overall productivity growth. Taken ers to competition are especially common: together, sound policies in these three areas barriers to trade, restrictions on foreign contribute to a positive investment climate, investmenits, administrative barriers to entry which is essential to accelerating growth and and exit, and monopoly positions granted to reducing poverty (Stern 2001). state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and newly privatized firms. While pnivatization has usu- -including having an enabling policy ally improved the performance of divested framework- firms, shortcomings abound in subsequent A stable macroeconomic environment is essen- industrial performance. Those shortcomings tial for a country to realize its investment may be associated with regulations that potential. Good public governance-including reduce competition and grant exclusivity be- transparent rules, low corruption, and re- fore sale of the enterprise. In addition, private 77 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 barriers to competition-including price- Investment climate and investment fixing and other collusive practices-can in- policies duce resource misallocation. After establishing 11V,hlie foreign direct investment (FDI) an adequate macro policy framework, coun- flows to developing countries receive tries that lower both policy barriers and pri- much attention and have special characteris- vate barriers to competition can usually mini- tics that can benefit recipients, most invest- mize investment distortions. They can also see ment in these economies remains domestic in more capital inflows, more rapid growth in origin (figure 3.1).1 This fact highlights the trade, and superior overall performance. importance of policies likely to affect the level and productivity of all investment, not just Public investment plays a critical role foreign. Since the mid-1980s, the share attrib- in increasing productivity utable to public investment has remained The level and composition of public invest- fairly constant, while private domestic invest- ment has changed over the past two decades. ment has declined slightly as FDI has grown. The wave of privatizations has reduced the level and scope of public investment through Governance, corruption, and property state enterprises, and many sectors once rights matter- thought to be natural monopolies can now One critical dimension of the domestic policy be exposed to competition. Public resources environment is whether the government formerly used to subsidize loss-making SOEs operates with transparency, credibility, and can potentially be used where the private sec- stability. Good governance-including inde- tor is unlikely to invest enough: education, pendent agencies, mechanisms for citizens to rural roads, and expanded access to under- monitor public behavior, and rules that con- served areas in many networks. While always strain corruption-is essential to development a challenge, investment in effective infrastruc- (World Bank 2002b). Barro (1991) finds a pos- ture and human capital projects has an espe- itive relationship between growth and mea- cially high return. sures of political stability for 98 countries from Figure 3.1 Domestic capital is the largest source of investment in developing countries (gross fixed capital formation, percent of GOP) 30 25 _ 20 Private investment 10 6 _ Public Investment 0 - . . . . . . . I I l 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Note GDP is gross domestic product. These are the aninlual averages for I 1 J developing countries Private investment is calculated as the difference berween gross fixed capital formation and the sum of public investment and FDI Public investment data measure total public investment, including SOEs Souirce World Bank anid International Monetary Fund data, and Everharr and Sumlinski (2001) 78 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I E S r o U N L 0 C K G l O r A l O P P o R T U N I I I 1: S 1960 to 1985. For example, as discussed in licenises and permits. Recenit empirical re- chapter 2, countries with stronger rule of law search confirms that measures of corruption see imore FDI (figure 2.17). are significanitly and negatively related to Transparency is among the most important FDI inflows (Smarzyniska and Wei 2000; Wei components of the domestic enabling environ- 2000). Lipsey ( 1999) observes a strong nega- ment. Transparenicy relates to both the actions tive correlation between corruption and the taken by authorities and the broader business location choice of U.S. affiliates across Asian environmient of the host country. A nontrans- countries.2 Hausinann and Fernanidez-Arias parcnt business environment increases the (2000) find positive, albeit weak, evidence cost of inforniationi, diverts corporate energies that FDI as a share of gross domestic product toward rent-seeking activities, and can be con- (GDP) increases with institutional quality.3 ducive to corruption. Case studies suggest that Corruption and poor governanice often go companiies may, for example, be willing to hand in hand with lack of investor protections invest in countries with legal and regulatory and with poorly functioning institutions, frameworks that would not otherwise be thereby deterring competitioni and investment considered "investor friendly," provided the No investor-domestic or foreign-is likely investors can obtain a reasonable degree of to risk assets if there is a highi probability that clarity about the environment in which they those assets will be arbitrarily seized. Security will be operating. Conversely, extremely of private property helps ameliorate asymmet- opaque business conditions can deter virtu- ric ilforimiatioi between inivestors and the guy- ally all private investimient, regardless of the ernment and reduces investor uncertainties, extent of the incenitives. thus reducing risk premiums and the overall While these factors affect all participants in cost of doing business. Empirical literature the host country's business sector, they are provides unamilbiguous support for this basic arguably more discouraging to outsiders who point, finding that the institutions protecting are not privy to locally available information property rights are among the most critical and who have other choices about where to for growth (Knack and Keefer 1995), that invest. As with earlier relations, causality can productivity and economic growth will in- run both ways, because FDI may coiitribute to prove whien governments impartially protect creating a more transparent environmcnt. and define property rights (Claugue and There are cases in which a foreign corpo- others 1999), and that countries without rate presence encouraged more open govern- adequate property rights are likely to grow inent practices, raised corporate transparency, more slowly (Zak 2001). Moreover, historical and energized the fight against corruption. evidence from industrial countries suggests More generally, by observing commonly that when ilivestors face the threat of asset agreed standards such as those in the Conven- expropriation, they are likely to charge much tion on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public higher prices to recoup investments quickly- Officials, implemented by the Organisationi if they choose to invest at all (Keefer 1996; for Economic Co-operation and Develop- Wallsten 2001c). ment (OECD), multinational firms can con- tribute to raising standards for corporate -but policies to channel private social responsibility in host countries. investment warrant caution- Corruption can deter foreign investors by Building a strong and stable investment cli- increasing transaction costs and by raising mate is neither easy nor quick. Governments uncertainty regarding the enforcement of may hope to jump-start the process or to coni- contracts, the predictability of operating pensate for a poor investment climate through costs, and the likelihood of obtaining needed targeted policies intended to draw investors 79 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 (usually foreign). Similarly, governments may tries each try to give the biggest incentives to compete for foreign investment in higher investors. In this section, we will consider value added industries as a way of moving up three common policies: tax incentives to en- the technology hierarchy of international trade courage FDI, subsidies to promote industrial and production. The lure of targeted policies "clusters," and measures to encourage indus- is clear: incentives can be legislated quickly, trial development through export processing and investment that occurs after the incentives zones (EPZs). are in place can be touted as a success. While actual success stories exist, they tend to be the Tax incentives for FDL Given the perceived exception rather than the rule because a com- benefits of FDI, many countries have explicit bination of design flaws and implementation policies to attract it. One recent study esti- failures could limit the hoped-for response. mated that 1 16 countries take a proactive Moreover, such schemes can be expensive, approach to FDI and offer incentives to for- with the risk that costs will outweigh any eign investors (Moran 1998). Figure 3.2 illus- benefits, that incentives will merely transfer trates the variety and frequency of fiscal and money to private investors who would have financial incenitives for FDI that developing invested anyway, and that incentives can lead countries offer. Typically, these policies focus to a "race to the bottom" as developing coun- on attracting particular types of investment- Figure 3.2 Incentives for FDI are varied and numerous Subsidized loans } VAT exemption on exported Inputs Reduction in local, municipal taxes/duties Loss write-off Export income treated preferentially _ Duty drawback VAT exemption for raw materials Raw material import duties exempted d Accelerated depreciation - -ECD countries VAT exemption for capital goods -Developing countries Lower tax rate Investment/reinvestment allowance Tax exemption/holiday Capital goods import duties exempted 0 10 20 30 40 50 Number of countnes Note VAT is value added tax Data on fiscal and financial incentives wvere compiled for 71 developing and 20 OECD countries The most common incentives (used in at least 18 percent of developing countries) are shown in the chart Source Bora (2002) 80 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P PO R r IUN I I ES or changing investors' conduct-rather than what is meant by an incentive. It is imiportant on improving the general invcstment climate. to distinguish betwccn the fiscal and financial Incentives designed to lure FDI can take the incentives (which are usually firm specific) forn of up-front subsidies that are designed to and the more general policies that promote help multinationals defray some of their fixed business activity. Evidence is uncontested that costs (financial incenitives), tax holidays (fiscal general policies matter a lot in attracting In- incentives), and other grants. The main goal of vestment. In a recent empirical analysis of the such policies is to alter either the magnitude or effect of U.S. state-level policies on the loca- the location of inward FDI. tion of manufacturing investment, Holmes There are three main categories of FDI (1998) found that the manufacturing share of incentives: fiscal-policies that are designed employment in states with a pro-business reg- to reduce the tax burden of a firm (including ulatory environment is one-third greater than loss writeoffs and accelerated depreciation); that in a bordering state without that environi- financial-direct contributions to the firm ment. Policies that encourage the adoption from the government (including direct capi- and adaptation of know-how-and other gen- tal subsidies or subsidized loans); and others eral incentives that apply across the hoard- that do not fall easily into either category. In are important and help foster a sound enabl- contrast to the industrial world, where the in- ing environm1ent. Examples include effective centives offered are usually financial, the over- enforcement of contracts, absence of red tape, whelming majority of developing-country adequate inifrastructure, and efficient traininilg incentives are fiscal (see figure 3.2). In a recent and education programs. study that included 71 developing countries, Under special circumstances, targeted FDI Bora (2002) concludes that fiscal incenitives are incentives may have positive effects. Many the most popular, accounting for 19 of the 29 government officials seem to think that such most frequently used incentives. Furthermore, incenitives work, as illustrated by statements the five most common incentives are all fiscal. from a number of representatives in the Work- Despite the popularity of FDI incentives in ing Group on Trade and Investment of the developing countries, the evidence of their World Trade Organization (WTO 11998i). effectiveness remains ambiguous. The United Several studies find that fiscal incentives do Nations Conference on Trade and Develop- affect location decisions, especially for export- ment (UNCTAD 1996) reports that incentives oriented FDI, although incentives seem to play can have an effect on attracting FDI at the a secondary role (see Devereux and Griffith margin, especially when one considers the type 1998; Guisinger and others 1985; Hines of incentive and the type of project. Con- 1996). However, fiscal incentives appear versely, Caves (1996) and Villela and Barrelx unimportant for FDI that is geared primarily (2002) conclude that incentives are generally toward the domestic market; instead, such FDI ineffective once the role of fundamental deter- appears more sensitive to the extent to which minants of FDI is taken into account. Further- it will benefit from import protection. Thus, a more, in a recent review of the literature on tax more nuanced view of the efficacy of incen- incentives and FDI, Morisset and Pirnia (2000) tives may be in order. Although useful for at- conclude that such instruments rarely make up tracting certain types of FDI, incentives do not for deficiencies in a host country's overall eco- seem to work when applied at an economy- noiTnic environment, and they fail to generate wide level (see Hoekman and Saggi 2000). the desired externalities. Overall, recent evi- Moreover, even when targeted, FDI incen- dence provides little support for those who tives may impose excessive costs on govern- believe that incentives will bring in extra FDI. ments, especially when fiscal incentives are To some extent, the ambivalent perspec- provided through special tax provisions. tivcs may reflect differences in views regarding Because benefits (a new manufacturing plant, 8] G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 jobs created) are visible, whereas costs are hid- some scope for international action to prevent den (tax revenues are forgone), governments suboptimal outcomes (see chapter 4). Second, may offer too much. Also, the existence of ex- there is the possibility that incentives offered cessive FDI incentives is not just a developing- by high-income countries will end up retain- country phenomenon-in fact, such incenitives ing or attracting FDI that would be more are far larger in industrial countries. For exam- efficiently used in developing countries ple, in 1996, Mercedes-Benz received a sub- (Hoekman and Saggi 2000). For example, sidy of $300 million, which amounts to a labor unions and local interest groups may subsidy of $200,000 per employee, from the oppose plant closures by offering excessive U.S. state of Alabama for establishing an auto incentives for firms to remain. Similar motiva- plant (Moran 1998). Similarly, following reuni- tions underlie the use of trade policy instru- fication, Germany paid a subsidy of $6.8 bil- ments such as antidumping. It is imlportant, lion to Dow Chemical, which amounts to an therefore, to distinguish between the loca- astounding $3.4 million per employee (Moran tional competition that may enhance efficiency 1998). and the use of investment and trade policies Additional concerns about the use of in- (such as antidumping) that alter the incentives centives emerge from their effect on the dis- for outward FDI. The latter policies are inher- tribution of rents between governments, ently inefficient because they protect industries host-country firms, and large multinationals. that are no longer competitive, and they in- Developing countries may be tempted to offer duce various related distortions that are well investment incentives to multinationals in documented in the literature (Finger 1993). part because of an expectation of technology spillovers to local firms. Yet, investment in- Clusters. In the past decade or so, the concept centives to multinationals can put local firms of industrial clusters has received a great deal at a competitive disadvantage, at least initially, of attention (see, for example, Porter 1990). The net effect is hard to estimate: perhaps While there is no standard definition of a clus- incentives impose a short-run cost on local ter, it is usually characterized as a regional firms, which may gain from foreign invest- agglomeration of firms in related industries ment in the long run. (along with complementary infrastructure and A selective use of investment incentives support services such as business, financial, can have strategic consequences among for- and legal) that all work together in a virtu- eign firms, especially when multinationials are ous cycle to attract new firms and to help pervasive in markets with a high level of con- existing ones grow. California's Silicon Valley centration. For example, an exporting foreign typifies the high-technology cluster, with its firm from a developing country (or a local host concentration of high-tech firms, premier firm) may find itself at a disadvantage with re- universities that actively interact with local spect to another foreign firm that experiences businesses, and venture capitalists. Cluster- a decline in costs resulting from an investment ing, however, occurs in many other industries subsidy. Thus, incentives can alter the distrib- as well and is quite widespread (Ellison ution of rents among multinationals. and Glaeser 1997; Krugman 1991, 1998). In Finally, the use of investment incentives by the United States, evidence of knowledge developing countries poses a possible interna- spillovers within regions (Jaffe 1989; Jaffe, tional coordination problem in two respects. Trachtenberg, and Henderson 1993) and very First, as noted earlier, the possibility of exces- small areas (Wallsten 2001b) is consistent sive incentive "competition" among develop- with the idea that similar firms may benefit ing countries may increase the likelihood that from proximity with one another. the "winning" country will have given away Although the policy interest may be rela- far more than it receives. This area allows tively new, clusters have been recognized for a 82 D O M E S T I C P O LI C I ES r o UN LO C K G LO B AL O P P OR T UN III ES long time. In 1920, Alfred Marshall (as cited In sum, while much evidence shows that in Davenport 1935) hypothesized three rea- clusters of firms are beneficial and occur nat- sons for the existence of clusters: the benefits urally over time, there is little understanding from a pooled labor supply, access to special- of how to create them from scratch and no ized resources, and information flows among experience to suggest that governments have market participants. Today, these main bene- any expertise in selecting activities where clus- fits are still associated with clusters. In a suc- ters might flourish. Bigger payoffs are likely cessful cluster, these factors generate positive to come from interventions to improve the feedback loops because the concentration of broader business environment. If governments people and firms will attract more people and are obliged to provide incentives to stimulate firms (Arthur 1994; Krugman 1991). cluster development, they may do better by With these potential benefits, it seems nat- encouraging expansion of existing clusters, ural that policymakers would want to start rather than by trying to pick winners and clusters close to home. Unfortunately, there is ending up simply transferring resources to the little evidence that active efforts to create clus- private sector without generating any positive ters tend to be successful. This result is in part externalities. related to the difficulty that governments everywhere have in "picking winners." With- Export Processing Zones. EPZs have become out any clear market signals about what activ- a prominent feature of many developing and ities or clusters might be viable, governments transition economies, increasing from 1 75 in have a fairly poor track record. Bergman and 53 countries in 1987 to 500 in 73 countries Feser (2001) argue that "in less developed by 1995 (Kreye and others 1987 and OECD regions a policy decision to concentrate re- 1996, both cited in Schrank 2001). Along sources on key industries, instead of more gen- with this increased prevalence, it is not eral infrastructure needs or other strategies surprising that EPZs now account for fairly that would serve best a broad array of indus- high shares of total employment in many tries, brings with it significant risks against countries-for example, as much as 6 percent which the gains remain unverified." In indus- in the Dominican Republic (de Ferranti and trial countries, research suggests that efforts others 2002). Despite EPZs' ubiquity in the to promote cluster developmenit througlh developing world, there is little agreement on science parks and public venture capital tend whether EPZs are an effective development to be unsucccssful (Braun and McHone 1992; tool. While some view EPZs as the first step Felsenstein 1994; Wallsten 2001d). down a virtuous path of liberalizing domestic Of course, this cautionary conclusioni does markets (Rodrik 1999), others believe that, by not mean that emerging clusters should be creating a special "property right" of value to ignored. Indeed, it may be that governments those who participate, EPZs represent an es- can draw on the problems such clusters face cape valve that curtails broader reform efforts when prioritizing where to undertake reforms. and that hampers overall liberalization and In other words, cluster promotioni may be developmncit. more successful when directed toward areas in The inimediate benefit of EPZs to the host whicih significant activity is already ongoing, economy lies in job creation, greater foreign as weil as areas where additional efforts on the exchange earnings, and, possibly, higher real margin by government may be the catalyst wages. In many instanices, workers seem to needed for further expansion. This type of perceive EPZ employment as an attractive selective interventioni may underlie the success opportunity. For example, Brown (2001, cited stories that do exist, such as Hsinclu Science in de Ferranti and others 2002) finds that Park in Taiwan, China (Saxenian and Hsu men and women employed in Mexico's 2000). maquila (maniufacturing EPZ) sector earn 31 83 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 and 38 percent more, respectively, than their Schrank suggests that smaller countries may peers in non-EPZ sectors. Similarly, in a sur- be unable to "transform feeble manufactur- vey described by Sargent and Matthews ers into world market-oriented firms" and are (1999, cited in de Ferranti and others 2002), less likely to draw themselves onto a "large- 73 percent of Mexican maquila workers in- country growth trajectory." terviewed reported their current job to be at Research does show that, in some in- least as good as their previous employment. stances, EPZs can be successful and can act Furthermore, worker welfare in EPZs is also as a catalyst for the rest of the economy (for improved through employer practices of example, Jayanthakumaran and Weiss 1997; providing worker benefits (such as medical Johansson and Nilsson 1997). Moran (2002) insurance), stable work schedules, and week- argues that EPZs will have only a limited ends off. Moran (2002) evaluates worker con- effect unless they are supported by efforts to ditions in EPZs in a number of countries and integrate them more fully into existing com- concludes that there is "extensive evidence mercial and industrial hubs and unless they that wages and working conditions in foreign- are located near existing or potential pools owned or foreign-controlled factories com- of better-educated labor. In particular, this pare favorably with those of alternative occu- argument implies that government efforts to pations." Moran (2002) further notes that the use EPZs to encourage development of demand for jobs is high and that workers "backward" regions that are far from existing tend to return to existing jobs following a industrial centers (where the infrastructure is holiday. English and de Wulf (2002) credit limited and skilled labor is scarce) are unlikely EPZs with creating more job opportunities to be successful. The more successful EPZ for women in Bangladesh, with reducing fe- experiments that Moran considers are in male poverty in the Dominican Republic, and Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, and the with raising wages for EPZ workers above Philippines. Those examples show how EPZs wages for workers in the rest of the economy. have facilitated a shift in foreign investment Beyond the direct effect of EPZs on job away from lowest-skill operations that are creation, a comprehensive evaluation of them limited to export enclaves toward higher-skill should look at two additional criteria. First, operations that are better linked to the rest of do EPZs actually encourage firms to export the economy and that provide both employ- (or to increase exports), rather than causing ment opportunities for higher productivity firms that already export to relocate into the (and higher wages) and better worker con- EPZ so they can take advantage of financial ditions. Without such complementary efforts, incentives? Second, do EPZs produce spillover EPZs risk becoming another entrenched effects by drawing local manufacturers into interest that simply maintains trade barriers the world markets, thereby indirectly bring- and delays broader market reforms. ing reform and enhanced competitiveness to a Another view of EPZs focuses on their role greater segment of the nation's producers? as "transition property rights." It highlights Schrank (2001) compares EPZs in the their function in helping the country steadily Dominican Republic and in the Republic of improve its investment climate. That is, EPZs Korea, arguing that market size is a major may act as a catalyst for the host economy, thus determinant of EPZ success. Despite the good sparking a sequence of beneficial changes in the performance within the Dominican Republic's economy. The experience of Mexico is highly EPZ sector, few benefits appear to spill over illustrative in this case: the transition began into the rest of the economy. Korean EPZs, with establishing maquilas in a 2-mile border however, are increasingly integrated with local zone, which was next expanded to 12 miles, suppliers, thereby helping to transform much then to entire states, and eventually to the whole of the economy into world-level competitors. country. In this case, EPZs were able to help 84 DO ME ST IC PO LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL 0 P 0 R I1 U N I T I E S improve the investment' climate by acting as large effects on productivity and welfare. In- a bridge between the old and the new systems. dustries generally function better when they operate in a competitive environment, and -and incentives cannot offset a poor richer and faster-growing countries tend to policy environment have more competition and fewer barriers to Governments may hope to make up for an entry. Changes in technology, global business unfriendly investment environment through organization, and regulation have created new incenitive mechanisms. But while there are opportunities for competition in areas that clearly examples in which targeted interven- had formerly been seen as natural monopolies tions (such as fiscal incentives, EPZs, or sup- (infrastructure) or that were considered neces- port for clusters) may indeed lead to higher sary to preserve domestic sovereignty (services, investment levels-and the jobs and related real estate, and the financial sector). Countries spillovers that go along with such levels-there that do not change their investment policies is unfortunately little evidence that such initia- and do not exercise well the powers and re- tives can be systematically successful. Instead, sponsibilities of the state-such as regulating the impression is that these interventions work privatized industries, providing education, or best when they work in support of broader re- enforcing conditions of competition-will form packages, either to catalyze support for forgo poverty-reducing growth opportunities. emerging opportunities (such as clusters) or to At the broadest level, competition and ease create an initial constituency for reform that of entry are both positively correlated with can be progressively expanded (such as EPZs). economic growth (figure 3.3). A host of policy But more broadly, as Wells and others (2001) and private barriers in developing countries note, "Incentives will generally neither make work to restrict competition. Restrictions on up for serious deficiencies in the investment trade and FDI rob an economy not only of environment nor generate the desired long-run potential sources of investment, but also of strategies." To encourage productive invest- one incentive for firms to improve productiv- ment and benefit from globalization, govern- ity. While causality goes both ways, both trade ments must tackle the challenges of promoting and FDI are correlated with higher produc- competition and entrepreneurship and of un- tivity of firms in an economy. But potential dertaking complementarily productive public competition does not come solely from inter- investment in areas such as education. We now actions with the global economy. Many devel- turn to these issues. oping countries still protect incumbent firms- whether state-owned or private-by giving them monopoly power even when there is lit- Promoting efficient private tle rationale for doing so. While such actions investment: harnessing may protect particular firms, they almost al- competition ways impose net costs on everyone else in the W 7Tthile a stable macro environment and country. Finally, other private barriers-such W good governance are important to at- as collusion, price-fixing, and cartels-block tracting investment, policies that promote con- competition and reduce welfare. This section testable markets and that protect against of the chapter reviews some of these barriers abuses of market power are required to ensure to competition, and details how they can harm that new investment is both productive and developing countries' economies. efficient. Of particular importance in this re- gard are investment and competition policies, Policy barriers to competition are a drag which are important elements of the invest- on productive investment ment climate and also are basic pillars of the Barriers to competition stemming from gov- economy's micro foundations that can have ernment policies can emerge either through 85 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Figure 3.3 Competition and ease of entry are associated with higher growth (GDP growth rate, percent) (GDP growth rate, percent) 14 14 12 12 10 10 * 8 ^ *,*+ 8 * 6 . * *t6 * 6 ,- 4 .-*S - -t - - -t 4 0 ---- 0 -2 -2 -4 -4 -6 | | | | | | t -6 I I I 3 35 4 45 5 55 6 65 7 35 4 45 5 55 6 65 Competition Entry Note "Competition" is the average response in each country to the question "in most industries, competition in the local markets is (I = limited and price-cutting is rare, 7 = intense and market leadership changes over time) " "Entry" is the average response to the question"Entry of new competitors (1 = almost never occurs in the local market, 7 = is common in the local market)." Although competition and entry rankings suffer from methodological problems related in part to averaging of responses across respondents (see, for example, Lall 2001, Recanatini, Wallsten, and Xu 2000), those rankings can, nevertheless, provide a useful starting point for more rigorous investigations. One important question that these figures cannot answer is that of causality do entry and competition make countries richer, do richer countries have more competition, or does something else altogether drive both growth and competition' What does emerge clearly is that poorer and more slowly growing countries seem to have less entry and competition Source World Economic Forum (2002), World Bank SIMA indicators dtrect channels (such as when governments dispersion), research strongly suggests that create state monopolies) or through tndtrect greater openness is associated with higher channels (such as when policy choices made in growth in both industrial and developing pursuit of other objectives end up limiting nations. Sachs and Warner (1995) find that competition). In this section, we will focus on openness is a highly significant determinant of four channels through which competition is growth and, combined with property rights, affected by policy choices: may even represent sufficient conditions for growth in poor economies. Kang and Sawada e Import competition (2000) find a similar effect of openness on • FDI competition growth. They argue that, combined with finan- * Administrative barriers cial development, openness increases growth * State monopolies and private barriers to rates in developing economies by decreasing competition. the cost of human capital investment. Maloney (2001) offers regional support for the above Import competition can enhance result, citing evidence that Latin American productivity economies that are more open and that possess The important role that trade plays in pro- a more developed knowledge infrastructure moting productive investment and growth will grow faster. Consistent with this result, has long been recognized. Using different mea- Cuadros, Orts, and Alguacil (2001) find that sures of openness to trade, including both openness positively affects Latin American its relative size (as measured by import and growth and trade through increasing FDI.4 export shares) and its degree of distortion Such aggregate results fail to answer the (as measured by average tariff rates and question of exactly how increased openness 86 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I E S 'I 0 U N L O C K G L O B A L O P P O R T U N I I I E S (however measured) is translated into faster markets. In figure 3.4, markups are lowest growth. One approach emphasizes the learn- (measured on the vertical scale) when import ing and productivity gains that occur as do- competition is highest and when there are more mestic firms confront more competitive world firms (the front corner), and markups are high- market conditions, become more efficient, est when import competition is low and when and begin exporting. Another more compell- the market is more oligopolistic (back corner). ing approach emphasizes the rise in import Import competition pressures domestic propensities that often comes with trade firms to be more productive. A recent study of liberalization. Increased imports place domes- Brazilian manufacturinig firms, for example, tic firms under direct competitive pressurcs finds that foreign competition induces quick, and indirectly induce technological innovationi marked improvements in domestic productiv- or cost-cutting restructuring that further en- ity and, over time, forces inefficient firms to hances competitiveness and productivity. shut down (Muendler 2002). Cross-country Research finds that price-cost margins data are consistent with these findings, sug- (markups above cost) tend to fall with import gestng that higher tariff rates (which make competition, though the direction of causallty imports more costly and thus less competi- is not clear, and that foreign competition tends tive), are correlated with lower productivity to improve manufacturers' efficiency (Tybout (figure 3.5). 2001). Hoekmnan, Kee, and Olarreaga (2001) In addition to the direct competition af- found that import competition (defined as the forded by greater openness to imports, higher ratio of import volumc to domestic consump- trade prevalence can create spillover opportu- tion in an industry) reduces industry markup. nities through which domestic firms can gain The effect of import competition is particularly access to (improved) technology without pay- powerful when a few oligopolists dominate ing full cost. In general, imports from industrial Figure 3.4 Competition from imports checks markups in concentrated markets 1 800 Markup 1 400 1 200 ~ mpo/d Cfltn,10 Ntote Import penletrationl is dcftnted as the ratio of Iiitport volulme to the dontlesoc riurpulr of asn induistry Sousrce Hoekmlan,w Kcc, and Olarrc.igi (2001i) 87 G LO BA L EC ON OM IC PRO SP E CT S 2 O 0 3 manufacturing sectors in which productivity Figure 3.5 High tariffs are correlated with increased moderately. Imports did not seem to lower productivity affect productivity in sectors with low or high (percent) productivity growth. Using industry-level 40 data, Keller (2000) finds that imports may 30 5 boost technology diffusion if countries receive 25 Average productivity _ a relatively high share of total imports from a 20 Average tariff rate high-technology trading partner. Hakura and 15 Jaumotte (1999) find that the share of imports 10 [ - from industrial countries has a positive effect s- t _ 1[1< _ 1* on total factor productivity. Finally, Xu and 0 I I _, Wang (2000) find that the share of imports of capital goods from high-technology coun- tries is significantly related to productivity increases. Source World Batik staff, based on survey of more than 5,000 firimis Competitive effects of FDI depend on policy- FDI can be a potential vehicle for increas- countries are positively related to technology ing competition. Multinational corporations diffusion and productivity growth (Eaton and (MNCs) tend to be more efficient and produc- Kortum 1996; Lumenga Neso, Olarreaga, and tive than smaller, purely domestic firms. While Schiff 2001). Sjoholm (1996) finds a positive MNCs' entry into the domestic market can relationship between bilateral import shares put competitive pressures on local producers, and patent citations for Sweden.5 And Coe the mere presence of MNCs does not neces- and Helpman (1995) find that industrial sarily increase competition. Because they often countries that receive a larger share of imports possess significant intangible assets (brand from countries with a high level of research names, technology, managerial skills, and so and development (R&D) expenditures will ex- forth), MNCs often supply different markets perience faster productivity growth.6 Despite directly (through domestic production activi- agreement that imports are an important ties) rather than through exports. Such assets channel for technology diffusion, studies reach may permit MNCs to wield considerable mar- somewhat different conclusions on the condi- ket power. Openness to trade, low barriers tions under which such diffusion is most likely to exit and entry, and other regulatory condi- to occur. Coe, Helpman, and Hoffmaister tions can in turn help limit the capacity of (1997) extend the results of Coe and Helpman MNCs to abuse market power in the domestic (1995) to developing countries and find that market. developing countries' total factor productivity While the relationship between competi- is positively related to their openness to trade tion and FDI remains complex, over time the with the industrial countries. Furthermore, competition-increasing association has become productivity in developing countries increases more prominent. Historically, FDI was often as imports' share of GDP increases. attracted to regions that were protected by Some research finds that manufacturing high tariffs, as firms calculated that it was productivity in developing countries depends easier to set up a subsidiary than to pay the on the complexity of imported machines tariffs required to serve the market through (Navaretti and Soloaga 2001). Choudhri and exports. Such tariff-jumping investment was Hakura (1999) show that imports are signifi- also motivated by the opportunity to service cantly related to productivity growth only in the domestic market behind the tariff barriers 88 DO ME S II C P O L I C I E S T O U N L O C K G L 0 B A L O P P O R1 U N I T I E S while shielded from competition from abroad. allowed high-cost firms to produce for the This type of FDI has a long history: in the local market at very high prices, cven though post-World War 11 period, many developing they could have imported much more cheaply. countries encouraged both domestic and for- An even higher share of domestic projects that eign firms to invest in high-priority industrial they reviewed had negative value added. sectors by imposing high tariffs, quantitative Encarnation and Wells (1986) found that restrictions, and other nontariff barriers, 25-45 percent of 50 projects studied (depend- along with providing various additional incen- ing on analytical assumptions) reduccd natio- tives (Caves 1996). nal income; again the main culprit was high Investment induced in such a way, however, protection. is unlikely to be efficient and, therefore, is less capable of providing a basis for sustained -and benefits are higher when trade growth. First, the empirical evidence suggests barriers are lower that tariff-Jumping FDI is "likely to be tran- One clear implicationi is that If countries are sient, lasting as long as the artificial policy- open to foreign investment, trade barriers can induced incentives" (Balasubramanyam 2001). and should be kept low. Such openness to in- Second, it can harm welfare by increasing con- ternational competition will keep MNCs from sumer prices. In an era of much higher tariffs using high protective tariffs to exert market than generally exist today, Lall and Streeten power domestically and will discourage thcm (1977) found that more than one-third of the from joining domestic vested interests that are 90 foreign investments they studied actually lobbying for policies that perpetuate costly reduced national income. This reduction was rent-seeking activities. The cost of not doing mainly from excessive tariff protection that so can bc enormous, as illustrated in box 3.1. Box 3.1 Trade restrictions shield MNCs from competitve forces at enormous cost: the case of Argentina T rade and tax policy often interact in ways that subsidies were so lucrative that foreign (and some T magnify their competition-restricting effects. domestic) firms bought finished products in Japan; Newfarmer (2001) illustrates the importance of shipped them to Panama, where they were broken policy in determining thc net contribution of multi- down; and then shipped them to Tierra del Fuego national corporations (and domestic firms) by using for subsequent reassembly and resale in the main- the example of Argentina in the 1980s. In an effort land of Argentina. By 1990, estimates of the cost to encourage settlement of Tierra del Fuego, the to the (then-bankrupt) Argentine treasury ranged southernmost tip of the country (partly in response from 0.5 to 1 percent of gross domestic product. to territorial disputes with Chile), the government The winners in this scheme were the produciig set up a special production zone for assembling companies and a few thousand workers in Tierra electronic products with generous tariff protection del Foego; the losers were Argentine consumers and and tax subsidies. Firms were encouraged to businesses that had to pay high prices, thousands of assemble many types of electronic goods for resale workers who would have otherwise gotten jobs in to the highly protected Argentine market at more internationally competitive new activities on enormous markups. As a result, televisions in the mainland, and the Argentine poor, who, among Argentina routinely exceeded international prices others, had to pay the tax of high inflationi to close by 150-400 percent. The regime protection and the fiscal accounts. 89 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 In recent years, the incentives for tariff- this outcome is based on advantages associated jumping FDI have declined. Barriers to trade with greater efficiency, and if the resulting have come down considerably. As the impor- market structure remains reasonably compe- tance of production networks has risen, for- titive, these effects are generally positive. Fur- eign investors have found barriers to entry and thermore, MNCs could spark the entry of less-competitive environments less appealing. productive suppliers, encourage greater inno- In more recent studies, foreign investmenit is vation, increase the variety of available prod- deterred by high taxes or nontariff barriers ucts, and drive down prices. However, if a on imported inputs and is attracted to more- domestic firm's exit is driven more by the mar- open economies. In reviewing cross-country ket power of the MNC and if the exit results regressions on the determinants of FDI, in greater market concentration, then the long- Charkrabarti (2001) argues that, after market run result may be less competition. size, openness to trade has been the most reli- The case study literature provides both pos- able indicator of the attractiveness of a loca- itive and negative examples. After reviewing tion for FDI (see Kolstad and Tondel 2002). the evidence, UNCTAD (1997) concludes that As figure 3.6 illustrates, there is now a signif- although there is substantial evidence that the icant negative relationship between high entry entry of MNCs yields new products and im- costs7 and the attractiveness of a market to provements in existing products, there is no foreign investors (controlling for other factors systematic evidence on whether it ultimately such as market size, macroeconomic stability, reduces consumer prices. The overall effect and human capital). should not be judged at one moment in time. In MNCs can have an indirect effect on com- the short run, some less-efficient producers will petition by affecting ownership and market likely be driven out of the market, while over structure. For example, with a blend of deeper time, more productive entrants will emerge. financial pockets, marketing skill, and supe- There is evidence that domestic suppliers to rior product or process technology, MNCs MNCs enjoy higher productivity, both in levels may drive a significant number of domestic and growth (see Blalock 2001; Smarzynska competitors out of business. To the extent that 2002). Thus, the net effect of FDI on competi- Figure 3.6 High entry costs inhibit FDI inflows (FDI) More Less Low Entry costs High Note Partial correlations conitrol for market size, humati capital, and macroecoitomic stability The entry cost measure used in the figure refers to the costs of obtaining the iiecessary permits and licenses and other procedures required to set up a new establishment See Djankov and others (2002) Source World Bank staff 90 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P P O R T U N I T I E S tion, per se, depends on the level of interna- of reform and "have usually been the fastest- tional competition in the industry and on the growing segment in transition countries" ability of domestic firms to increase their pro- (McMillan and Woodruff 2002). The scale of ductivity in response to increased competition. entry that occurs when reforms promote com- Perhaps because the channels through petition can be impressive. Deng Xiaoping which FDI affects competition will vary de- expressed his surprise that "all sorts of en- pending on the institutional environment- terprises boomed in the countryside, as if a tariff structure, market size, competition strange army appeared suddenly from policy-the empirical findings about the nowhere" less than a decade after the first re- effect of FDI on growth are also mixed. FDI forms in China in 1978 (Zhou 1996 as quoted should contribute positively to growth, be- in McMillan and Woodruff 2002). Key to cause it can bring capital, technology, skilled promoting entrepreneurship and to improv- management, and technical staffs, plus busi- ing productivity is an environment that facili- ness practices that are usually more modern. tates entry and exit of firms (see, for example, Indeed, several econometric studies have Lansbury and Mayes 1996). Through this shown that, controlling for other factors, FDI process, poorly performing firms leave the flows are positively associated with economic market and dynamic new ones enter. Unfor- growth (for example, see UNCTAD 1998 and tunately, many developing and transition World Bank 2001 for all developing coun- governments fall to recognize that firm tries; Van Ryckeghem 1994 for Latin America; births and deaths are an inevitable corollary and Chunlai 1997 for China). of entrepreneurial risk-taking. Instead, those However, the direction of causation is not governments erect a maze of administrative clear: does FDI cause more rapid growth obstacles to starting, operating, and closing because of its associated characteristics, or is firms. FDI simply attracted to more rapidly expand- A growing body of literature documents ing markets to exploit growth opportunities? the difficulty that entrepreneurs face in estab- The answer is probably both. Theory does not lishing firms in developing countries (for ex- provide a simple answer because the institu- ample, Djankov and others 2002; Emery and tional settings and endowments are quite others 2000; Friedman and others 2000). varied and complex (see Cooper 2001). One Djankov and others (2002) compiled data on problem, for example, is that those elements entry regulations in 85 countries and discov- in the investment climate that are conducive ered enormous variation in the number of to FDI are also conducive to more domestic procedures required to start firms across investment and to greater growth in pro- countries, ranging from a low of 2 in Canada ductivity. Many of the methodological cri- to as many as 21 in the Dominican Republic tiques that Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999) and (with Bolivia and Russia close seconds at 20 Cooper (2001) apply to cross-sectional studies each). The time required to establish a firm of trade openness and growth also apply to ranged from 2 business days in Canada to 152 the somewhat less abundant literature on the in Madagascar. These procedures can be ex- relationship between FDI and growth. tremely costly to the economy. The cost of of- ficial procedures (that is, not including bribes) Administrative barriers are usually high for setting up a new business was 266 percent in developing countries- of per capita income in Bolivia. Djankov and Entrepreneurship is an important contributor others (2002) found that stricter regulation to economic growth and welfare improve- of entry is correlated with more corruption ments in transition and developing countries. and a larger informal economy. Moreover, For example, new firms created 10 million "countries with more open access to political new jobs in Vietnam in the first seven years power, greater constraints on the executive, 91 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 and greater political rights have fewer re- ings in countries where It takes longer to quired procedures for entry regulation-even start a firm, thus suggesting that keeping new- controlling for per-capita income-than do comers out of the market protects inefficient the countries with less representative, less lim- incumbents. ited, and less free governments" (Djankov and While exit barriers can be harmful, dealing others 2002). In a study of such obstacles in with a firm's exit is not simple. Ideally, bank- Africa, Emery and others (2000) discovered ruptcy and insolvency procedures rehabilitate that "when added together, this whole maze viable but financially distressed firms and of often duplicative, complex, and non- liquidate unviable firms. In practice, deciding transparent procedures can mean delays of up which firms are viable is difficult. Djankov, to two years to get investmenits approved and Hart, and Nenova (2002) note that many operational." countries have crude insolvency laws that Although policymakers and advisers tend push financially distressed companies directly to emphasize market entry, exit is important into liquidation, while other countries allow as well because it releases resources that can completely unviable companies to enter reha- be used in more productive ways. Healthy bihtation procedures. In the latter case, such economies have a high "churn rate" of firms, companies are often liquidated only after a and research demonstrates a strong positive long and expensive period of rehabilitation. In link between entry and exit (Love 1996). recent years, there is a growing movement in Moreover, as Caves (1996) has pointed out, insolvency reforms to introduce rehabilitation barriers to exit can be barriers to entry both procedures in countries that do not have them, by absorbing the scarce resources necessary but to allow creditors to replace management to start new enterprises and by making it dif- during the rehabilitation process (Djankov, ficult for new firms to compete. Entry barriers, Hart, and Nenova 2002). moreover, can become exit barriers (see fig- Barriers that limit firms' operating flexibi- ure 3.7). Claessens and Klapper (2002) find a lity exist even when entry and exit is not at smaller share of firms in bankruptcy proceed- stake. Friedman and others (2000) compile Figure 3.7 Barriers to entry can become barriers to exit (ratio of bankruptcies to number of firms) 8 7 6 5 4 0 o 0 50 100 150 200 Days required to start a new business Note Averages for 35 industrial and developing countries, 1990-99 The data panel used for cailculationi of averages is unbalanced that is, the enitire range of observationis (1990-99) was not available for some countries lThe measure of days required to start a new business is taken froin Djankov and others (2002) Source Claessens and Klapper (2002) 92 D O M E S T I C P O LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P PO RI UN III LS indices of taxation levels and overregulation see how such costs could quickly undo other (essentially, indices of the business environ- advantages that these firms might have when ment) of firms in 69 countries. Although competing in world markets. Friedman and others (2000) find no evidence A telling indicator of whether markets are that higher tax rates drive firms under- competitive in a country is the productivity ground, ". . . every available measure of over- dispersion of firms within an industry. In a regulation is significantly correlated with the competitive market with reasonably free entry share of the unofficial economy and the sign and exit, dispersion should be low because of the relationship is unambiguous: more unproductive firms either become more pro- over-regulation is correlated with a larger un- ductive or leave the market. Higher dispersion official economy." The important result here indicates that less-efficient producers are not is that higher tax rates do not seem to drive being forced to improve their productivity or away investors, but the myriad and often to exit the market. Firm-level studies in a arbitrary array of obstacles to starting and number of countries bear this out.8 Subsidies running a business do. or strict regulations that impede entry or exit can ultimately bolster high-cost producers. -and have real costs When such firms remain in the market, more The administrative obstacles have real costs to productive firms may not have either the ade- the economy, which means that even poten- quate incentives or the ability to increase pro- tially competitive firms often cannot compete ductivity or to grow. However, as competition because any efficiency advantages they may increases, firms face greater incentives to inno- have are consumed by the costs of administra- vate and greater penalties for failure to do so. tive hassles. Indian firms, for example, are Loss of protection and greater competition potentially competitive in a range of labor- from foreign firms can drive inefficient do- intensive industries; the combination of their mestic producers to better exploit scale eco- labor productivity and their wages makes nomies, eliminate waste, reduce managerial them low-cost producers at the plant level. slack, adopt better technologies, or shut down. The value added per unit of labor cost is lower As a result, productivity dispersion should in India than in East Asian competitors such shrink as productivity levels rise in the face of as Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand. greater competition. However, in practice this potential competi- Productivity dispersion-a measure of tiveness is often offset by investment climate inefficiency-tends to be associated with bar- bottlenecks, resulting in lower Indian exports. riers to competition, such as the administra- Several dimensions are of particular relevance. tive barriers to start a business for India, The regulation of factor markets, particularly China, the Philippines, Thailand, Malaysia, of labor and land, severely restricts the entry and Korea (figure 3.8). In Indian textiles, gar- and exit of firms. For example, firms with ments, and electronics, the higher performers more than 100 employees have not been have value added per worker that is five times allowed to retrench workers without govern- that of lower performers. The dispersion of ment permission. Meanwhile, the lack of cred- productivity is lower in four East Asian coun- itor rights and the severe backlog in judicial tries where the World Bank has conducted cases mean that India has one of the lowest similar surveys. In Thailand and Malaysia, levels of bankruptcies internationally. The the productivity dispersion ratios are just Confederation of Indian Industry estimates below 3, and in Korea not much more than 2. that proceedings can easily take more than Thus, more competitive countries in the group two years, and more than 60 percent of Iiqui- (as proxied by weeks to start a business) have dation cases before the High Courts have been lower levels of productivity dispersion than do in process for more than 10 years. It is easy to the less-competitive countries. 93 G LO B AL EC ON OM IC PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 countries. These administrative procedures Figure 3.8 Barriers to entry and exit vary across countries, with especially severe allow inefficient firms to stay in the delays in obtaining land and building permits. market They have found evidence that increased ad- (for productivity dlspersion, percent, for weeks, number) ministrative barriers deter foreign investment. 14 These findings are supported by a World 12 - Weekstostartbusiness Bank survey study that finds a similar result 10 r in a larger sample of 69 developing countries: 8 Produciviy there is a significant negative correlation be- 6 ~ ~ / r_ 1 | tween the amount of management time spent 4 VA; L- on obtaining the necessary paperwork and 2 ** **l * the levels of FDI (figure 3.9). 0 ** Eu 1 i Another obstacle to competition is mani- 0a Ss >s , F os 8fested in product delivery costs that go be- 1:P | yond producers' control and yet can have an enormous effect on their overall competitive positions. The effect of the quality of trans- Note Produictivitv dispersion serves as a measure of portation, as well as the performance of gov- inefficieiicy-more productivity dispersion means iltore iiieffiLient firms are allowed to stav in business ernment agencies such as customs admin- Souirce World Bank staff, based on suirvey of more than istration, can more than offset the cost 5,000 firms _____________________firms______________ advantage that producers enjoy at the factory gate. Indian textiles provide one such exam- ple. India's value added per unit of labor cost These obstacles can deter foreign investors. is lower than almost all its East Asian neigh- Morisset and Lumenga Neso (2002) have bors. However, if one takes into account the compiled data on the permits and procedures longer delays in clearing customs and the required for entry, access to land and infra- higher shipping costs, Indian textiles are much structure, and operation in 32 developing less competitive on international markets. Figure 3.9 Difficulties in obtaining licenses and permits discourage FDI (FDI) More y -0 5937x T 01851 0 v 0 ~0° 0 0~~~~ Less Less Time managers spend obtaining permits More Noie Partial correlations control for market si7e, human capital, anid macroeconomic stability Source World Bank staff 94 D O MI E S I I C ro I c I s 1 u N l O C K C I, o B A l o P P o R I U N I T I E S Figure 3.10 Inefficient customs hurt Indian exports (average number of days to clear customs) (average number of days in India to clear customs) 12 30 f 02 20 6 1 5 Lsie 4 10 2 5 India China Korea, Rep of Thailand Garmnents Textiles Pharmaceuticals Souirce World Baiik staff, figures based oit firm survey data Furthermore, World Bank surveys rcport infor- mation on the numilber of days needed to clear Figure 3.11 Inefficient ports raise India's customs (see figure 3 10). Here, India scores transport costs far above competitors' poorly relative to Korea and Thailanid, with the transport costs time about 50 percent longer in lindia (anid (percent cost advantage compared with India of shipping triple what many OECD countries report) 9 But the issue is not only the average time, 50 Wesl coast, U S All U S but also the variances in clearance time. Fig- 40 East_C l ure 3.10 shows the longest delay In the past 30 u s year for a typical firm in thrce sectors in India. 20 Although the average clearance timie is I I days, 10 the longest delays averaged almost 28 days for ° garmenats and 25 days for pharmaceuticals.'0 -10 The transportation costs associated with Brazil China Indonesia Korea, Thailand shipping a container of textiles to the United Rep of States from India are more than 20 percent Source World ltliik stitf higher than shipping costs from Thailand and 35 percent higher than shipping costs from China (figure 3.1 I). Variations in maritimie distances explain only a small part of the gap. economics whilc producilIg just more than Delays and inefficienicies in the ports account 10 percent of GDP (World Bank 1995). But for a higher share of the difference In port state ownership on such a scale was not sus- productivity. Together, inefficient customiis and tamable. Many SOEs rcquired large subsi- ports can hurt the investmiienit climate and can dies from cash-strapped governments to stay erode comparative advantage. afloat, thus constraining government spendinig on other priorities. For cxample, it was esti- SOEs use resources inefficiently- mated that "divcrtinig SOE opcrating subsi- Another way in which states make competi- dies to basic educatioin . . would increase tion and entreprencurship difficult is by their central governmeint education expcnditures by direct ownerslhip of many firms and industries. 50 percent In Mexico, 74 percent in Tanzania, By 1990, SOEs consumed nearly 20 percent 160 percent in Tunisia, and 550 percent in of gross domestic investmiienit in developing India" (World Banik 1995) 95 G LOB AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 both public and private superiority). The Figure 3.12 Privatization revenues dominance of studies finding superior pri- soared in the 1990s vate performance is robust across all sub- (in nominal billions of dollars) categories" (Shirley and Walsh 2000). 70 Privatization usually improved financial 60 and operating performance in privatized firms 50 (see Megginson and Netter 2001 for a com- 40 prehensive review of the literature). This result 30 holds in industrial and developing countries alike (Boubraki and Cosset 1998a, 1998b; 20 1 11 4 4 l Megginson and Netter 2001). The finding is .10 -robust across case studies, cross-sections of firms from different industries within a given g t P t .R. # #? ts$ $ WP country, cross-sections of firms from differ- ent countries, and performance of firms be- Sosrce World Bank privatization databaseencotrs,adpfrmceffisb- fore and after privatization (Sheshinski and Lopez-Calva 2000). Moreover, other research suggests that privatizations tend, overall, to Driven in part by the high and unsustain- increase welfare (Galal and others 1994). In able fiscal costs of state ownership, countries other words, privatization tends not only to around the world embarked on a massive improve the performance of privatized firms privatization wave. Privatization revenues in and to benefit investors, but also to make the developing and transition countries increased country better off. from almost nothing in the early 1980s to more than $60 billion in 1997, before de- -and is more successful when combined creasing somewhat to $50 billion in 1998 with competition (figure 3.12). It was estimated that by 2000, Simply pointing out the overwhelming evi- cumulative privatization revenues worldwide dence demonstrating improvements in pri- had exceeded $1 trillion (Megginson and vatized firms, however, masks important Netter 2001). The bulk of privatization in differences across industries in the challenges developing countries occurred in services, par- and pitfalls of privatization, especially with ticularly infrastructure. regard to introducing competition. Some sec- tors, such as manufacturing, generally lack -and privatization improves firm any economic lustification for state ownership performance- from the outset. SOEs that have been priva- Overall, privatization has dramatically im- tized into such competitive markets-while proved the performance of former SOEs. State being freed from unprofitable government enterprises were substantially less efficient controls or social "mandates"-tend to per- than private firms. Shirley and Walsh (2000) form quite strongly. Indeed, studies show that reported that most of the extensive literature the most robust results occur from privatiza- finds private firms superior to state firms. tion in competitive sectors (Kikeri and Nellis Of 52 empirical studies, 32 found that the per- 2001). formance of private and privatized firms is "significantly superior to that of public Infrastructure industries present special firms," and 15 studies found "either that there challenges is no significant relationship between owner- However, in infrastructure sectors such as ship and performance, or that the relationship telecommunications, electricity, gas, and is ambiguous (different evidence supports transport, existing SOEs traditionally were 96 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES TO UN 1.0 C K G LO B AL O P PO RI UN III ES considered "natural monopolies." It was distinguish-and to varying degrees separate- almost an article of faith that, in these indus- the true, natural monopoly clements of a sys- tries, a single firm could provide services at tem from the competitive segments. Second, the lowest cost. In most of the world outside even when competition is feasible, a dominant of North America, such natural monopolies incumbent in a network industry often has translated into state-owned monopolies from both the incentive and the means to thwart the 1920s through the 1980s. But by the late competition. 1980s, the combination of technological With privatization more likely to be suc- change, a clearer understanding of the costs of cessful in competitive sectors and with infra- state ownership and monopolies, and a wide- structure sectors, in gencral, less amenable spread failure of SOEs in developing countries to compctition, it is not surprising that expe- to deliver reliable services to consumers in riences in infrastructure privarization offer natural monopolies made privatization and more mixed outcomes. Perhaps not unexpect- competition both technically feasible and edly one key determinant of privatization suc- politically desirable. The benefits from this cess has been the degree of competition intro- process are clear: studies suggest that privati- duced in the regulatory regime. As Ambrose, zation or contracting out of public services, Hennemeyer, and Chapoii (1990) note, including many infrastructure services-if "[Slimply moving a monopoly from the pub- done right-can yield efficiency gains equiv- lic to the private sphere will not rcsult in com- alent to 10 to 30 percent of previous cost petitive behavior." Another factor affecting (Bartone and others 1991; Carnaghan and success relates to the sequencing of sector Bracewell-Milnes 1993; Domberger and reforms (including privatization) and the cre- Piggott 1994). When real competition is not ation of the regulatory institutions that are or cannot be introduced, it is more likely that necessary to achieve the broader objectives, privatizationi will be less effective, and well- including promoting competition. Policy run public firms may do as well as private reforms such as privatization often have ones (Kwoka 1996). But even in these cir- proceeded faster than the necessary support- cumstances, many private projects have ing institutions manage (see, for example, outperformed public eiiterprises. Examples Wellenius 1992). This outcome is hardly sur- include the water sector in Argentina, C6te prising because privatizing a firm, complicated d'lvoire, and Guinea (Clarke, Menard, and though it may be, is a relatively straight- Zuluaga 2000; Noll, Shirley, and Cowan forward and discrete task when compared 2000). with building a regulatory agency where none At least two broad difficulties exist in pro- existed. Nonetheless, varied expcriences with moting competition when privatizing infra- privatization in the infrastructure sector cau- structure utilities. First, not all components of tion developing countries to develop a system infrastructure industries are equally amenable of checks and balances before privatizing sec- to competition; therefore, privatization might tors in which competition has until recently not be appropriate for all activities in a sector. been a foreign phenomenon. For example, relatively low-cost wireless tech- For several reasons, governments may sell nologies make most elements of telecommuni- off state monopolies and may grant whole or cations potentially competitive, whereas gen- partial monopoly privileges to new private eration of electricity is more likely to support incumbenits. The government may face sub- competition than is transmission of electricity. stantial pressure to maximize privatization The key to successful reform in any sector is, revenues, and the first metric by which the therefore, an adequate reform of market success of the sale is likely to be judged is the structure to maximize the potential for real sales price. Privatizations tend to be contro- competition. Market structure reform tries to versial, and the government may be wary of 97 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 being accused of giving away the crown jewels tive environment and the monopolists face the if the sale price is too low. This wariness, plus same cost of capital, and neither will invest a need to build support for privatization, may unless the expected revenues make the invest- create an incentive to generate a high sales ment worthwhile. The monopolist's market price, even at the expense of future improve- power makes it less, not more, likely to un- ments in the network. These pressures may dertake a given investment because monopoly have been especially intense during the first profits are typically obtained by providing privatizations when there was little evidence lower quantities of the good or service at that privatizations could be successful or that higher prices. A firm with a guaranteed mo- failing state-owned firms could attract private nopoly is also likely to invest less because it investors. does not have to worry about more efficient Consider the growth rate of networks in competitors stealing market share. Even the telecommunications when investors were threat of entry-which is typically the situa- given "exclusivitv"-temporary monopoly tion when reforms are introduced-can be rights-compared with when they were not. enough to induce the incumbent to invest. In a sample of about 20 countries that pri- Indeed, in telecommunications, empirical vatized their telecommunications firms, one work consistently demonstrates that competi- study found that although private investors tion, typically in the form of mobile providers were willing to pay more for an exclusivity (which have much lower fixed costs than period (figure 3.13), telecommunications in- wire line firms) is extremely successful in im- vestment was substantially lower in countries proving telephone penetration (for example, that gave exclusivity periods than in countries Fink, Mattoo, and Rathindran 2002; Galal that did not (Wallsten 2000). In other words, and Nauriyal 1995; Li and Xu 2001; Ros investors wcre likely paying for the expected 1999; Wallsten 2001a, 2001c). Figure 3.14 streaimn of monopoly profits, not for the right illustrates how the penetration of the mobile to invest. telephone market in Africa is influenced by Another reason for granting monopolies is competitive versus monopolistic regimes. the mistaken belief that restricting competi- However, introducing competition-even tion can stimulate investment. As Noll (2000) when technically feasible-can be difficult. notes, both the firms operating in a competi- Incumbent firms can use their considerable Figure 3.13 Granting monopoly rights Figure 3.14 More competition means brings in revenues more phones (dollars per line) (mobile subscnbers per 100 Inhabiltants) 3,000 4 0 2,5003 2,500 , ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Competitive market S r_ 2,000 ,2;_ _ __;_ 1,500 20 500 _ _ 0 5 Noexclusivity Exclusivity 1996 1998 2000 2001 1996 1998 2000 2001 Niotr Average price paid in releconii privatiations Souirce African Telecommtniiication Research Project Souirce World Batik sraff Database, DECRG, World Bank 98 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I E S T O U N L O C K GC OIi B A lO P o R T U N I I I E S market power to ensure that competitioni never Table 3.1 Profitability on equity, succeeds. Taking full advantage of the compet- concentration, and market share (percent): itive forces in the global economy requires Brazil, 1971-78 introducing a regulatory framework that Four-firm maximizes competition. Establishing a clear concentratio- - regulatory framework in advance of privatiz- amo (CR4)! I L ing companies is key to achieving a competitive outcome. Wallsten (2002) studied 200 coun- 20 l - | 40 i 4 - tries from 1985 to 1999 and has found that, 60 l _ 60 l*. 1 4 -| . in telecommunications, creating a regulatory 80 14 I I 1- I I- I capacity before privatization is significantly 100 14 - I - i - i - and positively correlated with subsequent a CR4 is the ratio of foor largcst plants to total uicdUstry performance (using measures of capacity and sales, weightLcc by the fotir-digit grotip product grouip to sales of firni investment). Moreover, earlier existence of a b RMS is the ratio of firmn's sales to indLuistr) sile,, weighted regulator seemed to increase the price received by four-digit produLct sales of the firm for privatized telecommunications flrms by Source Newfarimicr and Marsh (1994) FigUres are hased o regressioni coefficicents holding other structural vai iahles (for reducing uncertainty over the future stream of example, size, leverage, capital iitenisity) at their 1eacis earnings.11 Regulatory agencies are discussed in more detail on page 27 and page 33. found a statistically significant relationship Private barriers to competition are between concenitration and firm profitability often difficult to identify and can in Brazilian manufacturing (table 3.1). Similar be pernicious results were reported by Connor (1977) for Even if policy barriers to competition are re- Brazil and Mexico. moved, private firms-usually in concentrated Interpreting these results, however, re- industries-can raise barriers to competition. quires care. Both concentration and profits In particular, dominant firms can exercise their could be high because firms exercise market market power to prevent entry by competitors power and block entry, or because better, in order to keep prices and profits high. Such more efficient firms are morc likely to succeed, anticompetitive behavior may be especially to capture higher market shares, and to be prevalent among newly privatized firms in more profitable (Bresnahan 1989; Feeny industries that are traditionally dominated and Rogers 2000). Nonetheless, empirical by a single firm, such as telecommunications. research-primarily in industrial countries- Another form of private barriers is collusive demonstrated that there is a great deal of behavior-often in the form of cartels-to fix market power in some industries and that prices and discourage entry. anticompetitive conduct can lead to high Early research explored links first between price-cost margins (Bresnahan 1989). And, as concentration and profitability and then be- Weiss (1989) noted, "[lUn smaller lands and/or tween concentration and prices. The underly- in nations with less enthusiasm for antitrust ing hypothesis in this line of research was that [than in industrial countries], the problem firms in highly concentrated markets would must surely be greater." earn higher profits (implying monopoly prof- Many believe that markets in general are its) and would be able to charge higher prices. less competitive in developing countries. With In general, empirical work supported this the exception of Brazil, China, India, and view, finding that firms in highly concentrated Indonesia, domestic markets tend to be small, markets were more profitable and charged with low human capital, poor infrastructure, higher prices (for example, Weiss 1989). volatile economies, and few manufactured In addition, Newfarmer and Marsh (1994) inputs produced domestically. Surprisingly, 99 G LO BA L ECO NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 though, some evidence suggests that manufac- horizontal and vertical restraints, of abuse of turing sectors, on average, are not less com- dominant market position, and of mergers petitive than elsewhere. As Tybout (2000) and acquisitions [M&A1) are similar, their notes, "[B]ecause of institutional barriers, scope, institutional design, budgets, staffing, labor market regulations, poorly function- and other resources vary widely. Competition ing financial markets, and limited domestic laws generally complement and buttress other demand, the industrial sectors of developing policies, such as policies on deregulation, pri- countries are often described as insulated, vatization, and trade and investment liberal- inefficient oligopolies. To date, however, there ization, that enhance competition. However, is little empirical support for this characteriza- the overzealous application or misapplication tion. Turnover is substantial in developing of competition law in the context of weak countries that have been studied, unexploited administrative capacity can also have serious scale economies are modest, and evidence of negative consequences. Effectively implement- widespread monopoly rents is lacking." ing competition law requires an adequately Nonetheless, he notes, "[lit would be foolish funded agency with well-trained, knowledge- to conclude that market power is a non-issue able, and experienced staff members. This is in developing countries." a challenge in industrial countries and even more so in the developing world.13 In this re- Collusive behavior and domestic cartels gard, some developing countries have made limit competition noteworthy progress, but it is still too early to A single firm abusing a dominant market form an overall view of the effectiveness of position is not the only way firms can engage their competition agencies. International in- in anticompetitive practices. Vertical restraints vestors have raised the issue that the prolifer- between manufacturers or suppliers and ation of competition laws has led to higher downstream distributors in the form of exclu- costs for M&A transactions-a primary vehi- sive dealing and geographic market restric- cle for FDI. And in some cases, the decisions tions can also raise barriers. In addition, firms arrived at by the competition authorities are that would be price-takers individually-and highly questionable. unable alone to control any significant part of The remedy for anticompetitive conduct of the market-can work together to control firms necessarily depends on a country's ca- the market, thus increasing prices and dis- pabilities. As the first order of business, all couraging entry. Collusive behavior is not countries are well advised to look for ways to uncommon, and competition authorities in reduce policy barriers to competition. Small- developing countries have prosecuted several market countries in particular can look to cases of price-fixinig, as the illustrative list in trade to discipline domestic pricing. Govern- table 3.2 suggests. In one colorful example of ments in countries with weak regulatory a bid-rigging conspiracy in the electrical equip- capacity, high levels of corruption, and poor ment industry (high-voltage switchgears), accountability would be better advised to do participants used the phases of the moon to the following: first, limit the powers of a com- determine which firm's turn it was to submit petition agency to review of government poli- the "low" bid.12 cies for their competitive consequences and, During the past decade, a number of devel- second, concentrate on improving information oping and transition market economies have and reporting requirements of firms so that adopted or strengthened existing competition increased transparency will attract entry. laws (see box 3.2). More than 90 countries Trying to establish more comprehensive com- have such legislation; more than half the laws petition authorities in countries without an were enacted since 1990. Although the core appropriate legal-economic framework may provisions of these laws (addressing issues of simply create another avenue for corruption 100 DO ME ST IC PO l IC I ES IO UN l O C K G l O B AL O P PO R r UN IIII S Table 3.2 Cartel enforcement in selected developing countries Country Year Market Acuons Bulgaria 2000 Intenrediate transportation Price-fixing 2000 I'honc cards sales Price-fixinig 2002 Gasification Contracts with non-compete clauses China 1998 School building Bid-rigging conspiracy 1998 Engineering construction Bid-rigging conispiracy 1999 Brickyard Bid-rigging conspiracy Estonia 1999 Taxi services l'rice-fixing 1999 Road transport Price-fixing 2000 Milk produicts Price-fixing Indonesia 2000 Pipe andl pipe-processilng services Bid-riggiiig Latvia 1998-99 Aviation Cooperatioii in organization of passenger flights 1959 Courier post Agrecissent betweeti two postservice coinpaniies l'eru 1995-96 Poultry market Price-fixing, voluime control, and cinspiracy to establish entry barrier 1997 Building and constructioii Bid-rigging 1999 Taxi tours Price-fixing Romania 1997 Mineral water Price-fimng 1997-2000 Drugs Conspiracy in market-sharinig in pharrmaceutical distribution Slovenia 2000 Electricity lPrice-fixing 2000 Organization of cultural events Cooperation anid establishment of enitry bartiers South Africa 1999 Citrus fruits Conispiracy relatinlg tri the purchase, packaging, anid sale of citrus fruits Taiwan, Chinia 1997-98 Wheat Buyer's cartel imposing quatitry control and quota system 1998 Mobile craines Bid-rigginig Liquefied petroleum gas Pu ce-fixing Ukraine 1999 Electronlic cash nsachines Price-fixing 2000 Kaolin Noncompete contract Zambia Not available Ploultry Agreement foreclosing competition 1997 Oil Price-fixisig Souirce OECD (2001) and rent seeking. Governments In countries Regulatory agencies may help promote with stronger regulatory capacity have many competition, but one size does not fit all options that go beyond policy review for One way that regulatory authorities can play competitive consequences and for improved a positive role in encouraging competition disclosure. They may be able to prosecute and investment has to do with bringing com- price-fixing and other horizontal restraints, as petition to industries that are dominated by well as prosecute restrictive marketing and a small number of firms or to industries in other vertical restraints that hobble entry. which cartels have developed. For example, 101 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Box 3.2 ComperHirdin pohcy and compeaion Iaw share sinilar objectives across ccmun%11i n recent years, many countries have enacted spe- predatory pricing) is more difficult to enforce Lcific legislation to safeguard and encourage com- because authorities must focus not on the firm's size petition. Enforcing competition (or antitrust and or dominance itself (which is not illegal) but rather antimonopoly) laws can increase welfare and can on the "abuse" of a dominant position. Competition improve efficiency by combating the negative exter- agencies must have the expertise to distinguish nalities generated by anticompetitive firm behavior, between dominance resulting from superior business The focus and objectives of competition agencies practices and dominance from erecting anticompeti- entrusted with this task vary across countries: tive barriers. some, such as Canada, New Zealand, and the o Vertical restraints between manufacturers, suppliers, United States, place the emphasis on consumer wel- and distributors (such as resale price maintenance, fare and economic efficiency, while others, such as exclusive dealing, and geographic market restriction) Brazil and the European Union (EU) member coun- can be tricky because such measures can improve tries, look to serve the broader "public interest." But efficiency just as easily as discourage competition. even with these differences in scope, the underlying The emerging consensus is that adverse effects are principles are similar. more likely to dominate if the participant firms enjoy The conduct provisions of competition law a certain degree of market power. Therefore, vertical relate primarily to the following: restraints should be evaluated within the context of AOD market competition laws. o Horizontal agreemnents are entered into by firms to fix prices (and agree to similar practices such as The structural provisions relate primarily to the bid-rigging; restricting output; and allocating market following: shares, geographic markets, or customers). Such agreements represent an unambiguous welfare loss to o Mergers and acquisitions, where the principal con- consumers in terms of reduction in price or output cems arise in horizontal transactions, and joint competition. Firms that enter into these agreements ventures compose two structural approaches. Two are severely prosecuted and, in some countries different views are prevalent. First, when transactions (Canada and the United States), such conduct is significantly reduce firm numbers or increase concen- treated as a criminal offense, with CEOs liable for tration, competition may substantially decrease. imprisonment. However, such anticompetitve behav- Second, transactions may be strongly motivated by ior is often difficult to investigate because managers efficiency goals, and substantial anticompetitive out- generally avoid written communication. As a conse- comes are likely only if there are barriers to entry or quence, some countries have adopted amnesty or to new competition. Because most horizontal M&A leniency programs for cartel members who are the activity will lessen competition but may also increase first to "blow the whistle" against other members. efficiency, a cost-benefit approach is often pursued in Encouraging new entry by removing both private which mergers are exempted or are permitted to and policy barriers may be the best policy to combat proceed on a restructured basis if the efficiency gains horizontal agreements because collusive behavior are likely to be greater than the competition losses. drops as the number of firms rises. o Abuse of dominant (AOD) market position (that is, monopolistic practices such as market foreclosure and Source: Khernani (2002). Galal and Nauriyal (1995) compare the per- balance regulatory objectives: commitment, formance of the telecommunications sector in information asymmetry, and pricing issues. In several countries before and after reforms as their sample, they find that the country they explore how well countries were able to (Chile) that resolved all three issues achieved 102 D OM N E S f I C P o L I C I E S T O U N L O C K G L O B A L O P P O R T U N I T I E S the greatest improvement, while the country tion "iS generally associated with greater cor- (the Philippines) that did not experienced the ruption and a larger unofficial economy, but worst performance. Countries that resolved not with better quality of private or public some issues but not others experienced mixed goods ... The principal beneficiaries rof reg- success. A more recent study of competition, ulationJ appear to be politicians and bureau- privatization, and regulation hints at the im- crats themselves." portance of effective regulatory institutions This observation does not mean that devel- (Wallsten 2001 a). Like other research (for ex- oping nations are doomed to failure when ample, Petrazzini 1996; Ros 1999), the study building effective regulatory institutions. It finds that competition resulting from priva- also does not detract from the general point tization positively affects network growth, that introducing competition in potentially but it also concludes that privatization brings competitive sectors that are dominated by a greater benefits in the presence of an indepen- single firm requires competent regulation that dent regulator. both protects consumers and assures investors Given the potential importance of regula- that their assets will not be expropriated. In- tory institutions in promoting competition, It stead, as already discussed, it suggesrs that rnay seem surprising that regulation has been such agencies should focus on promoting entry, given relatively little emphasis in developing not regulating it, and that they themselves countries. Three factors may have worked to should operate in an especially transparent diminish the focus on regulation. First, the pri- fashion to gain credibility. This feat is not easy vatization wave was picking up strength lust to achieve, and such agencies must find the del- as the United States and other industrial coun- icate balance between accountability and inde- tries were engaged in a process of deregula- pendence from short-term political pressures. tion, which often meant removing government controls to allow the industry to compete or to encourage new entry. Second, privatization Public investment in infrastructure in developing countries often faced competing and human capital objectives because governments want not only 11//hle the government plays a crucial role to maximize revenues from privatizing state- VW in providing a general framework to owned firms but also to improve the delivery encourage investmiient and in establishing the of service by firms in the industry. The easiest conditions that use competition to create effi- (and most common) means to increase the ciency, its role as a direct investor is pivotal firm's value for private investors is to include in shaping investment climate. There is some monopoly rights in service provision, but, Ull- question as to what effect public investment fortLnately, precluding competition is likely to has on private investmiient (see box 3.3). More- retard investment. over, all governments make public investments Third, the challenge of building effective that work through several channels: Govern- regulatory agencies is enormous and will not ments can invest directly in physical and automatically lead to better outcomes. These hutnan infrastructure provision. In addition, agencies are costly, require tremendous capac- their involvement in less-tangible areas (pro- ity in terms of human rcsources, and probably viding policy stability, setting standards, and work best in the presence of complemenitary establishing legal and regulatory frameworks) organizations such as competition agencies. affects opportunities even in areas in which Moreover, there is little evidence that, in gen- direct government involvenment is minimal. In eral, regulatory agencies in developing coun- this section, we wvill evaluate the scope and tries have been successful. Regulation often rationale for governmenit engagement in the takes the form of regulating entry, and, as areas of infrastructure and human capital Djankov and others (2002) document, regula- provision. 103 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Box 3.3 Does pubhc investmet "6crowd out" or 6crowd in" private investment? W hile direct government investment in the econ- Recent results from the developing world are ambigu- omy is necessary, direct expenditures should ous and show little consistency. For example, Ahmed be targeted carefully, because resources are scarce. In and Miller (2000) find general evidence of crowding particular, governments should not invest where the our, but note that public infrastructure expenditures, private sector is willing and able to go. A government such as spending oin transport and communication, can crowd out private investment in two general seem to crowd in private investment. ways. First, it can invest in areas where the private C hura and Goodwin (2000) report a crowd-in returns are likely to be high. Such investmenits result for a sample of 31 countries, but find more may tempt politicians because they can then tout variation on the regional level: Asian and Latin "successful" investments on the basis of their high American countries exhibit crowding out, while Sub- returns. But such successes are illusory because Saharan Africa shows that public and private invest- private investors would have undertaken the invest- ment are complements. In a slightly smaller sample, ments anyway, and there is an opportunity cost from Herrera and Garcia (2000) find crowding out in the suboptimal use of scarce government resources. both Latin America and East Asia, with the effect Second, using high governmlenit deficits and borrow- much stronger for Latin American countries. ing to fund public investments can indirectly crowd Everhart and Sumlinski (2001) add SOEs to the out private investment by means of macro channels definition of public investment and, with a sample such as pushing up interest rates-and thereby raising of 62 developing countries, find that corrupnon borrowing costs-or creating credit constraints for exacerbates crowding out. In fact, the effect of the private investors. Conversely, some government corruption interaction variable is so significant that spending can also crowd in investment by attracting in thc long run there may well be no crowding out additional private investment that would not other- if no corruption is present wise occur. The government may need to build Finally, Wang (2002), using ainual data for certain parts of the infrastructure to attract private East Asian economies (developing as well as indus- investors, to build roads that connect rural areas to trial), finds evidence of substantial gains from positive markets, and to make education universally available. externalities generated by the public sector, therefore In any particular country, it is likely that some hinting at crowding in. However, he cautions that in public investment choices will crowd out private in- the long run the influence of private production on vestment, while other choices will have the opposite public capital expansion is stronger than the reverse, effect. It is, therefore, not surprising that the empiri- which might indicate a causal chain in which higher cal research on which effect dominates is mixed. private demand leads to greater public investment. Aschauer (1989) argues that while public investment There is thus no consensus within the literature reduces private investment almost one-to-one by on whether crowding in or crowding out dominates. encouraging the private scctor to take advantage of Empirical results are often sensitive to sample choice public capacity instead of building its own, it is also and vary with regard to individual countries and true that public capital (and infrastructure capital time periods. Hence, whether crowding in or crowd- in particular) complements private capital in the ing out dominates may depend on complex interac- production of goods and service. Hence, public tions betweeni private and public investment. It is investment raises the marginal product of private possible that, up to a certain level, higher public investment so that-despite the direct negative investment may encourage private investment and effect-the long-term consequence of an increase in growth. However, when undertaken in excess (or public investment on private investment is positive. when existing capacity is used inefficiently), any These results, however, were based exclusively additional increases in the level of public capital on the United States, and a subsequent wave of cross- may crowd out private investment. country tests of the crowd-out or crowd-in hypothe- sis has thus far failed to yield any clear conclusions. Source: World Bank staff 104 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P P O R T U N I T I E S Infrastructure affects opportunities with stronger climates, there is significant for growth room for improving the climate in particular The quality and availability of infrastructure areas: moving to the best Indian practice has a major effect on investnment opportunities would add 1.5 percentage points to the in the private sector. World Bank (2002) notes growth rate for these states. Note that in many that "improvements in infrastructure services ways this is a conscrvative counterfactual can help promote competition in other mar- scenario because it would raise states to the kets, and there is evidence that infrastructure levels of regulation and infrastructure quality has a positive impact on growth and poverty that are already observed in India. If India reduction." In a sample of 100 countries, could achieve Chinese or Thai levels in various Easterly and Rebelo (1993) attach an impor- investment climate areas, its potential growth tant role to infrastructure capital-particularly acceleration would be even more dramatic transportation and communications-in eco- (World Bank 2002a). nonmic growth. Elemenits of infrastructure such The efficiency of infrastructure capacity as paved roads, telephone density per worker, utilizationi is just as important as (if not more and adequate generation of electricity have important than) the capital stock itself. been found to have a strong effect on growth Easterly and Levine (2001 ) propose that "cre- (see Easterly and Levine 1997; Canning 1999; ating conditions for productive capital accu- and Caniing and Bennathan 2000). Even in mulation is Imlore importanlt thanl accuminula- industries that have very low requirements tion per se and policynmakers should focus on for energy and transportation services, such as encouraging TFP Itotal factor productivityl the software industry, the quality and avail- growth." Hulten (1996) notes that those low- ability of infrastructure play a key role in se- and middle-income countries that use infra- lecting firm locations because firmns rely on structure inefficiently pay a growth penalty in satellite facilities to export their products the form of a much smaller benefit from infra- (Balasubramanyanm 2001). In addition to pro- structure investments. More than 40 percent moting economic growth, greater coverage of of the growth differential is due to the infrastructure services is also a key detcrini- efficiency effect, making it the single most nant of FDI (Balasubramanyam 2001; Stein and Daude 2001). Infrastructure is a key determinant of the Figure 3.15 Better infrastructure means quality of a nation's investment climate. A higher growth recent survey study that Iilked quantitative (annualaverage GDP growth rate 1992-98, percent) measures of the investnment climate to firm investment and growth experiences demon- 9 8 strates the potential for improvements in in- 7 frastructure. The study, which is based on 6 more than 1,000 firms in 10 Indian states, 5- _ finds that if each state could attain the "best 4- practice" in India in terms of regulation and 2 hi . infrastructure, the national economy could 1- grow about 2 percentage points faster (see fig- o ure 3.15). The gains would be particularly Good and best Poor climate All India large in the states with weaker investmenit climate states states climates (an extra 3.2 percentage points of Note Sirvey of more than i,000 firmns in 10 Itidiani states growth), thus reflecting the fact that the move Indtia in terms of infrasnent of r the best nd ractgceaiD from current to best practice in India would Sotirce World Bank staff be a large improvement. But even in the states 105 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 important explanatory variable in differential that for a sample of 98 countries, the growth growth performance. Similarly, Aschauer rate of real per capita GDP during 1960-85 (2000) attributes an important role to the was positively related to initial human capital efficiency variable, although he cannot reject (proxied by 1960 school-enrollment rates). the hypothesis of parallel importance of the Figure 3.16 illustrates this concept by showing quantity and effectiveness of public capital at a clear positive relationship between the 1970 conventional levels. Aschauer (2000) also cal- literacy rate and the growth in GDP per capita culates the growth-maximizing level of public between 1970 and 2000 for 75 developing capital, which is vastly exceeded by the actual countries. sample average of 46 developing countries. Easterly and Levine (2001) caution that Thus, it would seem that the average country economic growth differences across countries in his sample has overspent on capital expen- cannot be easily explained by factor (including ditures, thereby lowering the productivity of human capital) accumulation and should its public investment program. focus instead on technology and productivity growth. However, the success of dissemina- Investments in human resources are tion of more advanced technologies in devel- critical oping economies is largely determined by the Human capital is widely recognized as an absorptive capacity of the host country. That important determinant of development and is, to realize the growth potential of new growth. Seminal work by Manklw, Romer, and technology, the country must possess a high Weil (1992) demonstrated a significant im- enough stock of human capital to be able provement in the explanatory power of the to assimilate the technology. For example, Solow growth model when it included mea- Borensztein, De Gregorio, and Lee (1998) sures of human capital. Similarly, many en- show that the magnitude of the effect of FDI dogenous growth models have benefited from on growth depends on the available stock of the inclusion of an education variable (see, human capital in the host country. Within an forexample, Romer 1990). Barro (1991) found endogenous growth model, the researchers Figure 3.16 Greater literacy is associated with higher growth (1970 literacy rate, in percent) 120 100 80 ° 60 _ * C~~~~~~~~~` 20o ° ° e * Cu * 20 -100 -50 0 50 100 150 200 250 Percent GDP per capita growth rate, 1970-2000 Source World Bailk data 106 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P P O R T U N I T I E S obtain a positive and highly significant coeffi- human capital suffer the opposite effect cient on the interaction variable between FDI (Herrera and Garcia 2000). Thus, high levels and human capital. The results suggest that of human capital may help increase the overall "the flow of advanced technology brought level of investment through a crowd-in mech- along by FDI can increase the growth rate of anism. Countries with higher human capital the host economy only by interacting with also have lower fertility rates and higher ratios that country's absorptive capacity." of physical investment to GDP. Some evidence Several other studies have looked at the suggests that additional government expen- relationship between FDI and human capital. diture on education induces additional private For example, Coughlin and Segev (1999), expenditures on education. For instance, Noorbakhsh, Paloni, and Youssef (2001), Foster and Rosenzweig (1996) show that in and Kolstad and T0ndel (2002) show a India higher returns to primary schooling positive link between FDI inflows and the actually induce increased private investment stock of human capital in the host country. in schooling. Balasubramanyam (2001) notes that human Despite the overwhelming consensus that resources are a key determinant of FDI. human capital is one of the keys to sustained Countries with the highest levels of both economic growth, finding a robust empirical schooling and FDI grew much faster than relationship between education and growth countries with the lowest levels in the pe- has proven difficult (see Easterly 2001 for a riod 1970-89 (figure 3.17). Human capital is review). One striking example lies in compar- also important as an interaction variable be- ing East Asia to Sub-Saharan Africa: Between tween FDI and domestic private investment. 1960 and 1985 East Asia's per capita GDP Countries with high levels of human capital grew more than 4 percentage points quicker seem to experience crowding in of domestic than incomes in Africa, yet Africa's educa- investment by FDI, while countries with less tional capital growth was actually higher than Asia's (Pritchett 1999). However, part of the answer to this puzzle emerges from the multi- dimensionality of the investment climate: Figure 3.17 Education raises the education matters only if people are given productivity of FDI, which leads to higher opportunities to use their skills in productive growth industries in a supporting enabling environ- (per capita GDP growth rate, in percent) ment. Easterly (2001) contends that econo- 5 mies with low black-market premiums14 4 /High schooling on foreign exchange grow faster with higher 4 / schooling levels, while economies with high 3 * black-market premiums grow slowly regard- 2 Medium schooling less of the levels of education. That is, 2 L so "schooling pays off only when government __ 1_1 ~~~~~Low sch oling actions create incentives for growth rather mU w 1 wthan redistribution." High Medium Low FDI-to-GDP ratio Policies to promote competition Note The low, medium, and high categories for FDI-to- R1'hile competition and entrepreneurship GDP ratio are below 0.OI percent, 0 01 percent to 02 2AI percent, and more than 0 2 percent, respectively For the VV are essentially private sector activities, schooling variable, the low, medium, and high categories they require markets that function well. And are below 0 4, 0 4 to 1, and more than 1, respectively Souirce Borenszteun, De Gregorio, and Lee (I998). it is up to governments to ensure an environ- ment in which markets remain contestable 107 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 and entrepreneurship is rewarded, which is Competition and regulatory agencies can not easy. Entrenched interests are powerful, be instrumental in reducing abuses of market and it is often hard to determine whether power and in ensuring that markets remain any particular program is largely in the pub- contestable. Agencies can work toward this lic interest or in the interest of a much smal- general vision by focusing on two objectives: ler, but more vocal, private constituency. In protecting consumers while ensuring that the general, though, following certain basic prin- regulatory and market rules are credible to ciples can help promote competition and investors. These objectives, however, may be growth. difficult to balance when interests compete for Governments and government agencies regulatory favor. Moreover, there is the risk should operate with transparent rules, should that a new regulatory agency will become minimize corruption, and should respect another avenue for corruption, especially in property rights. They should also make it eas- countries with very poor investment climates. ier to start and run businesses. The maze of An agency will be better able to accomplish its bureaucratic paperwork that is often required objectives of correcting market failure while to start businesses in developing countries avoiding government failure if it meets sev- seriously deters entry into many industries. eral criteria. In particular, it must operate in Moreover, such administrative hassles can be a transparent manner, be accountable, be in- especially pernicious: in some cases they may dependent from short-term political pres- punish small, local entrepreneurs who lack the sures, have limits on its discretion, and have resources to overcome such high hurdles. adequate capacity to do its job. Having more government agencies that can The downside associated with failing to block a firm's path will lead inexorably to meet these criteria can be severe. For example, more points at which a firm is required to pay investment will be difficult to attract if regula- bribes to move the process forward. tory policies can be easily changed to benefit The government's role extends beyond any given politician's short-term objectives. setting up a generally investment-friendly en- Likewise, an agency that is not transparent vironment. Until the past decade or so, SOEs and accountable runs the parallel risks either have had monopolistic positions in many in- of frightening away investors or of being cap- dustries throughout the developing world. tured by the industry it is supposed to regulate The recent wave of privatizations not only has at the expense of consumers. Without limits to led to large efficiency improvements in these its discretion, meanwhile, an agency may seek firms and their provision of services, but also to expand its influence into new areas and has opened those industries to competition. may become primarily another obstacle to The greatest improvements in service have oc- development and an avenue for rent seeking. curred in industries in which the government Finally, if the agency lacks the capacity to do promoted competition along with priva- its job, it will simply be ineffective. tization and in which it avoided giving the This range of criteria highlights the point privatized firm any special monopoly rights. that-especially in regulatory and competi- Privatizations are often difficult and contro- tion agencies-one size does not fit all. The versial. However, governments should be optimal type of regulatory and competition aware that while they can usually increase the agency (if any) depends not only on the con- price that investors are willing to pay for a pri- ditions of the market (for example, to what vatized firm by giving the firm a monopoly, extent an individual firm can exercise market that same exclusivity usually lowers subse- power to thwart entry), but also on the extent quent investment. That is, investors will be to which the country is likely to be able to paying for the stream of monopoly profits, credibly design and run an institution that not for the right to invest more. meets these criteria. Larger, more stable 108 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I E S r O U N L O C K G L 0 B A L 0 P P O R T U N I T I E S countries with effective existing bureaucracies that they imperfectly reflect a country's trade policy are more likely to be able to meet all the crite- regime. The high correlation of components of the ria. Other countries may facc great difficulties. Sachs and Warner index with policy and institutional variables yields an upward bias in the estimation of trade restriction effects. Meanwhile, tariff and nontar- quately staff an agency can be quite sizeable, iff barriers, the two variables that directly mcasure potentially making it unrealistic for a small, trade openness, have little cxplanatory power when poor country. Some have suggested that when considered separately in cross-country regressions resources and skills are scarce, countries could 5. Patent citations refer to a requirement in some work together to create regional agencies in patent offices that inventors include in their patent order to share the costs and responsibilities. application the citations of the patented technology with severe problems of corruption that they used in developing their inventioni (see Branstetter 2000) These citatiois are used as evidence and with a lack of transparency, meanwhile, of technological spillovers. may have difficulty convincing consumers and 6 However, Keller (1998) finds that the role played investors that a new agency would behave dif- by import shares in determining productivity levels is ferently from how the government behaved in limited. Using the Coe and Helpmian (1995) model the past. A governmcnt intent on overcom- with randomly generated import shares, he also finds ing this reputation and on encouraging com- a positive relationship between foreign R&D and productivity petition may make some progress in two poutvt 7. The entry cost ilmeasure used in figure 3 6 refers ways: increasing the amount of publicly avail- to the costs of obtaining the necessary permits and able information on both firms and govern- licenises and the other procedures required to set up a ment agencies, and taking special steps to new establishment See Djankov and others (2002) for ensure the transparency of any new initiatives further details while emphasizing the discretionary limits of 8 See Hallward-Driemeier, larossi, and Sokoloff those agencies. (2002) for a longer discussion; Levinsohn (1993), Haddad and Harrisoni (1993). 9. Of the various regulatory agencies that are seen as obstacles, customs officials ranked second-only Notes behind labor regulators-as a major constraint to doing 1 Note that these investment categories are not business in India. strictly comparable because the FDI flows are taken 10 Delays are similar for clearing imports through from balance of payments statistics and include for- customs With such uncertainty, firms are likely to need eign inflows intended for both new investimient and to keep greater invenitories of materials on hand, thus acquisition of existing assets Meanwhile, the other incurring significant storage costs and tying up investmenit figures are derived from national accounts resources that could otherwise he put to more produc- and refer only to new investmenit. The "domestic pri- tive use. vate" category is calculated as a residual and, there- 11. This will not always be the case, of course A fore, may not match figures available from other country could easily enact a regulatory regime that sources. deters investors and increases the risk premium Yet, 2. However, his corruption indicator is correlated on average, regulator)' certainty seemed imiportanit to with other explanatory variables so that the coefficient investors. on corruption is not significant once other explanatory 12. See Scherer and Ross (1990), chapters 7 and 8, variables are included in the equation for a description of this case and others about 3 The rise in FDI is moderated because improve- collusion ments in institutions are also associated with a reduc- 13. Some commentators have suggested that it is a tion in FDI as a share of total capital inflows because mistake to encourage developing and emerging market other types of capital inflows are more sensitive to economics to enact competition laws because the risks instititional quality of misapplication are high as a result of weak institu- 4. Not everyone is persuaded by these cross- tional capacity. Such laws may also become another country regression results For example, Rodriguez and form of government intervention in markets and Rodrik (1999) argue that some indicators of openness may give rise to corruption However, suchi objections are highly correlated with other indicators of economic could also be applied to other policy areas suchi as rax performance-including macroeconomic policy-or collection, bank regulation, and so forth. The main 109 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 implication instead is that it is important, first, to de- Economic Growth?" Journal of International sign a system of checks and balances, including mea- Economics 45(l)1 115-35 sures for accountability and transparency, and, second, Boubraki, Narless, and Jean-Claude Cosset. 1998a to support institutionial building of capacity. "The Financial and Operating Peformance of 14. The black-market premium here is seen as a Newly Privatized Firms: Evidence from Devel- proxy for available opportunities for legal and produc- oping Countries." Journal of Finance 53(3): tive employment 1081-110. -_____ 1998b. "Privatization in Developing Coun- tries: An Analysis of the Performance of Newly References Privatized Firms." Public Policy for the Private Ahmed, Habib, and Stephen M. Miller. 2000. Sector. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. "Crowding-Out and Crowding-In Effects of the Branstetter, Lee. 2000 "Is Foreign Direct Investment a Components of Government Expenditure." Con- Channel of Knowledge Spillovers) Evidence from temporary Economic Policy 18(1). 124-33. Japan's FDI in the United States." University of Ambrose, William, Paul Hennemeyer, and Jean-Paul California-Davis, Economics Department Work- Chapon. 1990. "Privatizing Telecommunications ing Paper Davis, Calif. Systems: Business Opportunities in Developing Braun, Bradley, and W. Warren McHone. 1992. Countries." International Finance Corporation "Science Parks as Economic Development Policy. Discussion Paper. Washington, D C A Case Study Approach." Economic Develop- Arthur, Brian. 1994. Increasing Returns and Path De- ment Quarterly 6(2) 135-47. pendence in the Economy. Ann Arbor: University Bresnahan, Timothy. 1989. "Empirical Studies of of Michigan Press. Industries with Market Power." In Richard Aschauer, David Alan. 1989. "Does Public Capital Schmalensee and Robert Willig, eds , Handbook Crowd Out Private Capital?" Journal of Mone- of Industrial Organization Amsterdam: Elsevier tary Economics 24(2): 171-88. Science Publishers, pp. 1011-57. - 2000 "Public Capital and Economic Growth Brown, Cynthia J. 2001. "Gender in Mexico's Maquila Issues of Quantity, Finance, and Efficiency " Eco- Industry." World Bank, Washington, D.C. nomic Development and Cultural Change 48(2). Processed. 391-406 Canning, David. 1999. "Infrastructure's Contribution Balasubramanyam, V. N 2001. "Foreign Direct Invest- to Aggregate Output" World Bank Policy Re- ment in Developing Countries. Determinants search Working Paper Washington, D.C. and Impact " New Horizons for Foreign Direct Canning, David, and Esra Bennathan. 2000 "The Investment. Paris: Organisation for Economic Social Rate of Return on Infrastructure Invest- Co-operation and Development. ments " World Bank Policy Research Working Barro, Robert J. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross- Paper Washington, D.C. Section of Countries." Quarterly Journal of Eco- Carnaghan, Robert, and Barry Bracewell-Milnes. nomics 106(2): 407-43. 1993. "Testing the Market Competitive Tender- Bartone, Carl R., Luiz Leite, Thelma Triche, and ing for Government Services in Britain and Roland Schertenleib 1991. "Private Sector Par- Abroad." IEA Research Monograph: London. ticipation in Municipal Solid Waste Service: Caves, Richard. 1996. Multinational Enterprise and Experiences in Latin America." Waste Manage- Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge Uni- ment and Research 9' 498 versity Press. Bergman, Edward M., and Edward J. Feser. 2001. Charkrabarti, Avik 2001. "The Determinants of "Industrial and Regional Clusters: Concepts and Foreign Direct Investment: Sensitivity Analyses Comparative Applications." Regional Research of Cross-Country Regressions " Kyklos 54(1): Institute, West Virginia University, Morgantown. 89-114. Blalock, Garrick. 2001. "Technology From Foreign Choudhri, Ehsan, and Dalia S. Hakura. 1999. "Inter- Direct Investment: Strategic Transfer Through national Trade and Productivity Growth- Explor- Supply Chains." Haas School of Business Work- ing the Sectoral Effects for Developing Countries." ing Paper. Berkeley, Calif. International Monetary Fund Working Paper Bora, Bqiit. 2002. "Investment Distortions and the Series. Washington, D.C. International Policy Architecture." World Trade Chunlai, Chen 1997. "The Location Determinants of Organization Working Paper. Geneva. Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Coun- Borensztein, E., Jose De Gregorio, and J. W Lee. 1998. tries." University of Adelaide Working Paper. "How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Adelaide, Australia. 110 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I E S T O U N L O C K G L O B A L O P P O R I U N I T I E S Claessens, Stijn, and Leora Klapper. 2002 "Bank- Mayer, ecis , Privatizationz antd Economic rmptcy Around the World. Explanationi for its Performance. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Relative Use " World Bank Ilolicy Research Paper Press. \Vashington, D.C. Easterly, William 1999. "The Ghost of Financing Gap Clarke, George R G , Claude Menard, and Ana Maria Testing the Growth Model Used in the Interina- Zuluaga 2000 "The Welfare Effects of Private tonial Fnalicial Institutionis " Joirnral of Devel- Sector Participation in Guinea's Urban Water opinett Econoniiics 60(2) 423-38 Supply" Woild Bank Policy Reseaich Woiking 2001. Thbe Elusive Quiest fol Gioivth Paper Washington, D C Cambridge, Mass M?IT Press. Claugue, Christopher, Philip Keefer, Stepihen Knack, Easterly, Williaam, and Ross Levine 1997 "Africa's and MIancur Olson. 1999. "Contiact-Intensise Growth Tragedy Policies and Ethnic Divisions Money. Contract Enforcement, Property Rights, Qutarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): and Economic Performanice " Jouirnial of Eco- 1203-50 nomnic Grovutb 4- 185-21 1 . 2001. "It's Not Factor Accumulation. Stylized Coe, David T., and Elhallan Helpillan 1995 "Interna- Facts and Growth M\odels." World Bank Eco- tional R&D Spillovers " European Econoniic nomic Reviewu 15(2). 177-219 Reviewv 39(5): 859-87. Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo 1993 "Fiscal Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander Policy and Economic Growth An Empirical W Hoffmaister 1997. 'North-South R&D Investigation " Jouirnzal of Monietary Economics Spillo%crs " Econouiicjoiurnal 107(440). 134-49. 32(3) 417-58 Connor, J 1977 Maiket Poever of Mtltiznationals. Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. 1996. "Trade in New York. Praeger. Ideas Patenting and Productivity in the OECD " Cooper, R 2001. "Groxvth and Inequality The Role of Jouirnial of lInterniational Economics 40(3-4) Foreign Trade and Investmenit." Paper presented 251-78. at ABCDE Washington, D C Ellisonl, Glenin, and Edward L Glaeser 1997. "Geo- Coughllin, Clerus, and Eran Segev 1999 "Foreign graphic Concenrtiation in U S Manufacturing Direct Investment in Chinia: A Spatial Economet- Indusnies A Dartboaid Approach." Journial of rics Study." Federal Reserve Bank of St LouIs Political Econom1y 105(5): 889-927 Workinig Paper St Louis Emery, James, MNIelvin T Spence, Louis T Wells, and Cuadros, A., V. Orts, and NI T. Alguacil. 2001 Timoth) Buelhrer. 2000. "Administrative Barriers "Openness and Growth: Re-examininig Foreign to Foreign Investmenit: Reducing Red Tape in Direct Investment, Trade, and OutpuLt Linkages in Africa." Internatioial Finance Corpoiation Dis- Latin America " University of Nottiighiam CLussion1 Paper Washington, D C CREDIT Research IPaper Nottingham, U.K. Encarnation, Deniis, and Louis T. Wells 1986 Davenport, H J 1935 The Econiomics of Alfred Mar- "Evaluating Foreign Investnmenit " In Theodore shall. Ithaca, N Y' Cornell University Press. Moran, ed., Investing in Development Neruv de Ferranti, David, Guillermo E. Perry, Daniel Roles for Private CaptialR New Brunswick, New Lederman, and William F. Nlaloney 2002 Jersey. Transactioni Books Froni Natural Resources to the Kio0uvledge Englisi, Phillip, and Luc de Wulf 2002 "Export Economy. World Bank, NWashington, D C Development Policies and InstititiolIs." In B. Devereux, Michael P., and Rachel Griffith. 1998 Hoekman, A. Mattoo, and P. English, eds , De- "Taxes and the Location of Production Evidence velopIpient, Trade, antd the WTO A Handbook. from a Panel of U.S. Multinationals." Jotirnal of Washington, D C, World Bank Plibitc Econonmics 68(3)' 335-67. Everhart, Stephen, and Mariusz Sumlinski 2001 Djankov, Simeon, Oliver Hart, and Tariana Nenova. "Tiends in Piivate Investment in Developing 2002 "Efficient Insolvency." Background Paper Countries: Statistics foi 1970-2000 and the for Doing Business in 2003 report Piivate Sector Impact on Piivate Investment of Corruption Advuisory' Services World Bank, Washington, D C and the Quality of Public Investment." Interna- Diankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez- tional Finance Corporation DIscussion Paper de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer 2002. "The Washington, D.C. Regulation of Entry." Quarterly Joufrnal of Feeny, Simon, and Mark Rogers 2000 "The Role Economics 117(1): 1-37. of Market Share and Concentiation in Firm Domberger, Simon, and John Piggott. 1994. "Privati- Profitability Implicationis for Competition zation Policies anid Public Enterprise A Survey " Polic)y " Economi0Zc Aialysis antd Policy 30(2) In Matthew Bishop, Johli Kay, and Cohn P 115-32 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Felsensteini, Daniel 1994 "University-Related Science Herrera, Santiago, and Conrado Garcia. 2000 Parks- 'Seedbeds' or Enclaves of Innovation?" "Aggregate Investment and Foreign Direct Invest- Technovation 14(2): 93-110. ment in Latin America and East Asia- Is There a Finger, J. M. 1993. Antidumnping. Ann Arbor: Univer- Crowding-Out Effect." World Bank Working sity of Michigan Press. Paper. Washington, D.C Fink, Carsten, Aaditya Mattoo, and Randeep Hines, James R. 1996. "Altered States: Taxes and Rathindran. 2002. "Liberalizing Basic Telecom- the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in munications: Evidence from Developing Coun- America " American Econonmic Review 86(5): tries " World Bank Working Paper Washington, 1076-94. D.C Hoekman, Bernard, and Kamal Saggi. 2000. "Assess- Foster, Andrew D, and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 1996 ing the Case for Extending WTO Disciplines on "Technical Change and Human-Capital Returns Investment-Related Policies." World Bank Work- and Investments: Evidence from the Green ing Paper. Washington, D.C. Revolution." American Economic Revietv 86(4) Hoekman, Bernard, Hiau Looi Kee, and Marcelo 931-53. Olarreaga 2001. "Markups, Entry Regulation, and Friedman, Eric, Simon Johnson, Daniel Kaufmann, Trade- Does Country Size Matter)" World Bank and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton 2000. "Dodging the Policy Research Working Paper. Washington, D C. Grabbing Hand The Determinants of Unofficial Holmes, Thomas J. 1998 "The Effect of State Policies Activity in 69 Countries " Journal of Public Eco- on the Location of Manufacturing Evidence from nomics 76(3): 4S9-93. State Borders." Journal of Political Economy Galal, Ahmed, and Bharat Nauriyal. 1995. "Regulat- 106(4): 667-70S. ing Telecommunications in Developing Coun- Hulten, Charles R 1996 "Infrastructure Capital and tries " World Bank Policy Research Working Economic Growth How Well You Use It May Be Paper. Washiisgton, D.C More Important Than How Much You Have." Galal, Ahmed, Leroy Jones, Tandon Pankal, and Ingo National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Vogelsang. 1994. Welfare Consequences of Sell- Working Paper. Cambridge, Mass. ing Public Enterprises- An Empirical Analysis Jaffe, Adam 1989 "Real Effects of Academic New York Oxford University Press. Research." American Economic Review 79(5): Ghura, D., and Barry Goodwin 2000. "Determi- 957-80. nants of Private Investment A Cross-Regional Jaffe, Adam, Manuel Trachtenberg, and Rebecca Empirical Investigation." Applied Economics Henderson. 1993 "Geographic Localization of 32(14): 1819-29. Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Guisinger, S , and others 1985. Investment liicentives Citations." Quarterly Jotirnal of Econonzics and Performance Requirements New York: 108(3) 577-98. Praeger. Jayanthakumaran, K, and John Weiss. 1997. "Export Haddad, Mona, and Harrison, Ann. 1993 "Are Processing Zones in Sri Lanka: A Cost-Benefit There Positive Spillovers from Direct Foreign Appraisal." Journal of International Develop- Investment? Evidence from Panel Data for nient 9(5) 727-37. Morocco " Journal of Developnient Econoniics Johansson, Helena, and Lars Nilsson 1997. "Export (Netherlands) 42: 51-74 Processing Zones as Catalysts." World Develop- Hakura, Dalia, and Florence Jaumotte. 1999 "The nient 25(12). 2115-28 Role of Inter- and Intra-Industry Trade in Kang, Sung Jin, and Yasuyuki Sawada. 2000. "Finan- Technology Diffusion." International Monetary cial Repression and External Openness in an Fund Working Paper. Washington, D.C Endogenous Growth Model." Journal of Interna- Hallward-Driemeier, Mary, Guiseppe larossi, and tional Trade and Economic Development 9(4): Kenneth Sokoloff. 2002. "Exports and Manufac- 427-43 turing Productivity in East Asia: A Comparative Keefer, Philip 1996 "Protection Against a Capricious Analysis with Firm-Level Data," National Bureau State: French Investment and Spanish Railroads, of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper 1845-1875." Journal of Economic History 56(1)- no 8894. Cambridge, Mass. 170-92. Hausmann, R, and E. Fernandez-Arias 2000. "The Keller, Wolfgang. 1998 "Are International R&D New Wave of Capital Inflows Sea Change of Just Spillovers Trade-Related? Analyzing Spillovers Another Title." Inter-American Development among Randomly Matched Trade Partners." Bank Working Paper. Washington, D.C. European Economic Review 42: 1469-81 112 D O M E S T I C PO LI C I ES IO UN LO C K G LO B AL O P P O R I U N I T I E S 2000 "Do Trade Patterns and Technology of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper Flows Affect Productivity Growth"' World Bank Cambridge, Mass. Economic Revietv 14(1) 17-48. Love,James H 1996 "EntryandExit.ACounty-Level Khemani, R. Shyain. 2002 "The Role of Competition Analysis." Applied Ecouoni,cs 28(4): 441-5 1 Law-Policy " Unpublished World Bank staff Lumenga Neso, Olivier, Marcelo Olarreaga, and report Maurice Schiff. 2001 "On Indirect Trade Related Kikeri, Sunita, and John Nellis. 2001 "Privatization R&D Spillivers " World Bank Workinig Paper in Comperitive Sectors- The Record So Far" Washington, D.C Private Sector Advisory Services, World Bank, Maloney, W F 2001 "Missed OpportuLlities. Ininova- Washington, D.C. tion anid Resource-Based Growth in Latin Amer- Knack, Stepheln, and Philip Keefer. 1995 "InstituLtios ica " World Bank Working Paper. Washingtoni, and Economic Performance. Cross-Country Tests D C Using Alternative Institutionial Measures" Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N Economnics and Politics 7(3) 207-27 Wel. 1992. "A Contribution to the Empirics of Kolstad, Ivar, and Luie Tondel 2002 "Social De- Economic Growthi " Quarterly Journal of Eco- velopment and Foreign Direct Investments in noniics 107(2) 407-37. Developing Counrries." Chr Michelson Institute McMillai, John, and Christopher Woodruff. 2002 Report 1 1. Bcrgen, Norway "The Cenitral Role of Entrepreneurs in Tranisition Kreye, Otto, Folker Frobel, and Jurgen Heinrichs Economies " Jomrnal of Economic Perspectives 1987 "Export Processing Zones in Devel- 16(3) 153-70 oping Countries. ResLitts of a New Survey " Megginsoni, William L., and Jeffrey M Netter. 2001. Multinationial Enterprise Programme Working "From State to Market. A Survey of Empirical Paper 43. Internationai Labour Organisation, Studies on Privatization " Jour,ial of Econoniic Geneva. Literature 39(2). 321-89 Krugmaln, Paul 1991 Geography and Trade Moran, Theodore 1998 Foreign Direct lnt'estuient Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press and Development. Washington, D C.: Instittite 1998. "The Role of Geography in Develop- for Interinational Economics ment " Annial World Bank Cooferenice on De- 2002 Beyond Siveatshops Foreign Direct velopment Economics. Washington, D C. Investment and Globalizationz ii Developinig Kwoka, John E. Jr. 1996. Power Structture Ownership, Cointries Washington, D.C.: Brookings InstitIte Integration, and Competition in the U.S Elec- Press. tricity Industry. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Morisset, Jacquies, and Olivier Lumenga Neso 2002 Kluwer Academic Publishers "Administrative Barriers to Foreign Investment Lall, Sanijaya. 2001. "Competitiveness Indices and in Developing Countries " World Bank Policy Developing Cotintries An Economic Evaluation Research Workinig Paper. Washington, D.C. of tie Global Competitiveniess Report." World Morisset, Jacques, and Neda Pirnia 2000. "How Tax Developmiienit 29(9): 1501-25. Policy and Incentives Affect Foreigin Direct Lall, Sanlaya, and Paul Streeten. 1977 Foreign 1nvest- Investment: A Review." World Bank Policy ment, Transnationals, and Developing Coointries Research Working Paper. Washington, D C Boulder, Colo : Westview Press. Muendler, Marc-Andreas 2002 "Trade, Technology, Lansbury, Melanie, and David Mayes. 1996 "Entry, and lProductivity: A Stidy of Brazilian M1anufac- Exit, Ownership and the Growth of Productivity." turers, 1986-1998 " Dissertation. Berkeley, Calif. In David Mayes, ed., Sources of Productivity Navarettim Giorgio Barba, and Isidro Soloaga. Growth. Cambridge, U K : Cambridge University "Weightless Machinies and Costless Knowledge Press. An Empirical Analysis of Trade and Technology Levinsohn, J. 1993. "Testing the Imports-as-Market- Diffusion." World Bank Policy Working Paper Discipline Hypothesis." Jouirial of International Washington, D.C Economzics 35(1/2). 1-22. Newfarmer, Richard 2001. "Foreign Direct Invest- Li, Wei, and Lixin Cohn Xu 2001. "Liberalization and ment: Policies and Institutions for Growth." In Performance in Telecommunicationis Sector New Horizons for Foreign Direct Investment around the World." World Bank Policy Research Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation Working Paper. Washington, D.C. and Development. Lipsey, Robert E. 1999. "The Location and Character- Newfarmer, Richard, and Lawrence Marsh. 1992 istics of U S Affiliates in Asia." National Bureau "IIndustrial Structure, Market, and Profitability." 113 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 In C Frischtak and Richard Newfarmer, eds, Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Transnational Corporations Market Struicture Paper. Cambridge, Mass and Industrial Performance. London: Routledge Sargent, John, and Linda Matthews 1999. "Exploita- Noll, Roger. 2000 "Telecommunications Reform in non or Choice? Exploring the Relative Attractive- Developing Countries." Stanford Institute for ness of Employment in Maquiladoras " Journal Economic Policy Research (SIEPR) Policy Paper. of Business Ethics 18 213-27 Stanford, Calif. Saxenian, AnnaLee, and Jinn-Yuh Hsu. 2000. "The Sil- Noll, Roger, Mary Shirley, and Simon Cowan 2000 icon Valley-Hsinchu Connection: Technical Com- "Reforming Urban Water Systems in Developing munites and Industrial Upgrading." University of Countries." In Anne Krueger, ed , Economnc Pol- California-Berkeley Working Paper. icy Reform. The Second Stage. Chicago: Univer- Scherer, E M., and David Ross 1990. Induistrial sity of Chicago Press Market Structuire and Economic Performance Noorbakhsh, Farhad, Alberto Paloni, and Ali Youssef. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. 2001. "Human Capital and FDI Inflows to Schrank, Andrew 2001. "Export Processing Zones Developing Countries New Empirical Evidence." Free Market Islands or Bridges to Structural World Developmient 29(9): 1593-61 0. Transformation." Development Policy Review OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and 19(2). 223-42. Development) 1996. Trade, Employment, and Sheshinski, Eytan, and Luiz Felipe Lopez-Calva 2000 Labour Standards. A Stuidy of Core Workers' "Privatization and Its Benefits Theory, Evidence, Rights and Inteinational Trade Paris. and Challenges." Consulting Assistance on Eco- 2001. "Summary of Cartel Cases Described by nomic Reform (CAER) II Discussion Paper 35 Invitees " Paris OECD Global Forum on Compe- Cambridge, Mass Harvard Institute for Interna- tition. October 5 tional Development Perrazzini, Ben. 1996. "Competition in Telecoms- Shirley, Mary M , and Patrick Walsh 2000. "Public Implications for Universal Service and Employ- vs. Private Ownership: The State of the Debate." ment." Puiblic Policy for the Private Sector: World Bank Working Paper. Washington, D.C. Washington, D.C World Bank. Sjoholm, Fredrik 1996. "International Transfer of Porter, Michael. 1990 The Comipetitive Advantage of Knowledge: The Role of International Trade Nations. New York Free Press. and Geographic Proximity " Weltwirtschaftliches Pritchett, Lant. 1999. "The Tyranny of Concepts Archiv 132(1): 97-115. Cumulative Depreciated Investment Effort Smarzynska, Beata. 2002 "Does Foreign Direct In- (CUDIE) Is Not the Same as Capital Accumula- vestment Increase the Productivity of Domestic tion " World Bank Policy Research Working Firiis' In Search of Spillovers through Backward Paper. Washington, D C Linkages." World Bank Policy Research Working Recanatini, Francesca, Scott Wallsten, and lixin Cohni Paper. Washington, D C Xu. 2000 "Surveying Surveys and Questioning Smarzynska, Beata, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2000. "Cor- Questions: Learning from World Bank Experi- ruption and Composition of Foreign Direct ence." World Bank Policy Research Working Investment Firm-Level Evidence." World Bank Paper Series. Washington, D.C. Working Paper. Washingtoni, D.C. Rodriguez, F, and D. Rodrik. 1999 "Trade Policy and Stein, Ernesto, and Christiani Daude. 2001. "Institu- Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the tions, Integration, and the Location of Foreign Cross-National Evidence." Centre for Economic Direct Investment " New Horizons for Foreign Policy Research Working Paper. London, U.K Direct Investment Paris' Organisation for Eco- Rodrik, Dani. 1999. The New Global Economny and nomic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Developing Couintries: Making Openness WXork. Stern, Nicholas. 2001 "Investment and Poverty: The Washington, I) C . Overseas Development Role of International Financial Institutions." Council Econonncs of Transition 9(2): 259-80 Romer, Paul. 1990 Endogenous Technological Change Tybout, James R. 2000 "Manufacturing Firms in Jouirnal of Political Economy 98(5) 57-102. Developing Countries: How Well Do They Do, Ros, AgustinJ. 1999 "Does Ownership or Competition and Why?" Journail of Economic Literature Matter? The Effects of Telecommunications 38(1): 11-44. Reform on Network Expansion and Efficiency." 2001 "Plant and Firm Level Evidence on Jourmal of Regulatory Economics 15(l): 65-92. 'New' Trade Theories." National Bureau of Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner 1995 "Economic Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper Convergence and Economic Policies." National Cambridge, Mass ]14 D O M E S T I C P O L I C I ES TO UN LO C K G LO B AL O PPO R T UN IT I ES UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Asian Economies." Journzal of Policy Modeling Development) 1996. "World Investment Report: 24(5) 411-35. Investmenit, Trade, and Internationial Policy Wei, Shang-Jin 2000 "Howv Taxing Is Corruption on Arrangemiienits." New York International Investors?" Reviewv of Econoniics 1997 "World Investment Report: Transna- and Statistics 82(1). 1-11 tional Corporations, Market Structmre, and Com- Weiss, Leonard. 1989 Concentration and Price petition Policy." New York Cambridge, Mass N41T Press 1998 "World Investment Report Trends and Wellenius, Bjorn 1992 "Telecommunications. World Determinants " New York. Bank Experience and Strategy." World Bank Van Ryckeghemil, Willy. 1995 "Domestic Policy Fac- DIscussionI Paper Washington, D.C. tors Influenicing FDI Inflows in Latin America " In Wells, Louis T, Nancy J Allen, Jacques Morisset, and W Grabendorff, ed , Foreign Direct Investnent Neda Pirnia 2001 "Using Tax Inicenitives to it Developing Countries The Case of Latin Compete for Foreign Investment Are They Worth Amnerica Madrid: IRELA the Costs?" Foreign Investment Advisory Ser- Villela, Luiz, and Alberto Barreix 2002 "Taxation and vice Occasional Paper. World Bank, Washington, Investment Promotion." Background Nore for D C. Global Economic Prospects 2003 Washington World Bank. 1995 Butreautcrats in Business The Eco- Inter-Americani Development Bank. noniics and Politics of Government Ownierships Wallsten, Scott. 2000 "Telecommunicationis Privatiza- Oxford, U K Oxford University Press. tion in Developiig Countries. The Real Effects - 2001 Global Development Fniance 2001 of Exclusivity Periods." SIEPR Policy Paper. Coalition Btilding for Effective Developnicnt Stanford, Calif. Finance Washington, D C 2001a "An Econometric Analysis of Telecom - . 2002a. "Improving the Investment Climate in Competition, Privatization, and Regulation in India." Investment Climate Unit Working Paper Africa and Latin America " Jotirnal of induistrial Washington, D C. Economics 49(1) 1-20 2002b World Developnient Report 2002: - . 2001b. "An Empirical Test of Geographic Building Institutions for Markets. Oxford, U K Knowledge Spillovcrs Using Geographic Informa- Oxford University Press non Systems and Firm-Level Data " Regional World Economic Forum 2002 Global Conipetitive- Science & Urban Econouiics 31(5) 571-99 ness Report 2001-2002. Oxford, U K., and New 2001c. "Ringing in the 20th CentuIly- The York. Oxford University Press. Effects of State Monopolies, Private Ownership, WTO (World Trade Organization) 1998 "Report of and Operating Licenses on Telecommunicationis the Working Group on the Relationship between in Europe, 1892-1914 " World Bank Research Trade and Investment to the General Council Working Paper Washington, D C WT/WG/TI/2. December 8. - 2001d "Thle Role of Government in Regional Xu, Bin, and Jianmao Wang 2000 "Trade, FDI, and Technology Development: The Effects of Public Interniationial Technology Diffusion " Journial of Venture Capital and Science Parks." SIEPR Work- Economic Integration (Korea) 15(4) 585-601 ing Paper Stanford, Calif Zak, Paul 2001 "Institutions, Property Rights, and 2002 "Of Carts and Horses. Regulation and Growth." Th7e Gritter Institute XVorking Papers Pri atization in Telecommunicationis Reforms " on Law, Econoniics, and Evolutionary Biology Policy Research Working Paper. Washington, D C 2(1): Article 2. Wang, Eric 2002 "Public Infrastructure and Eco- ZhouL, Kate Xiao. 1996. Hoto the Fartners Cbaniged nomic Growtlh: A New Appi oach Applied to East Cbina. Boulder, Colo . Westview Press 115 International Agreements to Improve Investment and Competition for Development F ast-growing developing countries have Ministers of the World Trade Organization commonly been successful in setting up (WTO) set an agenda for investment and com- F investment regimes that facilitate private petition when they met in Doha, Qatar, in investment and marshal competition to ensure November 2001, and decided to launch nego- growth in productivity. As with trade reform, tiations on a multilateral framework that cov- most of the benefit from new sound invest- ers investment and competition. These negoti- ment and competition policies comes from ations are subject to a decision to be made unilateral reforms of domestic policies. This by explicit consensus on modalities at the chapter explores the potential of international Cancun Ministerial Conference, to be held in collaboration-collaboration principally in 2003. The purpose of the new framework is the form of international agreements-to help "to secure transparent, stable, and predictable developing countries consolidate sound invest- conditions for long-termi cross-border invest- ment climates. ment" that will expand trade and "enhance International agreements that are associ- the contributioii of competition policy to in- ated with multilateral or regional arrange- ternational trade and development."' ments can potentially provide additional The international community, and develop- benefits when coupled with domestic reforms. ing countries in particular, therefore faces two Benefits can take several forms. For investment questions: What types of new multilateral mi- policies, international agreements usually have tiatves on investment and competition policy the objective of eliciting more investment by can promote more-and more productive- locking in reforms and providing additional in- investmiient, and hence more rapid develop- vestor protections. They can also reduce policy ment? And, which issues are best tackled externalities that have "beggar-thy-neighbor" through voluntary initiatives and multilateral consequences. Moreover, participating in in- cooperation, and which are best handled ternational negotiations can prompt partners through binding commitments, such as those in to undertake reciprocal reforms that would the WTO and regional arrangements? The an- not otherwise occur, as well as strengthen the swers to these questions require a separate dis- hand of domestic reformers. For competition cussion of investment and competition policy. policy, international agreements might lead to removal of restraints that inhibit competition, Can coordinated investment policies thereby unleashing new price competition that increase flows to developing countries benefits all countries. A central purpose of this and reduce beggar-thy-neighbor policies? chapter is to identify collective actions that An overall purpose of coordinating an invest- have the greatest development effects. ment policy is to expand the flow of investmenit 117 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 around the world, to minimize distortions that reducing trade barriers in rich countries. The hurt neighbors, and to help improve economic second issue is the curbing of emerging com- performance. Coordination might contribute petition among countries in order to lure to achieving these goals through three main foreign investment through incentives. Unfor- channels: (a) protecting investors' rights in tunately, information on the extent of invest- order to increase incentives to invest, (b) liber- ment incentives is inadequate to assess their alizing investment flows to permit enhanced effects. Thus, a high priority for international access and competition, and (c) curbing poii- collaboration is to systematically compile this cies that may distort investment flows and information. trade at the expense of neighbors. Finally, participating in international in- Analysis suggests several broad conclusions. vestment agreements may have benefits over As with trade reforms, unilateral reforms to and above unilateral reforms if those agree- liberalize foreign direct investment (FDI) are ments are accompanied by reciprocal market likely to have the greatest and most direct access in areas of importance to developing benefit for the reforming country. Beyond countries. These benefits can become clear this, new international agreements that focus only in the course of negotiations. on establishing protections to investors cannot be predicted to expand markedly the flow of Collective action can improve competition investment to new signatory countries. This is Greater competition is associated with more because many protections are already covered rapid development. Lowering policy barriers through bilateral investment treaties (BITs), to trade and foreign investment in develop- and even these relatively strong protections do ing countries, as shown in chapter 3 of this not seem to have increased flows of investment volume, is a powerful, procompetitive force. to signatory developing countries. These facts International agreements on competition pol- suggest that expectations for new flows associ- icy might bring benefits beyond unilateral ated with protections emerging from any mul- actions-provided that the agreements address tilateral agreement should be kept low. the major restrictions that adversely affect International agreements that allow coun- developing countries. tries to negotiate reciprocal market liberaliza- Restrictions on competition in the global tion and to promote nondiscrimination can marketplace that will most hurt development reinforce sound domestic policies and con- can take three forms. First, policy barriers in tribute to better performance. Because most of markets abroad limit competition from devel- the remaining investment restrictions are on oping countries in these markets. Particularly services, the existing General Agreement on harmful are the $311 billion in agricultural Trade in Services (GATS) provides an oppor- subsidies and textile quotas, as well as the tunity to meet this objective. Similarly, curb- high border protection, tariff distortions (such ing beggar-thy-neighbor policy externalities as tariff peaks and escalation), and protection- can benefit developing countries, especially ist use of antidumping. Those policy barriers if agreements focus on two critical issues. are common in all countries-rich and poor The first issue is the reduction of trade barrn- alike. All of these restrictions limit the ability ers that-by depriving developing countries of exporters in developing countries to com- of market access and discouraging their pete in international markets. exports-will lessen the attractiveness of Second, private restraints on competition opportunities for both foreign and domestic can adversely affect prices for consumers and firms to invest in developing countries' export producers in developing countries. For exam- industries. In this regard, reducing trade barn- ple, companies that are based in high-income ers in developing countries is as important as countries have cartelized some markets; 118 IN T ER N Al IO NA L AG R Ee MEN r s IO I MP RO V E INV EST MEN T AND CO MNP ET IT IO N proven cartels have taxed consumcrs in devel- International efforts to promote oping countries by up to $7 billion in the investment 1990s. Actions that facilitate prosecution of A ny pro-development effort to coordinate cartels should be hligh on the priority list. Ainvestmlecnt policies through agreemenit Such actions can range from more systematic has as its objectives increasing the flow of arrangements to exchange informationi, to investment, minimizing distortions among granting developing countries the ability to counltries, and helping countries participate sue under foreign antitrust laws when their ni the potential gains from investment and trade is adversely affected. Indeed, developing investment-related trade. Chapter 3 of this countries would benefit from much greater volume singled out domestic policies that in- efforts to identify and to document restrictive fluence the quantity and productivity of pri- business practices that adversely affect prices vate investment, both domestic and foreign. of their trade. Governments that have provided stable Third, many governments in high-income macroeconomic policies and effective prop- countries officially sanction trade restraints by erty rights for investors, and that have low- exempting their companies from domestic an- ered policy barriers to competition have, by titrust laws. For example, many governments and large, enjoyed greater success in creating permit their comilpanies to cartelize exports. the conditions for sustained growth. Interna- Although these cartels are shrouded in the tional efforts to support these policies can secrecy of government registries, national ex- take several forms: bilateral, regional, and port cartels may well raise prices to develop- multilateral. They can be binding, as in the ing countries. Efforts should be made to make case of the WTO and the North American transparent any information on national ex- Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), or nonbind- port cartels. If cartels were found to have ing, as in the case of the Organisation for Eco- adverse price effects, everyone would benefit niomic Co-operation and Development from reducing these officially sanctioned pri- (OECD). The current regimen is a mixture of vate restraints on trade. Similarly, antitrust binding and nonbonding efforts. exemptions of ocean transport have given rise to price-fixing arrangements that systemati- Today's international investment cally hurt consumers everywhere, includinig framework is a patchwork quilt sewn consumilers in developing countries. together over many years Competition policies in developing coiun- The growing waves of FDI observed in recent tries themselves can, in many cases, be irn- decades have been accompanied by a steady proved through increased transparency, rise in international agreements on invest- nondiscrimination, and procedural fairness. ment. Agreements are typically founded on However, international cooperation in this the presumptions that cross-border investmiienit complex area of regulation has to recognize provides benefits to both investing and reci- that countries have different capacities and pient couintries, that rules can minimize dis- iiistitutional settings, which warrant caution putes and provide for their resolution, and in recommending-much less in mandating- that agreed-on rules can enhance both the across-the-board policies. This is an area where quantity and quality of investment. The voluntary programs that facilitate learning and Havana Charter, designed to create the Inter- adoption of best practice in developing coun- national Trade Organization (ITO) at the end tries can pay high dividends. of the 1940s, proposed the inclusion of invest- This chapter analyzes first the investment ment provisions together with trade provi- policy issues, and then the global competition sions. The investmenit provisions were quite issues. limited in scope because many countries- 119 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 particularly developing ones-feared foreign of norms and principles that govern interna- control over their natural resources and strate- tional trade. gic industries.2 Since then, a patchwork quilt has emerged, made of differing bilateral Bilateral agreements. Recent years have treaties, regional arrangements, and multilat- witnessed a surge in BITs. The number of BITs eral instruments relating to cross-border in- quintupled during the 1990s, reaching 2,099 vestment. This regulatory quilt stands in sharp by the end of 2001 (see box 4.1). During 2001 contrast to the more comprehensive system alone, 97 countries concluded 158 BITs (see Box 411 What is a BIT? t he number of BITs mushroomed in the 1990s treatment, and treatment according to customary (see box figures). These agreements typically international law. In addition, BITs prescribe specific contain broad definitions of foreign investment, investment protections, which cover topics such as inclusive of nonequity forms, various types of invest- the transfer of funds, expropriation, and nationaliza- ment assets (including portfolio investments), and tion. They typically provide for the settlement of intangible assets such as intellectual property. BITs disputes between the treaty partners and between generally avoid a direct regullation of the right to investors and the host state. Provisions for so-called establishment, referring this matter to nationial laws investor-state arbitration normally refer to pre- (and thus recognizing implicitly the right of host existing arbitration rules, notably those under the countries to regulate the entry of FDT). Most BITs International Center for the Settlenment of Investment BITs are increasing ... ... even among developing countries 2,000 500 400 1,500 1,500 _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~With transition Europe __ 300 1,000 South-South BlTs 200 North-South \\_ 500 100 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s Source UNCTAD (2000) Source UNCTAD (2000) also do not explicitly address ownership and control Disputes (or TCSID, which is affiliated with the issues, though they often cover some operational World Baiik); the United Nations Commission on restrictions, such as the admission of key managerial International Trade Law (UNCITRAL); or the Inter- personnel. Only a few BITs discipline the use of per- national Chamber of Commerce (ICC). formance requirements. Most BITs prescribe national treatment, most- favored nation (MFN) treatment, fair and equitable Source: World Bank staff. 120 IN TE RNAT IONA L AG RE EM ENT S TO I MP R O V E INV 1: SIM ENT AND CO MP ET IT IO N UNCTAD 2002). For much of the post-World agreements include technology transfers, envi- War II period, BITs tended to be negotiated on ronmental protection, taxation, conflicting a North-South basis. More recently, however, requirements, and standards for the conduct there has been strong growth in the number of multinationial enterprises. of South-South BITs. In 2001, for example, treaties between developing countries ac- Multilateral accords. Significant multilateral counted for 42 percent of new BITs (UNCTAD rules for investment were put in place dur- 2002). BITs covered an average of 50 percent ing the Uruguay Round, which concluded in of all foreign investment flows to developing 1994. All of the following agreements either countries in 1999-2001. directly or indirectly address key investnment issues: the Agreement on Subsidies and Coun- Regional arrangements. Investment discl- tervailing Measures (ASCM), the Agreement plines have figured prominently in regional on Trade-Related Investment Measures trade and integration agreements, particularly (TRIMs), the GATS, the Agreement on Trade- the most recent ones. Some of these agree- Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights ments embed foreign investmenlt into a (TRIPs), and the plurilateral Government Pro- broader framework of rules that are aimed at curement Agreement. promoting economic cooperation and deeper Numerous multilateral agreements and integrationl. This framework includes the arrangements that have been concluded out- European Union; NAFTA; the free trade side the WTO also affect investment and can agreement linking the G-3 countries (Mexico, make a positive contribution to enhancing the Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, and investnment climates in developing countries. Colombia); the recently concluded Singapore- Among others, these arrangements include Japan agreement; and the European Free efforts to curb bribery and corruption (OECD, Trade Area. Other agreements-such as the Organization of American States LOAS]); rules OECD's Codes of Liberalizationi of Capital governing the conduct of multinational enter- Movements, the Colonia Protocol on the Pro- prises (OECD Guidelines on Multinational motion and Reciprocal Protection of Invest- Enterprises, United Nations IU.N.1 Global ments within the Southern Cone Common Compact); guidelines on corporate social Market (Mercosur), and the Asia Pacific responsibility and corporate governance Economic Cooperation (APEC) Non-Binding (OECD, World Bank); and cooperation on Investment Principles-are less comprehensive best practices in investment promotion activi- with regard to their treatment of the trade- ties (U.N. Conference on Trade and Develop- investment interface. ment (UNCTAD), World Bank). A distinguishing feature of regional agree- ments with investmiienit disciplines is their ten- New efforts exist for collective action on dency to address both investment protection investment and liberalization (entry) issues, together with The rising tide of FDI around the world has disciplines on post-establishment operating been, in part, a consequence of a progressive re- conditions and means to settle investment ceptivity of developing countries to FDI flows. disputes (both state-to-state and investor- Just as tariffs have fallen, so too have restric- state disputes). The architecture of the most- tions on incoming investments (particularly in advanced regional free trade and integration manufacturing) been lifted. Governmenits once agreements reflects the complex interrelations hostile to transnational corporations (TNCs) among investment, trade, services, intellectual now actively seek their participation-and property rights, competition policy, and the even compete for it. One indicator of this is the movement of business people. Other impor- change in investment regulations. Between tant issues that are dealt with in some regional 1991 and 2001, a total of 1,393 regulatory 121 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 changes were introduced in national FDI facilitate access and entry, establishing in- regimes, of which 1,315 (or 95 percent) were in vestor protections as an incentive to invest, the direction of creating a more favorable envi- and curbing investment-distorting policies ronment for FDI (figure 4.1). During 2001 that affect trade and investment location. alone, a total of 208 regulatory changes were made by 71 countries, only 14 of which (or Liberalizing investment promotes 6 percent) were less favorable for foreign in- market access- vestors (UNCTAD 2002). This opens the ques- The inclusion of investment in international tion of whether this evident willingness to im- negotiations may lead to greater openness of prove the investment regime could be leveraged investment regimes that can be accomplished to achieve some additional benefits, through unilaterally. If investment is negotiated as part reciprocating in multilateral negotiations, an of a broader set of trade negotiations, rather issue that we take up below. than in isolation, then the traditional mecha- The potential-and the challenge-of co- nism of reciprocal access concessions can help operation on investment policies become create support for greater openness at home clearer if it is broken down into the three core and abroad. For example, exporters in devel- subagendas that parallel the investment cli- oping countries who obtain improved access mate discussions in chapters 2 and 3. These to foreign agricultural markets can be a coun- policies relate to liberalizing investment to tervailing force against those who resist the Box 4.2 The Mu1tilateral Agreement on Invemtn,enit (MAI) B ecause investment regulations extend beyond tar- of the GATS's MFN requiiement without making J)iffs into domestic regulation, the political difficul- any reciprocal concessions). Also at play was the ties of enticing large groups of countries to harmo- reluctance of OECD countries to open up sensitive nize their domestic rules are not trivial. Those sectors to foreign investment (for example, to mar- difficulties were evident in the latest-and failed- itime transport and audiovisual services). Labor and attempt at crafting a multilateral accord. In 1995, environmental groups objected to the fact that the developed countries pushed to establish a Multilat- MAI would give TNCs more power to ignore work- eral Agreement on Investment (MAI) within the ers' interests and environmental concerns while OECD that had the objective of setting "state of the providing rheni with extensive rights to challenge art standards for investment regimes and inivestment domestic regulatory conduct before international protection with effective dispute settlement proce- arbitration panels. Meanwhile, many developing dures.`3 These efforts were unsuccessful, and the countries, left out of the discussions because of the MAI was not established. MAI's venue in the OECD, protested their unwilling- One reason for the MAI's demise was the wan- ness to accept rules that they had no voice in design- ing support within the business community as it be- ing (Gilpin 2000).4 By the fall of 1998, negotiations came apparent that the level of investment protection on the MAI were formally abandoned, thereby offer- afforded to MAI signatories would almost certainly ing sobering insights on the complexity and political be lower than that offered in BITs. It was apparent sensitivities involved in attempts at comprehensive that prospects for significant investment liberaliza- investment rulemaking. tion would be held back, first, by concerns of free riding by non-OECD WTO members (which stood l to receive many of the benefits of the MAI by virtue Souirce WVorld Bank staff 122 IN T ER NAT IONA L AG RE E MEN TS TO I MP R o V E IN VE S TM ENT AND CO MP ET IT IO N Figure 4.1 Countries are increasingly liberalizing their investment regimes National regulatory changes In FDI regimes, 1991-2000 (number of regulatory changes) (number of regulatory changes) 80 250 70 _ More favorable to FDI 60 r 200 50 / 150 - / Less favorable to FDI 40 / 30_100 _ _ _ t _ _ _ 20 50 10 _ °l I l I I I I I I I 01 I O I I I I I 1 I I, R R o 9r 0R 5 R a - 5 O 0 0 4 Soiarcc UNCTAD (2002) elimination of investment barriers in telecom- invest primarily in other developing countries. munications. At the same time, the need to Estimates suggest that nearly one-third of fight these battles about the domestic politi- foreign investment flows to developing coun- cal economy makes a country a credible ne- tries originated in other developing countries, gotiator for improved access. The process, if it up from negligible amounts in the early 1990s works, could produce a double benefit: liber- (World Bank 2002a), so South-South FDI alizing countries would benefit from the in- flows have grown.5 (See figures 4.2 and 4.3.) creased competition that is associated with FDI, and their firms would have improved access to foreign markets. A key issue-which Figure 4.2 South-South FDI is rising can be determined only during the negotiation FDI flows to developing countries process-is the extent to which an investment (billions of dollars) agreement leverages reciprocal commitments among trading partners. Because reciprocal 100 gains are difficult to gauge, an important pre- High OECD (North-South) countries requisite for each country is to ensure that any 80 domestic policy commitment makes sense 70 Sout h-South when seen through the lens of promoting 60 national development. 50 Even though most foreign investment orig- 40 inates in rich countries and is destined for 3 High non-OECD countries other rich countries, there may well be some 20 scope for reciprocal agreements that benefit ' developing countries, even within the narrow domain of investment. Because developing 0 I , 1 994 1 995 1 996 1 997 l1998 1 999 2000 countries are increasingly becoming active as investors themselves, they have a mIutual in- Souirce Aykur and Ratha (2002) terest in clear rules of access. They tend to 123 G LO B AL EC ON OM IC PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 the host country's business environment either Figure 4.3 Share of South-South FDI in translates into higher risk premiums (in the case total FDI is rising of pricing corporate assets) or imposes addi- South-South FDI is rising and so is its share in total tional information costs on enterprises. To be FDI sure, transparency, alone, can add little if the (percent) underlying laws and rules are inadequate or 100 - unpredictable. 90 - no-E,E I . Case studies suggest that companies may, 70 - for example, be willing to invest in countries 60 - North-South FDI/total FDI with legal and regulatory frameworks that 50 - would not otherwise be considered "investor 40 - fnendly"-provided the compames are able to 30 fredy-rvddte-opne r bet 20 - South-South FDI/total FD obtain a reasonable degree of clarity about the 10 - environment in which they will be operating. 019 94 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Conversely, there appear to be certain thresh- old levels for transparency beneath which the Source Aykut and Ratha (2002) business conditions become so opaque that virtually no investor is willing to enter, re- gardless of the extent of the inducement. The preceding argues that the potential These policies do not lend themselves well for benefits investment agreements to gener- to including sanction-based dispute resolution ate merits examination. Coordinated efforts to procedures in legally binding agreements. liberalize investments can subsume two issues: Thus, international collaborative efforts should first, transparency, and second, nondiscrimi- perhaps take other forms such as increasing nation in treatment of foreign investment in developing countries' participation in nonbind- market access. ing best-practice instruments or developing as- sistance to strengthen institutions. To the ex- Transparency. Transparency involves mak- tent that transparency obligations are anchored ing relevant laws and regulations available in WTO agreements, monitoring by multilat- to the public, notifying parties when laws eral peer review and surveillance may provide change, and ensuring uniform administration the best means for promoting governance- and application. In addition, transparency can enhancing reforms in host countries. be increased by offering affected parties the opportunity to comment on laws and regula- Nondiscrimination in treatment of foreign tions, which implies communicating the policy investment in market access. The practice of objectives of proposed changes, allowing time placing foreign and domestic sellers on an for public review, and providing a means to equal competitive footing is a hallmark of communicate with relevant authorities. trade agreements. This objective is no less A nontransparent business environment in important in investment agreements. Promot- a host country raises information costs, diverts ing liberalization in international investment corporate energies toward rent-seeking activi- essentially boils down to securing nondiscrim- ties, and may give rise to corrupt practices. This inatory terms of entry and operation. This environment weighs down both domestic and approach has elements of both MFN treat- foreign businesses, though in many cases it may ment (that is, nondiscrimination as between all be particularly discouraging to foreigners who foreign entities) and national treatment (that are usually less privy to locally available infor- is, nondiscrimination between "like" domestic mation. This heightened risk of operating in and foreign entities). 124 IN T ER NAT IO NA l AG RE E MEN TS TO I MP R O V E INV ES I MEN I AND CO MP ET IT IO N Box 4.3 South-South flows: who invests and who receives? M ost FDI flows within developing couintries are has also expanded Its boundaries from East Asia to M between the Association of Southeast Asian Latin America and to parts of Africa. Since the sec- Nations (ASEAN) countries, and, recently, among ond half of the 1990s, almost 30 percent of total the Latin American countries, especially the Mercosur FDI inflows into India are from other developing members (UNCTAD 1999). There are signs that countries-the principal sources being Mauritius, FDI flows from East and Southeast Asia to Latin Malaysia, and Korea (Aykut and Ratha 2002). Out- America and Africa are picking up. According to the flows from Latin America in 2001 were directed pri- Chinese Ministry of Foreign Trade and Economic manly at other countrics in the region (UNCTAD Cooperation, China attracted $3 billion in invest- 2002). Chile continued to be the major player in ment from 22 developing countries in 1998. Though interregional investment, followed closely by Mexico this figure made up only 7 percent of total FDI in- and Argentina. Some South African TNCs have flows to China, the flows originated in a wide spec- recently moved to a strategy of international growth, trum of countries (in terms of size and per capita partly through cross-border mergers and acquisi- income levels) and extended to varying sectors tions. A noteworthy example of a global player is (Aykut and Ratha 2002). In addition, Chinese TNCs South African Breweries, which operates 108 brew- are becoming prominent in world markets. China eries in 24 countries including China, large parts of has invested, not only in Asian countries, but also in Africa, and Europe (UNCTAD 2002). FDI outflows Bangladesh, Brazil, India, the Islamic Republic of from the Central and Eastern European countries Iran, and Poland, in addition to countries in Africa. such as Croatia, Estonia, and Slovenia are also The Republic of Korea, an OECD member, headed primarily to neighboring countries. A ten- invested nearly one-third of its direct investment in dency to invest in neighboring countries that are at developing countries (excluding those in Africa similar or lower levels of development is another fea- and the Middle East) in 1998. By 1999, Korea had ture of South-South FDI (Aykut and Ratha 2002). invested nearly 50 percent of its aggregate invest- ment in other developing countries. Malaysian FDI Source: World Bank staff. Departures from nondiscrminiiatory treat- establishment phase can thus send to foreign ment essentially take one of two forms: before investors powerful signals of the credibility of entry in the "pre-establishment" phase of an a host country's reform efforts. investmenit, and aftcr entry in the "postestab- By far the most contentious aspect of liber- lishment" operating conditions of a business. alization is the pre-establishment commitment Governments everywhere have been reluctant to openness, given the tendency to maintain to extend full pre-establishment privileges to restrictions on entry in a few sensitive sectors. all potential entrants in every sector. Securing Most countries now permit liberal access to nondiscriminatory conditions of treatment is foreign investors in manufacturing. The same equally important in the postestablishment holds true-if to a lesser extent-in mining phase, because foreign investors will typically and agriculture. Indeed, as a result of various have significant start-up costs and will be investment incentive schemes that are not averse to sudden, unanticipated changes in available to domestic firms, foreign investors regulatory conditions that may tilt competi- In manufacturing often enjoy treatment that tive conditions in favor of local competitors. is better than that available to domestic in- Nondiscrirriination commitments in the post- vestors. Most governmental measures that 125 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 overtly discriminate against foreign investors tially arise from the liberalization of invest- and that restrict FDI inflows are maintained in ment in services: the GATS. The GATS has the service sector and concern key industries several features that are attractive to countries, such as telecommunications, broadcasting and potentially making it a useful tool to widen related audiovisual services, satellite services, nondiscriminatory access in a reciprocal frame- energy services, financial services (especially wvork. By having a positive list approach-in banking and insurance), civil aviation, and which countries voluntarilv schedule sectoral maritime transport.6 Sauve (2002) estimates commitments to apply national treatment that 80-85 percent of restrictions affecting in- and to grant market access-governments ternational investment are maintained in ser- enjoy considerable flexibility to exempt sec- vice sectors. Among the most dynamic sectors tors that they deem of special national interest. of the global economy, services are also where Once commitments are undertaken, countries some two-thirds of cross-border FDls have accord all suppliers-foreign and national been directed in recent years (see chapter 2, alike-the same conditions of entry and oper- this volume). ation in a nondiscriminatory fashion. To date, One telling proxy of the potential of ser- however, the GATS has fallen short of its vices for investment liberalization is provided itberalizing potential. The coverage of com- by the negative lists of measures drawn up by mitments for a large number of countries is prospective signatories of the ill-fated MAI. limited. About two-thirds of the WTO mem- The lists identify those sectors in which the bership has scheduled fewer than 60 sectors negotiators wished to restrict access by foreign (of the 160 or so specified in the GATS list) investors (see figure 4.4). A similar trend is ev- (see Stern 2002). In many cases, commitments ident under the NAFTA. Simply put, the mar- do not reflect the actual degree of openness ket access or agenda for investment is largely (Mattoo 2000). In other cases, countries have centered on services (Hoekman and Saggi not moved actively to schedule sectors-even 2000; Sauv6 and Wilkie 2000). when domestic policies are open to foreign A multilateral vehicle already exists for investments. Finally, sometimes countries' realizing the positive externalities that poten- commitments serve to protect the privileged Figure 4.4 Revealed preferences: governments shield services more often than manufacturing from the winds of investment competition All setr< <=,Business 16% All sector 21%/ \ Communication 16% Construction 2% Services Financial 21% 63% Tourism 2% Recreation 2% Transport 37% Goods Other 4% 16% Total 100% Note Listed are iioniconiforiiing measures reserved siitder che draft Multilateral Agreementit on tinvestrnent Soutrce Sauvce (2002) 126 I N T E R N A I I O N A L A G R E E M c N T S I 0 I M P R O V E I N V E S I M r N T A N D C O NI P E I I T I O N position of incumbenits, domestic or foreign, caveat to this argumlienit: To the extent that rather than to enhance the contestability of the power imbalance is redressed in a multi- niarkets lateral agreemelit in favor of weaker states, Countries could take greater advantage of then the constituencies within the global busi- the opportunity offered by the GATS to lend ness communilty may well prefcr-as was the credibility to reform programs by committing case in the MAI negotiationis-the stronger to maintain current levels of openness or by level of investimicilt protection flowing from precommitting to greater levels of future BITs, and may lose interest in a multilateral openness. To advanice the process of services agreemcilt. reforms beyond levels undertaken indepen- Third, a multilateral set of disciplines on dently and to lcad to more balanced outcomes investimicit protection would arguably hclp from the developing countries' points of vicw, developing countries send a positive signal to countries could better harness the power of potential forcign investors regarding the per- reciprocity by devising negotiating formulas manence of policy changes, the expected that widen the scope for tradeoffs across sec- standard of treatmenit afforded to foreign in- tors (both goods and services) and across vestors, and recourse to a dispute-settlemeilt modes of delivery, notably temporary move- procedure. menit of workers (Mattoo 2002). While these factors suggest that investmenit flows might increase because of such an -but protecting investment may not arrangemilenit, care should be taken not to increase flows overstate the response of investors Five facts A foundation of any country's investment cli- argue for caution. First, the absence of a body mate is the protection of property rights for of multilateral disciplines on investincilt its investors. An agreement that encourages protection has hardly deterred cross-border countries to improve investor protections has investimient activity. Indeed, FDI has far out- the potential for improving investment flows stripped trade and output growth over the from abroad and for elicitinig more domestic past decade and a half (see figure 4.5). investiienit. The interinational communiity, in Second, the absence of an agreemenit has general, and developing countries, in particu- not prevented substantial unilateral reform lar, might find three benefits from multilateral (see discussion above, and figure 4. 1). disciplines on investment protection. Third, a more precise iiidicator is the his- First, an agreement on common standards torical experience of the BITs in clicitinig new would promote efficicncy by carr-ying potcn- investmcnt. Does the signing of BITs increase tially' significant economies of scale in makinig the flow of FDI? Hallward-Driemileier (2002) rules: one multilateral agreement could be- finds few independent effects of BITs on sub- come a "one-stop" substitute for the complex sequent increases in investment (box 4.4). and legally divergent web of existing BITs. Fourth, it is not clear whether multilateral Second, a multilateral regime for invest- investment disciplines-whether in the U.N, ment protection could help counterbalanice WTO, or OECD-will embody investimielit the bargaining asymmetries built into BITs protections that are superior-and, therefore, and into regional agreements conducted along additive-to BITs. In the case of the WTO, the North-South lines. In some cases, the negoti- Doha Ministerial Declaration reflects a signif- ating asymmetries that are common to bilat- icantly more-limilited approach that cicarly eral agreemenits have led to treaties in which does not view a multilateral framework on in- developing countries have taken on substan- vestment as a substitutc for bilateral and re- tive obligationis without any reciprocity other gional arrangemcnts. Recent negotiating briefs than the promise of increases in future private in the WTO indicate that some malor coUIn- investmenit. However, there is an important tries have withdrawn support for investor-state 127 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Figure 4.5 FDI is growing faster than exports and output Developing countries: merchandise exports, output, and FDI inflows, 1980-2000 (index, 1980 = 100, average annual growth rates in parentheses) 3,000 - L.-I ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~FDI inflows 2,500 - - ~~~~~~~~~~~~~(1981-90 5 3%) …- - ~~~~~~~~~(1991-2000 20 8%) 1,500 1,000 GDP L1-I-+--1-I--l-l---1--I--b--4-~ 1IfiIf If(1 9B1-90 3 2%) 500 ---- (1991-2000 4 4%) I ~~Merchandise exports 0 - ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~(1 981-90 3 3%) 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 (1991-2000 9 6%) Source UNCTAD (2001), Handbook of Statistics World Bank (2002), World Developmenit Iindicators, and WTO (2001), Interinationial Trade Statistics dispute settlement, which would tend to lessen national investment. Three negative policy the additive value of investor protection in a externalities-when one country's policies multilateral accord. adversely affect another-merit discussion. Dispute settlement is another critical-and The first and most powerful of these negative as yet unresolved-issue that will influence policy externalities are investment-distorting the content of any multilateral agreement to trade barriers. Tariffs, tariff escalation, strengthen investor protections. Most BITs and other forms of protection discourage contain dispute resolution mechanisms that investment-both foreign and domestic-in allow investors to challenge government rul- export industries in developing countries. ings before arbitration panels or international Said differently, if developing countries con- courts. In the context of the WTO, while there front impediments to market access abroad, is generally little support for the inclusion the effect of the barriers is to lower the poten- of investor-state arbitration provisions in a tial stream of earnings in their export activities. prospective multilateral investment agree- This change reduces the incentive for foreign ment, WTO rules on investment protection and domestic investors to invest in produc- could entail complications even when admin- tion for export in developing countries. Quota istered through state-to-state dispute settle- arrangements, antidumping actions, subsidies, ment. For example, what would be the appro- overly restrictive rules of origin, and other priate remedy in an instance of unlawful trade restrictions distort not only trade, but expropriation of a foreign investment? These also investment, and these distortions are difficult and contentious issues will take time arguably the largest negative policy externality to resolve in any international agreement. affecting investment in developing countries. Two other sets of policy externalities figure Beggar-thy-neighbor investment prominently in investment decisions: perfor- distortions must be minimized mance requirements-to compel multina- Governments have adopted policies that may tional companies to locate a greater part of the affect the location and performance of trans- value added chain in the domestic market- 128 IN T E RN AT IO NAL AG RI: E MENTS TO I MP R O VPE INV ES TM ENT AND CO MP ET IT IO N B3ox 4.4 Do BITs increase investment flows? Only a bit B ITs are instrumenits used by countries to protect their foreign investors, while host countries view The share of FDI received by developing BITS as an importanit means of attracting foreign countries is relatively unaffected by the investors. BITs can provide the basis for resolving signing of a BIT disputes; they can also impose potentially extensive (share of annual FDI flow) obligations on the part of the governments hosting 0 3 the investment. For example, almost all treaties stip- ulate comiipensation for the expropriation of invest- ments. ln some cascs, trcaties proscribe any govern- 0 2 ment action-even environmental actions or other regulations-that would reduce the value of the privare investment and they establish grounds for 0 1 compensation. Such compensation could cither entail extensive liabilities for the host government or compel it to refrain from making certain policy -3 -2 T- Year T-1 T2 +3 choices. Against this backdrop, the question of signed whether BITs actually increase FDI is important. Years before signing Years after signing Surprisingly little empirical work has been done to test BlTs' role in attracting FDI. UNCTAD, in a Source ia.lIlward-Orieine,cr (2002) recent stUdy, found little evidence that BITs increased FDI (UNCTAD 1998). That work looked at a single year of investments and tested whether the number host country was affected by the presence of a BIT. of BITs signed by the host was correlated with the The evidence here is that concluding a BIT is posi- amount of FDI it received. Hallward-Driemeicr tively associated with receiving a larger share of a (2002) redid that test, but applied it to 20 years of source country's FDI outflows, but that the result is data, looking at the bilateral flows of OECD memn- not statistically significant. bers to 3 i developing countries. The Hallward- Some countries have looked to BITs as a way of Driemeier test covered the vast majority of FDI signaling their respect for property riglts. Particularly flows, as well as those relationships that were histor- if their reputation for protecting suchi rights is weak, ically the bulk of such treaties. Overall, the evidence they have seen the signing of a BIT as a way of assuag- is, at best, weak that BITs increase the amount of ing the concerns of foreign investors. Conversely, the FDI. By the end of the 1990s there were many more crecibility of such a signal may not be that strong. It BlTs, and FDI had increased dramatically. However, may be that the domestic rule of law must be suffi- controlling for a time trend, there was little indepen- ciently strong before foreigners are willing to consider dent role for BITs in accounting for the increase in the terms of the BIT as being enforceable. To test he- FDI. Countries that had concluded a BIT were no tween these hypotheses, the study ran regressions that more likely to receive additional FDI than were included measurements of the rule of law, government countries without such a pact. effectiveness, and regulatory quality. These measures Another question is whether a BIT would draw were then interacted with the presence of a BIT. The attention to a particular location, thus leading to an results indicate that in weak investment climates, the increase in flows in the aftermath of negotiations. BIT does not serve to attract additional FDI. However, However, comparing flows in the three years after a in cotintries with stronger investment climates, the BIT was signed to those in the three years before, there presence of a BIT does weakly increase the amount was no significant increase in FDI (see box figure). and relative share of FDI that the host receives. A third question is whether the relative amount of FDI that a source country allocated to a particular Source- Hallward-Dricmeier (2002) 129 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 and investment incentives-usually through Round's ASCM introduced limited disciplines tax breaks or direct transfers from the state to on the granting of investment incentives. attract FDI. Even when these policies benefit These disciplines are largely indirect because the domestic economy, they both have the po- they apply solely to export subsidies and other tential for adversely affecting trade and invest- goods-related transactions-that is, a govern- ment flows with neighbors. Therefore, further ment may invoke the agreement's provisions internationial cooperation to curb their nega- only when certain types of investment incen- tive effects can create positive benefits for all. tives used by certain types of members can be Unlike restrictions on entry that primarily shown to distort trade in goods.9 affect services, performance requirements and Strengthening disciplines on investment- investmenit incentives usually affect manufac- distorting incentives could benefit developing turing. In general, performance requirements countries because those disciplines would re- have been the instrument of choice for devel- duce the scope for this zero-sum tax competi- oping countries that are seeking to ensure that tion. However, progress in crafting a set of TNCs' activities generate the greatest possible multilateral disciplines on investment incen- spillovers for their economies. OECD coun- tives has been negligible to date. One reason tries have been the predominant users of in- for this stalemate is that in large federal gov- vestment incentives to attract investment, ernments many investment incentive programs though in recent years numerous developing originate at the subnational level as instru- countries have followed suit (see chapter 3, ments to promote regional development. this volume; see also UNCTAD 2002). Another reason is that many emerging devel- The trade-distorting effects of performance oping countries have themselves become heavy requirements-termed TRIMs-havc for users of incentives in recent years. Conse- some time been subject to negotiated disci- quently, investment incentives have not figured plines at both the regional and multilateral promineitly among topics to be discussed in levels. WTO disciplines on performance re- international forums such as the WTO. The ill- quirements were codified with the TRIMs fated discussions in the MAI were also unsuc- Agreement in 1995. Among performance re- cessful in broaching investment incentives. quirements, the most prevalent measures Nonetheless, competition among govern- relate to local content, joint ventures (or ments for FDI through incentives is becoming domestic equlty participation), exports, tech- increasingly common in many parts of the nology, and employment requirements. The world. Developing countries often find them- initial rationale for export requirements was selves in competition with each other, but few in part to relieve the pressure on the trade bal- examples can be found of developing coun- ance that inward investment-particularly tries in direct competition with developed import-substituting investment-was generat- countries. Also, competing developing coun- ing. Local content requirements were designed tries are often middle-income countries. Four to maximize vertical linkages and develop- reasons seem to explain these patterns. ment of local skills.7 Current discussions of First, studies show that the bulk of chaniges to the TRIMs Agreement are associ- incentive-bidding activity among governments ated with the review process that is mandated takes place within regions, rather than glob- under Article 9 of that agreement.8 At present, ally (Oman 2000; Chariton 2002). Only a these debates are not on the Doha Agenda. handful of developing countries situated close In contrast with disciplines on performance to developed nations experience direct compe- requirements, disciplines on investment incen- tition with the deep pockets of the treasuries tives are-with the exception of the European of rich countries. Mexico's automotive indus- Union's comprehensive set of disciplines on try under NAFTA is perhaps the most promi- state aids-more limited. The Uruguay nent example of this situation.10 130 I N T E R N A T I O N A l A G R E E M E N T S r o I i P R O o 1. I N V 1 S T M E N I A N D C 0 Ni P I I I IO N Second, locational competition tends to be information that can be used to assess the strongest between close neighbors with similar trade- and investment-distorting consequenccs economic conditions, factor endowments, and of incentives-and, more broadly, to evaluate policy regimes. Competition is also strongest their net development benefits. in high-skill, technologically intensive indus- Taken together, the existing multilateral tries, particularly for firms producing goods agreements do provide Iimited discipline on for export. Automakers, silicon chip produc- certain types of beggar-thy-neighbor policies ers, and pharmaceutical firms are among the that are currently in use around the world most sought-after investimnents. Only a Iimited With respect to curbing incentives, even number of higher-income developing countries though potential benefits for countries exist are likely to qualify for such a category of from a multilateral accord, the absence of investment. evident momeintumil at the multilateral level- Third, competition is likely only when in- when combined with a regional pattern of vestors are somewhat indifferent about where possible tax competition and trade effects- to locate an investment among alternative lo- suggests that regional arrangements may be cations. This indifference implies that only the more promising for international collective ac- more relatively advanced economics (emerg- tionis. Howvever, data are lacking. Multilateral ing or transition economies) could have cause efforts to improve informiationi on investment to bid against developed nations.1 incentives, perhaps through a WTO mecha- Fourth, overt bidding wars between coun- nism, would help remedy that lacuna and tries are relatively rare-even though bidding allow better analysis of the extent of invest- may be intense within particular countries- ment distortions. and are typically limited to a few sectors. They generally occur when individual projects are ex- Summary: Getting the biggest ceptioially large and when the sectors in ques- development benefit from international tion (for example, automobiles or electronics) collaboration on investment are considered a high priority for national or Developing countries can benefit from inter- regional economic strategies (Charlton 2002). national collaboration to liberalize market To be sure, striving for a ban on all inceni- access for investment, to address investor pro- tives may bc counterproductive because, in tections, and to minimize investment distor- some cases, incentives can offset local disad- tions. Five concltisionis emerge vantages or can be used to capture spillovers First, in each of these areas the primary from inward FDI (see Hoekman and Saggi benefits of attracting high-quality investment 2000). In the case of Ireland and Portugal, from sound investimienlt policies are likely to for example, incentive programs have played result from unilateral enacting of domestic a significant role in attracting investmenit to reforms. Long a truism for trade liberalizing less-developed regions. In the case of Brazil, reforms, this conclusion-given the apparent some evidence shows that incentives competi- lack of investor responsiveness to interna- tion i-nay have contributed to reducing re- tional agreements-is increasingly germane to gional disparities, because FDI in some sectors investment. Many of the remaining restric- (particularly automobile manufacturing) is in- tions are on services. As we have seen in chap- creasingly located outside the traditional in- ter 3, progressive liberalization in services can dustrial heartland around S5o Paulo (Cano produce substantial economy-wide benefits 1998). While it is probable that, with re- and should be a priority for consideration as spect to incentives, stories of failures and part of any development strategy. Better excessive expenditures outnumber successes, telecommunicationis, banking, auditing ser- agreements must contain some elements of vices, retail and wholesale trade, and the other flexibility. A first step is generating adequate service industries have multiple linkages to the 131 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 O 0 3 B3ox 45 DliscipUnes on corporaitions can also improve the investment climate Currently, proposed investment rules in the Affairs Center, and by international organizations (CWTO focus exclusively on disciplines for gov- and banks, such as the World Bank, the International ernments, but they say little about responsibilities Monetary Fund (I_MF), the Asian Development Bank, of corporations (see Moran 2002). Improper corpo- the U.N. Development Programme, and the U.S. rate behavior-bribery or improper accounting- Agency for International Development, in developing can corrode the social fabric of developing and de- approaches to counter corruption are noteworthy. veloped countries alike. In the wake of the Enron, Other programs have a more technical focus. Arthur Andersen, and WorldCom accounting scan- The World Bank's work on corporate governance dals in the United States, efforts to improve corpo- emphasizes disclosure, transparency, the rights and rate transparency and good conduct assume a new treatment of shareholders and stakeholders, and the importance. Many such activities outside the WTO duties of board members. Using the OECD's Princi- are under way. ples of Corporate Governance as a benchmark, the To help combat bribery and corruption, the Bank prepares corporate governance assessments for OECD has recently established the Convention on its client countries to assess their institutiolal frame- Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in works for corporate governance. In addition, the fnternational Business Transactions. The convention, World Bank and the IMF together initiated the put into force in 1999, currently includes all 29 Financial Sector Assessment Program and the OECD members and five nonmenibers (Argentina, Reports on the Observance of Standards and Codes. Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, and the Slovak Republic) as More broadly, the U.N. adopted the Global signatories. The convention makes bribing a foreign Compact in July 2000 to allay concerns about the public official a criminal offense. It also encompasses social effects of globalization on the developing noncriminal rules for prevention, overall trans- world. About 100 major multinationals and 1,000 parency, and cooperation berween countries, and it other companies across the world's regions are cur- ends the practice of allowmg tax deductibility of rently engaged in the Global Compact. Projects foreign bribes. Many countries, however, have yet to relate to making microcredit more accessible, reduc- modify their national legislation to implement the ing carbon dioxide emissions, fighting against human convention fully. Regional forums of cooperation can immunodeficiency virus/acquired immune deficiency also help. For example, the Inter-American Conven- syndrome (HIV/AIDS), and expanding of basic edu- tion against Corruption was established in 1996 in cation in local communities. In a similar vein, the the OAS; in April 2001, the Summit of the Americas OECD significantly revamped its Guidelines on created an implementation mechanism for the Inter- Multinational Enterprises in 2000 by adding American Convention. Experience shows that, for recommendations about eliminating child and forced anticorruption initiatives to be effective, participa- labor, improving internal environmental manage- tion by civil society, private agencies, and the general ment, addressing human rights, finding methods to public is critical. In this context, cooperative efforts combat corruption, and improving disclosure and by nongovernmrental organizations (NGOs), suclh as transparency. Transparency International, the Global Coalition for Africa, the Novartis Foundation, and the Public Source World Bank staff. rest of the economy, and can be sources of ulations that are consistent with local capaci- productivity growth for the whole economy. ties and national objectives. The international But the pace and form of investment liberal- community can assist with these efforts ization necessarily must vary across sectors through multilateral and bilateral develop- and across countries, because they require reg- ment assistance, government-to-government 132 I N T E R N A I I O N A L A G R E E M E N Tr O T 0 o M P R O V E I N V E S I M E N T A N D C O M P 1: I I 1 I 0 N information exchanges, and private efforts to quota arrangements, and other barriers- inform and assist governments. barriers that are common among developing Second, international agreements that countries as well as between rich and poor focus on liberalizing conditions of entry by re- countries-stifle developing countries' exports moving barriers that discriminate against for- and the investment needed to supply them. eign competition may help consolidate domes- Reducing these trade barriers would precipi- tic reforms at the same time that they open tate new investment in exports as these activi- new avenues for reciprocity abroad. Because tiCs expand, and some portion of this new of the sensitivity of investment regimes, espe- investment can he predicted to come from cially in services, any agreement has to allow abroad. The second set of externalities con- for country diversity and must permit govern- cerns disciplines for investment incentives that ments the flexibility to design liberalization in distort the allocation of investmenit. Coopera- ways consistent with their development strate- tive measures at the multilateral level have the gies. Because the GATS provides this flexibil- advantage of being conceptually clean and ity and addresses most of the remaining out- broad based. However, because investments standing restrictions, multilateral efforts could tend to affect countries in close regional prox- concentrate on expanding the still-limited cov- imity, countries may find it easier to work on erage of the GATS by increasing the number rules that curb disadvantageous competition and quality of commitments that allow com- on investment incentives through regional mercial presence. Harnessing the full force of arrangements. A prerequisite for collective reciprocity-both across modes (especially by action is information on the extent of invest- putting on the table any temporary movement ment incentives and their effects; thus, a mul- of workers) and across sectors-may help tilateral inventory of investment incentives is motivate this expanded coverage. a high priority. One option is to set up an an- Third, an international agreement that nual surveillance process, perhaps under the seeks to substantially increase investment auspices of the WTO or as part of the IMF's flows by increasing investor protections seems annual surveillance. destined, on the basis of available evidence, to Finally, if new investment arrangements fall short of expectations. Some key issues are leverage reciprocal commitments for reforms already covered by relatively strong investor abroad on other issues on the trade agenda, protections in BITs. Moreover, it is not clear particularly new market access, then agree- that any investor protections emerging from ments would certainly help developing coun- multilateral negotiations would add markedly tries. These matters can be decided only in the to existing protections found in bilateral course of negotiations. agreements. Finally, merely creating new pro- tections does not seem to be strongly associ- ated with increased investment flows. For International agreements to these reasons, the overall additional stimulus promote competition and of multilateral rules that apply to new Invest- competition policy ment over and above unilateral reforms would promoting development requires not only probably be small-and virtually nonexistent policies to encourage investment, but also for low-income developing countries. policies to ensure that investmenit is produc- Fourth, international agreements can use- tive; among these policies, competition is one fully discipline two forms of beggar-thy- of the most powerful. Most pohcies to pro- neighbor policy externalities that are particu- mote competition are domestic, and an impor- larly adverse to developi-nent. The first and tant conclusion of chapter 3, this volume, is most important are investment-distorting that the reduction of policy-related barriers to trade measures. Tariff escalation, tariff peaks, competition is essential to raising domestic 133 G LO BA L ECO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 productivity. Among the many domestic policy arrangements that systematically hurt devel- barriers to competition, the most prominent oping countries. Competition policies in de- often involve aspects of globalization, such as veloping countries themselves can, in many tariffs, restrictions on FDI (especially in ser- cases, be improved through increased trans- vices), state monopolies, and competition- parency, nondiscriminationi, and procedural limiting regulations in postprivatized sectors. fairness. All of these policies are subjects of Competition policy that disciplines private re- international negotiation, but they have quite straints in domestic markets is also important. different potential effects on development. However, competition laws have to be appro- priate to local circumstances because they rely The most important restraints on heavily on the strength and independence of competition are policy barriers to trade the judiciary, the enforcement capacity of Exporters from developing countries- legal authorities, and probity in public admin- particularly exporters of agricultural prod- istration. A well-intentioned law in an map- ucts, textiles, and labor-intensive manufac- propriate institutional environment can be- tures and services-confront significant come a source of bureaucratic harassment and restraints on their ability to compete in global corruption. markets. Developing countries generally face Governments working together in a multi- higher barriers to exports than do industrial lateral or regional framework may be able to countries (World Bank-IMF 2002). Japan and enact policies that widen the scope of compe- the United States provide maximum protec- tition and thereby confer benefits beyond tion against imports from developing coun- those obtained from unilateral reforms. Analy- tries, while European Union protection is sis has to begin with the restraints on compe- skewed against imports from middle-income tition in the global marketplace that most countries. Developing countries, with average adversely affect developing countries and that, barriers higher than those in rich countries, if removed, would provide the biggest stimu- also raise barriers against competition from lus to development. other developing countries. Taken together, Three categories of restraints on competi- protectionist measures such as high tariffs, tion in the global marketplace are particularly tariff peaks, restrictive tariff rate quotas on adverse. First are those that involve policy low-tariff imports, and domestic and export barriers to trade that disadvantage exporters subsidies are ubiquitous and raise barriers to in developing countries by directly limiting competition from all developing countries. Be- their ability to compete in markets. The most cause the world's poor people usually produce important barriers affect agriculture, textiles, agricultural and labor-intensive products, the and other labor-intensive manufactures and world trading system is tilted against the poor. services. Second are private restraints on inter- The average poor person selling into the national competition that can raise prices to global marketplace confronts tariffs that are consumers or to producers in developing twice as high as those faced by people who are countries. These restraints include interna- not poor (World Bank 2002c; see also Oxfam tional cartels that are commonly illegal in 2002). OECD countries when they affect OECD mar- Subsidies and trade barriers in agriculture kets. Third are officially sanctioned restraints are particularly pernicious. In developed that may adversely affect developing coun- countries tariff rates in agriculture are twice tries' import or export prices. We discuss those of manufactures. Sheltering of agricul- below the effects of exemptions from antitrust ture by hefty subsidies aggravates the effects laws that governments grant to their firms of these tariffs (OECD 2001; World national export cartels, and the price-raising Bank-IMF 2002). The costs of such price sup- effects of ocean transport and aviation ports are borne by low-income consumers in 134 IN T ER NAT IO NA L AG Re E MEN T S T O IM P R OV E I N V E S T MI E N T A N D C O M P E T I T I O N protected markets-those consumers who oping countries' terms of trade through its spend a large proportion of their income on effects on long-term world prices. Protection food, while the supports benefit only a hand- of agriculture is also common in developing ful of large farmers. The U.S. subsidies to countries-comparable in weighted ad val- cotton producers, for example, cost taxpayers orem equivalent terms-but is much lower nearly $4 billion a year-three times the U.S. when subsidies are taken into account (see aid budget for Africa-while adversely affect- World Bank-IMF 2002). ing low-inconme West African economies that Policy barriers restrain competition in produce cotton. High protection and support clothing and textiles with similarly adverse of the sugar industry in the European Union effects on developing countries. Developing and the United States is another example of countries account for about 50 percent of these harmful policies. Total OECD support world textile exports and 70 percent of world for agriculture amounted to 1.3 percent of the clothing exports (World Bank-IMF 2002). gross domestic product of those countries in Under the Uruguay Round Agreement on 2001, with the producer support estimates12 Textiles and Clothing, quota restrictions are to the highest in the European Union in absolute be abolished gradually during 1995-2005. terms (see figure 4.6). Prices received by The slow pace of removing restrictions on OECD farmers were on average 31 percent competition in textiles and clothing has re- above world prices (measured at the border) sulted in sizable losses in export earnings and (World Bank-IMF 2002). Though efforts productive employment in many developing have been made to lower protection for agri- countries. The combined negative income ef- culture in OECD countries, the recently en- fect for developing countries caused by quotas acted 2002 U.S. Farm Bill increases support and tariffs o1 industrial-country imports spending to a projected $45 billion, or 21 per- amounts to $24 billion annually, and the cent of producer income during fiscals export revenue loss is $40 billion (World 2002-07 (see appendix 2). This increase may Bank-IMF 2002). well aggravate secular deterioration in devel- Impediments to competition take other forms as well. Between 6 and 14 percent of the tariff lines of Canada, the European Union, Japan, and the United States are subject to Figure 4. 2001 ountriesptu$23 tariff peaks, in some cases at rates well over producers 100 percent (Hoekman, Ng, and Olarreaga 2001). Developing-countries' exporters may Producer support estimate by the OECD countries be displaced by high tariff peaks in Canada totaled $230 billion In 2001 and the United States (in textltes and clothing) and in the European Union and Japan (in agri- culture, footwear, and food products). Even though France exports 12 times more to the L4~7,242 mll1on United States than Bangladesh, U.S. tariff European union revenues on imports from Bangladesh were $93,083 million roughly the same tariff revenues on imports from France (Gresser 2002). Escalating tariffs-in which protection is lower for pri- United States Inary products but increases as the local value $49,001 million added increases-discourage development of forward processing. Chilean firms, for exam- Soturce World Bank-1\4F (2002) ple, can export fresh tomatoes to the United States, paying a tariff of 2.2 percent; however, 135 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 if they dry and package the tomatoes, the U.S. need to convince the importing government to tariff is 8.7 percent; and if they make salsa impose or tolerate entry restrictions, or need out of the tomatoes for export, the duty is to be able to raise private entry barriers 11.6 percent (Schiff 2001). By reducing the (Hoekman and Kostecki 2001). demand for higher-processed imports from de- In practice, post-World War II cases of suc- veloping countries, tariff escalation prevents cessful predatory dumping are the exception, developing countries from diversifying exports not the rule. More than 90 percent of all an- into areas of their competitive advantage. tidumping investigations would never have These tariff structures are common in poor as been launched if a competition standard- well as in rich countries (see World Bank potential threat of injury to competition-had 2002c: 45). been used as a criterion (Messerln 2000).'3 As Another restraint on competition is fre- it has evolved, antidumping has become a fa- quent recourse to antidumping and other vored vehicle for restricting competition from types of contingent protection. Antidumping imports, and it is applied with increasing fre- laws were originally created to counteract quency by developing countries against each predatory practices of foreign sellers into a other. Since 1995, countries have initiated home market. ThLs was the original rationale more than 1,800 antidumping investigations for U.S. antidumping legislation of 1916. The (table 4.1). Although industrial countries have fear was that a foreign firm (or cartel) could traditionally been the main users of such mea- deliberately price products low enough to sures, developing countries have been more drive existing domestic firms out of business active in recent years, led by India, Argentina, and to establish a monopoly. Once estab- Brazil, and South Africa. In the seven years to lished, the monopolist could more than re- 2001, developing countries initiated almost coup its losses by exploiting its market power. two-thirds of all investigations, well in excess For predation to work, the monopolist or car- of their share in world trade. However, devel- tel would not only have to eliminate domestic oping countries have also been the target of competition, but would also have to be able to nearly 60 percent of investigations, mostly mi- block entry by new competitors. It would, tiated by other developing countries. The re- therefore, need to have a global monopoly, cent steep rise in antidumping investigations Table 4.1 Many antidumping investigations were initiated during the 1995-2001 period Affected countries indusmat United Eutropean Dicloping Transition l Initiating country countries States Union counttnes counai es Total Number of investigations 511 102 313 1,086 248 1,845 Industrialcountries 128 17 67 363 114 605 Of which United States 79 0 46 146 30 255 European Unton 15 6 0 165 66 246 Developing countries 379 85 242 718 131 1,228 Transition countries 4 0 4 5 3 12 Percentage of investigations 28 6 17 59 13 100 Industrial countries 21 3 11 60 19 100 Of which United States 31 0 18 57 12 100 European Union 6 2 0 67 27 100 Developing countries 31 7 20 58 l 100 Transition countries 33 0 33 42 25 100 Souirce WTO Secretariat, as reported In World Bank-IMF 2002 136 IN T ER NAT IO NA L AG RE E MEN TS T O I M P R O V E I N V E S T M E N T A N D C O M P E T I T I O N puts the predictability and nondiscriminatory countries. These cartels are typically illegal application of trade policies at risk. when they adversely affect a country's own Removing these restraints on competition commerce. However, OECD governments from developing countries would have a big have no authority to prosecute cases when development payoff. These issues and detailed cartel activities function outside their national policy recommendations have been well ana- jurisdictions and cannot be shown to affect lyzed elsewhere (see, for example, World Bank prices of imports or domestic goods. 2002c). Suffice it to say that dismantling both The 1990s saw the uncovering of several worldwide trade barriers and agricultural sub- interinational cartels. Prosecutions of interna- sidics could increase long-term growth in de- tional cartels picked up after 1993 when the veloping countries by as much as 0.5 percent United States revised its anticartel enforce- annually, which, when taken together with ment practices to grant amnesty to the first termis-of-trade improvements, could reduce cartel member that cooperated with authori- the number of people living in poverty by as ties. Before 1993, approximately one firm a much as 13 percent by 2015. One-third to year applied for leniency under anrticartel one-half of the welfare gains would accrue to laws, and big cases were rare; now, one firm a the developing world (World Bank 2002c). month applies for leniency. U.S. fines against Because of the growing importance of South- domestic and international cartels during the South trade and the remaining high barriers 1990s totaled $1.7 billion. The publicity asso- among developing countries, removing the ciated with these prosecutions (many of which barriers to competition among themselves affected international markets as well as the would produce substantial gains (see World United States) encouraged prosecutions by Bank 2002a; and World Bank-IMF 2002). other enforcement agencies, including those in These facts underscore the importance of the several middle-income countries (for example, Doha Development Agenda of the WTO and Brazil and Korea). Antitrust authorities in the the various regional efforts arounid the world United States and European Union alone that could lower trade barriers to developing prosecuted 40 international cartels during the countries' exports. Because not all countries 1990s. will benefit from some reforms (such as re- Cartels that have been uncovered through moving the textile quotas), a broader reform law enforcement have had a substantial role in that covers all trade issues and is linked to increasing the prices to developing countries. development assistance is vital. Although estimates vary, the average interna- tional price increases caused by international Private restraints on international cartels have been estimated to be on the order competition can raise prices of 20-40 percent. The estimated price in- to developing countries creases resulting from cartels, as shown in six Besides policy barriers to competition, large high-profile international cartel prosecutions international companies with market power (table 4.2), vary widely-from 10 percent for can form cartels that fix prices, allocate mar- stainless steel tubes to 45 percent for graphite kets, and restrain competition. Although trade electrodes. Cumulative overcharges to devel- reform and the expansion of potential com- oping countries over the life of the cartels in petitors in markets around the world have the six cases ranged from $3 billion to $7 bil- undoubtedly reduced the scope for private lion, depending on whether SITC or HS codes cartels, the numerous international cartels un- are used. Developing countries imported 12 covered in the 1990s suggest that market products that had a value of sales of $11 bil- forces alone do not offer complete protection lion in 2000 and that were sold by interna- against price-fixing and market-allocation tional cartels prosecuted during the 1990s arrangements that raise prices to developing (figure 4.7); if price collusion were to raise 137 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table 4.2 International cartels can be expensive: estimates of sales and overcharge Possible overcharge to Cartel sales devcloping countries Ycars of Number Pocc Product cartel of firms srrc HS increase SITC HS Fines Vitamins 1990-99' $26.4 billion $10 8 billion 35% $3 05 billion $1 71 billion Almost $2 billion Citric acid 1991-95 111 $9 9 billion $447 million 20%/, $402 million $67 million Over $250 million Bronsine 1995-98 2 $598 million $409 million 15% $46 million $8 milliols $7 million Seamless steel tubes 1990-95 8 $26 6 billion $21 7 billion 10% $1 63 billion $1 19 billion 99 million euros Graphite electrodes 1992-97 23 $9 billion $7 billion 45% $1 35 billion $975 million Over $560 million Lysine 1992-95 5 $4 8 billion $913 million 10% $294 million $43 million About $200 million SITC = Standard International Trade Code, HS = Harmonized System Classification Notes Figures for each cartel span the entire period of the conspiracy Sales are approximated using export statistics from countries of origin of indicted firms and thus exclude domestic sales If participating firms are multinationals and the locations of their subsidiaries are known, sales are calculated by taking into account the exports of countries of subsidiaries When that information is unavailable and production is understood to be global, sales are calculated by using exports of all countries producing the cartel product Overcharge refers to Imports to developing countries / (1 + price increase) x price increase Sales calculations provided are based on the SITC Revision 11 and the HS 1988 a Because the cartel ended in February 1999, sales and overcharge estimates are aggregated from 1990 to 1998 Soturce Connor (2001), Levenstein and Suslow (2001), OECD (2000), and World Integrated Trade Solution database prices by an average 20 percent, the total over- questions about the effectiveness of prosecu- charges would have reached almost $2 billion tion as a deterrent for cartel behavior. More- in 2000. over, 24 of the 40 cartels prosecuted by the Despite the rise in prosecutions, reining United States and the European Union lasted in international cartels remains difficult. The for at least four years, indicating that market fines imposed by authorities often fall well forces are not always adequate to rapidly short of the estimated overcharges, raising eliminate cartels. The history of cartels Figure 4.7 Imports affected by cartels rose from 1981 to 2000 for both rich and poor countries Total imports ot twelve products where proven cartels existed (in billions of dollars) 35 30 25 25 ~~~~~~Imports to industrial countries_ ___- = _ __ 20 - .:; - ---- 10 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Year Souirce World Banik staff 138 I N T E R N A -r I o N A L A G R E E M E N T S T O I M P R O V E I N V E S T M E N r A N' D C O M P E1 I T I O N Box 4.6 The lysine cartel, 1995-2001 Lysine is a food additive used in hog and poultry The cartel had a significant effect on both po- feeds. The global lysine cartel lasted from 1992 tential producers and users of lysine. Lysine produc- to 1 995. During that period the five participants tion in 1994 was at least 20 percent less than under controlled more than 97 percent of global capacity. competitive conditions, resulting in lower production Cartel members engaged in price-fixing, allocating among the feed and meat industries that depend sales quotas, and monitoring volume agreements. In on lysine. Moreover, the cartel limited potential 1994, at the peak of the cartel's effectiveness, the developing-country competitors by Lising price dis- price of lysine reached about $1 .20 per pound, ap- crinminationl across regions, and it froze the relative proximately $0.50 above the competitive price level. positions of the leading firms in the market, when Estimates of the overcharges to U.S. customers compared with the very fluid situation before the during this period vary and are as high as $141 mil- conspiracy. Although a few relatively small produc- lion. Although no formal analysis of non-U.S. over- ers entered the market during the 1990s (mainly in charges is available, the observed lower prices in Hungary, the Slovak Republic, and South Africa), Asia suggest overcharges in the rest of thc world most new entrants began production only after the were lower than those in the United States. Accord- lysine cartel had been broken up In 1995. China, in ing to Connor (2001) a teasonable projection of the particular; has been a source of increasing lysine pro- global overcharge by the lysine cartel would be in duction. Nevertheless, the five original participants the $200 million to $250 million range. A more con- in the cartel continued to control 95 percent of servative estimate assumes a 10 percent overcharge global capacity at the end of the decade. on $1.4 billion in global sales during the life of the cartel, for a total of $140 million (OECD 2000: 1 6) Souirce Connor (2001) indicates that some operate intermlilttently over ability of prosecution to be very low (Eveniett, decades. 14 Lehmann, and Steil 2000). One option for curbing illegal international New initiatives to discipline illegal cartels ts to extend further the extraterritorial international cartels reach of industrial nations' anticartel laws Firms will be deterred from price fixing and (Hoekman and Mavroidis 2002). When a forming cartels if the fines for doing so, multi- competition authority in an industrial econ- plied by the probabdiity of being caught (that omy uncovers a cartel that affects markets is, the expected value of the cost), exceed the both inside Its owin borders and in other coun- extra profits that result from this anticompet- tries, then that authority could take enforce- itive behavior (that is, if the potential punish- ment action on behalf of all affected nations. ments for creating cartels exceed the benefits). A stronger version would have the competi- Reforms that raise the sanctions on cartels and tion authority take action even if the cartel that increase the probability of successfully affected a foreign market without affecting the prosecuting cartels will tend to dissuade more home rnarket. In both cases, the authority firms froi-n forming cartels, whether domestic could request help in collecting evidence from or international. The secret nature of most enforcement bodies in other nations. Fines cartel agreements poses a special problem and sanctions against the cartel would be de- because it implies that governments must ac- termined on the basis of its detrimental effects tively search for evidence or must encourage on all affected economies. cartel members to come forward with evi- Yet another option is to granc govcrnmcnts dence; otherwise, firms wvill perceive the prob- of developing countries-or their citizens- 139 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 standing in the major OECD countries so provisions have, unfortunately, been applied those affected could initiate private injury to illegal conduct uncovered during cartel in- suits against companies headquartered under vestigations. These restrictions on information the jurisdiction of a particular antitrust au- exchange are especially worrisome at a time thority. Because most antitrust actions are dri- when so much evidence about international ven by private complaints and through private cartels is being collected through national suits, such legal changes would markedly leniency programs, thereby suggesting that the strengthen the hand of consumers and busi- potential for information exchange could be nesses in developing countries to curb private considerable. restraint practices. The principal attraction of Another approach is a multilateral agree- such a proposal is that it would allow devel- ment. Proponents of including competition on oping countries to benefit from the sophisti- the multilateral agenda have gravitated to- cated investigative powers and regulatory ward a relatively narrow focus. They are seek- expertise in the OECD competition authori- ing disciplines on (a) the so-called core issues ties. The enforcement record in the 1990s sug- of nondiscrimination, national treatment, and gests that the overwhelming malority of cartel transparency; and (b) private "hard core" in- members have their headquarters in industrial ternational cartels. These disciplines would economies. A drawback to the proposal is that apply to all WTO members, both industrial extraterritorial application is a perennial and developing, with technical assistance and source of tensions among countries, and the capacity building envisaged. Most recent dis- incentives are low for OECD governments to cussions have emphasized the need for volun- take actions against their own firms for effects tary international cooperation (Anderson and in foreign markets. Jenny 2001).)S A more modest option for reform could In summary, policies that help developing focus on notification and information ex- countries discipline international cartels more changes by national enforcement authorities. effectively would have a potentially large ben- This exchange would build on the growing efit, for consumers in rich and poor countries number of bilateral cooperation agreements alike. on competition matters, thus expanding their scope to include many more economies. The Officially sanctioned private restraints can objective here is to raise the probability of suc- hurt trade to developing countries ... cessfully prosecuting cartels by encouraging Officially sanctioned restraints on trade make the sharing of conspiracy-related information up the third major category of competition between enforcement authorities. The modali- restrictions that adversely affect developing ties for this type of international cooperation countries. These restraints take the form of have received considerable attention in recent exemptions from domestic antitrust laws and years, not the least of which is the OECD's pertain to certain types of international activ- nonbinding Recommendation on Hard Core ity. Many governments legally permit their Cartels. However, this approach essentially of- own private firms to cartelize export mar- fers gains only to those economies that have kets-as long as markets affected are outside effective competition laws, and many devel- the country, and export cartels do not provide oping economies do not. Furthermore, the an opportunity for producers to fix prices amount of information that can be exchanged at home. Indeed, numerous economies have on cartel cases today is highly constrained explicitly exempted export cartels from because most countries have laws against their domestic competition laws-essentially sharing confidential information. The original providing some legal cartel privileges for intent of those laws was to protect legal busi- their national firms, but not foreign firms ness secrets and pLans, and the confidentiality (table 4.3). U.S. soda ash producers have 140 IN T ER NAT IO NA l AG RE E ME NT S TO I MP R O V E INV EST ME NI AND CO MP ET IT IO N Table 4.3 National exemptions to competition law for exporters Country Type of exemptioon Reporting requirement Australia Contracts for the export of goods or Submission of full particulars to the national supply of services outside Atistralia authority within 14 days Brazil Joint ventures for exports, as long as there Approval by the national authority are 11o effects on the Brazilian market I Canada Export activities that dc) not affect domestic None cornpetitioti Croatia Agreements that contain restrictions that aim Notification of the agreement to national autlority to improve the competitive power of . h.-, days after coniclusions of the agreenenit undertakings on the international market Estonia Activities that do not affect the dtinestic niarket None Hungary Activities that do not affect the domestic market Nonie Japan Agretmients regarding exports or amonig NotticaElon of and approval by the industry domestic exporters administrator Latvia Activities that do not affect the domestic market i None Lithuania Activities that do inor affect the domesti mLiarket None Mexico Associations and cooperatives that export None New Zealand Arraigements that relate exclusively to exports Authorization of the national authority and that do not affect the domestic niarket Portugal Activities that do not affect the domestic niarker |.. Swedeii Activities that do not affect the doniestic market Nonie United States Webb-Pomerene Act activities that do not i. I i's Act, filing of agreements with the affect domestic competition i' 1.1 . ,Iade Commission Export Trading Companies Act strengthened F. 1 . , 0 .rJ Companies Act- Certificates of immunities granted by Webb-Pomerene Act Review provided by U.S. Department of Commerce Source Eveniett and Ferrarini (2002), drawn from OECD (1996), OECI) (2000), and (accessed May 2002) taken advantage of these provisions in U.S. legitimate in the past, most small- and medium- law to form an export cartel, which has sized enterprises in industrial economies today subsequently been the target of European export without a need for cartels, so the ratio- and Indian enforcement actions. Generally, nale is moot. these cartels may attempt to raise prices in Another exemption from OECD antitrust their export markets to the detriment of laws is maritime transport, which inadver- overseas consumers. Their success depends on tently put developing countries at the mercy the number of other foreign competitors in of price fixing. The exemption in U.S. law these markets. Because competitioll is more extended to maritime transport has facili- likely to be limited in the smaller markets tated, through shipping conferences, collusive of developing countries, it is probable that de- arrangements in ocean-liner shipping. Agree- veloping countries are adversely affected ments among private shlipping companies disproportionately. have a long history, beginning with trade be- Because cartel registers are secret in Europe tween the United Kingdom and India in the and Japan, and virtually secret in the United 1870s. Such arrangements have taken differ- States, information on their extent, products, ent forms, includinig the conclusion of agree- and geographic coverage is nil. The legal ex- ments on uniform freight tariff rates and emptions are known, and the latest available conditions of service, the establishment of ex- information-from the OECD in 1974-has clusive or preferential working relationships indicated a broad proliferation. The initial between shipping Iines, or the integration of rationale for export cartel exemptions was that shipping networks through strategic alliances. small exporters could join to share the The power of such arrangements has allegedly substantial costs of marketing their eroded in recent years because outside ship- products abroad. Even if such arguments were ping lines have gained a significant share of 141 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 Table 4.4 Breaking up floating cartels beyond their borders. Government support could help developing countries for beggar-thy-neighbor export cartels is (Econiomic effects of eiding private restrictioiis anachronistic in an era of global trade rules. on ocean-liner conipetitton) ______________ Reciprocal international agreements offer the Effect Amount promise of reducing foreign distortions to Reduction in price of ocean transport 20% domestic markets in return for commitments Projected total savings for U S imports $2 I billiorI to desist from such practices. Agreements on Proiected savinlgs for developing-country international cartels ivolve givig up some imports $2 3 billion _ rents from exporting in return for the benefits Souirce Fink, Matroo, anid Neagu (2001), WVorld Bank of more competitive markets at home. (2002c) A multilateral accord to curb export cartels would probably benefit developing countries. the market and regulators have moved to en- An alternative and less-ambitious approach is courage greater price competition. Nonethe- to narrow the coverage to sectors in which it less, Fink, Mattoo, and Neagu (2001) con- can be demonstrated that small- and medium- clude that a breakup of cooperative working sized enterprises cannot compete internation- agreements and price-fixing arrangements ally without a mechanism to share burdens among the major private carriers could reduce such as marketing costs, and so on. Because transport prices by 20 percent on U.S. routes, the extent of injury to foreign consumers is for a savings of $2 billion or more (see not known, a minimalist policy toward export table 4.4; see also Francois and Wooton 2001). cartels involves disclosure. If export cartels are If developing countries could save the same allowed to retain their legality, governments percentage of their import costs, then their should agree to require that firms seeking to total import bill would fall by $2.3 billion. establish an export cartel publicly register as This figure is probably an underestimate of such-and that those registries be updated an- the effect of breaking up private constraints nually and made accessible to the public over on ocean trade services for developing coun- the Internet. Furthermore, if these cartel ex- tries. Their freight charges are more likely to emptions were specifically to aid small firms, be subject to price-fixing than are freight then there is no argument for permitting large charges on industrial-country routes because firms to participate. low traffic volumes limit the number of com- Similarly, countries could agree to end anti- mercially viable competitors. For example, the trust exemptions for maritime transport and, European Commission found that the Associ- at the same time, give standing so exporters ated Central West African Lines abused its in developing countries that are harmed by dominant position by providing rebates to subsequent cartel activities can sue under an- shippers that complied with its policies, as titrust statutes. This change would have sig- well as carrying out other anticompetitive iificant effects by unleashing competition in practices. 16 this sector and by altering an arrangement that today drives up the cost of exporting and international agreement could from many developing countries. rein in their adverse effects Multilateral efforts to curb national export International collaboration can strengthen cartels, as well as to rein in private restraints domestic competition policies in regulated industries that have been rooted Domestic policies in developing countries in exemption from antitrust laws, are particu- have a significant effect on competitive con- larly well suited to the WTO. Most govern- ditions. Chapter 3 underscored the particu- ments today either encourage or acquiesce to lar importance of policy barriers to competi- national cartels that adversely affect markets tion, particularly in trade, in restrictions on 142 IN i ER NAT IO NA L AG RE E MEN TS TO I MP R O V E INV EST MEN t AND C O Nl P E r I I o N incomliing FDI, and in restrictions on new tion law is technical and requires the usc of entry (foreign or domestic) in regulated indus- skills that are in short supply In many devel- tries. Chapter 3 also concluded that the po- oping countries. Building capacity to apply tential role of a domestic competition agency competition legislation effectively will take was shaped largely by the domestic institu- time. Given that competitioni law is applied tional environment. In some countries with on a case-by-case basis, dealing with systemic strong legal and judicial systems, a compcti- trade and investment barriers and with gov- tion agency could help augment competition; ernment regulations that rcstrict competition in other countries with weak legal and judicial may generate a higher rate of return (see systems, establishinig a competition agency chapter 3). Kee anid Hockman (2002) have could be counterproductive if they become a investigated the effect of the existence of a source of rent-seeking and corruption. competition law on estimated industry International discussions on trade policy markups over cost. They used cross-country, have, since their inceptioni, seen domestic cross-industry time series panel regressions competitioni policy as an issue associated with that include data on the nunmber of firms bv market access. Competition policy is intrinsi- industry (turnover), sales (market size), and cally related to the principles of national treat- import competitioni. They concluded that ment and MFN treatment insofar as competi- antitrust legislation on its own has no effect tion law allows recourse to address certain on markups, but that imports and entry have kinds of discrminiiatory policies and arrange- a major and statistically significant effect in ments that deny foreigners access to markets. 1 7 reducing markups (see chapter 3). Competi- The launchiniig in 1997 of the WTO Work- tion law is found to have an indirect effect, ing Group on Trade and Compctition Policy however, by reducing the first order marginal signaled the beginning of the most recent in- effect of imiports and by reinforcinig the mar- ternational discussions about the interface ginal cffcct of domestic competition. That betweeni trade and competition, as well as the effect is stronger In the more-developed and possibility of multilateral cooperation on larger economies. competition law. Not all domestic competition The effect of government policies that re- matters give rise to internationial trade prob- strict competition for nontradables may be lems, and vice versa. There are sitiations more important from a developmenit perspec- when the lack of, or inappropriate applicatioii tive thani is antitrust enforcement, because of, competition law can impede trade and those policies affect the price and quality of market access, however. After five years of key intermediate inputs that determine the discussions, governments have progressively competitiveness of industrics on world mar- retreated from ambitious applications (such as kcts (for example, Fink, Mattoo, and Neagu harmonization) to proposals that focus on 2002; Francois and Wooton 2001). Depend- core principles, transparency, nondiscrimnia- ing on the capacity of governnmenit, a role may tion, and procedural fairness. Governments exist for a competitionl agency that reviews may perhaps also focus on provisions address- new policy and rcgulatory barriers to compe- ing illegal interinationial cartels (see discussion tition (see chapter 3, thlis volume, as well as above). Aside from these general principles, Anderson and Holmes 2002). the exact content of national competition As Winters (2002) notes, administration of laws could vary considerably in the range of competition law is complex, and its misappli- conduct and structural disciplines that they cation can have a costly and chilling effect on include. investment. Issues relating to the institutional From a national point of view, for compe- design, the indepenidence of investigatinig au- tition law to be a priority it must yield a thorities, the effective judicial review and higher payoff than other choices. Competi- appeal mechanisms, and the availability of 143 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 expertise-both legal and analytical-are all the national administration will operate out- critical issues for the effective application of side its direct control. Until a few decades ago antitrust law. Therefore, the development of most European Union member states had no competition law in many countries has oc- experience in the field of antitrust. Before a curred gradually over a long period, and con- government determines national priorities, tinues to evolve. The necessary administrative both the costs and benefits of competition en- apparatus cannot be put into place within a forcement ought to be considered, including short time frame. The institutional guarantees the possibility of perverse outcomes through necessary for a competition authority to be capture or corruption. independent from eventual political influence This discussion suggests that the reciprocal (so that it can concentrate on its mandate) re- bargaining and enforcement framework of quire government acceptance that branches of the WTO is less well suited to collective action Box 4.7 HInternatioinial cooperation aai±d competition policy S everal entities outside the WTO have activities that ICN, created on October 25, 2001, to deal with in- iare germane to competition policy. For example, ternational antitrust enforcement through regular the OECD launched a Global Forum on Competition consultations between government officials, private in October 2001 to stimulate a comprehensive policy firms, and NGOs from around the world. According dialogue about competition, and that goes beyond its to its mandate, the ICN will "formulate proposals previous activity of providing technical assistance. for procedural and substantive convergence through The Forum, backed by the OECD's Committee on a results-oriented agenda and structure." Its special Competition Law and Policy, engages in high-level status stems from the fact that it is maintained by the discussions with key officials from member and non- enforcement authorities themselves, has voluntary member countries, including countries that do not membership, and is not bound by rules, but rather have well-developed competition enforcement author- by a community of interests. The first annual confer- ities. The objective of the Forum is, first, to encourage ence was held in Italy during 2002 and sparked dis- common understanding and sharing of experiences cussions on reforms to the merger review process; among a larger number of competition officials and, the advocacy role and activities of competition agen- second, to generate benefits through cooperation, cies (especially in developing and emerging conflict prevention, and voluntary convergence. Its economies); and recommendations on best practices. first meeting successfully highlighted the role of Individual enforcement authorities will have the flex- competition policy and of its authorities In economic ibility to make decisions on the most suitable means reform; it also fomented greater international cooper- of implementing the recommendations. The ICN will atnon on such matters. The latest semiannual meeting address complex issues, and newly established com- in February 2002 discussed the merits of competition petition authorities will no doubt benefit from the policy for developing economies, international coop- collective experience of other member agencies. eration in merger and cartel cases, capacity building, Though it is too early to gauge the success of and technical assistance. In addition, the forum bene- the Global Forum on Competition and the ICN in fits from contributions of regional organizations such terms of fostering global cooperation, they play a as the Common Market for Eastern and Southern useful role in disseminating information on best Africa and international organizations such as the practices for implementing a competition law policy. World Bank, UNCTAD, and the WTO. Another example of an entity outside the WTO I with activities germane to competition policy is the Source: World Bank staff 144 IN T ER NAT IO NA L AG RE E MEN TS 'IO I MP R O V E INV EST MEN T AND CO MP ET I 'II ON on competition law than internationial col- cific objectives that will be important to de- laboration through development assistance veloping and reinforcing positive domestic and other venues. To be sure, international policies rather than distorting them. negotiations can help reinforce progressive For investnient policy, international agree- domestic reforms in competition law (see ments may help increase flows of foreign Birdsall and Lawrence 1999).18 However, in investment, but evidence suggests that these this complex area of domestic regulation, one benefits are likely to be limited unless they size does not fit all, and, as maniy WTO mem- focus on creating nondiscriminatory terms bers have noted, cooperation on competition- of liberalization and on eliminating adverse law policy requires establishing a domestic policy externalities. Agreements that curb enforcement capacity that at present is beyond beggar-thy-neighbor investment policies that the reach of many developing countries. Other distort investment location are particularly channels can help disseminate best practices to important in two areas. One critical area is countries wishing to strengthen their competi- investment-distortinig trade barriers-that is, tive conditions. Several agencies and forums border protections, agricultural subsidies, tar- have work programs on interiationlal compe- iff escalation, and other practices that bias in- tition policy. These agencies include the vestment flows away from developing coun- OECD, UNCTAD, and the International tries' export activities because such barriers Competition Network (ICN) (see box 4.7). discourage imports from those countries A The OECD and UNCTAD have developed second critical area is disciplining competition their own guidelines or recommendations for among governments to lure foreign invest- tackling international cartels, but they have no ment through wasteful investment incentives. powers of enforcement or investigation. The An important initial step is developing an in- nascent ICN has focused more on interna- ventory of the extent, costs, and distorting tional mergers and acquisitions, and it is in- consequences of those incentives. Agreements tended to facilitate informationi exchange and should be carefully designed to limit their disseminiation of best practices. scope to areas where international externali- ties exist. In the case of the WTO, the design should focus on reducing discrimination and Conclusions increasing market access. International coop- For both investment and competition policy, eration on the design of domestic regulation is Fdomestic reforms that are implemented more effectively provided through develop- unilaterally in the national interest of promot- ment assistance-whether bilateral, regional, ing a sound investment climate and a more or multilateral. competitive economily are likely to yield the For competition policy, an agreement most direct and positive effect on growth and would potentially have large benefits if it poverty reduction. The interinational commu- addressed those restrictions on competition in nity can assist the reform process through the global marketplace that most adversely multilateral and bilateral development assis- affected developing countries: policy barriers tance, government-to-government informa- to competition that hurt exporters, private re- tion exchanges, and private efforts to inforimi straints in the form of international cartels, and assist reform-minded governments. Coun- and officially sanctioned private restraints em- tries may be able to use regional and multi- anating from antitrust exemptions. Much lateral agreements to motivate progressive re- more information is needed in this area on the forms at home at the same time that they use prevalence and effects of policies that restrict reforms to leverage reforms abroad to pro- competition. The international community mote development. Yet to be effective, these can collaborate with developing countries by agreements must be designed to achieve spe- providing technical and financial assistance 145 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 to foster mutual learning, information ex- the "financial contribution" that could cover the range changes, and cooperation on competition of fiscal and financial incentives that are used by de- policy. veloped and developing countries. These disciplines have yet to be tested. In the case of services, the GATS provides a mandate for developing "necessary multi- lateral disciplines to avoid such trade-distortive Notes effects." The work has progressed slowly 1. WTO 2001a, Paragraphs 20 and 23 in the Doha 10. There is evidence of significant investment diver- WTO Ministerial Declaration. The need for enhanced sion away from the Caribbean Basin countries and to- technical assistance and capacity building in these ward Mexico, but Mexico's adherence to NAFTA has areas was also recognized. almost certainly been a more important motivating fac- 2. See Ostry 1997; see also Hart 1996. tor than the use of fiscal or financial incentives, which 3. United States 1998, as cited in Gilpin 2000: 184. it can generally ill afford. 4. See Smythe 1998. 11. This is not to deny the potential risk of "invest- 5 South-South FDI is calculated by comparing ment poaching," including within developing coun- developing countries' FDI inflows with recorded out- tries. Studies have indeed documented the negative flows from other regions. This figure may be more ac- welfare implications that derive from incentive pack- curate than others because developing countries often ages that merely transfer investment from one location underreport FDI outflows In addition, round tripping to another without creating new jobs or improving of a country's own capital can overestimate the FDI productivity. In the case of Brazil, for instance, the con- figure (World Bank 2002a). sensus among researchers is that heavily indebted 6 For a cogent description of the predominance of states have granted very large tax breaks to automotive services in the NAFTA reservation lists, see Rugman companies to build factories that the companies had and Gestrin 1994 See also Gestrin and Rugman 1993. intended to build in Brazil anyway (Rodriguez-Pose 7 By 2003, all members must have completely and Arbix 2001). phased out performance requirements that were in 12. Producer support estimates are the annual place at the time of the agreement and that were grand- monetary value of gross transfers from consumers fathered through a notification process. All 27 notifi- and taxpayers to support agricultural producers. These catnons of policies nor consistent with the agreement numbers are taken from World Bank-IMF 2002. were from developing countries. Almost half of noti- 13. The fact that predation has very little to do with fied measures related specifically to the automotive sec- antidumping as it is practiced is perhaps best illustrated tor. Many of these performance requirements have by the United States, which has two antidumping already been phased out during the transition period. statutes. One, the Antidumping Act of 1916, maintains Ten countries that requested an extension of the tran- a predation standard for antidumping, the other, the sition were granted an additional four years, to 2003. Tariff Act of 1930, as amended, has a price and cost- 8. WTO members are faced with two options. discrimination standard. Invariably cases invoke the First, they can agree to re-open the agreement, which second act and not the first. seems unlikely. Second, they can seek to reduce or elab- 14 Epstein and Newfarmer 1980, for example, orate on the length of the Annex Illustrative List The found that a cartel for heavy industry operated off and issue is that, even though both notifications and dis- on from December 1939 through the mid-1970s, with putes have, to date, centered primarily on the "illus- overcharges of more than 20 percent on sales of steam trated" list (notably on local content and, less so, on turbines and other products. trade-balancing requirements), the agreement arguably 15. WTO members with established competition prohibits a greater range of as-yet unspecified perfor- enforcement seem to insist that a precondition for co- mance requirements. Introducing greater specificity in operation is that developing countries adopt legislation the language could enlarge the effective coverage of the and establish enforcement capaciry- "[C]ooperarion agreement or confine it to the illustrated list. with respect to competition matters [is] only possible 9. Within the framework of the ASCM the scope when a competition regime [is] already in operation, for discipline lies in the challenge of an investment in- that is, when there [is] a domestic competition law of centive that can be shown to be specific, to be within some sort and a domestic competition authority ex- the meaning of the agreement, and to be contingent on isted with sufficient powers to effectively enforce that export or on having an "adverse effect" on the trade of law . While cooperation could be provided within a another member. The difficulty of such a challenge de- voluntary framework of mutual interest, it would not pends on the specific types of policies that are in ques- be possible for a developing country to eradicate anti- tion. One of the key factors in determining a subsidy is competitive practices which had an impact on their 146 IN I ER NAT IO NA L AG RE E MI ENTS IO s MP R O V E INV ES I MIN T AND C O M P E I I r I o N markers unless it also developed a national competitioni Evenett, Simon J , and Benno Ferrarini 2002 "Devel- law" (WTO 2001c 27, para. 79). oping Country Interests in Internationial Carrel 16. See World Bank 2002c for a fuller discussion of Enforcements in the 1990s " Background paper conferenices on ocean liners, for Global Economnic Prospects 2002. Iunvesting 17 See WTO 2002. to Unlock Global Opportuntties World Bank, 18 Birdsall and Lawrenice (1999) write "iWhen de- WXashington, D C veloping countries enter into modern trade agreements, Evenett, Sinon J , A Lehmann, and B. Steil 2000 they often make certain commitments to particular Antitriest Goes Global: What Futture for Trausnza- domilestic policies-for example, to antitrust or other tional Corporatio;P Lonidoni Royal Institute of competition policy. Agreeing to such policies can be in Inteinational Affairs, and Washington, D C the interests of developing countries (be) ond the trade Brookings Institution Press benefits directly obtained) because the commitment Finger, J. Michael, and A. Winters 2002 "Reciprocity can reinforce the internal reform process Indeed, partic- in the WITO." In Bernard M Hoekman, Philip ipation in an international agreemenit can make feasi- English, and Aaditya Mattoo, eds., Developymenit. ble internal reforms that are beneficial for the country Trade, anjd the WTO A Hanidbook Washington, as a whole [andl that might otherwise be successfully D C World Bank resisted by interest groups. Fink, C, A Mattoo, and I C. Neagu 2001. "Trade in International Nlai itire Services How Much Does Policy Marter`" IWorld Batik Econtomiic Review 16 81-108 References Francois, Joseph F, and I Wooron 2001 "Trade in Anderson, Robert D., and F Jenniy 2001. "Curient International Transport Services- The Role of Developments in Competition Policy in the World Competition i" Review of International Econoni- Trade Organization." Antitrnst 16(1l) 40-44 Fall ics 9(2). 249-61 (May). Anderson, Robert D., and Peter Holmes 2002 'Com- Gestrin, Michael, and Alan M. Rugman 1993 "The petition Policy and the Future of the Multilateral NAFTA's Impact on the North American Invest- Trading System " Jottrnal of Iinternational Eco- ment Regime " C. D. Howe Commentary no 42, nomic Lavw 5(2) 531-63 C D. I-fowe InstitLute, Toronto March. Aykur, D , and D. Ratha. 2002 "South-South Flows Gilpin, Robert 2000 The Cballenge of Global in the 1 990s " Background Paper for Global Capttalisn- The World Economy rn the 2 Ist Cen- Developmtenit Finance 2002 NWorld Bank, tury. Princeton, N J Princeton University Press Washington, D C. April. Gresser, Edward. 2002 "America's Hidden Tax on Birdsall, N , and Robert Z. Lawrence 1999. "Deep the Poor The Case for Reforming U S Tariff Integration and Trade Agreemenits. Good for Policy." Progressive Policy Institute Policy Report Developing Countries?" In Kaul, GCunberg, and Progressive Policy Institute, Washington, D C. Stern, eds , Global Puiblic Goods. Internationjal March. Cooperation in the 21st Century. 128-151. Hallward-Driemeter, M. 2002. "Bilateral Investment [[City']]. Oxford University Press. Treaties Do They Iicrease FDI Flows'" Back- Cano, Wilson. [998. Deseqtilibrios Regionais e Con- ground Paper for Global Economic Prospects centrado Industral no Brasil, 1930-1995 2d ed. 2003. lnitestuog to Unlock Global Opportzitittes Campinas, Sao Pauilo- lnstituto de Economia da World Bank, Washington D.C. UNICAMP Hart, N4 1996, "A Multilateral Agrecmenit on Foreign Chariton, Andrew. 2002 "Incentive Bidding Wars Direct Iivestmenit Why Now?" In P' Sauv& and for Mobile Investment' Economic Consequences D. Schwanen. eds , Investment Rules for the and Potential Responses." OECD Developmenit Global Econonmy Enbancing Access to Markets, Center, Paris, Policy Study 28: 36-99. Toronto. C D Howe Connor, John M 2001 Global Price-Fixing. Oir Ctis- Institute. tomners Are the Eneniy Boston. Kluwer Academic Hoekman, Bernard M., and Michiel Kosteck-i. 2001 Publislsing. The Polrtical Economy of the World Tradintg Epstein, B., and Richard S. Newfarmer. 1980 "Inter- Systeon: The WTO and Beyond Oxford and national Electrical Association. A Continuing New York: Oxford University Press Cartel." Report to the Committec on Interstate Hoekmnan, Bernard AI., and Petros C. Mlavrordis and Foreign Commerce, U.S. House of Repre- 2002 "Economic Development, Competition sentanves U S Government Printing Office, Policy, and the WTO " P'aper presented at the Washington, D C June Roundtablc "Inforiilng the Doha Process New 147 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Trade Research for Developing Countries." Oman, Charles. 2000. Policy Competition for Foreign Cairo, May 20-21 Direct Investment: A Stidy of Competition Hoekman, Bernard M., and K Saggi. 1999. "Multi- among Governments to Attract FDI. Paris: lateral Disciplines for Investment-Related Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Policies " Policy Research Working Paper no. Dcvelopment 2138 Development Research Group, World Ostry, Sylvia. 1997. "A New Regime for Foreign Bank, Washington, D.C Direct Investment." Occasional Papers no 53. . 2000. "Assessing the Case for Extending WTO Group of Thirty, Washington, D.C. Disciplines in Investment-Related Policies." Jour- Oxfam (Oxfam International). 2002. "Rigged Rules nal of Economic Integration 15(4) 629-53 and Double Standards: Trade, Globalization and (December) the Fight Against Global Poverty." London. Hoekman, Bernard M., Francis Ng, and M Olarreaga. Rodriguez-Pose, Andres, and Glauco Arbix. 2001. 2001. "Eliminating Excessive Tariffs on Ex- "Strategies of Waste: Bidding Wars in the ports of Least-Developed Countries." Working Brazilian Automobile Actor." Internatzonal Jour- Paper no. 2604. World Bank, Washington, nal of Urban and Regional Research 2(1): 134-54 D C. May (March). Kee, Hiau L., and Bernard M. Hoekman. 2002. "Com- Rugman, Alan M., and Michael Gestrin. 1994. petition Law as Market Discipline." Development "NAFTA's Treatment of Foreign Investmiient." In Research Group, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Alan M. Rugman, ed., Foreign Investment and Processed NAFTA 47-79. Columbia, S. C.: University of Levenstein, Margaret, and V. Suslow. 2001 "Private South Carolina Press. International Cartels and Their Effects on Devel- Sauve, Pierre. 2002. "Collective Action Issues in In- oping Countries." Background paper for the vestment Rule-Making." Background Paper for World Bank's World Developnient Report 2001. Global Economic Prospects 2003: Investing to World Bank, Washington, D C Unlock Global Opportunities World Bank, Mattoo, Aaditya 2000. "Developing Countries in Washington, D C. the New Round of GATS Negotiations: Towards Sauve, Pierre, and Christopher Wilkie. 2000 "Invest- a Pro-Active Role." World Economy 23(4): ment Liberalisation in GATS." In Pierre Sauve 471-89. and Robert M. Stern, eds., GATS 2000: New Di- . 2002 "Shaping Future Rules for Trade in rections in Services Trade Liberalization 331-63. Services: Lessons from the GATS." In Takatoshi Washington, D.C.: Centre for Business and Gov- Ito and Anne Krueger, eds., Trade in Services. ernment, Harvard University, and Brookings Cambridge, Mass: NBER. Institution Press. Messerlin, Patrick A. 2000 Measuring the Costs of Schiff, Maurice. 2001 "Chile's Trade Policy: An Protection in Europe Washington, D.C Institute Assessment." World Bank, Washington, D C. for International Economics. November. Processed Moran, Theodore. 2002. "The Relationship between Smythe, Elizabeth. 1998. "Agenda Formation and the Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Develop- Negotiation of Investment Rules at the WTO: ment: New Evidence, Strategy, and Tactics under The History of a Campaign." Paper presented at the Doha Development Agenda Negotiations " the Annual Meeting of the International Studies Paper prepared for Asian Development Bank's Association, Washington, D.C. February 18. Study on Regional Integration and Trade: Emerg- Stern, Robert M. 2002. "Quantifying Barriers to Trade ing Policy Issues for Selected Developing Member in Services." In Bernard M. Hoekman, Philip Eng- Countries, September. lish, and Aaditya Mattoo, eds., Development, OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Trade, and the WTO: A Handbook Washington, Development). 1974. Export Cartels. Report of D.C.- World Bank. the Committee of Experts on Restrictive Business UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Practices. Paris: OECD. Development). 1998. World Investment Report. . 1996. "Antitrust and Market Access. The New York: United Nations. Scope and Coverage of Competition Laws and 1999. World Investment Report. New York: Implications for Trade." Paris: OECD. United Nations. 2000. Hard Care Cartels. Paris: OECD. . 2000 Bilateral Investment Treaties 1959- 2001. "Agricultural Policies in Emerging and 1999 United Nations: New York and Geneva. Transition Economies: Special Focus on Non- - 2001a. World Investment Report. New York: Tariff Measures." Paris: OECD United Nations. 148 IN T ER NAT IO NA L AG RE EM EN TS TO I MP RO V E INV ES TM ENT AND CO MP ET IT IO N 2001b Handbook of Statistics. New York World Bank-IMF (World Bank-linternational United Nations. Monetary Fund) 2002 "Market Access for 2002 World Investment Report United Developing Country Exports-Selected Issues Nations September. United States 1998 Economitc Report of the Presi- WTO (World Trade Organization) 2001a "Doha dent. Washington, D C U S Government Print- WTO Ministerial Declaration." (WT/MIN(01)/ ing Office February DEC/1) November Winters, Alan. 2002. "Doha and the World Poverty 2001b. "International Trade Statistics Targets " Paper presented at the ABCDE Confer- 2001c. "Report of the Working Group on the ence World Bank, Washington, D C. April. Interactioni between Trade and Competition World Bank 2002a. Global Development Finance. Policy to the General Council." (WT/WGTCP/5). Washingtoni, D C World Bank. October 8 2002b World Development Indicators . 2002. "Core Principles, Including Trans- Washington, D.C.: World Bank parency, Non-Discrimination, and Procedural 2002c. Global Economic Prospects' Making Awareness." Background note by Secretariat. Trade Work for the World's Poor. Washington, (WT/WGTCP/W/209). Geneva, September 19 D C.: World Bank 149 Appendix 1 Regional Economic Prospects East Asia and Pacific The recovery so far has been underpinned by both external and domestic demand. A Recent developments gradual pickup in world conditions from T HE EAST ASIA ECONOMIC RECOVERY 2001's severe global slowdown supported a that began in late 2001 continued to revival of exports, including exports in the imn- strengthen in the first half of 2002, but portant high-tech sector. U.S. dollar prices for momentum slowed after the summer and uni- many important East Asian primary commod- certainties have increased. Output growth in ity exports such as rice, rubber, palm oil, co- developing East Asia is estimated to have risen conut products, and lumber also rose sharply to 6.3 percent in 2002 from about 5.5 percent after late 2001, although they rose from the in 2001, led by China growing at more than very low levels reached following several years 7 percent. Output growth has rebounded in which steep declines in the terms of trade most rapidly in those economies, such as the inflicted large income losses in many East Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Taiwan (China), Asian countries. Intraregional exports have Singapore, and Thailand, that had been hard- been strong, most notably those to China, est hit by 2001's steep fall in world trade and which jumped an amazing 50 percent in the high-tech demand. Annualized growth in the first half of 2002. Supportive monetary and first half of 2002 over the last half of 2001 (in several cases) fiscal policy conditions have jumped to a 5- to 10-percent range in most of fueled domestic demand. Household spending these economies, although industrial produc- in the region has been especially robust, boost- tion and trade data indicate that output ing spending on cars and other consumer growth softened in the second half of the year. durables, but private investment still lags. Elsewhere in the region growth had in any Debt-equity ratios, though they have fallen case slowed less among transition economies in some instances, remain high by internia- such as China and Vietnam, because of con- tional standards in most cases, and together tinued strength in domestic demand and a with low corporate profitability, continue to less marked slowdown in exports. Growth in depress the investment climate and undermine Indonesia and the Philippines had fallen less the prospects for accelerated medium-term sharply to a 3- to 3.5-percent pace in 2001 growth. from a 4- to 5-percent pace in 2000, and World semiconductor sales and orders for the cyclical rebound in these countries (while high-tech equipment in the United States re- more pronounced in the Philippines), has also bounded strongly in late 2001, but growth been less clear-cut than elsewhere in the rates had already peaked before the summer region. of 2002, and the levels remained far below the 151 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 crisis. Local East Asian financial markets have Figure A1.1 Emerging high-tech Asia: been remarkably resihent in the face of the semi-conductor dollar sales and global equity and emerging market turmoil. industrial production* On balance, countries in the region appear (percent change, 3m/3m saar) comparatively well placed to weather the pre- 125- Semiconductor - S0 sent high levels of external risk, especially 100 - g /sales (left axis) ^ - 40 if they can build on recent successes and con- 75 - [ Indusrial roduction 30 tinue to advance reforms that further reduce 50 - ( // Industritaxi p r o duclion - 20 their vulnerability to external shocks and fos- 25 -v \/ \ R 0 ter sources of domestic productivity growth. -25- - -10 Improvements in macroeconomic conditions -S0 __ __ -20 have been key to cushioning the impact of Jan Jul Jan Jul Jan Jul external shocks and volatility in international 2000 2000 2001 2001 2002 2002 capital markets on East Asian countries over Note Through August 2002 'Rep of Korea, Malaysia, the last three years. Most countries have Singapore, and Taiwan (China) Source SIA and national sources through Datastream, strengthened national balance sheet positions World Bank staff estimates by running continuous current account sur- pluses since the 1997 crisis, reducing foreign debts (including short-term debt), and build- ing up foreign reserves. The adoption of more record levels of 2000 (figure A1.1). A sharp fall flexible exchange rate regimes has also allowed in North American semiconductor equipment countries to adapt to external shocks more bookings in August and September suggests smoothly (while the recent fall in the U.S. dol- that this year's incipient revival in the depressed lar has alleviated concerns about a loss of global high-tech industry may have faded. Sev- competitiveness in countries with currencies eral East Asian countries report some slippage on a dollar peg, such as China and Malaysia). in August-September export and industrial A potential source of macroeconomic vul- production growth from the high rates reached nerability in East Asia, however, is the higher around midyear. level of public sector debt (including contin- Steep falls in global equity markets in June gent liabilities) accumulated after the 1997 through September, evidence of renewed crisis in several countries. Public debt levels weakness in industrial country growth, con- are quite high in Indonesia and the Philippines, tinued turmoil in emerging markets, rising and are not insignificant elsewhere. Public world oil prices, and terrorist attacks in the debt-to-GDP levels are now starting to fall Philippines and Indonesia are among the fac- because of rising currencies and lower interest tors that have substantially increased uncer- rates, and well-judged fiscal policy measures tainty about prospects for the region. can build on this trend so as to secure medium- term fiscal sustainability. Near-term outlook Private investment in the crisis-affected How well are East Asian countries able to ride countries still remains weak, compared with out new external and internal shocks that may pre-1997 crisis levels. However, these peak arise? Here the experience of the last two levels were based on overoptimistic expecta- years is cautiously encouraging. Neither the tions and abundant foreign capital. Continued serious export decline of 2001 nor the hefty economic growth, macroeconomic stability, terms-of-trade losses of recent years led to a low interest rates, rising currencies, and policy new wave of corporate and financial failures efforts to improve the investment climate in the countries previously hit by the 1997 should lay the groundwork for an investment 152 R EG I O N A L E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C L S revival in due course. Equity markets in East ness confidence could reduce Indonesia's Asia also fell sharply in this period, but over growth by 1 percentage point in 2003. Gov- the last one or two years they have generally ernments in Southeast Asia must now grapple outpaced industrial country equity markets. with a major security challenge that also has In countries with flexible regimes, currencies potentially divisive domestic political implica- generally rose against the dollar during 2002 tions-all at a time when many countries are while remaining steady or depreciating mod- moving into the next turn of their electoral estly against the yen. The stronger trend in cycles. A loss of focus on development and currencies occurred despite the fact that do- reform priorities could result. mestic interest rates in most countries were In this environment, acceleration of growth significantly lower than average 2001 levels, is unlikely, although there are also no signs of and is striking evidence of improving investor sharp deterioration. Regional GDP is expected perceptions of the region. to grow 6.1 percent in 2003 and 6.4 percent in The October terrorist attack in Bali is 2004. Growth in the region, excluding China, is also expected to reduce near-term growth in expected to reach 3.8 and 4.3 percent in 2003 Indonesia. Receipts from tourism represent4to and 2004 respectivcly. Median inflation is cx- 5 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in pected to remain low, albeit probably above the Indonesia, and in Southeast Asia generally. historically low 2 5 percent in 2002 With cx- Indonesian tourist arrivals could fall by port volumes growing at a rate of around 9 per- around 20 percent, based on the experience of cent, the current accounts remain on average at the 1997 terrorist attack on tourists in Luxor, a comfortablc surplus of 2.5 percent of CDP. the Arab Republic of Egypt, and the impact of previous political unrest tn Indonesia itself. Long-term outlook Lower levels of tourist arrivals and the adverse East Asian countries face growing demands impact of the attack on consumer and busi- for better-quality public goods and services, Table A1.1 East Asia and Pacific forecast summary (percent per year) Baseline forecast Growth rates/ratios 8T 2002 2003 2004 2005-i5 Real GDP growth SOS I 6 3 6 1 6 4 6 2 Private consuimptioti per capita £ iJ v 5 7 5.2 s 6 5 6 GDPper capitr a 4S 5 4 5 2 5 6 5 4 P'opulation l DJ!D I 0 9 0 9 0 8 07 Gross domestic InvestmentlGDP° St 1 31L11 32 8 33 9 34 9 30 4 Inflatiornb £5 IJD j 2 5 3 6 3 6 Central gvt bridget balance/GDP _f =B =3 -U 336 -3 4 -3.3 Export market growthc G) =IN LM ) 3 6 9 2 8 7 Export volumed - It 15 9 15 7 113 Terms of trade/GDPe A4 -0 5 -0 I -0 3 Current account/GDP } , 5i - 2 7 2 7 2 5 Memorandumrt items GDP growth East Asia excluding Chinla I 3 6 3 8 4 3 5 0 Not available a Fixed investmenit, miieasuired in real terms b Local currency GDP deflator, median c Weighted average growth of import demand in export markets d Goods and nionfactor services e Change in terms of trade, measured as a proportion to GDP (percentage) Source World Blank baseline forecast, November 2002 153 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 not least for better law and order. Protecting Efforts to strengthen regional cooperation the lives and property of the public and up- in East Asia have gained ground in recent holding rule of law are essential complements years, alongside the region's long-standing to the ongoing emergence or consolidation commitment to multilateral trade liberaliza- of representative or democratic government in tion and integration. The Association of the region, as well as a basic underpinning for Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) Free Trade economic development. The Bali terrorist at- Area (AFTA) came into force at the begin- tack underlines the importance of strengthen- ning of 2002 among the six original members. ing security and law and order, through both Association members now seek to build on national and cooperative regional efforts. their success in reducing tariff barriers and Continued public sector and governance re- fostering deeper integration by tackling issues forms are important if greater fiscal discipline in such as non-tariff barriers, product standards, East Asia is to be combined with meeting pub- customs procedures, trade in services, trans- lic demand for more and better public goods port and logistics, and investment flows. At and services, such as law and order, health, ed- the same time the Initiative for ASEAN Inte- ucation, basic research, technology dissemina- gration (IAI) has been launched to help new tion, and infrastructure generally. Many of these and less-developed members (Cambodia, the things are valuable to consumers in their own Lao People's Democratic Republic, Myanmar, right, are key elements of a productive invest- and Vietnam) build capacity and integrate ment climate, and provide a crucial underpin- more fully into the AFTA over time. Regional ning for political legitimacy and stability. There discussions and cooperation in the ASEAN+3 is now open discussion and acknowledgment of (ASEAN, China, Japan, and Korea) and other these issues in the region, though the pace of re- new forums also continue to develop. form is generally slow, except in the Republic of Against this background, per capita GDP Korea, Malaysia, and Singapore. in the region could grow solidly at a rate of Countries have generally continued to make around 5.5 percent during the coming decade, some progress (at varying rates) on corporate although this implies a slowing by 1 percent- and financial restructuring, reforms to improve age point compared with the previous decade financial supervision and regulation, and of rapid catching up. As population growth strengthening corporate governance. However, also slows during the coming 15 years-being most countries need to deepen corporate and 0.5 percentage point lower than during the financial sector reform efforts, as well as fur- 1990s-the long-run trend in GDP growth is ther the broader institutional agenda of foster- estimated to be 6.2 percent, 1.5 percentage ing private sector development and strengthen- point below the trend during the 1990s. ing the investment climate. It is notable that the sectors which are more dynamic are those where the corporate restructuring agenda is South Asia less urgent, for example, small- and medium- scale enterprises or large exporters who have Recent developments moved more quickly to resolve their debts. j rowth in the South Asia region is proj- This is especially important because China's ected to average 4.6 percent in 2002. World Trade Organization (WTO) accession is . This downward revision from the leading to a restructuring of regional produc- Global Economic Prospects 2002 forecast of tion networks, a surge in foreign direct invest- 5.3 percent GDP growth for the year largely ment (FDI) to China, and an increase in com- reflects adverse weather conditions, continued petitive pressures in other countries in the internal and external security concerns, and region, especially those competing directly the more protracted than anticipated recent with China in low wage sectors. global economic slowdown. As a consequence, 154 REG IO NA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS given slower demand growth, inflation has remained low throughout most of the region, Figure A1.2 Industrial production in notwithstanding high oil prices. Further, gov- South Asia ernment budget balances are expected to post (3-month movlng average, y/y percentage change) rising deficits in most countries. On an ag- 25 Bangladesh Pakistan gregate level, current account balances- 20 India which strengthened during 2001, reaching a 15 __ __I-it surplus in the case of India-are projected 10 to show a slight improvenient during 2002. 5 This is partly due to lower levels of imports, 0 which are generally projected to more than -s offset the negative impact of slow export -10 v volume growth dampened by weak external -15 v de i and. s, ,. qO. IO i4 iv i ii Because agriculture is a key sector in the re- - # -S -S W -S , @ gion's economies, important to both employ- Source International lMonetary Fund, international ment and growth, the recent drought has re- FiTaa1cial Statistics strained output, although the late rains (in some cases flooding) have somewhat amelio- rated the shortfall for the season. As a conse- quence, 2002 harvests are expected to be gen- erally smaller than in 2001, an outcome that is 2002, although it shows some firming relative cxpected to put some additional pressure on to the contraction witnessed in 2001 for most government coffers through increased trans- of the region's economies. During the second fers for drought relief. half of 2002, preliminary data suggest some Security issues are an ongoing concern, al- further acceleration of export volume growth, though there has been some easing of tensions although not as strong as projected in Global in parts of the region, paving the way for Economic Prospects 2002, given the more improved growth conditionis. The diminished protracted recovcry in world trade volumes. fighting in Afghanistan from late 2001, and Import volume growth has been dampened by the more recent introduction of a new govern- sluggish demand for raw materials and inter- ment in June 2002, has led to a rebound in ac- mediate goods by exporters and by weak do- tivity to begin rebuilding the economy from mestic demand conditiois. The overall impact extremely low levels and contraction in 2001. of these factors has led to a net improvement Throughout the region, the weakening of in the region's trade balance. This improve- economic conditions has complicated cfforts ment, combined with a rise in the region's ag- at fiscal consolidation. Although some coun- gregate worker remittances-reflecting port- tries were able to achieve budget targets by folio shifts following the September 11 attacks cutting expenditures-including spending on and, in the case of Bangladesh, a sharp in- development programs-to offset revenue crease in private inflows due to improvements losses, India notably did not cut expenditures. in the speed with which remittances are trans- Citing concerns about the magnitude of ferred through official channels-has con- India's domestic debt-estimated at 70 per- tributed to an increase in the region's foreign cent of GDP-Standard and Poor down- reserve holdings. Given the rcccnt weakness of graded Indian government paper to junk bond the U.S. dollar, a number of currencies in the status in October 2002. region have appreciated during 2002. How- External demand in South Asia's major ever, a general monetary stance of maintaining markets has been subdued in the first half of competitiveness suggests that these short-term 155 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 cross-currency dynamics will reverse and that provides the largest share of employment. regional exchange rates will resume a path of Higher rural incomes will feed through into depreciation. stronger private consumption growth, but prospects for investment-particularly in the Near-term outlook private sector-are more mixed, as continued Our near-term outlook is premised upon con- concerns over stability will at least partially tinued improvement in both domestic offset the impetus to invest generated by political stability and regional security issues- stronger domestic and external demand. In- although tensions will remain evident. A dustrial production will marginally underpace marked improvement in Sri Lanka's political real GDP growth, as the service sector contin- and policy environment, for example, should ues to provide the main near-term contri- allow that country to enjoy a sharp accelera- bution to growth over much of the region. tion of GDP over the near term-and, indeed, Our global projections of a recovery in into the medium term. In contrast, continued world trade prospects translate into strength- domestic political pressures would cause Nepal ening external demand conditions for the to underperform relative to regional growth economies in the South Asia region. Partly be- averages in the near-term forecast horizon. cause of the above assessment of the domestic We are also assuming a return to more economy, the region is forecast to post a firm- normal weather patterns over the next two ing of growth to an average of 5.4 percent in years, in contrast to the recent drought condi- 2003 and 5.8 percent in 2004. Trade balances tions discussed above. Agriculture accounts should benefit, although import growth will for approximately one-fourth of regional out- also strengthen along with external demand, put, but the impact of improved harvests will given the high import content of exports be even more pronounced for the poorest and high import intensity of consumption. households, for whom the rural economy Coupled with a modest deterioration in the Table A1.2 South Asia forecast summary (percent per year) Baseline forecast Growth rates/ratios 1991-2000 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005-15 Real GDP growth 5 2 4 8 4 4 4 6 5.4 5 8 5 4 Private consumption per capita 2.0 1.4 4.1. 2 6 3.6 4 0 3 2 GDP per capita 3.3 2 9 2.6 2 9 3.8 4 2 4 l Population 1.9 19 1.7 1 7 1 6 16 1.3 Gross domestic mvestment/GDPa 21 9 24.2 24.9 25 8 25 8 25 5 24 8 Inflationb 7.9 3.9 6.t 5 0 5.1 6 8 Central gvt budget balance/GDP -10.3 -9 7 -10.3 -10 3 -9 8 -9.2 Export market growth' 128 13.1 04 28 73 79 Export volumed 10 9 7.4 5 3 8 3 8 8 8 5 Terms of trade/GDP' -0.1 -0.8 0.4 0.0 0 2 0 2 Current account/GDP -1.5 -0 8 -0 3 -0 1 -0 2 -0 2 Memorandum items GDP growth South Asia excluding India 4 3 4 2 3 8 3 9 4 8 5 2 5 3 Not available a Fixed investment, measured in real terms b Local currency GDP deflator, median c Weighted average growth of import demand in export markets d Goods and nonfactor services e Change in terms of trade, measured as a proportion to GDP (percentage) Source World Bank baseline forecast, November 2002 156 REG IO NA L EC ONO MI C P R O S P E C I S terms of trade, these growth patterns are ex- Long-term prospects pected to translate into a slight increase in the Long-term growth in South Asia is forecast regional average current account deficit to to average about 5.5 percent, in line with GDP ratios. the growth forecast in Global Economic Macroeconomic policies in the region have Prospects 2002. This forecast is somewhat historically been biased toward accommodat- higher than the 5.2 percent average real ing growth and have generated fiscal imbal- growth posted during the 1990s. The higher ances. Generally, revenue mobilization remains projected growth over the coming decade, a challenge in the region. The unsustainable through 2015, reflects a number of underly- nature of fiscal deficits has been widely rec- ing assumptions, such as the assumption of a ognized by governments across the region- larger contribution of growth by the private although this does not imply that a consensus sector. This in turn reflects the expectation of has been reached. Therefore, the introduction progress with fiscal consolidation and contin- of prudent fiscal policies over the next two ued structural reforms, including reforms in years could be tempered by political consider- trade, banking, privatization, and infrastruc- ations, and by the need to address the lagged ture. These factors, combined with the im- effects of the current downturn in agricultural provement in human capital indicators in output. Indeed, budget deficits in many coun- recent years-such as rising literacy rates and tries could deteriorate in the next fiscal year. school enrollments, and declining infant mor- One of the key problems is the scale of public tality rates-will lead to an increase in pro- debt-large servicing requirements limit the ductivity. Despite a projection of declining scope for cutting expenditures, especially in infant mortality rates, overall the South Asian conditions of extreme poverty. The main issue population growth rate is projected to deceler- for the region is extending the tax base, but ate because birthrates are expected to decline progress to date has not been as rapid as an- faster. Lower population growth in the com- ticipated. The introduction of tax reforms in ing decade, along with the forecast growth India, for example, has been delayed. rates, implies that per capita GDP growth will Most regional economies have a general be close to 4 percent per year. monetary policy posture involving deprecia- tion aimed at shoring up foreign reserves and Risks promoting exports through increased compet- Downside risks to the forecast include a weaker itiveness, which is forecast to also have a pos- than anticipated recovery in global demand, itive impact on current account balances. This translating into slower export growth and conduct of monetary policies had been facili- lower regional GDP. Similarly, a continuation tated by relatively weak inflationary pressures of adverse weather conditions would result in across the region. In general, consumer price lower than anticipated growth caused by inflation in the region has been relatively low, lower agricultural output. Domestic political despite the droughts and firm oil prices of re- uncertainty could slow down implementation cent years. Several countries have subsidies for of fiscal and other structural reforms. fuel and some foods, a policy that cushions Regional political tensions also pose impor- the impact of imported inflation on consumer tant threats to the growth forecasts, poten- prices. However, these are being lifted in some tially aggravatilg economic disruptions and cases (for example, Pakistan). While the recent increasing poverty rates, as well as generating slowdown in demand will restrain price rises less severe effects, such as declines in tourism initially, inflation is forecast to rise moderately revenues and the reduction of foreign assis- later in 2003 and in 2004 as growth momen- tance. Generally, the region faces a number of tum builds, and as the average prices of non- vulnerabilities, as evidenced by the covariant oil imports rise. shocks over recent years-such as droughts in 157 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Pakistan, floods in Bangladesh, natural disas- of 1.2 percent. Negative spillover effects from ters in parts of India, and civil war in Sri the meltdown in Argentina began to affect Lanka. Vulnerability to such shocks has con- neighbors in the region in the second half of tributed to the high incidence of transient the year. poverty in a country such as Pakistan, and The external environment for most of Latin probably explains the large year-to-year fluc- America was more adverse than expected at tuations in income and poverty that are ob- this stage of the global economic recovery. served. Such vulnerability can also have a Despite low interest rates in industrial coun- profound impact on the growth prospects of tries, capital flows to developing countries fell, a country, since uninsured risk can affect the and the decline was especially pronounced ex ante behavior of economic agents. in the Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) region, partly because of the crisis in Argentina and its small neighbors. After Latin America and the Caribbean falling for most developing countries between October 2001 and April 2002, spreads on Recent developments external debt rose sharply for many LAC U nihke most other developig regions countries-Chile, Mexico, and small Central where economic growth strengthened American and Caribbean countries had only a Lin 2002, GDP contracted 1.1 percent small rise (figure Al.4). Few countries were able In Latin Amenica, about 1.6 percentage ponts to attract the necessary capital flows to sus- lower than antclpated in the spring. This tam a strong growth recovery in the absence growth deceleration from 0.4 percent in 2001, of rising domestic savings. U.S. growth, after a however, was the result of enormous eco- strong start in the first quarter of 2002, weak- nomic contraction in a handful of countries, ened significantly thereafter, while European fueled in large part by the external environ- growth was anemic, resulting in lower growth ment and aggravated by domestic factors. expectations for LAC principal markets in the Growth performance in the region, excluding short term. The region's export market growth Argentina, is expected to be 0.7 percent in rate was a disappointing 1.2 percent in 2002 2002, somewhat lower than last year's growth and was not helped by the price fall in key commodities exported by the region (for ex- ample, sugar fell by 26.5 percent, arabica Figure A1.3 GDP growth in LAC, coffee by 8.8 percent, bananas by 7.4 per- 1997-2002 cent, aluminum by 6.5 percent, and copper (percent y/y) by 0.2 percent). Moreover, tourism revenues 12 were weak because of reduced air travel from 8 Argenhina OiherLAC North America (affecting the Caribbean coun- 4 tries), and the collapse of income in Argentina o, , significantly affected tourism in Paraguay -4 \y \ and Uruguay as well as workers' remittances -8 \ to Bolivia and Paraguay. \8 Domestic factors are important in explain- -12 ing the weak economic performance in a small -16 -20 V set of countries, and these countries contri- Q1 Q1 01 01 01 01 buted most to the region's dismal growth 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 performance in 2002. In Argentina, the lack of Note *Other LAGC= Bra7dI, Chile, Mexico political consensus on a sustainable macro- Souirce Datastream and World Bank staff estimates econ1omic framework has delayed an Interna- tional Monetary Fund (IMF) program, shrunk 158 REG IO NA L EC ONO MI C PRO S rEC IS Figure A1.4 Spreads for selected LAC countries (basis points above US Treasures) 2,500 - - 7500 2,000 - -6 000 Argentina (right axis) 1,500 - A- 4500 Countrnes outside Bank sf esti tes Latin Amen dca e cu d,000- pt Ia o th a3,000 -- / ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Mexico 500 p T a o - 1.5M0 0 0 Jan Apr Jul Oct Jan Apr Jul Nov 2001 2001 2001 2001 2002 2002 2002 2002 ucSoerrce Dasasorea t and World Ba thk s eaff estimaoes net capital flows gcbn furtlor, and led to a reserves aond CatSIlg the currency to float, deep, protracted economic contraceiof in g x- and forcing thB authoritnes to ethebark obe fis- cess of 10 percent. This affected other Merco- cal consoidation and tmonetary tighted ig. surafflates deeply, especially Ui-uguay and, to GDP growth is estIloated to havc fallon by a lessdr ixtent, Paragtay and Bonvia. In Brazil, about 10 percant. Brazil was forced to tightea uncertainty associated with the elections as fiscal pobicy but was able to lower short-tari well as with th. global outlook weighed on pohcy rates owly teoporarily and experienced mvestor confidence f1 Spite of sorsnd macro- sigcalficant cicreases an long rates. The xpctial cconomic poelcies, siowing th pac ogeou Urgroth Brazul ina conveStr ent at the beginnng recovert . tn the Repcbrca Boglvariana de of the yea d gave way to a sore lmued second- Venezi. ela, asn acute poitical crisis that culmd- half growth. en Colotibca, the fiscal accounts nated in a short-ived coup coIntributd to a renai vauthcrable, with the governdecit mnak- resurgence in large-scalc capital outfhows, lttle tg sfiall progress an reducing the fiscal deficit lnvestmeat outside of the oll sector, and a stiep to brag debt dynamics oiinto a sustaable decline in growth. path in the wake of presidential elections, The conflueTnce of these factors weakened escalatin1g civil war, and lower-tliaii-expected the acceleration in growth that one would ex- growthi. Peru, in contrast, was able to make pect in the context of recovering global activ- progress in addressinig the fiscal deficit andc ity. Policy responses, constrained by hijgh debt in keeplnlg the public debt situation under levels, high external borrowviig requirements, conitrol; growtlh accelerated in 2002. Ecuador and contracting external fni1ancing, were Uil- benefited from relatively hiigh oil prices, but avoidably contractionary. In Uruguay, a fin- thc authorities had diffiCLIlty in reducing aiicial crisis elnsued as Argentnnies withdrew the fiscal deficit, a move rnecessary to rnana- a large amount of dollar deposits, depletn1lg tain tnacrocconioiiiic discipliile in a dollar 159 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 economy. In Central America, low export $10 billion lower than at the end of last year, earnings from falling coffee prices and weak due primarily to sharp declines in Argentina demand in the United States, and relatively and Uruguay. high fiscal and external deficits, limited fiscal expansion. And some Caribbean countries Near-term outlook were faced with little scope for fiscal expan- The region's growth prospects are expected to sion or monetary easing in light of declining improve in 2003, supported by strengthening tourism revenues; weak prices of bananas, of the global economy, particularly in trade sugar, and aluminum; and, in the case of volumes, commodity prices, and capital flows. Jamaica, a large debt overhang that was ex- The region's GDP is now expected to grow by acerbated by the financial sector crisis in the 1.8 percent in 2003-still almost 2 percentage mid-1990s. In Mexico, the government stuck points lower than the spring forecast and in to fiscal discipline-helped by higher-than- line with the downgrading of world growth, expected oil prices-and is making slow provided there is a turnaround in the current progress with key reforms, while being only uncertain political and financial market out- partially successful in increasing non-oil gov- look. Greater fiscal adjustment in a number of ernment revenues. countries with high debt and relatively large Overall, policies in Latin America were in- financing requirements is a necessity for reduc- strumental in keeping inflation from accelerat- ing economic vulnerabilities. This, along with ing in most countries. However, countries that reforms currently on the agendas of many had a sharp adjustment in their exchange rates countries, is needed to restore investor confi- due to a sharp fall in net capital flows did face dence (which will lower interest costs), attract inflationary pressures. Inflation (as measured more equity external financing, and reinvigo- by consumer price index-CPI) rose to fairly rate growth. high levels in Argentina (about 45 percent), in In the baseline forecast, it is assumed that Venezuela (in excess of 20 percent), and in Argentina will put in place an externally sup- Uruguay (about 20 percent). Given high debt ported macroeconomic program that will be levels and worsening public debt dynamics- reaffirmed by the new government after the due to high interest rates and depreciating election in March 2003. Depending on its currencies-most authorities were unable to actual timing, this would lead to a revival of pursue countercyclical policies, and unemploy- growth, possibly by midyear-but may not ment remained high throughout the region show up in strong annual growth until 2004. (21.5 percent [Mayl in Argentina, 19 percent If this scenario were to materialize, it would [September] in Uruguay, 16.2 percent [unel improve prospects for the smaller Mercosur in Venezuela, 17.2 percent [September] in countries. The base case also depicts a new Colombia, and 9.7 percent [Septemberl in Brazilian government that maintains prudent Chile). macroeconomic policies and succeeds in Slow world growth and external financing restoring market confidence. Regional GDP constraints compelled an adjustment in the re- growth is expected to rise to 3.7 percent in gion's external accounts. Import volumes fell 2004. for a second consecutive year (mostly due to There are a number of positive factors for sharp declines in Argentina, Uruguay, and the region that give credence to the baseline Venezuela), and the current account deficit forecast. Mexico has weathered the recent narrowed from over $50 billion (or 2.9 per- global downturn very well. Sound policies cent of GDP) in 2001 to below $25 billion (or have kept investors confident and inflows 1.5 percent of GDP) in 2002, with most of large, and the upturn in U.S. growth should the adjustment coming after April. The level bolster a rapid expansion in 2003. Chile also of foreign reserves in August was around has fared well in light of negative effects from 160 REG IO NA L EC oNO MI C PRO SP EC IS Table A1.3 Latin America and the Caribbean forecast summary (percent per year) 14 _ . Baseline forecast Growth rates/ratios jI.'1-2i iii .wi 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005-1S Real GDP growth 3 3 3 7 0 4 -I 1 1.8 3 7 3 8 Private consumption per capita 2.3 2 4 -1.1 -2 8 -0 3 1 9 2 5 GDP per capita 1.6 2.1 1 2 -2 6 0 3 2 3 2 6 Population 1 7 1.6 1 6 1 S 14 14 1 2 Gross domestic investment/GDPa 19.8 19 7 19 3 18 0 17 3 18 1 22 0 Inflationb 12 S 6.4 6.9 5 0 4 2 4 4 Central gvt budget balance/GDP -3.1 -1 8 -1 8 -2 6 -3 1 -3 0 Export market growth, 114 11.9 - I 5 1 2 82 8 8 Export volumed 8.6 10.5 14 4 7 11 1 10.9 Terms of trade/GDIp 0 2 0 6 -0.5 -0 1 -0 3 -0S Curreit account/GDP -28 -24 -2.9 |- 5 -1 3 -I 8 Memnorandum itenms GDP growth LAC excluding Argentinia 3 1 4 5 1 2 0 7 19 3 6 3 8 Cenitral America 4 4 2 9 1.6 21 3.1 3 6 4 0 Caribbean 3.5 6 2 2.7 3 6 4 3 4 3 4 2 Not available a Fixed investment, measuired in real terms b Local currency GDP deflator, median c Weighted avcrage growth of import demanid in export issarkets d Goods and nionifactor services e Change in terms of trade, measured as a proportion to GDI' (percentage) Souirce World Banik baseline forecast, November 2002 Argentina and adverse terms of trade, and monetary overhang and weak public finances. expected firming of copper prices should un- While it is assumed that the required political derpin growth. The policy stancc of the new consensus will be attained before the March Colombian administration has been positive 2003 elections, there are risks that the con- for investors, and it has strong support from sensus may not materialize that quickly. The the United States for assistance in resolving incoming Brazilian admitlistration will have the guerrilla war. Expected strengthening of to take confidence-building measures to re- metals prices next year should help Peru to verse the current market uncertainty. Should reduce the rise in external financing as the Brazil fail to maintain a sustainable macro- economy recovers from the 2001 recession. economic policy framework, its correspon- And the small island states in the Caribbean dent weak economic performance will have have shown resilience in the face of strongly a major impact on regional economic pros- negative external and domestic factors- pects. Venezuela will be facing lower oil Jamaica has stayed the course with tight fiscal prices, which will make necessary adjustment policy (a primary surplus of 9 to 11 percent of even more painful. And Caribbean countries GDP in the past three years); Trinidad and face the possibility of a delayed recovery in Tobago's economy continued to grow despite tourism, which would reduce the fiscal political uncertainty. space to tackle the ever-present risk of natural However, risks are on the downside in the disasters. short term. Argentina faces enormous ob- stacles in its financial system, and while the Long-term prospects situation has stabilized somewhat in 2002, Per-capita GDP growth over the long term the authorities will face a difficult situation (2005-15) is projected to average 2.6 percent in containing inflation in 2003-with the a year, 1 percentage point higher than the G L0 B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 growth achieved by the region in the 1990s. prices. Finally, the region still lags in financial Improvement in macroeconomic management deepening (which could help raise national in a number of countries throughout the saving rates), infrastructure, and quality of 1990s, albeit emanating from crises, should institutions-areas that need to be improved provide the basis for a good investor climate. before the region can attain high sustainable This has already encouraged FDI into the re- growth rates. gion at the fastest pace of all regions, even though this has been due partly to privatiza- tion of public enterprises and mergers and ac- Europe and Central Asia quisitions. The next wave of FDI is likely to be in greenfield activities, as witnessed in Costa Recent developments Rica's attracting high-tech firms. Regulation he slack external environment, espe- and supervision of financial sectors have been cially in Western Europe, is contribut- strengthened since the early 1990s, but there , ing to a general slowdown of growth remains room for further improvement. Poten- in most of the countries of the Europe and tial gains from global trade have increased Central Asia (ECA) region in 2002 relative to with trade liberalization during the 1990s, 2001. However, the region has weathered the leading to high and rising ratios of trade to recent global economic downturn relatively GDP (Chile, Mexico, the Caribbean Commu- well, largely because of fairly strong domestic nity and Common Market, and other small demand throughout most ECA countries, and economies are examples). Moreovcr, the re- sustained high oil prices to the benefit of the gion has been proactive in deepening trade in- oil-exporting Commonwealth of Independent tegration, especially with North America, States (CIS) countries. Whereas almost all ECA through negotiations to establish a Free Trade countries are facing a moderation of growth in Association of the Americas (FTAA) and bilat- 2002, Turkey is expected to post a recovery- eral agreements (Chile and Central America a massive swing from the over 7 percent col- with the United States). lapse in GDP that it posted in 2001-which is At the same time, the region remains more raising the region's average growth for the vulnerable than many other developing re- year. As a consequence, aggregate growth for gions. First, a high debt overhang from the the ECA region is projected to expand from an 1980s remains a problem to finance in many estimated 2.3 percent in 2001 to 3.6 percent in countries. In the 1990s, some countries con- 2002. Growth in the ECA region (excluding tinued to rely on significant debt financing, Turkey) is forecast to decelerate to 2.3 percent particularly in the public sector. Public debt- in 2002 from 2.9 percent in 2001. to-GDP ratios rose in some countries and the The Central and Eastern European (CEE) maturity of that debt shortened in duration, countries, in particular, have been affected by increasing their vulnerability to shlifts in in- weakening demand from Western Europe- vestor sentiment as they question debt sustain- their main export market-as well as by ex- ability. LAC countries may have to learn to change rate appreciation in many of the sub- live with less debt in the future, adjusting pub- region's economies. As a result, export volume lic expenditures as required. Countries need to growth has slowed significantly, although it create fiscal space during good times (boom still remains at impressive levels in a number years) to be able to conduct countercyclicaL of countries (such as the Czech Republic, policies in future downswings in economic Hungary, and Poland), as they have increased activity. Second, many countries, especially the market penetration (see box 1.2 in chapter 1). low-income coffee producers, also need to Thus, the consequent drag on GDP is not as further diversify their export base to reduce high as it might have been. Furthermore, eas- vulnerability to large swings in commodity ing iniport volumes-which largely reflect 162 R E G I O N A L E C O N OM N I C P R 0 S P E C I S Figure A1.5 German imports and CEECs exports in dollars, 1999-2002 (3-month moving average, yly percentage change) 25 20 15 10 /-/.\\ CEEC-exports 5 -10 -15 i prs German rnports' -20 Jun Aug Oct Dec Feb Apr Jun Aug Oct Dec Feb Apr Jun Aug Oct Dec Feb Apr Jun Aug Ocl 1999 1999 1999 1999 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2001 2001 2001 2001 2001 2001 2002 2002 2002 2002 2002 Sozurce inrernational ANionerar) Fund, Interiearional F inanoccal StItistics high import intensity of exports in all of the Turkey remains a key question mark. Indica- CEEs-are helping to reduce the impact of the tors for early 2002 polit to a recovery, facili- slowdown in export volumes. Strong domestic tated in part by the new reform program, demand, witnessed in most of the CEE coun- lower interest rates, and improved confidence tries, is partially offsetting the loss in impetus relative to 2001. However, uncertainty linkedl to growth from the slowdown in the external to the continued implementation of the cur- sector. Domestic demand has been generally rent economic program of the new govern- supported by lower inflation, easing iilterest nient, as well as heightened political instability rates, and expanding private constimption. In in the Middle East, could contain the building some countries, fiscal policy has become more growth momentuim, as interest rates have expansionary, notably in the Czech Republic, begun to rise and market sCentimilent is becorn- Hungary, and the Slovak Republic. Poland is ing more cautious. Lowering interest rates re- the main exception to this picture of relatively mains important to achieving a sustainabie strong domestic markets, with tight monetary public debt. conditions, weak wage growth and record Relatively firm oil prices-fueling fiscal unemployment rates translatinig into anemic linkages in oil producers and bolsterlitg intra- domestic detmanid. While inflationiary pres- CIS trade-have sustained the recent recovery sores have generally been subsiding in the CEE in the CIS subregion, partially buffering it subregion, they reainai significant (in double from the deterioration in external conditionis. digits) in Romania, Turkey, and the Federal Nevertheless, given the moderation in external Rlepublic of Yugoslavia. Many of the CEE demand, exchange rare appreciation in a counltries conltinue to rin relatively high cutr- number of counti-es (such as the Russian Fed- rent account deficits of above 4 percent, al- eration), and some easing in oil prices in the though sufficient external financing has been first half of 2002, growth is moderating sustained. Continued significant FDI inflows, throughout the CIS subregion. Hydrocarbon in particular, are helplig to finance the current exporters-Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Russia, account deficits, in addition to generally suip- and Turkmenistan-in particular have experi- porting domestic demand and regional growtth. enced robust groNvthi, although growth has 163 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 slowed significantly from 2001. Increased in- Russia's current account surplus has nar- vestment in production capacity in the energy rowed, although it remains very large. sector has also supported economic activity in these countries. Among the energy-importing Near-term outlook CIS countries, other factors have contributed Growth in the CEE countries is expected to to the continued strong growth, including rel- begin increasing again in 2003, assuming a atively good harvests in the Kyrgyz Republic firming of European Union (EU) import de- (combined with increased gold production), mand in 2003, which is projected to strengthen Tajikistan (combined with increased alu- significantly in 2004. For Turkey, assuming rel- minum production), and Ukraine. Not only ative political stability and the continued pur- because Russia represents the largest weight in suit of the current reform program by the new the subregion, but also because it represents a government, the recovery is expected to be sus- major export market for many of the CIS tained in 2003. Growth in the CEE subregion countries (in addition to some of the CEEs), is forecast to accelerate from 2.3 percent in continued strong growth in Russia has also 2002 to 3.11 percent and 4.3 percent in 2003 sustained growth in the subregion. As in many and 2004, respectively. As the EU accession CEE countries, domestic demand has been un- process moves forward, it is expected that the derpinned in the CIS countries by falling infla- first round of new members in particular will tion rates and lower interest rates. While in- continue to receive significant FDI inflows (in flationary pressures have eased in all the CIS addition to EU transfers), which will remain an countries, they remain a source of concern in important source of external finance and un- some cases, particularly in Belarus and Uzbek- derpin long-term growth.' While a number of istan. Inflation rates in Russia and Talikistan important hurdles remain-linked in particu- are also expected to post in the double digits lar to the negotiations on the existing common in 2002, but at more moderate levels. While agricultural policy (CAP), on the EU's budget, energy-related receipts boosted revenues, fis- and on transfers to new member countries- cal positions remained relatively prudent in the process is still on schedule.2 Growth is ex- the energy-exporting CIS countries, although pected to slow in the CIS subregion (through they became somewhat more expansionary fiscal and trade linkages) through 2004, as- in Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan. To provide suming significant declines in oil prices in both for budgetary smoothing, Azerbaijan and 2003 and 2004 (from a projected $25 per bar- Kazakhstan have created national funds for rel in 2002 to a forecast of $23 per barrel and windfall oil rents. With the decline in energy $20 per barrel in 2003 and 2004, respectively). prices posted in 2001 (in both real and nomi- CIS GDP is forecast to decline from a pro- nal terms) from the spike posted in 2000, the jected 4.4 percent in 2002 to 3.5 percent and fiscal surplus in Russia narrowed, although re- to 3 percent in 2003 and 2004, respectively. cent firming in oil prices should contribute to While Russia's current account is expected to some stabilization of budget receipts for 2002 remain in surplus over the near term, it is over 2001. In other CIS countries, fiscal policy forecast to narrow markedly as energy prices has been more expansionary, in general, gen- soften. In 2003 and 2004, growth is expected erating widening deficits (for example, in to average 3.4 percent and 3.6 percent, respec- Ukraine). Throughout the CIS subregion, cur- tively, for the ECA region as a whole. rent account surpluses (for instance, in Russia and Ukraine) are narrowing and deficits (in Long-term prospects most of the remaining CIS economies) are In the CEE, during the second decade of tran- widening somewhat, because of exchange rate sition, a number of factors are expected to appreciation, rising imports, and, until more contribute to stronger growth than posted recently, moderating oil export earnings. during the previous decade. These include 164 R E G I O N A L E C O N OM l I C P R O S P E C r s Table A1.4 Europe and Central Asia forecast summary (percent per year) . Bfasehine forecast Growth-, . i. i-**i-ii. 2'""' 2i.,i 2 22 Real Gi ,.-. .rh -I - . : 1 ;- Private oi.iuiiptL-) pcs iapin. H - 2t 1 1 > 4 o 4 u . o J 37 GDP per (apita -I 6 4 2 2 3 5 3 3 3 5 3 5 Population - 0 1 0.1 01 01 01 01 Gross domestic investment/GDPa ' *. 22 1 21.9 20 6 20 8 212 28 6 lInflationb . - -4 7 0 3 2 5 8 5 7 Central gvt budget halance/GD' -4 4 _5 4 -6 5 -6 2 -6 0 -5 5 Export market growthc ii' - 12.9 6.7 2 1 6 4 8 1 Export voluimed ' 1 10.9 8 8 6 4 8 2 7 5 lerms of trade/GDI" ,,, -1.6 3.0 -2 5 -1 3 0 1 Currenr account/GDP - -4 9 -18 -2 4 -2 4 -2 3 Menmoraidim itemns GDP growth transition cotintriesf -2 . 6 4 4.6 3 5 3.3 3 5 Ceiitral and Eastern Europef r 3.8 2 9 2 3 3 1 4 3 Cis -44 84 59 44 35 30 Not available a Fixed investment, measured iii real terms b Local currenicy GDP deflator, median c Weighted average growth of inmport demanid in e'spoir markets d Goods and inonfactor services e Change in terms of trade, measured as a proportion io GDP (percentage) f Excluding Turkey Souirce World Bank baseline forecast, November 2002 higher investment rates and ongoing restruc- achieved higher growth rates until diversifica- turing of the capital base. Continued improve- tion from energy becomes much more broadly ments in the policy environment, including based. Given the degree of energy dependence greater macroeconomic stability, are expected in many of the CIS economies, particularly to underpin the projected higher growth rates. Russia, the projected softening of oil prices- The EU accession process and coming mem- to an average nominal price of about $18 bership will continue to act as an anchor for to $19 per barrel for the 2005-1O period, in structural reforms and will help attract signif- the underlying forecast-implies a ratcheting icant inflows of FDI. While structural reforms down of the subregion's growth from recent are being pursued in many CIS countries, in high rates. general, implementation is not as advanced or as widespread as in the CEE subregion's Risks economies, and in some cases there is signif- Weaker than anticipated recovery in the EU icant resistance to structural reforms. This area would reduce external demand for re- implies lower long-run growth in comparison. gional economies, particularly for the CEE The recent boom in hydrocarbon rents has countries, and thus translate into lower provided an impetus to growth, facilitated the growth. In many CEE countries high current introduction of a number of reforms in many account deficits could become an important of the oil-exporting countries, and contributed downside risk for international credit, if FDI to an increase in investment outlays (particu- inflows suddenly dry up (which a pronounced larly in the energy sector). However, given delay in the EU accession process could the volatility of energy market prices, these trigger). For CIS hydrocarbon exporters, ecoilomies will not be able to sustain recently which are highly dependent on energy prices, 165 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 a sharper decline in oil prices than forecast strong. Meanwhile, countries where severe poses a significant downside risk. In Russia, as drought put a damper on agricultural pro- a consequence, a more rapid decline in growth duction fared worse and, as usual, the worst than projected would result in lower external outturns were to be found in countries experi- demand for a number of the other economies encing civil and political strife. But slowdown of the CIS and of some CEEs (that is, the was widespread throughout the region. Baltic states). Greater political uncertainty or The subdued economic performance in a reversion from the reform program in 2002 is attributable to the region's export de- Turkey could undermine its fledgling recovery pendence on European markets, where growth and result in much lower than anticipated was weak. As a result, exports remained basi- growth-and affect some of its trade partners cally stagnant in real terms. On the plus side, (including Bulgaria). Some of the poorest CIS there was a turnaround in non-oil commod- countries (Georgia, the Kyrgyz Republic, and ity prices, albeit from historically depressed Talikistan) have relatively high external debt levels. After reaching a low In October 2001, (up to 200 percent of exports), placing them at non-energy commodity prices rebounded risk of default if growth does not materialize sharply, gaining 26 percent in export weighted as anticipated and external assistance Is not terms by August 2002. The main contributor forthcoming. Greater political instability and was cocoa, which was up 80 percent, but other heightened tensions in the Middle East could commodities gained as well-robusta coffee prove destabilizing to economic (and political) up by 20 percent, cotton up by 33 percent, positions in the neighboring ECA countries, copper by 7 percent, and gold by 10 percent. particularly in Turkey and in some of the Because the upward momentum began late in southern-tier CIS countries. Aside from poten- the year, on an annual basis many commodity tially undermining tourism revenues, there prices exhibited declines in 2002, and most re- could be trade disruptions and a general rise in main well below peak levels of the mid-1 990s. the perception of risks in the region leading to Nevertheless, modest real price gains over the higher interest rates. medium term will deliver a measure of relief to external balances. Oil prices, too, remained stronger than expected, an outcome that, Sub-Saharan Africa though unwelcome to non-oil exporters, was a positive benefit to the region as a whole. Recent developments The disappointing results for tourism, S ub-Saharan Africa was not immune to which accounts for I 1 percent of regional ex- the chilling effects of the global recession. port receipts, reflected not only the weakness The slowdown may have been less pro- of Europe's economy, but the aftermath of nounced there than elsewhere, but the collapse September 11. Some important destinations- in world trade and steep declines in commod- such as Mauritius, which benefits from its rep- ity prices had a depressing effect on economic utation as a safe destination-saw an increase performance. Services exports, prtimarily in the flow of arrivals in 2002. Most other tourism, were further affected by the Septem- countries, however, only partially recovered ber 11 terrorist attacks. In real terms, GDP from the impact of September 11. According growth slowed from 3.2 percent in 2000 to to estimates by the World Travel and Tourism 2.9 percent in 2001 and 2.5 percent in 2002. Council (WTTC),3 Sub-Saharan travel and With the exception of Nigeria, oil exporters tourism exports slowed to just 1.5 percent generally outpacecl the region, especially those growth in 2001 before recovering to 4.3 per- where production was increasing-Angola, cent in 2002. Both years represent growth sig- Equatorial Guinea, Sudan-as oil prices, nificanitly below potential. The WTTC esti- though down from 2001, remained relatively mates September 11 to have cost 3.2 percent 166 R E G I O N A L. E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C T S of exports and 1.3 million jobs over the period 2001-02. Figure A1.6 Real GDP growth of In the domestic sphere, agricultural pro- Sub-Saharan Africa oil and non-oil duction was disrupted by drought and, in the exporters case of Zimbabwe, political disturbances. As (percent) a result, nearly 30 million persons were left 5 in need of emergency food aid. Approximately Ol4 half of them were in southern Africa, which Non oil experienced a second successive year of poor 3 harvests. Malawi, Zambia, and Zimbabwe were most affected, and because agriculture 2 constitutes a large share of their economies, 1 * 0 2 2 incomes and consumption spending were de- pressed. But Ethiopia suffered the worst, with o , drought putting at risk an estimated 15 mil- 2001 2002 2003 2004 lion persons. However, the effects were quite Souirce World Bank staffestimates localized. South Africa experienced a bumper maize harvest, which gave a strong boost to domestic spending. expenditure side, domestic demand grew at a South Africa sustained a recovery through 2.3 percent annual pace in the first half, re- the first half of 2002, with broad-based flecting buoyant fixed investment, strong pri- strength in agriculture, as well as in export- vate consumption, and a moderately expan- oriented mining and manufacturing, which sionary fiscal stance, though weak inventory benefited from the rand's weakness. On the accumulation slowed the pace. In the external Table A1.5 Sub-Saharan Africa forecast summary (percenzt per year) Baseltne forecast Gros.th rates/ratios 1991-2(00 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005-15 Real GDIP growth 2.2 3 2 2 9 2.5 3 2 3 8 3 7 Private consumption per capita -0 6 -1 4 0.7 0 3 0 8 1 3 1 2 GDP per capita -0 4 0.7 05 01 0 9 15 1.5 Population2 2 25 2.4 2 4 2 3 2 3 2 2 Gross domestic investment/GD)P' 16 9 17 9 18.7 18 9 18 6 18 2 21 1 Inflatiollb 9 8 6.3 5.4 4 3 39 4 2 Cenitral gvt budger balance/GDP 3 0 -0 6 -0 3 -0 4 -0 5 -0 3 Export market growth' 14 1 10.8 0.1 2.4 71 7 8 Export voluimed -- - 4 3 28 1 1 53 5 8 Termiis of trade/GDPe 00 2 1 -1 1 -1 5 0 2 -0 8 Curretnt account/GDP -2 1 -2 3 -2 2 -3 0 -1 .8 - 1 2 Memoranzdumrz atelt1s GDP growth SSA excluding South Africa - 3 3 3 6 2 7 3 7 4 2 Oil exporters 453 4 4 2.0 3 6 3 8 CFA counrries 2.6 2.3 3.2 2 9 3.3 3 8 Not available SSA is Sub-Saharan Africa CPA is Comiimuniautie Finaniciere Africaine a Fixed investment, ineassired in real ternis b Local currency GDP deflator, imedian c WXeighted average growth of import demand in export markets d Goods and noiifactor services e Chalige in terms of trade, measured as a proportion to GDP (percentage) Souirce World Bank baseline forecast, Novemiber 2002 167 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 accounts, tourism has been slow to recover nal performance. Overall, the forecast antici- from the effects of September 11, but the pates real growth rising to 3.2 percent in 2003 weaker rand boosted net visibles trade, and and 3.8 percent in 2004, around 1.1 percent in the current account balance moved back into a per capita terms. Faster growth in Europe will small surplus. The main concern for the South boost export volumes, and price trends will African economy was an uptick in inflation- remain broadly favorable as supply-demand not surprising after a nearly 40 percent depre- balances for most commodities tighten with ciation of the rand in 2001, but nevertheless the recovery in the world economy. Cocoa, al- putting upward pressure on interest rates. ready at a 15-year high, is the main exception. Robust wage gains were only partially offset Oil prices are expected to ease, though they by higher productivity, resulting in a substan- remain significantly above late-1990s lows. tial rise in unit labor costs. Nevertheless, mdi- While large, real price gains for commodities cations are that monetary restraint will prevail, important to Sub-Saharan Africa are unlikely and the outlook is for inflation to ease. The to be sustained in the medium term, the wide- rand stabilized at an average of 10.9 against spread introduction of structural reforms and the dollar in the first three quarters of the year, market liberalization are expected to raise after weakening to above 12 in late 2001. export competitiveness, and the region should In Nigeria, adherence to reduced Organi- remain a significant commodity supplier for zation of Petroleum Exporting Countries the foreseeable future. On balance, with im- (OPEC) quotas more than offset the impact of port price inflation remaining low, non-oil stronger-than-expected oil prices, while bud- exporters' terms of trade are forecasted to get gridlock constrained government spend- strengthen marginally in 2003-04. ing, resulting in a real GDP decline estimated Along with a modest improvement in ex- at 0.6 percent from 2001. Unfortunately, the ternal sectors, the forecast assumes a stronger strength of oil revenues may have also relieved domestic performance. The expectation is for pressure to implement urgently needed struc- a return to more normal weather conditions, tural reforms, as evidenced by the discontinu- which will underpin a recovery of agriculture ation of the informal monitoring arrangement and consumption spending, while faster with the IME Politically, the situation remains growth stimulates a cyclical upturn in invest- tense. Local elections have been postponed ment. Overall, domestic demand will remain twice, and national elections are now sched- the primary source of GDP growth, as rising uled for April 2003. President Obasanjo has import demand-constrained mainly by the come under strong pressure by the National availability of financing-holds net exports in Assembly on budgetary issues. If oil prices de- check. Indeed, current account balances are crease, as expected in the near term, Nigeria's expected to narrow marginally as foreign di- problems will mount, though there are indica- rect investment eases back from recent levels tions that these problems may be offset by with a slowdown in privatization offerings a significant medium-term expansion of the such as Air Madagascar, though at the same energy sector, consistent with expected OPEC time more favorable economic conditions policies. The United States is particularly overseas should have a positive impact on interested in expanding oil purchases from remittances. Nigeria in an effort to diversify sources of For the region's oil producers, weaker ex- supply to decrease dependence on the Middle port prices will be offset by higher production. East. Major new offshore developments are sched- uled to come onstream in the Gulf of Guinea Near-term outlook (Angola, Equatorial Guinea, and Nigeria) The forecast calls for growth to accelerate in over the next few years, and despite the fall 2003-04 on the strength of a pickup in exter- in prices oil sectors should remain highly 168 REG IO NA L EC ONO MI C P R O S P E C T S profitable. As in the past, however, more ment, will promote diversification, encourage general spillovers to non-oil sectors will be higher savings and investment, and stimulate relatively muted. As a result, growth of oil productivity growth. Despite a dismal overall producers will improve from 2 percent in record, the region boasts a number of exem- 2002 to 3.6 percent in 2003 and 3.8 percent in plary performers (Botswana and Mauritius) 2004. Falling terms of trade will widen cur- and cases in which policy reform has pro- rent account deficits, though oil prices are duced dramatic turnarounds (Ethiopia, expected to remain comparatively strong, Mozambique, Tanzania, and Uganda). At the above $20 per barrel, containing the pressure same time, a panoply of deep-rooted problems on external performance and fiscal accounts. will continue to plague economic perfor- mance. There are no quick solutions to low Long-term prospects levels of human and physical capital, poor The forecast anticipates per capita growth av- infrastructure, HIV/AIDS, civil strife and neg- eraging 1.5 percent over the 2005-15 period, ative perceptions of international investors, near the levels achieved in the mid-1990s. The and excessive export specialization will con- outlook is optimistic-such a result would sig- tinue to expose external sectors to high price nify a reversal of the region's long-term histor- volatility. Nevertheless, if the new realism that ical decline-but even so growth will fall short appears to be taking hold on the continent of what is needed to reduce poverty and proves to be more than just rhetoric, there is achieve the Millennium Development Goals. adequate reason to believe the moderate im- Sub-Saharan Africa will continue to lag behind provement in overall performance that the other developing regions, and by 2015 the forecast anticipates can be achieved. number of persons living on less that $1 per day is forecasted to rise by nearly 30 percent, from 315 million to 404 million. Middle East and North Africa The outlook is predicated on a continuation of broad trends toward better standards of Recent developments governance and economic policies. The great espite a continuation of high oil majority of countries in the region have begun prices, growth in the Middle East and preparing Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers, D North Africa (MENA) region slowed and nine are in different stages of implemen- in 2002 to 2.5 percent, down from 3.2 percent tation of the strategies. Early results seem in 2001 as the events of September 11, 2001, promising. At the same time, NEPAD (the New continue to reverberate throughout the region. Partnership for Africa's Development) and For the oil-exporting countries, growth re- other regional initiatives are enhancing the mained above 2 percent. The larger increases credibility of governments and strengthering in growth that might have been expected intraregional cooperation. There has been from both high oil prices and increased public encouraging progress as well toward resolving expenditures were offset by a slowdown in intractable conflicts in central Africa, even production and exports, a result of tightened though events in C6te d'lvoire, Madagascar, OPEC quotas put into place in 2001 to sup- and Zimbabwe underscore the fragility of port higher oil prices. To counter these effects, the region's political processes. Improved pol- some oil exporters have implemented expendi- icy environments should stimulate faster pro- ture programs financed with increased oil rev- ductivity growth and diversification from enues. In the absence of a strong private in- agriculture, and reduce export dependence on vestment response to the reform program it primary commodities. had implemented, Algeria, for example, put a These internal developments, coupled with four-year economic recovery program in place modest improvements in the external environ- worth about 10 percent of 2001 GDP, aimed at 169 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 positive agricultural growth of 2001 in Figure A1.7 Oil prices and current Morocco slowed down somewhat in 2002 accounts because of the less favorable weather condi- (dollars/barrel) (billions of dollars) tions. To prevent a potentially steep increase 29 - - 40 in the current account deficit, fiscal and mon- 27- - X ,O______ - 3_5 etary policies were tightened in Tunisia; this 25 - Oi -prices action contained domestic demand pressures 23 - pessre 21 - ~_ \ - 20 and reduced pressures on external balance 19*- _ _- 15 but exacerbated the impact of the slowdown 17 - Current account 1 0 stemming from the external shocks. Though 15- I o tourism has begun to recover gradually in 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Egypt, the recovery of the private sector has Source. World Bank staff estimates been hampered by unresolved problems with the exchange rate regime, which have their roots in the late 1990s. supporting growth in domestic demand while Short-term prospects enhancing social and economic infrastructure. Growth prospects for MENA are clearly con- Diversified exporters faced worsening con- Gent pospether Military ction- ditions in 2002, with GDP growth falling to tingent upon whether military actions are 2.2 percent, a decline of 2 percent from 2001 taken in the region. Assuming that there is no External factors leading to this decline include conflict over the next year (and thus that there the deterioration in export market growth for is a gradual resumption i confidence in the Egypt, Morocco, and Tunisia, as well as sharp region), the region's growth is forecast at declines In the tourism sector in North Africa 3.7 percent for 2003-04. A recovery would be and the several countries in the Levant, fol- expected for both oil-exporting countries and lowing the events of September 1l, 200n In diversified exporters. The public expenditure Egypt, the number of tourists fell 41 percent programs being implemented by oil-exporting Egyp, te nmbe oftourstsfel 41perent countries over the next several years to im- year-on-year in the last quarter of 2001, and cove overe next al support even by the end of the first half of 2002, prove minfrastructure, agriculture, and support tourism had not yet returned to precrisis lev- reforms in social sectors would help to icrease els. In Morocco, tourist arrivals were down by the public sectors contribution to growth. over 20 percent in the first half of 2002. For Growth is expected to average 3.6 percent some countries in the region, however, the declines in tourism from abroad have been partially offset by MENA nationals diverting Figure A1.8 Export volume growth their tourism to within the region. Tourist (percent) (percent) receipts may likely show an even larger decline than tourist numbers, as many firms in the 8 - \ Export market growth (right axis) - 14 7 . _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ -12 tourist sectors have discounted heavily. Ex- 6 - 10 ports to the EU have also suffered, in particu- 5Exportgrowth5 - B lar Moroccan textiles and electronics exports 3- - to the EU. Jordan has been somewhat insu- 2 - -2 lated from this situation, as its export demand 1 - \/ -0 from India and the United States continued to 0 - _ _ _ _ - -2 grow quite strongly in 2002. 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Internal factors have also contributed to Souirce World Bank staff estimates a decline in growth in several countries. The 170 R E G I O N A l E C O N O M I C P R O S P E C F S Table A1.6 Middle East and North Africa forecast summary (percenit per year) Blaselinie f-rccast Gr,n,ah rates/ratios 1991-2000 2000. 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005-15 RealCGDPgrowth 32 42 32 25 35 37 32 Private consumption per capita 0 3 1 4 1 1 0 6 0 8 0 8 1 1 GlP per capita 1.0 2 2 1 3 0 6 1 5 17 14 l'opulation 2 2 2 0 1 9 1 9 1 9 19 1 8 Gross domestic investnient/GDPI 51-2 21 6 22 0 i 22 5 22 7 22 9 24 3 inflantuin -6 0 4 8 4 2 4 1 4 0 4 0 Central gvt buidget balance/GDP -1.1 -1 4 - 1 -2 1 -2 4 -2 4 Export market growvth, 10 1 13.3 -I 0 3 0 7.8 8 2 Expoit voluned 5 0 7 6 2.4 2 7 5 7 58 Terms of trade/GDP' 0 - 8 4 -0 9 -0 9 -II -14 Current accoUt1/GD)P -2. t 6.8 5.2 3 3 2 3 0 9 Memtorandumi itenis GDP growvth Oil exporters 24 3 6 2 4 2 4 3 7 3 6 Diversified exporters 4 0 3.7 4 3 2 2 2.7 3 6 Not available a Fised iivestnent, measuired in real terimis h Local currenicy GDI' detlator, median c Weighted averagc giosth of import demiland in export miarkets d Goods anid iioni-actor services e Chanige in terms of trade, measured as a propoitioni to GDP (p rcentage) Soiiice World Bank baseline forecast. Novemilber 2002 for the oil-exporting countries, supportecd by would be expected to rise considerably in likely increases in OPEC oil quotas in 2003 to 2003-04, anid the tourism industry would meet growing demand in a period of tight also be expected to recover from its slidc since crude inventories. Additionally, Algeria's crude September 11, 2001, as the external environ- production capacity is set to increase, and its nient gradually improves through 2004. Some gas exports are expected to experience growth of the diversified exporters, sLich as Morocco unfettered by quotas, iclicating higher growth and Tunisia, wvill not be able to rely on gov- in the short term. However, much of the ernnent stimulus for growthi because of the growth increase in Algeria in the medium term need to pursue fiscal consolidation and keep would come from the large public sector stirn- large inflexible expenditures, especially the ulus currently under way. This would revive government wage bill, under control. Over- domestic demand for the duration of the ex- coming the vulnerabilities unveiled by the penditure program. In Saudi Arabia, the stock external shocks would call for a faster pace of market is performing well, and credit to the structural reforms to improve prospects for private sector is rising, auguring favorably for private sector investment. Morocco must rely 2003-04. The Islamic Republic of Iran will see on privatization receipts to lower budget the revival of the agricultural sector after sev- deficits, but this finanicing option will dimiii- eral years of drought, with the expansion in ish over the medium term as the better candi- gas exports and the continuing relaxation of dates for privatization are sold off and the import restrictions buttressing growth in the revenues from the former parastatals decrease, non-oil sector. implying higher deficits in the future unless Growth in diversified exports would be ex- expenditure reforms occur. This will require, pected to increase to 2.7 percent in 2003 and among other thmigs, public sector reforms, 3.6 percent in 2004. Export market growth in particular reforms related to the wage bill, 171 G LOB AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 that underlie high expenditures. Weaknesses Jordan is reaping the benefits of a more open will remain in the private sectors of several trade regime, and many of the North African countries. Jordan is weathering the downturn countries are pressing ahead with more liberal more successfully than other countries be- trade relations. However, budget deficits in cause of the high demand for its exports in these countries could lead to problems, partic- India and the United States, but weak con- ularly in those countries that rely heavily on sumer demand and subdued rates of lending privatization revenues to finance increased ex- to the private sector indicate that domestic penditures. The temporary nature of receipts weakness will continue. Egyptian private sec- from privatization makes reforms in public tor activity is weak, reflecting credit condi- expenditures (and the public sector policies tions and tight monetary policy (although that underlie them) and taxation of para- the recent 100 basis point fall in the discount mount importance in the future. Furthermore, rate to 10 percent will help somewhat); falling many of the Mediterranean countries are cur- bank earnings in 2002 indicate that private rently facing sluggish growth or stagnation in sector investment will remain sluggish in the the private sector, with low levels of growth in short term. In the current policy context, the private investment. This indicates the need for government will continue expansionary fiscal strengthening the investment climate and re- policy despite already high deficits and will moving bottlenecks in access to finance and put off the implementation of reforms that backbone productive inputs that hamper pri- might have the potential for high social costs. vate sector investment. In Egypt, long-term Recent political events obviously cast a prospects appear weak. The policy reform shadow over prospects in the region. The con- agenda has slowed, mirroring the slowdown tinuing uncertainty stemming from the poten- in the domestic economy. The current policy tial actions against Iraq would significantly mix includes an expansionary fiscal policy to affect the gradual recovery in the short-term counter the tight monetary policy necessary forecast. Oil exporters would benefit from to support the exchange rate. increased quotas and higher oil prices initially, In the oil-exporting countries, Iran has uni- but these impacts would probably be short fied its exchange rate, allowed the formation lived. Diversified exporters would suffer of private banks, reaffirmed its commitment more, particularly from declines in the to privatization, and is pushing ahead with tourism industry. Even the expectations sur- fiscal reforms. Algeria is considering the rounding military action within the region deregulation of the power industry and open- could significantly affect growth in the short ing the sector to private investment, and has term. Moreover, the effects of military action announced the privatization of public compa- on confidence in already fragile global capital nies. In Saudi Arabia, customs tariffs have markets may lead to increased spreads and a been reduced to pave the way for a customs flight to quality, particularly from countries in union with the Gulf Cooperation Council in the region close to the field of war. 2003, negotiations are under way with the WTO, and new legislation is being prepared Long-term prospects to increase competition in domestic capital, Even if relatively stronger growth perfor- labor, and insurance markets. However, many mance is managed in the short term, growth in of these changes are occurring very gradually, the long term is expected to average just over and some are being greatly delayed. Algeria 3.2 percent. has not pushed ahead with its announced pri- The policy environment affecting long-term vatizations, and reform in the power sector is growth is gradually improving in many coun- very slow. Many of the oil-exporting countries tries in the region, albeit at a gradual pace. in the region still have large and inefficient 172 R E G I O N A L E C o N O M I c P R O S P E C I S public sectors, and low rates of private invest- 2005-06, when Caspian oil production is cx- ment in the non-hydrocarbon sectors. Re- pected to comc onstream. forms in these sectors leading to efficiency gains and higher potential growth rates will be Notes required. I At both the June 2002 summilt in Seville and In the long tcrm, the region has to continue October 2002 sumiiilt in Brussels, the Europeani to address several obstacles. The region relies Community (EC) confirmed that eight of the ECA EU very heavily on a narrow range of external accession candidate countries (the Czech Republic, revenue sources, particularly oil, remittances, Estonia, Huligary, Latvia, Lithuanila, Poland, the and tourism, and this reliaice introduces the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia) are on track ro con- potential for vulnerability * i export earings. clude accession negotiations at the end of 2002 and Although several countries have adjusted to sigin formal accession treaties in 2003. The official n i ele , f d target is for enlargement to happen in time for the nominal exchange rates in recent years, fixed mid-2004 European Parliament electionis Bulgaiia and exchange rate regimes in several countries Romania are at an earlier stage in the accession pro- may adversely affect export competitiveness cess and are expected to accede somewliat later Turke) and offset gains made from trade and customs is also an accession candidate, although it has yet to reforms Receipts from tourism and remit- begin formal negotiatiolns. tances are vulnerable to the sluggish income 2. Following the forthcoming EC Copenhagen sum- mit in mid-December 2002, the existing 15 EU member growth il source countries and recuarring countries' national parliaments will vote to approve or political conflicts and potential military action reject enlargement. in the region. Oil revenue windfalls are usu- 3 WTTC. 2002 The Impact of Travel and Tourism ally temporary, and real long-term oil prices on Jobs and the Economy-2002 http.//www are expected to decline, particularly after wttc org 173 Appendix 2 Global Commodity Price Prospects rude oil prices increased about 3 percent agricultural prices will be more strongly influ- G min 2002 as a result of tight supplies and enced by supply increases and by recent Middle East tensions. Non-oil prices in- weather disturbances such as El Nifio and creased about 5 percent, led by a 9 percent in- droughts. The index of nominal non-oil crcase in agricultural commodities, which more commodity prices is projected to increase by than offset a 4 percent decline in metals and 5.8 percent in 2003 and by nearly 8 percent by minerals (figure A2.1). Uncertainty about the 2005 in real terms. (Specific forecasts for com- strength of the global economic recovery con- modity price and price indexes for 2002, 2003, tributed to the decline in metals and mineral 2005, 2010, and 2015 in current and constant prices, but the effect of uncertainty on agri- dollars are given in tables A2.13-A2.15 later cultural prices was offset by lower supplies of in this appendix.) selected commodities, such as grains and Agricultural commodity prices appear to oilseeds, because of drought. The weakness in have reached a cyclical low, after declining the U.S. dollar supported commodity prices. since mid-1997, and by 2005 nominal prices Crude oil prices are expected to remain are expected to increase about 13 percent over firm in early 2003 because of the potential for 2002 levels. The increases will leave nominal military action againist Iraq and tight supply prices of most agricultural commodities well conditions resulting from production restraint below 1997 highs. Prices of specific agricul- on the part of the Organization of Petroleum tural commodities have declined much more Exporting Countries (OPEC). Once Middle than the average decline because of large sup- East tensions ease, oil prices are expected to ply increases, weak demand, or both. Some of decline because non-OPEC oil supplies will in- those prices are not expected to recover to crease and Iraqi oil will return to the market. 1997 levels for the foreseeable future. Because The average price of crude oil is projected of large supply increases from Vietnam and to decline from $25 per barrel in 2002 to Brazil and because of slow growth in demand $23 per barrel in 2003. By 2005, crude oil prices despite low prices, robusta coffee prices, for are prolected to decline to $19 per barrel. example, have fallen to nominal lows not seen Non-oil prices are in the early stages of since the 1 960s. In 2002, cotton prices fell to price recovery. That recovery is expected to nominal levels, which were last seen in 1986 last about three years before nominal prices will and the mid-1970s. Palm oil prices declined begin to weaken. The strength of the global by more than half from 1998 to 2002 and economic recovery will strongly influence the reached nominal levels last seen in 1986. timing and strength of the recovery in metals In real terms,] robusta coffee prices fell and mineral prices. However, the recovery of 85 percent from 1980 to 2001, and cotton 175 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 metal to sustain price increases that can be at- Figure A2.1 Commodity price trends tributed to low stocks and expectations of tight (index, January 1997 =100) supplies. Gold prices also rose strongly in 160 2002, mainly because of the buyback of pro- 1Crude oil ducers' hedge positions. However, the decline Agriculture T in equity markets, weakening of the U.S. dollar, 120 IIIIAA, ? land nervousness about military activity in the 100 Middle East also contributed to the price rise. 80 A \J Crude oil prices began 2002 below $20 per 80 v_ \ +; 5L barrel because of weak demand, increasing 60 mti r \ supplies from non-OPEC producers, and over- 40 _________ _______________ quota production in several OPEC members. Nevertheless, OPEC production restraint has 20 been sufficient to bring prices back to the top of o, , OPEC's targeted range of $22 to $28 per barrel. Jan Jan. Jan Jan Jan Jan Significant OPEC cutbacks, which commenced 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 in early 2001, started to draw down crude oil Source World Bank stocks during the second half of 2002 and gen- erally supported higher prices. In addition, increasing uncertainty about a supply disrup- prices fell 61 percent from 1980 to 2002. Real tion from a possible U.S. attack on Iraq helped palm oil prices declined 60 percent from 1980 push prices higher-to near $30 per barrel. to 2001. The extreme price declines in agri- Real commodity prices declined signifi- cultural commodities resulted from a number cantly from 1980 to 2001, with the World of factors, including large increases in pro- Bank's index of agricultural prices down ductivity, slow growth in demand caused by S3 percent, crude oil prices down 46 percent, falling population growth rates and income and metals and mineral prices down 35 per- elasticities, and policies that support prod- cent (figure A2.2). Such declines in commodity uction in high-income countries. Several large commodity exporters experienced deprecia- tion of exchange rates. That depreciation, Figure A2.2 Real commodity prices which was linked to Asia's economic crisis, (index, I 980 o Iprc) further contributed to price declines. Metals and mineral prices fell about 4 per- 140 cent in 2002 as a result of weak demand, high A12 Agiculiure stocks, and continued production increases. A Metals & minerals recovery in prices following the October 2001 100 lows stalled in 2002 as the economic recovery 80 slowed and as industrial demand failed to re- bound as expected. Most metal markets were 60 in surplus, and stocks remained high. A num- ber of metal producers closed their production 40 V - 1 facilities in an attempt to prevent further stock- 20 Crude oil building and price declines. Despite such ef- forts, production increased in a number of ° I countries. That increase, coupled with an ab- 1970 1980 1990 2000 sence of strong growth in demand, pressured Souirce World Bank prices lower. Nickel has been the one major 176 G LO BA L CO MM OD I TY PR ICE P R O S P E C T S prices, relative to manufactures prices, pose modities, such as coffee, cotton, and sugar. real challenges for developing countries that Real prices will rise an estimated 11 percent depend on primary commodities for a sub- from 2002 to 2015. However, the rise in real stantial share of their export revenues. The de- prices is a reflection of current low prices cines are expected to continue in the longer rather than a change in the long-term trend of term as productivity increases in commodities declining prices relative to manufactures. continue to outpace those in manufactures. There has been considerable disparity among commodities: prices of some com- modities (cocoa) reached multiyear highs in Agriculture 2002, while others (coffee and cotton) have A gricultural commodity prices are expected recently reached new lows or continue to to increase about 9 percent in 2002 after decline. The disparity is related partly to the falling 9 percent in 2001. The increase follows different levels of carryover stocks, and partly sharp declines from 1997 to 2001 that reduced to the effects of weather conditions on supply. the World Bank's index of annual agricultural Droughts in Australia, Canada, and the prices by 38 percent. Prices are expected to in- United States reduced yields and contributed crease 13 percent from 2002 to 2005 in nomi- to increases in grain and oilseed prices. nal terms. That increase will recover a little The United States enacted a new farm bill, more than one-third of the 1997-2001 decline. which will be in effect from 2002 to 2007. The The recovery of prices is expected to be mod- bill raised price supports for many commodi- est because of weak growth in demand, con- ties and included some commodities that had tinued rapid increases in production and not previously been included under govern- productivity, and high stocks in some com- ment programs (see box A2.1). The European Box A2.1 U.S. Farm Bill O n May 13, 2002, the United States enacted a new new subsidies for dairy farmers as well as for pro- farm bill, the Farm Security and Rural Invest- ducers of lentils, chickpeas, peanuts, honey, wool, ment Act of 2002. The new bill covers a six-year and mohair. It expands the Conservation Reserve period, from 2002 to 2007. Low commodity prices Program, which pays farmers to let environmentally had led to a series of annual bailouts to supplement sensitive land stand idle, and it establishes a new regular subsidy programs under the previous law. The Conservation Security Program to pay crop farmers new farm bill essentially extends those temporary for improved environmental practices. bailouts through the six-year life of the bill. Under the 1994 Uruguay Round Agreement on The key features of the new farm bill are higher Agriculture, the United States agreed to limit spend- price supports for major crops, the revival of target ing on domestic agricultural support programs, which prices to give more subsidies to producers when are considered trade distorting, to $19.1 billion per world prices fall, and a large increase in conservation year. Since payments are not fixed, but are deter- programs. The bill continues fixed annual payments mined by the levels of market prices as well as the lev- to grain and cotton farmers. It creates a new target els of support, it is not possible to know whether pay- price system similar to the one abolished in 1996, ments under the new farm bill will exceed the agreed to provide supplemental payments when prices fall limit. If it appears that this limit will be met or below certain levels-except that acreage set-asides exceeded, the U.S. Congress has instructed the U.S. are no longer necessary for farmers to qualify for Department of Agriculture (USDA) to take steps to payments under the new bill. It allows farmers to reduce payments so as not to exceed this limit. update planting records that are used in calculating certain program payments. The bill also establishes Source: Bank staff 177 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 BL)ox A2.2 E.U. Common Agricultural Policy Dresident Chirac of France and Chancellor Schroeder E.U. Agriculture Commissioner Franz Fischier JIof Germany reached a budget agreement on the had proposed radical CAP reforms in July 2002 in Common Agriculture Policy (CAP) in Brussels the Midterm Review of Agenda 2000. The reforms October 26-27,2002. The agreement limits CAP would shift income support away from production budgets to increases of 1 percent annually from 2006 of surpluses and toward meeting of tough environ- to 2013 from an estimated budget of 45.6 billion mental, animal welfare, and food safety standards. euros in 2006. Total direct and indirect support to According to the proposal, E.U. farmers would get E.U. agriculmtre was estimated at 117.9 billion euros a single decoupled payment based on historical in 2001 by the OECD; more than half of that support references-regardless of whether they continue comes from higher food prices paid by consumers. production on the same scale. Direct spending on Participants in the Brussels summit proposed farmers would be cut by 3 percent per year over that agricultural support to new E.U. accession seven years, and the savings would be spent on rural countries increase from 25 percent of current development. Aid to large farms would be capped. member-support levels when those countries join in This proposal has proved controversial, and several 2004 to 40 percent in 2007 and parity by 2013. The European states have indicated their opposition to agreement puts a Iliit on CAP spending increases changing the current system. even after the 10 accession countries join in 2004, a limit that could necessitate CAP reforms as the Sources: Agra Europe Ltd., London and Europeani Commission accession countries' support levels increase or that Information about the Common Agricultural Policy can be could require shifting of funds from farmers in found on the European Union Web site. current member countries. hrtp://europa.eu.int/polUagr/index-en htm Union reached an agreement that limits future In real terms, coffee prices are currently less budget increases for the Common Agricultural than one-third of their 1960 level. The decline Policy through 2013 (see box A2.2). reflects mostly the surge in supplies, but the equally important longer-term problem is Beverages weak demand. According to the U.S. Depart- The World Bank's index of beverage prices ment of Agriculture (USDA), per capita annual (comprising coffee, cocoa, and tea prices) coffee consumption in the major importing increased about 17 percent in 2002, largely countries has been stagnant, at about 4.5 kilo- because of a 70 percent increase in cocoa grams of green coffee equivalent, during the prices. In contrast, coffee and tea prices past decade. remained weak. The sharp increase in cocoa Global coffee production in the 2002-03 prices reflects production problems and the season is expected to increase 10.7 percent recent coup attempt in C6te d'lvoire, a major from last season's 110.7 million bags producer of cocoa. The weakness in coffee (table A2.1). Brazil, the dominant producer prices can be attributed to large stocks, weak with one-third of global output, is expected to demand, and large production increases by produce a record 46.9 million bags, while major exporters. Tea prices declined as a re- Colombia and Vietnam, the second and third sult of abundant supplies and weak growth in largest producers, will each reach about 10 mil- demand. lion bags. A number of unsuccessful attempts have Coffee. Coffee prices fell to record lows and been made to arrest the price decline. The became the most visible symbol of the declines Association of Coffee Producing Countries, in agricultural commodity prices during 2002. which has urged coffee producers to join its 178 G LO B AL CO M MO DI TY PR ICE PRO SP EC TS Table A2.1 Coffee production in selected countries (1m1illio/i bags) 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 Brazil 22.8 35.6 30.8 34.1 33.7 46.9 Colombia 12.2 10.9 9.5 10.5 11.0 10.9 Core d'lvoire 3.7 2.2 5.7 4.3 3.3 3.3 Indonesia 7.8 6.9 6.7 6.5 6.0 5.8 Mexico 5.1 5.0 6.2 4.8 4.7 5.2 Vietnam 6.9 7.5 11.0 15.3 12.3 10.5 World 96.4 108.4 113.3 117.0 110.7 122.6 Souirce: U.S. Departmenit of AgriCLlture. export retention scheme for the past three sea- Production in two major producers, C6te sons, ceased operating on February 1, 2002. d'lvoire and Ghana, is estimated to be down A plan backed by tihe Internatiolial Coffee 4 percent anld 2 percent, respectively, in the Organization, which called for removal of low- just-ending 2001-02 marketing season. The quality coffee beans from the market, was not extreme price increases in response to such well supported by same coffee-produciig couni- relatively small changes in output were partly tries because it did not compenisate producers caused by speculative buying by commodity of low-quality beans. A number of countries funds. In addition, uncertainty about the relia- have also undertaken their own price-support bility of supplies prompted strong demand schemes or stock-holding nmechanisms. Brazil, from processors. for example, has subsidized put options to Cocoa prices are expected to remain at effectively guarantee a minimum price to pro- their 2002 level next year. They will decline ducers. While such scIleiles may be partially 12 percent in 2004 as production continues successful in the short run, they could exacer- to increase. This forecast is based on the as- bate the oversupply problem in the long run. sumptions that (a) the strong prices enljoyed We project a recovery in both robusta and this season have already given inlcentives to arabica prices in 2003 and a further recovery growers to maintaini their trees anid to increase in arabica in 2004. Nevertheless, we recognize production; (b) part of the recent surge in the risk that it may take longer for the recov- prices may have been caused by speculative ery to materialize if the recent supply surge activities of a short-term nature that are un1- persists. Over the long term, real coffee prices likely to be carried over into the next year; are expected to recover, but they will remain and (c) the recent coup attempt in C6te well below the historical highs of the 1970s d'lvoire has been repelled. and more recelt highs of the 1990s. By 2015, In response to high prices, growth in de- real arabica and robusta prices are projected mand for cocoa in the current and next mar- to increase about 75 percent from the 2002 keting season is expected to slow from the levels. Prices would still be about only half of 1990-2000 average of 2.4 percent. But it their 1990s peaks. should then return to historical growth rates (table A2.2). By 20-15, real prices are projected Cocoa. Cocoa prices led the recovery of agri- to decline 25 percent from 2002 levels. cultural comnmodity prices, after falling to a three-decade low in February 2000. Since then, Tea. The three-auction average tea price fell cocoa prices have more than doubled to a 16- 6 percent in 2002 as supplies continued to in- year high amid supply disruption in major crease relative to demand and stocks remained producers from political instability and from high (table A2.2). Production in major ex- producers' responses to extremely low prices. porters (India, Kenya, and Sri Lanka) was up 179 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A2.2 Global balance for beverages Annual growth ratc (%) 1970 1980 1990 1999 2000 2001 1970-80 1980-90 1990-00 Coffee (thousand bags) Productioni 64,161 86,174 88.849 113,345 117,049 110,773 2 11 1 36 1 20 Consumptioni 71,536 79,100 96,300 104,670 106,580 108,450 1 01 1 97 0 22 Exports 54,186 60,996 76,163 92,256 89,968 88,788 078 241 1 68 Cocoa (thouisand tons) Production 1,554 1,695 2,506 3,073 2,812 2,750 0 46 4 62 1 16 Grindings 1,418 1,556 2,335 2,967 3,014 2,823 0 16 4.48 2.58 Stocks 497 675 1,791 1,341 1,111 1,101 238 1389 -466 Tea (thousand tons) Production 1,286 1,848 2,516 2,900 2,960 3,030 4 09 2 87 1 49 Exports 752 859 1,132 1,259 1,330 1,389 2 35 2 39 1 62 Notes Tinme referceice for coffee (production and exports) aisd cocoa are based on crop year showin under the year that production begins October to September for cocoa and April to March for coffee Coffee coiisumption and tea data are based oni the calendar year Souirces International Coffee Organization (ICO), International Cocoa Organization (ICCO), Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the United Nations, International Tea Committee (ITC), U S Department of Agriculture, and World Bank 4 percent in 2001-the last year for which data are available. Other exporters, such as Figure A2.3 Food prices China and Vietnam, have also been increasing (index, 1990 = 100) exports rapidly, and such increases could fur- 130 ther weaken prices. Prices are projected to increase modestly 120 from the 2002 lows (up 3 percent in 2003), but they will remain depressed relative to the highs 110 AJ in 1997 and 1998. If emerging exporters, such \ / as Vietnam, continue to increase exports, there 100 is a significant risk that prices could continue \ to fall. However, higher petroleum export prices in the Russian Federation and in major 80 w \v \v consuming countries in the Middle East have historically supported demand, and we expect 70 1 1 1 1 1 tea prices to begin a gradual recovery. By 2005, Jan Jan J Jan Jan Jan Jan we project nominal tea prices to rise 10 percent 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 from 2002 levels, which would leave nominal Source World Bank prices down 20 percent from 1997 levels. Food exporting countries. By 2015, real prices should The index of food prices has not changed for decline about 2 percent from 2002 levels. several years after declining sharply during 1997-99 (figure A2.3). The index rose about Fats and oils. Prices of fats and oils recov- 4 percent in 2002 and is expected to rise 7 per- ered 13 percent in 2002 after falling 40 per- cent in 2003 and 2 percent in 2004 because of cent from 1997 to 2001. The increase was higher grain and oilseed prices following this greatest in vegetable oils such as palm oil (up year's drought in major grain- and soybean- 35 percent) and coconut oil (up 30 percent) 180 G L O B A L C 0 MM 0 D I T Y P R I C E P R O S P E C T S because of lower production. Meal prices re- Table A2.4 Palm oil production mained weak, with soymeal down 3 percent (million tonls) because of weak demand for livestock and Year Indonesia Malaysia WZorld poultry feeds. Prices of most fats and oils are expected to increase during 2003-05, and the 1990-91 2.41 6.10 11.03 index of prices is expected to increase 13 per- 201-06 I 753 11.94 23 54 cent in nominial terms from 2002 to 2005. 2001-02 8.20 11.65 23.98 Global production of the major fats and 2002-03 8.50 '11.82 24.53 oils is expected to increase about 2 percent Soturce; Oil World. in 2002-03, while consumption is expected to increase by 3.2 percent, causing stocks to decline and prices to continue increasing. Palm Table A2.5 Global grain stocks-to-use and soybean oil production is the largest among (percentages excluding Chia) the vegetable oils. Together they represent Year Maize Rice Wheat Total grains 40 percent of total vegetable oil production. World soybean production is expected to re- 1998-99 1.' 9.6 18.6 14.0 main constant in 2002 because of drought in 1999-2000 11.4 t.s 17.7 13.7 the United States, after growing by 5.3 percent 2000-01 11.S 12.9 19.0 14.3 per year since 1990. This stoppage in growth 2002-03 610 10.9 21.1 1257 has led to higher soybean prices and reduced 1990s low 6.0 7.8 13.9 9.7 stocks in 2002 and is expected to support Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture. lmigher prices in 2003. Other major producers (table A2.3) are expected to increase soybean production despite econonmic problems and un- increases in response to price increases. There certainties. is a risk that grain prices could continue to rise Palm oil production has more than doubled even more sharply than projected if the since 1990 (table A2.4), with the largest in- drought conltinues in the major exporting creases coming from Indonesia and Malaysia. countries, or if other major grain producers However, production is expected to increase a have lower-than-expected production. Wheat more niodest 2 percent in 2002-03. prices are projected to rise an additional 19 percent in nominal terms by 2003 after Grains. World grain stocks, relative to use, increasing nearly 20 percent in 2002. Prices are are expected to fall significantly during the then expected to decline 6 and 12 percent in current crop year (table A2.5), and the declines 2004 and 2005, respectively, as production are expected to keep grain prices rising through responds to the higher prices. Maize prices rose 2003. Prices should then decline as production 12 percent in 2002 and are expected to rise an additional 25 percent by 2003 before declining Table A2.3 Soybean production in 2004 and 2005. Rice prices rose 11 percent (million tonls) in 2002 and are expected to rise an additional 22 percent by 2005. Year Argentina Brazil United Satres World Stocks in the major grain exporting coun- 1990 '1.5 15.8 52.4 '104.1 tries-the United States, the European Union, 1995 12.4 24.2 59.2 124.9 Canada, Australia, and Argentina-are ex- 2000 27.8 39.0 75.1 175.1 pected to fall to the lowest level in 2003-03, 2001 29.5 43.5 78.7 183. 2002 30.0 48.0 71.5 183.3 relative to total use, since 1997-98. The de- dline is mostly attributable to the droughts Note: Argentina, Brazil, anld the Uniited States accounit for ine i ted atesiCnaa, andrAustr about 80 percenit of global produictioni. In the United States, Canada, and Australia, Souirce: U.S. Departmenit of Agriculture. which are expected to reduce grain yields by 9, 181 G LO B AL EC O NO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 7, and, 6 percent, respectively, in 2002-03 keting year that just ended in August, and an compared with yields in the previous year. An increase in carryover stocks to nearly 50 per- El Nimio weather pattern has contributed to the cent of annual consumption. Brazil, the largest unfavorable weather pattern in Australia and exporter, is expected to have a sugar cane crop could further reduce production next year.2 that could exceed the previous year's crop by The lower yields in the United States, Canada, 8 or 9 percent. Imports are expected to be and Australia have been partially offset by weak because of large production in import- record grain yields and production in the ing countries. Hence, prices are unlikely to European Union. Economic problems in recover significantly in 2003. Argentina have contributed to lower produc- Brazil has nearly 30 percent of the export tion and exports from that country, but the share in recent years and has been the primary largest effect of the economic turmoil is ex- source of increased global exports, with pro- pected to be in the next crop year, because most duction and exports growing rapidly in the of the planting and input-use decisions had past decade (figure A2.4). The other major already been made before the economic crisis exporters, Australia and Thailand, increased fully emerged. production by 50 and 70 percent, respectively, Grain production in developing countries from 1990-91 to 1997-98, when sugar prices is projected to be down 1.8 percent in were attractive. However, they have cut pro- 2002-03, with production generally strong in duction as prices have declined. Asia, Latin America, and the Middle East, but Sugar prices are expected to begin to re- lower in Eastern Europe and Russia. Produc- cover in 2004 as low prices reduce global tion in China is expected to be up 2.3 percent, supplies. However, prices are expected to re- while production in India is expected to be main relatively weak for the next several years, down 4.9 percent because of a poor monsoon with fluctuations depending on the year-to- season. year balance of production and consumption. There is considerable variation in the stock By 2005, nominal sugar prices are expected situation in individual grains, with the global to increase 17 percent over 2002 levels. In the stocks-to-use percentage for maize at the low- long term, nominal prices are expected to est levels of the 1990s, while rice and wheat return to the center of the trading range, percentages are above previous lows. How- and real prices are expected to average about ever, grain prices are highly correlated, and 18 cents per kilogram (8.2 cents per pound). price increases in one grain would normally be reflected in the prices of others. Higher grain prices woulcl benefit developing-country net exporters such as Argentina (which is Figure A2.4 Sugar exports expected to export more than 22 million tons (million tons, raw equivalent) of grain in 2002-03) while harming net im- 40 Rest of world porters such as Mexico and the Arab Republic 35 1 of Egypt, which are expected to import 13 mil- 30 lion and 10 million tons of grain, respectively, 25 in 2002-03. 20 15 Brazil Sugar Sugar prices fell to 15 cents per kilo- 10 gram in 2002 (down 21 percent from 2001) to 5 return to the lower end of the trading range of 0 l l l l A . . , s >^ ~~~~~1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 10-30 cents per kilogram of the past 20 years. The decline follows an estimated 5 percent in- Source US Department of Agriculture crease in world sugar production in the mar- 182 G LO B AL CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE PRO SP EC TS Table A2.6 Global balance for foods Annual growth rates (%) 1970 1980 1990 1999 2000 2001 1970-80 1980-90 1990-2000 Grains (million tons) Productioni 1,079 1,430 1,769 1,871 1,839 1,860 2.88 1.55 1.04 Consumption 1,114 1,451 1,717 1,869 1,868 1,890 2.58 1.78 1.02 Exports 119 212 206 245 233 231 6.35 0.13 0.94 Stocks 193 309 490 529 500 470 7.24 3.83 -0.56 Soybean (tbousand tons) Production 42,133 62,173 104,093 159,904 175,098 183,724 6.84 1.87 5.08 Consumption 45,968 68,052 104,307 160,541 172,166 184,228 6.53 2.04 4.99 Exports 12,342 20,822 25,388 46,683 55,074 57,127 5.24 0.80 2.88 Stocks 3,394 10,266 20,569 27,908 30,803 30,218 13.83 -0.66 0.20 Sugar (thousand tonrs (rawv equsivalent]) Production 70,919 84,742 109,403 138,094 143,220 136,111 2.80 1.59 3.26 Consumption ' 65,395 91,062 106,807 130,281 133,104 134,712 3.30 1.40 3.00 Exports 21,931 27,571 34,078 38,710 42,015 38,495 3.26 0.83 3.12 Stocks 19,614 19,494 19,299 31,702 35,939 35,474 3.96 -0.77 4.52 Fats and oils (nilliont tots) Production 39.78 58.09 80.84 113.42 117.09 119.42 3.68 3.54 3.70 Consumption 39.82 56.80 80.87 111.98 116.94 120.74 3.55 3.69 3.64 Exports 8.83 17.76 26.89 35.55 38.10 39.57 7.05 4.19 3.39 Stocks 5.18 9.25 12.15 14.26 14.47 13.19 7.09 2.44 0.69 Note: Time referenices for grains, soybeans, and sugar are based on marketing years, shown under the year in which production begins, and they vary by counitry. For fats and oils, crop years begini in September. Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture and Oil World. The global balances for major foods are 2002 levels, while real prices are projected to given in table A2.6. The balances show that the rise 18 percent by 2015 over 2002 levels. rate of growth of production and consumption of grains has slowed during the 1990s com- Cotton. Cotton prices declined an additional pared with previous decades, while growth 5 percent in 2002 after declining 19 percent in rates have increased for soybeans and sugar. 2001 because of large production increases in The growth rates for fats and oils were rela- the United States and China, the two largest tively constant during the 1980s and 1990s. producers (table A2.7). Prices in 2002 were less than half of their 1995 highs, and they reached 30-year nominal lows. The extreme Agricultural raw materials price weakness was caused by a number of The index of agricultural raw materials prices factors, such as slow growth in demand, large (comprising prices of tropical hardwoods, production, and competition from synthetic cotton, and natural rubber) declined sharply fibers. Subsidies to cotton producers in the during Asia's economic crisis and then sta- United States and China have contributed to bilized before declining again as supplies the production surplus. During the past three of commodities continued to increase (fig- seasons, U.S. support to its cotton producers ure A2.5). Prices reached a low in 2001 and averaged almost $3 billion, and China's sup- have since recovered because of higher cotton port averaged $2 billion. and natural rubber prices. Nominal prices are Cotton production in the coming season is projected to increase 16 percent by 2005 from expected to be 19.2 million tons-10 percent 183 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Table A2.7 Cotton production in selected countries (thouisand tons) Country 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 China 4,501 3,830 4,350 S,320 4,420 Franc zone 897 928 700 1,034 921 India 2,710 2,650 2,350 2,686 2,500 Pakistan 1,480 1,800 1,750 1,853 1,731 United Stares 3,030 3,835 3.818 4,420 3,826 Uzbekistan 1,000 1,150 960 1,055 1,015 World j 18,551 18,887 19,126 21,422 19,157 Source International Cotton Advisory Committee prices gained momentum at the beginning of Figure A2.5 Raw materials 2002, with average 2002 prices rising about (index, 1990 =100) 32 percent from 2001. The recovery is mainly 130 a response to adverse weather conditions in Thailand and a slowdown in Malaysia's out- 120 put growth as natural rubber plantations are being converted to more profitable palm 110 oil plantations. Demand, however, remains weak as car tire manufacturing (the largest 100 demand for natural rubber) in Organisation 90 A 1tfor Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries is estimated to be down 80 \ \ 2 percent in 2002. The strength in natural rubber prices is 70 1_1_____ I_ _hlikely to persist because supply controls by the Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan Tripartite Rubber Corporation-a trilateral 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 organization formed last year by Indonesia, Soturce World Bank Malaysia, and Thailand following the col- lapse of the International Natural Rubber Organization-may restrict exports. We ex- lower than in the previous season, with the pected natural rubber prices to remain firm, United States and China accounting for most but not increase significantly, in 2003 from of the decline. In the United States, the drought 2002 levels because of weak demand that ac- has reduced production from the record companies the apparent slowing of growth in 2001-02 season. Global consumption is ex- the global economy. By 2005, nominal prices pected to increase about 2.6 percent, according are expected to increase 6 percent from 2002 to the latest forecasts by the International levels. Over the longer term, real prices are Cotton Advisory Committee. Given lower pro- projected to decline-down 3 percent from duction in combination with higher consump- 2002 to 2015. tion, we forecast the A Index cotton price to increase 10 percent in 2003 and 16 percent Tropical timber The decline in Asian tropi- in 2004. By 2015, real prices are projected to cal timber prices since the mid-1990s appears increase 30 percent relative to 2002 prices. to have ended, and prices have begun to re- cover from the lows reached at the end of Natural rubber. After prolonged weakness 2001. Nominal timber prices increased about following the Asian crisis, natural rubber 9 percent in 2002 compared with 2001 prices 184 G LO BA L CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE P R O S P E C r S as a result of the improved demand from slowed dramatically during the 1990s com- Japan, the weakening of the U.S. dollar pared with the 1980s. Exports of cotton grew relative to the yen, and the continued strong only 0.2 percent during the 1990s, which con- import demand from China. Prices are ex- tributed to the sharp price decline. Growth pected to continiue to recover in 2003 and rates of natural rubber production, consump- 2004, with annual average increases of 8 per- tion, and exports remained nearly constant cent per year, resulting from improved eco- during the 1990s compared with the 1980s. nomic growth in Asia. African sapelli log prices Tropical timber log production slowed while have declined less than Asian log prices, as production of sawnwood increased as timber- demand has remained firm in Europe. Sapelli producing countries shifted to increased do- nominal log prices are expected to increase mestic processing. Sawnwood imports in- about 5 percent from 2002 to 2005. creased while plywood imports slowed during Real tropical timber prices are expected to the 1 990s compared with the 1 980s. recover from lows, but they are not expected to reach new highs during the forecast period to 2015. By 2015, real meranti log prices are Fertilizers projected to rise 47 percent, while sapelli log ]ertilizer prices remained nearly constant prices are projectedto rise by only 18 percent. F in 2002 after several years of large adjust- The difference is due to the smaller decrease ments (figure A2.6). Import demand remained and, therefore, smaller rebound of African weak because of low commodity prices and sapelli logs prices compared with Asian mer- increased local production. However, fertilizer anti log prices. production in major exporters contracted in The global balances for raw materials response to low fertilizer prices. Hence, a are given in table A2.8. The data show that market balance was achieved with little pres- cotton production, consumption, and exports sure on prices. Acreage used for global grain Table A2.8 Global balance for raw materials Annual growth ratc s%) 1970 1980 1990 1999 2000 2001 1970-80 1980-90 1990-2000 Cotton (tbousa,nd tons) Production 11,740 13,832 18,970 19,126 19,408 21,422 1.2 3.1 0.8 Consumption 12,173 14,215 18,576 19,796 19.762 20,070 1.1 3.1 0.2 Exports 3,875 4,414 5,081 6,142 5,750 6,430 0.9 2.8 0.5 Stocks 4,605 4,895 6,645 9,559 9,274 10,630 1.7 2.8 1.4 Natural rubber (tboussand tons) Production 3,140 3,820 5,080 6,810 6,740 7,170 1.8 3.2 3.1 Consuimptioni 3,090 3,770 5,190 6,660 7,330 7,030 1.6 3.2 3.3 Net exports 2,820 3,280 3,950 4,670 4,940 5,160 1.3 2.1 1.8 Stocks 1,480 1,480 1,500 2,540 1,950 2,090 0.6 0.2 3.7 Tropical timber (thousanzd cubic nseters) Logs, productioni 210 262 300 286 287 276 1.5 1.7 0.5 Logs, imnports 36.1 42.2 25.1 18.3 21.1 21.0 0.2 5.1 5.4 Sawnwood, produiction 98.5 115.8 131.8 103.9 101.5 99.3 1.2 1.7 2.0 Sawnwood, imilports 7.1 13.2 16.1 21.2 24.3 23.5 5.0 2.6 3.3 Plywood, produiction 33.4 39.4 48.2 52.6 55.4 54.9 1.2 2.0 0.5 Plywood, iniiports 4.9 6.0 14.9 18.9 19.8 20.3 0.7 9.1 3.6 Notes: Time referenice for cottoni is based oni the crop year beginning in AuIguIst. For niatural rubber and tropical timber, time refers to the calendar year. Sources: Initernationial Cottoni Advisory Committee, linterisationial Study Rubber Grotip, FAO, and World Banik. 1.85 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 cent above 2002 levels, as the industry contin- Figure A2.6 Fertilizer prices ues to rationalize and reduce surplus capacity. (dollars per ton) Prices for potassium chloride (also known 200 as muriate of potash, or MOIP) declined 5 per- 180 cent in 2002 from weak demand and large 160 \ surplus capacity. Price declines could have 140 Xi \ A M X \ been much larger without aggressive supply 120 / s s I controls by major exporters. Increased domes- > 0 A /tic production in China is expected to weaken 100 \ /9 V future import demand and, along with a large 80 surplus in global production capacity, to keep 60 m U price increases small, despite the increased use MOP Urea for grain production, which accompanies the 20 recovery in grain prices. By 2005, nominal 0, , , MOP prices are projected to increase 10 per- 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 cent from 2002 levels, and real prices are pro- jected to fall 6 percent by 2015 compared with Note TSP = trpipe super phosphate, MOP = muriate of 2002 prices. potash 20 rcs Sonirce Fertilizer Week Triple super phosphate (TSP) prices in- creased 5 percent in 2002 after falling 27 per- cent from 1998 to 2001. Production fell in production, which accounts for more than half 2001 in response to low prices, and imports of total fertilizer use, declined for the sixth declined slightly because of increased local consecutive year in 2002, but it is expected to production in China and India. Demand increase in 2003 and 2004 in response to re- should increase along with increased grain cent and expected grain price increases. Pro- prices and area planted. Surplus capacity is duction capacity remains substantially larger smaller than for other major fertilizers and is than demand for all major fertilizers, but it is expected to decline over the next several years. most extreme in potash, where surplus capac- This decline will cause nominal TSP prices to ity may be as high as 30 percent of demand, increase by an estimated 13 percent by 2005. according to industry estimates. Real prices are projected to decline by 5 per- Nitrogen fertilizer prices (as represented by cent by 2015 from 2002 levels. urea prices) were down about 2 percent in The large surplus of global production ca- 2002, as exports from major producers In pacity in the fertilizer industry is largely a result Eastern Europe fell because of rising natural of the sharp declines in consumption in former gas prices, currency changes that made ex- Soviet bloc and Eastern European countries ports less profitable, and increased local fertil- following the collapse of the former Soviet izer demand. This fall was partially offset by Union and the transition of those countries reduced demand in major importing countries to market economies. Many countries (such as a result of low commodity prices and in- as Russia and Ukraine) were left with large creased local fertilizer production. Urea prices production capacities and reduced domestic are expected to continue to increase because demand-which led to export growth of nearly of higher grain prices and reduced exports 4 percent per year since 1993 from the former from Eastern Europe. By 2005, nominal urea Soviet Union. Those increased exports dis- prices are projected to increase 36 percent placed traditional exports and depressed prices from 2002, but then increases are expected to of nitrogen and phosphate fertilizers. Global slow, and real prices should decline. By 2015, fertilizer consumption fell about 17 percent real urea prices are expected to remain 19 per- from 1988 to 1993 and has only recently 186 G LO B AL CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE PRO SP EC T S Table A2.9 Global balance for fertilizers (million tolls) Aninual growth rates (%) 1970 1980 1990 1998 1999 2000 1970-80 1980-90 1990-2000 Nitrogen ProdLctioll 33.30 62.78 82.28 88.30 87.75 84.62 6.53 3.12 0.28 Consumption 31.76 60.78 77.18 82.77 84.95 S.62 6.86 2.60 0.56 Exports 6.77 13.15 19.59 23.00 23.94 24.70 7.23 5.10 2.34 Phosphate Plroductioni 22.04 34.51 39.18 33.09 32.51 31.70 3.72 1.70 -2.10 Constimption 21.12 31.70 35.90 33.35 33.46 32.65 3.85 1.39 -0.90 Exports 2.92 7.51 10.50 12.59 12.70 12.11 8.37 5,01 1.44 Potash production 17.59 27.46 26.82 25.01 25.01 25.54 3.97 -0.03 -0.49 Consumptioin 16.43 24.24 24.68 22.04 22.12 22.16 3.93 0.05 -1.07 Exports 9.45 16.72 19.82 22.23 22.65 23.41 4.89 0.73 1.68 Note: All data are in mizrkerinig years. Souirce: IFood and(l Agricultyre Organiization. recovered to near thie 1988 peak. Table A2.9 gives the global balances for fertilizers. Figure A2.7 Aluminum and copper prices (dollars per ton) 2,700 Metals and minerals P rices for metals and minerals rallied from Copper the October 2001 lows because of expec- 2,300 tations of a robust economic recovery that would lead to a strong demand for metals. However, the price rally stalled in the second 1,900 A quarter of 2002, as it appeared the recovery would be more muted than anticipated. With 1500 weak demanid and large inventories, most 1,500 metal prices have receded to at or below end- Aluminum 2001 levels (see figure A2.7 for aluminum and 1,100 I I l copper). Even with the rally, the index of Inet- Jan. Jan. Jan. Jan. Jan. Jan. als and minerals prices during the first nine 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 months of 2002 averaged 5.6 percent lower Source: I'latts Metals Veek. than for the same period a year earlier. Growth il demand has been very sluggish in 2002, with little indication of strong growth in the near term. Meanwhile, production con- num, have helped support prices, but more tinues to rise, despite efforts to shut capacity. closures may be necessary to prevent further As a result, the London Metal Exchange (LME) stock building and even lower prices. invenitories of most metals have continued to The price recovery will likely be delayed risc to relatively high levels (see figure A2.8 for until 2003, and the strength of the recovery aluminumil and copper). A number of produc- will largely be determined by the timing and tion cutbacks, notably in copper and alumi- strength of the rebound in the global economy. 187 G LOBA L EC ON OM IC PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Figure A2.8 Aluminum and copper stocks (thousand tons) 1,400 1,200 1,000 80 Aluminum 600 400 200 ~~~~~~~~Copper 200 Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Souirce London Metal Exchange There is a possibility that during the upturn surplus over the next two years, which should of the next economic cycle metal prices could prevent any substantial increase in prices. rise significantly, augmented by strong buy- Chinese exports are expected to continue rising ing from investment funds. However, this rise over this period, contributing to the surplus. would induce the development of new capac- The market is not expected to move into deficit ity and the restart of idle facilities, and prices until 2005, but there are many risks in the near would eventually decline. Real metals and term, such as the strength of the economic minerals prices are expected to decline in the recovery, the reactivation of idle capacity, and long term, as production costs continue to fall the amount of Chinese net exports. with the implementation of new technologies Real prices for primary aluminum are ex- and of improved managerial practices. pected to decline in the long term, as new low- cost capacity is developed to meet expected Aluminum growth in demand. However, investment in Aluminum prices have fallen back near the new aluminum plants will continue to require lows of October 2001 because of relatively low-cost power supplies. There is not expected weak demand, rising production, and soaring to be any significant constraint on alumina sup- stocks. Prices have been partly supported by ply in the medium term, because several new reductions in capacity caused by high electric- alumina capacity expansions are under way. ity prices and rationing in the Pacific North- west and Brazil, but reactivations in Brazil and Copper to a lesser extent in North America have con- Copper prices led the rally in base metals during tributed to the surplus. Production in China the past year following a series of production has grown significantly, and despite demand cuts, with prices rising 20 percent from October growth of more than 10 percent per year, 2001 to June 2002. Prices have since receded the country became a net exporter this year, because of prospects of weak demand in the adding to the downward pressure on prices. near term. However, the market is expected to Growth in demand is expected to accelerate be in reasonable balance this year as world mine in 2003, but the market is expected to remain in production declines about 2 percent because of 188 G LO BA L CO MM OD I TY PR ICE P R O S P E C T S industry curtailments. LME inventories re- 60,000 tons of stock as collateral against a main high, although they started to decline in three-year loan from Western banks, which May largely as a result of the strong growth of may keep the material off the market for the Chinese imports. duration of the loan. Demand for nickel has Demand is expected to strengthen next been relatively strong in the stainless steel sec- year, and supply is expected to almost keep tor, largely because of the shortage of scrap pace, largely because of the recent commis- supply. sioning of Chile's Escondida Phase IV project The nickel market is expected to move into and the restart of idle capacity. The firm mar- deficit in 2003 and over the next few years be- ket balance should help support prices, but cause production increases are expected to fall high stocks may prevent sharply higher gains short of a strong growth in demand. No major next year. The market is expected to remain in new projects are being commissioned until modest deficit over the next few years, which 2005. Poor technical and financial perfor- should support rising prices during the forth- mance with pressure-acid-leach technology in coming economic cycle. In the longer term, in- Australia has been a major reason for the cur- creases in new low-cost capacity are expected rent lack of investment, which could result in to result in the continued decline of real prices. fairly strong prices over the next couple of A major uncertainty over the forecast period years. Over the long term, large new develop- will be the volume of Chinese imports. ments are expected to come onstream, such as Inco's Goro project in New Caledonia (in Nickel 2005) and Voisey Bay in Labrador, Canada (in Nickel has been one base metal to sustain price 2006). Supply will originate from other new increases this year, with a 38 percent gain projects, expansions, and Norilsk's stockpiled between October 2001 and September 2002. material. New technologies will lead to lower Relatively low stocks and Russian Norilsk's costs, and real prices are expected to decline. efforts to keep surplus supplies off the export Table A2.10 shows the production, con- market have supported prices that are signifi- sumption, and LME ending stocks for alu- cantly higher than would be expected at the minum, copper, and nickel from 1970 through bottom of the business cycle. Norilsk is using 2001. Table A2.10 Global balance for metals and minerals (thousanid tonts) Annual growth rates (%) 19_0 1980 1_990 _ 9 _ 2000 201 _ 1970-80 1980-90 1990-2001 Aluminum Production &lI,I NA M 4(*) 3 2 1.9 2.2 Consumption N6= 1l BONO3 3I KM 3.2 1.8 1.8 LME ending stocks ff 132 wi X E P _p - n a. -0.3 9.2 Copper Production a!l !ULU- 8 f4Ie 86J03f i 1.9 1.1 3.4 Consumption 1 !3 4,M ffl" 10,(W lUs 4 2.5 1.0 2.8 LME endimg stocks f, X r D 'P -, 7.4 -56 14.6 Nickel Production t.j i.i' i!' inZJ ri 6 Consumpts .i. i. r. a LMEendiim .1.j. _ k 111 -4i 15 Sources: World Bureau of Metal Statistics, Loridon Metal Excliange, and World Batik. 189 G LO BA L E CO NO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Gold tions come onstream. An important deter- Gold prices have averaged more than $300 per minant of medium-term prices will be the troy ounce (toz) since April 2002, which is the decision by central banks on whether official first time since 1997 that prices have been gold sales should be stemmed further when above $300 for more than a month. Much of the Washington Agreement expires in 2004.3 the strength has been from buybacks of hedged Table A2.11 shows the demand for end sup- positions by gold producers. In addition, in- ply of gold from 1991 through 2001. creased investment demand-partly in reac- tion to declining U.S. equity markets and the declining dollar-has helped support prices. Petroleum However, the recent rally in gold prices isi il prices slumped after September 11, not expected to endure as producer buybacks 0J2001, because the economic recession, end and central bank selling continues. At mild weather, and reduced air travel weak- present, hedging by producers is unattractive ened demand. Also, OPEC made no attempts because of low interest rates, but at some to prop up falling prices (figure A2.9). How- point producer hedging could again become ever, as OPEC prices fell well below the attractive, which would push prices lower. Al- organization's target range of $22 to $28 per though the United Kingdom's central bank barrel (OPEC basket $17.53 per barrel in sales program ended in March 2002, other December 2001), 10 OPEC countries, exclud- central banks (such as Switzerland's) are pro- ing Iraq, agreed to reduce production quotas ceeding with their programs. 6.5 percent at the start of 2002. This reduction If prices remain above $300/toz, they will was the fourth cut in quotas in less than a year, weaken the price-sensitive jewelry demand totaling S million barrels per day or 19 percent market and will stimulate investment in new (figure A2.10). supply. Even when prices fall below $300 per Prices started to rebound at the end of 2001 toz, mine production is expected to continue on expectations that markets would tighten be- to increase moderately as new low-cost opera- cause of a recovery in world oil demand, OPEC Table A2.11 Global balance for gold (tons) Percent per year 1991 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 1991-2001 Demand Jewelry 2,358 2,618 2,791 2,851 3,349 3,149 3,188 2,995 24 Other fabrication 518 457 503 484 560 595 564 487 -0 6 Bar hoarding 252 231 306 182 325 240 214 220 -1.3 Other 2,358 n a 6 n,a n.a. 170 n a. n.a. n.a Total demand 3,128 3,305 3,606 3,518 4,234 4,154 3,982 3,804 2.0 Supply Mine production 2,159 2,279 2,274 2,361 2,479 2,568 2,580 2,595 1.9 Net official sales 111 81 173 279 626 464 471 468 15.5 Old gold scrap 482 617 625 640 628 616 608 695 3 7 Net hedging 66 163 535 142 504 506 n.a. n a n a. Other 310 173 n a. 95 297 n.a. 322 46 n.a. Total supply 3,128 3,305 3,606 3,946 4,154 4,154 3,982 3,804 2 0 n a = Not available Sources. Gold Field Minerals Service and World Bank 190 G LO B AL CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE PRO SP EC TS Figure A2.9 Oil price and OECD stocks (dollars per barrel) (million barrels) 35 - 2850 30 L Al-" Stcks WB price - 2800 v \ - ~~~~~~~~~~~~~2750 25 - A\ } \/>\ /\ / \ / - 2700 V'V ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~2650 20 A[-; ; > A & 2 \/ 2600 2550 15 vvv2500 2450 10 2400 Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan Jan 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Sou(rce; World Bank and Interna-ional Energy Agency Figure A2.10 OPEC-10 production and quotas (million barrels per day) 30 Plus Iraq production 28 27 26 25 OPEe: - quotas' Perroduction 24 . . . 23. . . . . . 22 21 Jan Jan Jan. Jan Jan Jan 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Source: International Energy Agency and Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries output restraint, and declining stocks. In addi- in March and approached $30 per barrel in tion, perceived threats of a supply disruption September as U.S. President George W. Bush from a United States-led invasion of Iraq also took his case for war against Iraq to the United helped push prices higher, and those anxieties Nations (U.N.). Market fundamentals also deepened as the year progressed. The World started to tighten heading into the peak- Bank's average price rose above $20 per barrel demand winter season. G LOB AL EC ON OM IC PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A2.12 Global balance for petroleum (million barrels per day) Annual growth rates 1970 1980 1990 2001 2002 2003 197G80 1980-90 1990-2001 Consumption OECD 34 0 41.5 41.5 47 7 47.6 48.0 2 0 0.0 1.3 Former Soviet Union . 5.0 8.9 8.4 3 7 3.8 3.9 6 0 -0,6 -7 2 Other non-OECD countries 6.8 12 3 16.1 25.1 25 3 25.7 6 1 2 7 4.1 Total 45.7 62.6 66.0 76 5 76.6 77.5 3.2 0.5 1.3 Production OPEC 235 27.2 24.5 30.2 28.5 28.7 1.5 -10 1 9 Former Soviet Union . 7.1 12.1 11.5 8.6 9.3 9.9 54 -05 -2.6 Other non-OPEC countries 17.4 24.6 30 9 38.2 38 6 39.1 3.5 2.3 1.9 Total 48.0 63.9 66 9 76 9 76.4 77.7 2.9 0.5 1.3 Stock change, miscellaneous 2.3 1.3 0.9 0.4 -0.2 0.3 Memo item: Iraq 1.6 2.7 2.0 2.4 1.9 2.0 5.5 -2.7 1.5 Sources BP, International Energy Agency, and World Bank Fundamentally, the market was in reason- difficult to quantify such a premium, and no able balance for much of 2002, and invento- precise definition exists. Energy expert Philip ries were at fairly typical levels, although K. Verleger Jr. defines the premium as the stocks could fall to relatively low levels during incremental amount a buyer is willing to pay the winter without higher OPEC production. for ensured prompt supply over deferred oil World oil demand is likely to rise only mar- given the level of inventories. He argues ac- ginally this year (table A2.12), similar to the cording to that definition that no war pre- gain in 2001. Meanwhile non-OPEC supplies mium existed at the end of September 2002.4 continue to increase strongly, rising by an esti- The near-term outlook for the oil market mated 1.2 million barrels per day, with more depends heavily on developments in Iraq and than half of the gain expected to come from on OPEC's production decisions. While there Russia. is agreement between the United States and It is only through significant production U.N. to allow weapons inspectors back into restraint that OPEC has kept prices within its Iraq, there is likely to be less agreement on target range-notwithstanding some overpro- how to proceed if Iraq refuses U.N. demands. duction by members of the group. In addition, Should an attack occur in the coming months, Iraq's exports have been less than half of the prices could spike sharply higher, depending country's potential for much of the year, be- on the prevailing level of inventories, the re- cause of disputes with the U.N. about Iraq's sponse from OPEC producers, and the draw- surcharges, which the U.N. sought to eliminate down of strategic reserves. During the 1990 with a retroactive pricing scheme. However, war in the Persian Gulf, more than 4 mbfd of buyers are exposed to large risks with this oil from Kuwait and Iraq were removed from mechanism, and crude oil purchases from Iraq international markets, and prices exceeded were curtailed. $40/bbl. There was substantial surplus pro- Expectations of an attack on Iraq have duction within OPEC, and the organization led to a wide range of estimates of a "war raised output-but not immediately. Impor- premium" on prices this year. Estimates range tantly, prices did not fall until the war com- from very little (prices reflect the market bal- menced (and its success was quickly assured) ance) to several dollars per barrel. It is very and the strategic stocks were released. 192 G L O B AL CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE P R O S P E C r s Since Iraq is exporting only around I mb/d, below $30/bbl, but the organization may have much less oil is at risk, although it is conceiv- to reduce output at winter's end to keep prices able that Iraq could launch scud missiles into within its price target. The demand for OPEC Kuwait and Saudi Arabia and could tem- oil is expected to rise only modestly in 2003. porarily disrupt supplies. There is more sur- An increase in non-OPEC supply of 1 mb/d plus capacity within OPEC than in 1990, and is expected to capture the bulk of the growth sufficient spare capacity within Saudi Arabia in world oil demand. Rising capacity withini alone could easily replace lost oil from Iraq. OPEC, requests for higher quotas (from However, OPEC desires prices of at least Algeria and Nigeria), and a recovery of Iraq's $251bbl, and it is not clear how quickly its exports could strain OPEC's efforts to support members will raise production to prevent a higher prices. But as long as the risk of a sup- surge in prices. In such an environment, crude ply disruption hangs over the market, prices prices could be bid up sharply because of are likely to remain well within OPEC's target higher demand, speculation, and hoarding. range. Buyers might have to pay a substantial pre- Oil prices are expected to decline from mium for prompt supplies, and prices could $25 per barrel in 2002 to $23 per barrel in rise to 1990 levels. 2003 as a result of rising supply competition Once war ends, prices could fall precipi- and below-trend growth in demand. By mid- tously as a result of a higher OPEC produc- decade, prices are expected to fall below tion, a draw from strategic stocks, and the $20 per barrel (figure A2.11). A risk to the return of Iraqi exports. Disputes within OPEC forecast is that OPEC could maintain strong over market share could take prices well below production discipline over the next few years $20/bbl. to keep prices at or above $25 per barrel. If In the absence of an attack, OPEC's pro- such efforts prove successful, they would duction decisions will heavily influence prices. add to the growing pressures on prices-by The group will likely attempt to keep prices negatively affecting demand and by stimulat- at $25/bbl. Higher OPEC production will be ing competing supplies-and prices would still required during the wtnter to keep prices be expected to fall below $20 per barrel by Figure A2.11 Crude oil prices (dollars per barrel) 50 45 40 35 30 25 1990 dollars Nominal 20 Real 15 10 5 , 2 O ;I I I I I I i I I I I I I I I I I I i I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2110 2015 Souirce W'orld Bank 193 G LO BA L EC O NO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 mid-decade. By 2005-06, significant new sup- deep water offshore and the Caspian Sea), and plies from West Africa, the Caspian Sea, and development costs continue to fall from new elsewhere are expected to become available. technologies (shifting supply curves outward). Coupled with rising capacity within OPEC, In addition, OPEC members are increasing those supplies will exert severe downward capacity and will add to the supply competi- pressure on prices. tion in the coming years. Consequently, real In the long term, growth in demand will oil prices are expected to continue their long- be only moderate, as it has been for the past term decline. 20 years (table A2.12), but new technologies, As mentioned at the beginning of this ap- environmental pressures, and government pendix, we will now present tables showing policies could further reduce this growth. actual commodity prices for 1970 through Prices somewhat below $20 per barrel are suf- 2001, plus price projections for 2002 through ficiently high to generate ample development 2015. Table A2.13 gives the commodity prices of conventional and unconventional oil sup- and forecasts in current dollars, table A2.14 plies, and there are no apparent resource con- uses constant 1990 dollars, and table A2.15 straints far into the future. In addition, new displays weighted indices of commodity prices areas continue to be developed (for example, and inflation. 194 G LO B AL CO MM OD IT Y PR ICE PRO SP EC TS Table A2.13 Commodity prices and price projections in current dollars Actual i Projections Conmmodiy Unita 1970 1980 1990 2000 2001 2002 2003 2005 2010 2015 Energy Coal, Australia $/mt n a n a 39 67 26 25 32 31 26 50 26 00 27.00 29 50 32 00 Crude oil, average $/bbl 121 36 87 22 88 28 23 24 35 25 00 23 00 19 00 19 00 21.00 Natiural gas, Europe $/mmbtu n a 3 40 2 55 3 86 4 06 3 00 2.80 2 60 2 75 3 00 Natural gas, U S $Imnibtu f 017 1 55 1 70 4 31 3 96 3 25 3 20 3 00 3 00 3 25 Nonenergy commodities Agriculture Ifeveragcs Cocoa c/kg 1 67 5 260 4 126.7 90 6 106 9 |82 0 182 0 160 0 157.0 168 0 Coffee, other milds c/kg 1 114 7 346 6 197 2 192 0 137.3 133 0 141 1 187.4 242.5 280 0 Coffee, robusta c/kg 91 4 3243 1182 913 607 639 706 838 1100 142.6 Tea, aUction1s (3) average c/kg 83 5 165 9 205 8 187 6 159 8 150 0 155 0 165.0 175.0 180.0 Food Fats and oils Coconut oil $/mt 397 2 673 8 336 5 450.3 318 1 415 0 450 0 600 0 645 0 670.0 Copra $/mt 224 8 452.7 230 7 304 8 202 1 268.0 375 0 450 0 480.0 500 0 Groundnut oil $/rit 378 6 858 8 963 7 713 7 680 3 680.0 750.0 820.0 850.0 875 0 Palm oil $/mt 2601 583.7 289 8 310 3 285 7 385 0 390 0 400.0 450 0 475.0 Soybean meal $/mt 102.6 2624 2002 1892 181 0 175 0 2000 205.0 2150 2200 Soybean oil $/mt 286 3 597 6 447 3 338 1 354 0 440 0 450 0 430.0 460 0 505 0 Soybeans $S/mt 116 9 296 2 246 8 2118 195 8 i 210 0 230 0 235 0 240.0 250 0 Grains Maize $/mt 58 4 125.3 109 3 88 5 89 6 100.0 125 0 115 0 120 0 130.0 Rice, Thailand, 5% i/nt 126 3 410 7 270 9 202 4 172.8 192 0 210.0 235 0 260.0 265 0 Sorghum i/mt 51 8 128 9 103 9 88 0 95 2 102.0 125 0 116.6 119 5 128.0 Wheat, US, HRW $/m f 549 1727 1355 1141 1268 1515 1800 1500 160.0 165.0 Othcr food Banianas, U S $/mt 1661 377 3 540 9 424 0 583 3 530 0 518 1 529.1 568 0 590 0 Beef, U S c/kg 130.4 276 0 256 3 193 2 212 9 215 0 230 0 228 0 222.0 230 0 Oranges $/mt 1680 4002 531 1 363.2 5955 5880 5500 5000 5250 550.0 Shrimp, Mexico c/kg is a 1,152 1,069 1,513 1,517 1 1,040 1,150 1,650 1,700 1,720 SLigar, world c/kg 8 2 63 16 27 67 18 04 19 04 15.00 15 00 17.60 21 00 22 00 Agricultural raw materials Timber Logs, Camerooni S/cumn 43 0 251 7 343 5 275 4 266 1 265 0 275 0 300.0 338.0 385 0 Logs, Malaysia $/cumn 43 1 195 5 177.2 190 0 159.1 163 0 170.0 215.0 260 0 295 0 Sawniwood, Malaysia $/cum 175 0 396 0 533 0 594 7 481 4 528.0 560.0 625 0 720 0 820 0 Other raw materials Cotton c/kg 676 2062 1819 1302 1058 1000 I1102 127.9 149.9 1600 Rubber, RSS1, Malaysia /kg 40 7 142 5 86 5 69 1 60.0 79 4 81.6 83 8 87.7 95 1 Tobacco $/mt 1,076 2,276 3,392 2,976 3,005 2,770 3,000 3,250 3,275 3,300 Fertilizers DAP $/mt 54 0 222.2 171 4 154.2 147 7 158 0 168.0 170 0 175.0 180.0 Phosphate rock $/mt 1100 4671 4050 4375 41.77 4080 41 00 43.00 4500 4600 PotassiUm chloride S/mt 320 1157 98 1 1225 118 1 1130 120.0 124.0 1270 1300 TSIP $/mt 430 1803 1318 1377 1269 1330 140.0 150.0 1500 1550 Urea, East Europe, bagged $/mt n a n a 119 3 101 1 95 3 93.0 108.6 126.7 131.3 135.8 Metals and minerals Aluminum $/mt 556 1,456 1,639 1,549 1,444 1,340 1,400 1,500 1,600 1,700 Copper $/nmt 1 1,416 2,182 2,661 1,813 1,578 1,545 1,650 1,900 2,000 2,050 Gold $/toz 35 9 607 9 383 5 279 0 271 0 310.0 300 0 275.0 300 0 3000 Iron ore c/dmtu ' 9 84 28 09 32 50 28 79 30.03 29 50 30 00 31 00 32.00 32 50 Lad c/kg 303 906 81.1 454 476 45.0 480 550 600 62.5 Nickel S/mt 2,846 6,519 8,864 8,638 5,945 6,700 7,500 7,500 6,700 6,800 Silver c/toz i 177 0 2,064 482 0 499 9 438 6 460 0 480.0 500 0 525 0 550 0 Tin c/kg 367 3 1,677 608 5 543 6 448 4 405.0 4500 525.0 540 0 550 0 Zinc c/kg 29 6 76 1 151 4 112.8 88 6 77.0 84.0 100.0 105 0 110 0 ti a = Not available a $ = U S dollar, c = U S cent, bbl = barrel, cumo cubic meter, dmtu = dry nietric ton init, kg = kilograin, mmhtu = million British thermal unit, mit = metric ton, anid toz = troy ouince Note Projections as of Novemiiber 12, 2002 Soturce World Bank, Developmenit Piospects Group 195 G LOB AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A2.14 Commodity prices and price projections in constant 1990 dollars Actual Projections Commodity Unita 1970 1980 1990 2000 2001 2002 2003 2005 2010 2015 Energy Coal, Australia $/mt n.a. n.a 39.67 26 97 33 68 2748 26 18 26 06 26.53 27.00 Crude oil, average S/bbl 4 31 46 80 22 88 29 01 25.38 25.92 23 16 18.34 17.09 17 72 Natural gas, Europe $/mmbtu n a 4 32 2.55 3 96 4 23 3.11 2 82 2.51 2.47 2 53 Natural gas, U.S. $/mmbtu 0 61 1.97 1.70 4 43 4.12 3.37 3.22 2.90 2.70 2.74 Nonenergy Commodities Agriculture Beverages Cocoa c/kg 240 6 330 5 126.7 93.1 111 4 188.7 183.2 154.5 1412 141 8 Coffee, other milds c/kg 408.8 440.0 197 2 197 3 143.1 137.9 142.1 180.9 218 1 236 3 Coffee, robusta c/kg 325 7 411 7 118 2 93 8 63 3 66 3 71 0 80.9 98.9 120.3 Tea, auctions (3) average c/kg 297.7 210 6 205 8 192 8 166.6 155.5 156 1 159.3 157.4 151 9 Food Fats and oils Coconut oil $/mt 1,416.0 855 3 336.5 462 7 331.5 430 3 453 0 579.2 580.1 565.4 Copra $/mt 801.6 574 7 230.7 313 1 210 6 277 9 377.5 434.4 431 7 421 9 Groundnut oil $/mt 1,349.5 1,090 1 963 7 733 3 709 0 705.0 755.1 791 6 764.5 738.3 Palm oil $/mt 927 1 740 9 289.8 318 8 297 7 399.2 392 6 386.1 404 8 400 8 1 Soybean meal $/mt 365 7 333 1 200.2 194.4 188 6 1814 201.4 197.9 193 4 185 6 Soybean oil $/mt 1,020 8 758 6 447 3 347.4 368 9 456.2 453.0 415.1 413 7 426.1 Soybeans $/mt 416.8 376.0 246 8 217.7 204 1 217.7 231.6 226.9 215 9 211 0 1 Grains Maize $/mt 208.2 159.0 109.3 91.0 93.4 103 7 125.8 111.0 107.9 109.7 Rice, Thailand, 5% $/mt 450 3 521.4 270.9 208 0 180 1 199 1 211.4 226.9 233.9 2236 Sorghum $/mt 184.7 163.6 103.9 90.4 99 3 105.8 125.8 112 6 107.5 108.0 Wheat,US,HRW $/mt 1957 2193 1355 1172 132.2 157.1 1812 1448 1439 1392 Other food Bananas, U.S. $/mt 592 1 478 9 540.9 435.7 607.9 549.5 521.6 510 8 510.9 497 9 Beef, U.S c/kg 465 0 350.3 256.3 198 5 221 9 222.9 231 6 220.1 199.7 194.1 Oranges $/mt S99.1 508.0 531.1 373.2 620.6 609.6 553 7 482.7 472.2 464.1 Shrimp, Mexico c/kg n.a. 1,462 1,069 1,554 1,581 1,078 1,158 1,593 1,529 1,451 Sugar, world c/kg 29 32 80.17 27 67 18.5 19.8 15.6 15.1 17 0 18.9 18.6 Agricultural raw materials limber Logs, Cameroon $/cum 153.3 319.5 343 5 283.0 277.3 274 8 276 9 289 6 304.0 324.9 Logs, Malaysia $/cum 153.8 248.2 177.2 195.2 165.8 169.0 171.2 207.6 233.9 248 9 Sawnwood, Malaysia $/cum 623 9 502 7 533 0 611.1 501.7 547.4 563.8 603 3 647 6 691 9 Other raw materials Cotton c/kg 241 1 261.7 181.9 133.8 1103 103.7 111.0 1234 1348 1350 Rubber, RSSI, Malaysia clkg 145.2 180.8 86.5 71 0 62.6 82.3 82 1 80.9 78.9 80.2 Tobacco $/mt 3,836 2,889 3,392 3,058 3,131 2,872 3,020 3,137 2,946 2,785 Fertilizers DAP $/mt 192.5 282.1 171 4 158.5 154 0 163.8 169 1 164.1 157.4 151.9 Phosphate rock /int 39.2 59.3 40 5 45 0 43.5 42.3 41.3 41 5 40 5 38.8 Potassium chloride $/mt 114.1 1469 98 1 125.9 123.1 117.2 1208 119.7 114.2 1097 TSP $/mt 153.3 228.8 131.8 141.5 132 2 137.9 140.9 144.8 134.9 130.8 Urea, East Europe, bulk $/mt n a n.a. 119.3 1039 99.3 96.4 1094 1223 118.1 114.6 Metals and minerals Aluminum $1mt 1,982 1,848 1,639 1,592 1,505 1,389 1,409 1,448 1,439 1,434 Copper $/mt 5,047 2,770 2,661 1,863 1,645 1,602 1,661 1,834 1,799 1,730 Gold $/toz 128.1 771.6 383.5 286.7 282 4 321.4 302.0 265.5 269.8 253.1 Iron ore c/dmtu 35.1 35 7 32 S 29.6 31.3 30.6 30.2 29.9 28 8 27.4 Lead c/kg 108.0 115.0 81 1 46.6 49.6 46.7 48.3 53.1 54.0 52 7 Nickel $/mt 10,147 8,275 8,864 8,876 6,196 6,947 7,551 7,240 6,026 5,738 Silver c/toz 631.0 2,619 4 482.0 513.7 457.1 476.9 483 2 482.7 472.2 464 1 Tin c/kg 1,309.6 2,129.3 608.5 558.5 467.4 419.9 453.0 506.8 485 7 464.1 Zinc c/kg 105.5 96.6 151.4 115.9 92 3 79.8 84.6 96.5 94.4 92 8 n.a. = Not available. a. $ = U.S. dollar, c = U S cent, bbl = barrel, cum = cubic meter, dmtu dry metric ton unit, kg = kilogram, mmbtu = million British thermal unit, mt = metric ton, and toz = troy ounce. Note: Projections as of November 12, 2002. Souirce: World Bank, Development Prospects Group 196 G L O B A L C OIM IM O D I T Y P R I C E P R O S P E C T S Table A2.15 Weighted indices of commodity prices and inflation (1990 = 100) Actual Prolectionsa Index 1970 1980 1990 200(0 2001 1 2002 2003 2005 2010 2015 Current dollars 1'etroleumli 5 3 161 2 100 0 123.4 106 4 109 3 100 5 83 0 83 0 918 Noncinergy commoditiesh 43 8 125 5 100 0 86.9 79 0 82 9 87 7 94 2 102 7 109 9 Agriculture 45 8 138 1 100.0 87.7 79 7 86 5 91 7 98 0 108 9 118 0 Beverages 56.9 181.4 100 0 88 4 72.1 84 4 87 5 97 8 1151 130 6 Food 46 7 139.3 100 0 84 5 86 0 89 8 96 3 97 8 104 3 108 2 Fats and oils 64 4 148 7 100 0 96 2 89.0 100 2 108 2 1131 120 9 126 1 Grains 46.7 134 3 100 0 79 5 78 2 89 0 104 5 99 4 106.6 111 1 Other food 32 2 13-1 3 100 0 77 7 87.9 819 819 84 4 89 4 92 0 Rav materials 36.4 104.6 1000 91.4 774 836 888 984 1102 1212 Timber 318 79 0 1000 111.0 902 98 1 1039 1178 1366 1555 Other raw nmaterials 39 6 122 0 100 0 78.0 68.6 73 7 78 5 85 2 92 2 97 8 Fertilizers 30 4 128 9 100 0 105 8 98 8 I 102 0 104 4 111 0 112 8 116 1 ,Metals and minierals 40 4 94 2 100 0 83 0 75 1 72 4 76 5 83 2 86 4 89 5 Conistant 1990 dollars' Iletroleunm 189 204.6 1000 1268 1109 1133 1012 802 747 775 Noinenergy comniodities 156.3 159 3 100 0 89 3 82 3 86 0 88 3 90 9 92 4 92 7 Agricilturc 163 3 173 3 100 0 90.1 83 1 89 6 92 3 94 6 97 9 99 5 Beverages 2028 2303 100.0 908 751 875 881 944 1035 1102 Food 166 5 176.8 100 0 86 8 89 6 93 1 96 9 94 5 93 8 91 3 Fars and oils 229 5 188 7 100.0 98 9 92.8 103 8 109 0 109 2 108 8 106 4 Graiis 1666 1705 1000 817 815 923 1052 960 959 938 Other food 114 9 170 5 100 0 79 9 916 84 9 82 4 81 5 80 4 77 6 Rawv materials 129 8 132 7 100 0 93 9 80 6 86 7 89 4 95 0 99 1 102 3 Timber 113.3 100.3 100.0 1141 94 0 101 7 104 6 113 7 122 9 1312 Other raw materials 141 1 154.9 1000 80.1 71 5 765 790 822 829 825 Fertili,ers 108.3 163 6 100 0 108 7 102.9 10S 7 105 1 107 2 101 5 98 0 Metals anid min[erals 143 9 119 6 100.0 85 3 78.3 75 1 77 0 80 3 77 7 75 5 Inflatioi indicesd MUVindexe 2805 7878 100.00 9732 9595 9645 9933 10359 111 18 11851 Percentage chanige per annum 10 88 2 41 -0 27 -1 40 0 53 2 98 2 12 1 42 1 29 US GDI' deflator 33.59 65.93 100 00 123.73 126 42 I 127 69 129.73 136 03 153 01 172 27 Percentage change per annLum 6 98 4.25 215 218 1 00 1 60 2 40 2 38 2 40 a Commodity price projections as of November 12, 2002 b 'IThe Wrorld Bank primiiary commodity price indices are compuited front 1987-89 export values in U S dollars for low- and middle-incomiie econoinies. rehased to 1990 Weights for the subgroup indices expressed as ratios to the Tioneniergy index are as follows agriculture-69 1 percelnt, fertilizers- 2 7 percent, anid nmetals anld mincrals-28.2 percenit, bevcrages-16 9 percent, food-29 4 percent, and rawv materials-22 8 percent, fats and oils- 10 I percent, graiiis-6 9 percent, anid other food-12 4 percent, tinber-9 3 percent and other raw inaterials-13 6 percent c Computed from unirounded data and deflated bv the imialnLufactuires unlit value (MUV) index d Inflation indices for 2002-15 are proecticons as of November 8, 2002 MUV for 2001 is an estimate Growth rates for 1980, 1990, 2000, 2005, 2010, and 2015 refer to compound annuial rate of change between adjacent endpoint years, all others are annual growth rates from the previous year e Unit vaLie index in U S dollar terimis of manufactures exported from the G-5 countries (France, Germany, Japan, the Ulnited Kingdonm, and the Uniited States) weighted proportionially to the countries' exports to des eloping cointries Souirce World Bank, Developmenit Prcispects GroLIp U S Departiment of Commerce for historical U S GDP deflator 197 G LO BAL EC ONO MI C PROS P ECTS 2 0 0 3 Notes Centigrade warmer in 1997 Thus the effects of this 1. As measured relative to the manufactures unit year's El Nifio are expected to be smaller than in 1997, value (MUV) index, which is the unit value index in U.S. when drought in Southeast Asia led to wildfires and dollar terms (1990 = 100) of manufactures exported poor crop harvests. from the G-S countries (France, Germany, Japan, the 3. The European Central Bank and 14 European United Kingdom, and the United States) weighted by the central banks agreed in September 1999 to limit sales country's exports to developing countries. to only 400 tons of gold per year, and not more than 2. An El Niflo occurs when the Pacific Ocean 2,000 tons in total, over the subsequent five years. warms, as occurred this year. But this year's El Niiio is 4. Verleger, Philip K. Jr The Petroleum Economics significantly weaker than the last one, which occurred Monthly. August 2002, p. 11, and September 2002, in 1997. The Pacific is about 1 degree Centigrade P. 1. warmer than usual this year compared with 3 degrees 198 Appendix 3 Global Economic Indicators G LO BA L EC ONO MI C PRO SP E CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A3.1 Growth of real GDP, 1971-2015 GDP in 199S prices and exchange rates, average annual growth (percentt) GDP in 2001 Growth percent (current billions Esnmate Forecast of dollars) 1971-80 1981-90 1991-2000 2001 2002 2003-15 World 30,790 3.7 3.0 2.6 1.1 1.7 3 1 High-income economies 24,852 3.5 3.1 2.5 0.7 1.5 2.6 Industrial countries 24,088 3 4 3 1 2 4 0.8 1 4 2.5 G-7 countries 20,632 3.4 3 1 2 3 0 5 1.3 2 5 United States 10,082 3.3 3 2 3 2 0.3 2 3 3 1 Japan 4,166 4 5 4 1 1 3 -0.3 0 0 1 6 G-4 Europe 5,678 2 9 2 4 18 L.4 0 7 2 2 Germanva 1,856 2 7 2 2 1 7 0.7 0.4 1.9 Euro area 6,090 3 2 2 3 2.0 1 5 0.8 2.3 Non-G-7 industrial 3,456 3.2 2 9 3 0 2.0 2 2 3 0 Other high income 764 7 7 5 1 5 1 -07 2 3 4 3 AsianNIEs 531 95 74 61 -1.4 26 47 Low- and middle-income economies 5,938 4.8 2.6 3.2 2.9 2.8 4.6 Excluding CE Eur / CIS 5,101 5 5 3 0 4 7 3 0 2 7 4 7 Asia 2,205 5 2 6 8 7 0 5.2 5.8 6 0 East Asia and Pacific 1,573 6 6 7 3 7 7 5 5 6 3 6 2 China 1,150 6 2 9.3 10 1 7.3 7 8 Indonesia 145 7 9 6 4 4 2 3 3 3 2 South Asia 632 3 1 5 7 5 2 4 4 4.6 5 4 India 495 3 0 5 8 5 6 4.5 4.8 Latin America and the Caribbean 1,882 5 9 1 1 3 3 0 4 -1.1 3 6 Brazil 503 8 5 1 5 2 7 1 5 0 7 Mexico 618 6 7 1 8 3.5 -03 1.3 Argentina 269 3 0 -1 5 4 5 -4.4 -11 9 Europe and Central Asia 977 3 5 1 7 -1.7 2 3 3.6 3 6 Russian Federationb 310 3.7 1 5 -4 0 5 0 4 3 Turkey 148 4 1 5 2 3 5 -7 4 4.1 Poland 176 5 1 -1 7 3 7 1 0 1 0 Middle East and North Africa 568 6.5 2 5 3.2 3 2 2 5 3 3 Saudi Arabia 188 10 3 0.4 2 2 1 2 1 1 Iran, Islamic Rep of 114 1.8 2 7 4 1 4.8 4 5 Egypt, Arab Rep of 96 6.6 5 5 4 4 2 9 1 0 Sub-Saharan Africa 306 3 3 1 7 2 2 2 9 2 5 3 7 South Africa 113 3 5 1 3 1 7 2 2 2.2 Nigeria 41 4 7 1 1 2 6 4.0 -0 6 a Data prior to 1991 covers West Germany b Data prior to 1992 covers former Soviet Union Note Growth rates over intervals are computed using compound average methods Souirce World Bank data and staff estimates Figure A3.1 Real GDP growth (percent) 100 80 1991-2000 2003-15 60 40 -20 -40 High-income East Asia South Latin America Eastern Middle East Sub- countries and Pacific Asia and the Europe and and North Saharan Canbbean Central Asia Africa Africa Source World Baiik data and staff estimates 200 G LO BAL EC ONO MI C I ND ICA rOR S Table A3.2 Growth of real per capita GDP, 1971 -2015 GDP in 1995 prices anid exchange rates, average atnnial growth (percent) capita ~Growthi percent dolr) 1971-80 1981-90 1991-2000 i 0321 World ~i~l 1.8 1.3 1.2 14 i High-income economies' 3 2.6 2.5 1.8 14 ho1 oI Industrial countries 2 6 2 5 1 8 *0A 1.1 G-7 countries 2 7 2 5 1.7 111 14 United States 2 2 2 2 2 2 -1 l~~ Japan 3.3 3 5 1 1 -04 '1L 13 G-4 Europe ~I$1 2 6 2 1 15 FI ® .4 Germanyb 2 6 2.0 1 4 l1ll 113 ~ 4 Euro area ~i11. 2 7 2.1 1 7 I1 lI13 l Non-G-7 industrial ll~11 2 2 2 2 2 4 14 11)~ 4 Other highi income 1lI~ 5 1 3 3 3.6 11.1 ~~ AsaianNIEs 11i 7 2 5 9 4 7 i113 l4 Low- and middle-income economies 1j1 2.6 0.7 1.6 14 13 ~ 4 Excluding CE Eur /CIS ll9l1l. 3 1 0 9 2.9 13 14 o¶ Asia W 3 0 4 8 5 4 ~ 4 13 ~ I East Asia and Pacific 1 4 6 5 6 6 4 414 .941 34 China ¶1~ 4 3 7.7 9 0 W65 - Indonesia 13. 5 4 4 4 2 5 Xl 14 South Asia 43 0 7 3 4 3 3 3 14) .11 India iI) 0 7 3 6 3 7 3) £4 o Latin America and the Carihbean 6' 3 3 -0.9 1 6 111'12 ~ 14 Brazil l1? 5 9 -0 4 1 2 11u 1 Mexico 6,=31 3.6 -0.3 1 7 ___ Argentiiia ?1l 3 3 -2 9 3 2 ___ 1 Europe and Central Asia 131f1 2 5 0.7 -1 9 .14 14 Russian Federation' 3J~ 3 1 0 8 -3 9 3 14 - Turkey 13¶® 1 7 2 8 1 9 08!7 3 Poland 43 4 2 -2 4 3.5 14 !4 Middle East and North Africa 1 ~ 3 6 -0 6 1 0 1 Saudi Arabia 5 1 -4 8 -1 2 -113 Iran, Islanmic Rep of --1 4 -0 7 2 4 &3 £1 Egypt, Arab Rep of -4.4 2 9 2.4 1143 Sub-Saharan Africa 414 0 5 -1 2 -0 4 1 go3(i~1 1 South Africa 1321 12 -1 2 -0.3 (LIP? 1111 Nigeria M311 1 7 -1 9 -0.2 113 3J a Regional aggregates compuited as surn(GDP,)/surn(POP,), where "i" indicates country, in the region, and are unweighted by population or other measures b Data prior to 1991 covers West Germany c Data prior to 1992 covers former Soviet Uniioni Note Growth rates oiver intervals are computed using compound annual methods Source World Bank data and staff estimTates Figure A3.2 Real per capita GDP growth (percent) 7 0 2003-15 6 0 4 0 _____ 1991-2000 2 0 10=F 0 0 -1 0 -2 0 -3 0 High-income East Asia South Latin Amenca Eastem Middle East Sub- countries and Pacific Asia and the Europe and and North Saharan Canbbean Central Asia Africa Africa Source Wosrld Batik data and staff estimates 201 G LOB AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A3.3 Inflation: GDP deflators, 1971-2015 Deflators in local currency units, 1995=100, percentage change' Growth percent Growth percent Estimate Forecast 1971-80 1981-90 1991-00 2001 2002 2003-15 World 9.0 5.8 3.7 2.3 1.7 1.9 High-income economies 8.8 5.3 2.0 1.5 1.0 1.3 Industrial countries 8.7 4.6 2 0 1.5 1.1 1 3 G-7 countries 8 3 4.2 1 7 1 2 0 9 1 1 United States 7.0 4 3 2.1 2.4 1.1 1.4 Japan 7.8 2.0 0.1 -1.2 -0 9 0 0 G-4 Europe 9.9 5.7 2.6 1.8 1.9 1.7 Germanyb 5 3 2.6 2.6 1.4 1 4 1.2 Euro area 9.6 6.1 2.8 2.3 2.1 1 6 Non-G-7 industrial 11.1 7.1 3 3 2.9 2.1 1.9 Other high income 19.3 33.1 3 8 0 4 -0 4 1.9 Asian NIEs 9.5 4 7 2 4 -0.4 -1 0 1.5 Low- and middle-income economies 9.6 8.3 11.7 5.8 4.4 4.2 Excluding CE Eur / CIS 11.4 10.0 9 2 5 7 4 3 4 1 Asia 10.5 7.2 6.9 6.3 3 4 4 5 East Asia and Pacific 9.6 5 5 5.6 6.6 2 5 3 4 China 0.9 5.4 6.3 0.0 0.4 ... Indonesia 20.6 8 8 15 0 11.4 11 4 South Asia 11 9 9 0 7.9 6.1 5 0 5.5 India 8 9 8.5 8.1 4.0 2 8 ... Latin America and the Caribbean 14.6 19.3 12.5 6.9 5 0 4 1 Brazil 39.7 330.8 206 1 7.3 7.9 Mexico 18.1 63.7 18.1 5 4 3.3 Argentina 117 7 439 5 10.2 -1.1 36.5 Europe and Central Asia 0.3 2 4 50.3 5.9 4 7 4 0 Russian Federation' 0 3 2 3 104 5 18.0 5.8 Turkey 32.8 46 6 71.7 47.2 27 9 Poland 4 4 72 1 24.1 1.7 3.8 Middle East and North Africa 11 7 8 7 6.0 4.2 4 1 4 0 Saudi Arabia 23 8 -3.1 2.9 7.0 4.8 Iran, Islamic Rep. of 20 2 15 6 25.6 8 6 5.1 Egypt, Arab Rep. of 11 0 13 1 8.6 4 5 4.1 Sub-Saharan Africa 10 4 9.4 9 8 5.4 4.3 4.0 South Africa 13.3 15 1 9.8 7 1 12 0 Nigeria 13.4 16.6 28 6 5 9 4.5 ... a High-income group inflation rates are GDP-weighted averages of local currency inflation, LMIC groups are medians, world is GDP-weighted average of the two groups b. Data prior to 1991 covers West Germany. c Data prior to 1992 covers former Soviet Union. Note. Growth rates over intervals are computed using compound annual methods. Source. World Bank data and staff estimates Figure A3.3 GDP inflation (percent) 50 3 140 120 10 0 - _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ 80 011991-2000 - 4 0 __7 20- - m High-income East Asia South Labn Amenca Eastem Middle East Sub- countries and Pacific Asia and the Europe and and North Saharan Canbbean Central Asia Afnca Africa Source World Bank data and staff estimates 202 G LO BA L E CON OM IC IND I CATO RS Table A3.4 Current account balances, 1971-2015 Expressed as shares of GDP (percent) Cufrrent Acct Sbares percent * 2001 (billions Estimate Forecast of dollars) 1971-80 1981-90 1991-2000 2001 2002 2003-15 Worlda -187 -0.1 -0.5 -0.4 -0.6 -0.7 -0.6 High-income cconomies -190 -0.1 -0.2 0.0 -0.8 -0.9 -0.7 Industrial countries -247 -0.3 -0.5 -0.1 - 1.0 - 1.1 -0.9 G-7 countries -289 -0.1 -0.4 -0.3 -1.4 -1.6 -1.3 United States -393 0.0 -1.9 -1.8 -3.9 -4.8 -3.3 Japan 89 0.3 2.3 2.5 2.1 2.8 2.3 G-4 Europe -4 0.1 0.3 -0.1 -0.1 0.6 0.4 Germanyb 2 0.5 2.4 -0.7 0.1 1.7 0.4 Euro area 10 -0.1 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.8 1.0 Non-G-7 industrial 42 -1.5 -0.6 0.8 1.2 1.3 1.3 Other high income 57 12.3 10.3 4.0 7.7 6.6 3.0 Asian NlEs 50 1.8 6.9 5.4 9.5 10.3 4.2 Low- and middle-income economies 4 0.0 -1.7 -1.6 0.1 0.4 -0.3 Excluding CE.Eur / FSU 11 0.2 -1.9 -1.6 0.2 0.6 -0.1 Asia 42 -0.7 -1.6 -0.1 1.9 1.9 1.6 East Asia and Pacific 42 -0.8 -1.4 0.5 2.7 2.7 1.8 China 17 0.1 0.2 1.6 1.5 1.6 ... Indonesia 7 -2.3 -3.1 -0.4 4.8 2.6 South Asia 0 0 -0.5 -2.0 -1.S 0.0 -0.1 -1.2 India 1 0.2 -1.7 -1.2 0.2 0.2 ... Latin America and the Caribbean -54 -2.8 -1.8 -2.8 -2.9 -1.5 -2.3 Brazil -23 -4.4 -1.6 -2.2 -4.6 -2.8 ... Mexico -18 -3.9 -0.8 -3.7 -2.9 -2.7 Argentina -4 -0.4 -2.2 -3.2 -1.7 9.4 ... Europe and Central Asia -7 -0.8 -0.5 -2.3 -2.0 -2.4 -1.6 Russian Federationc 36 2.1 3.5 4.7 11.7 8.0 ... Turkey 3 -2.1 -1.3 -1.1 2.5 -0.6 ... Poland -7 -0.9 -1.4 -3.6 -4.4 -3.7 ... Middle East and North Africa 29 9.5 -1.7 -2.1 5.2 3.3 -1.0 Saudi Arabia 13 22.0 -7.2 -6.6 6.9 5.5 ... Iran, Islamic Rep. of 7 11.8 -0.4 1.9 7.1 4.3 ... Egypt, Arab Rep. of 0 -3.4 -3.4 1.5 -0.4 -0.2 ... Sub-Saharan Africa -7 -1.8 -2.7 -2.1 -2.2 -3.0 -2.0 South Africa 0 -1.3 0.4 -0.2 -0.2 0.3 ... Nigeria 0 1.S -0.7 -0.4 0.4 -4.8 ... a. CtLrrent account as defined in Balance of Payments (BOP) version 5.0, world represents statistical discrepancy; shares over inter- vals are period averages. b. Data prior to 1991 covers West Germnany. c. Data prior to 1992 covers former Soviet Union. Source: World Bank data and staff estimates. Figure A3.4 Current account balance-to-GDP ratio (percent of GDP) 3.0 2.0 1991-2000 2003-15 1.0 0.0 r L -2.0 -3.0 -4.0 High-income East Asia South Latin America Eastem Middle East Sub- countries and Pacific Asia and the Europe and and North Saharan Caribbean Central Asia Africa Africa Source: World Bank data atid staff estimates. 203 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A3.5 Exports of goods, 2001 Merchandise exports (FOB), millions of dollars, average annual growth rate 1992-2001 (percent); effective market growth (EMG) 1992-2001 (percent) Exports Growth EMGb I Exports Growth EMGb | Exports Growth EMGb World 6,056,976 7.0 10.6 Europe and Sub-Saharan Central Asia (cgntinued) Afnca Iconinued) All developing Belarus 7,421 9.6 10 4 Sudan I 1 797 14 4 7.3 countries 1,509,357 8.2 9.4 Bulgaria 4,872 2.2 9.6 Zambia '789 -0 5 13.1 Czech Republic 33,690 8 7 9.0 Zimbabwe 2,063 7.8 9 2 Asia 574,958 11.3 8.8 Estonia 3,347 35.1 8 6 East Asia 509,540 11.7 8.5 Georgia 505 15.0 8.0 High-income China 266,322 16 0 8 3 Hungary 28,244 8.7 9.1 countries 4,547,619 6.7 10.9 China 266,322 16 0 8 3 Kazakstan 10,569 44 8 9.8 Fij i 483 4.3 6 1 Kyrgyz Republic 548 10.4 19.5 Industrial Indonesia 56,321 8 2 8 5 Latvia 2,091 13 6 9.6 Idsra Malaysia 87,980 8 7 8.6 Lithuania 4,706 22 1 9.5 countries 4,010,686 6.7 11.1 Myanmar . Poland 42,674 10 8 9.4 Papua New Romania 11,385 10 3 9 8 G-7 countries 2,793,252 5.7 11.3 Guinea 1,813 3 7 6.5 Russian Canada 267,706 7 9 8.3 Philippines 31,242 12 3 7.9 Federation 104,501 4 3 10 9 France 323 886 6 5 16.1 Thailand 65,379 8 1 88 Slovak Republic 12,534 104 104 Germany 543:416 63 136 Vietnam 15,470 19 2 8 1 Tajikistan 858 48 6 16.2 Italy | 264,390 4 9 9 9 South Asia 65,418 8.5 11.3 Turkmenistan 1,619 44 4 8.3 Japan 384,482 27 9.1 Bangladesh 5,790 13 1 11.2 Turkey 28,121 9.3 9 1 United Kingdom 276,076 5.8 12.5 India 43,268 9.6 11.3 Ukraine 17,319 10 1 9.7 United States 733,297 6.6 9.8 Nepal 698 8 1 89 Uzbekistan 3,428 48 0 15.0 Pakistan 9,665 3 0 10 1 Other industrial 1,217,435 6.7 7.8 Sri Lanka 5,998 8 5 13 4 Middle East and Australia 63,759 6 7 7.8 N. Africa 164,753 2.2 9.0 Austria 63,459 7 7 8 5 Latin America 351,608 8.2 9.7 Algeria 19,567 0.8 10 5 Belgium' 178,698 40 4 6.1 Argentina 26,670 7.1 9 0 Egypt, Arab Denmark 50,912 1.9 8.2 Bolivia 1,196 7.1 12.5 Rep of 6,830 3 6 10.2 Finland 43,006 71 10 0 Brazil 58,223 5.3 11.9 Iran, Islamic I Greece 10,615 43 81 Chile 18,505 6 7 10.2 Rep of 24,517 2 1 10.1 Iceland 2,035 09 7.8 Colombia 13,281 23 110 Jordan 2,192 86 6.9 Ireland 83,242 123 10.9 Costa Rica 5,709 103 14.7 Morocco 7,139 1 7 9.5 Korea, Rep of 150,494 136 8.3 Dominican Oman 10,563 6 0 8 1 Netherlands 193,239 7 0 203 Republic 5,594 19 9 11.8 Saudi Arabia 78,342 1 5 8 1 New Zealand 13,918 3.5 7.9 Ecuador 4,923 4 6 10 3 Syrian Arab Rep 5,151 2.3 5 7 Norway 59,701 4 2 9 4 El Salvador 3,367 13 7 13.6 Tunisia 6,684 2 9 12.7 Portugal 114,427 8 8 9.6 Guatemala 2,975 5 6 10.0 Yemen, Rep of 3,769 9 9 8.5 Spain 114,427 8 8 9 6 Jamaica 1,520 1 0 6 8 Sweden 77,635 7 4 10 S Mexico 158,449 13 2 8 3 Sub-Saharan Switzerland 86,497 3 8 9 0 Panama 5,919 2 8 8.9 Africa 92,057 3.3 12.5 Paraguay 2,251 -3.2 103 Angola 7,944 6 7 12 3 Other high- Peru 7,518 3 3 10.4 Botswana .., income 536,932 7.0 9.1 Trinidad and C6te d'lvoire 3,741 6 4 9 0 Bahrain 6,260 5 0 7 4 Tobago 3,153 6 9 7.4 Cameroon 2,262 1.9 9 0 Brunei I 3,156 -1.1 6 5 Uruguay 2,081 0 3 10.1 Ethiopia 396 13 9 6 9 Hong Kong, Venezuela, Gabon 2,540 -1 1 7.9 China 189,842 7 2 9.9 R B de 25,928 5 4 8 3 Ghana 2,021 9 5 113 Israel 31,275 9 0 13 3 Kenya 1,712 4 9 7.7 Kuwait 1 17,968 29 0 7.5 Europe and Madagascar 796 9 6 11.5 Singapore 121.747 7.4 8 4 Central Asia 325,981 8.3 10.1 Nigeria 16,443 0 7 7 3 Taiwan, China 122,495 5.7 8.3 Armenia 327 -8 2 30.1 Senegal 1,024 3 6 6 5 United Arab Azerbaijan 2,110 0 5 9.7 South Africa 30,198 2.8 6 1 Emirates 37,638 2 7 6 4 FOB is free on board a Includes Luxembourg. b Effective market growth (EMG) is a weighted average of import volume growth in the country's export markets Source See Technical Notes 204 G LO BA L E CON OM IC IND I CATO RS Figure A3.5a Merchandise exports as share of GDP, 2001 (penrcent) 40 30 20 01 Industrial Sub- East Asia South Latin Eastern Middle countries Saharan and Pacitic Asia America and Europe and East and Atrica the Caribbean Central Asia North Atrica Source World Bank data Figure A3.5b Annual growth rate of export volumes, 1992-2001 (percent) 15 10 World - _ _ Industnal Sub- East Asia South Latin Eastern Middle countnes Saharan and Pacific Asia America and Europe and East and Afrca the Caribbean Central Asia North Atrica Source World Bank data 205 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PRO SP EC TS 2 0 0 3 Table A3.6 Imports of goods, 2001 Merchandise imports (CIF), millions of dollars, average annual growth rate 1992-2001 (percent), merchandise imports share of GDP (percent) | Imports Growth Share Imports Growth Share Imports Growth Share World 6,079,466 6.2 18.1 Europe and Sub-Saharan Central Asia (chntinued) Africa (continued) All developing Czech Republic 36,746 14 1 67.0 South Africa 27,873 5.5 25 3 countries 1,375,828 6.2 19.7 Estonia 4,255 22.3 83.0 Sudan 1,439 2 4 11 5 Georgia 1,047 30.3 37.0 Zambia 1,018 2.8 27.9 Asia 502,434 9.2 22.7 Hungary 30,759 11 9 63 7 Zimbabwe 920 -5 9 10 2 East Asia 424,657 9.7 26.8 Kazakstan 9,322 25.2 46.9 EaChmAsia 4242,65 95.7 268 Kyrgyz Republic 552 -1 2 37.5 High-income China 232,322 15.8 20 1 Latvia 3,351 14.7 46.9 countries 4,703,638 6.9 18.9 Fiji 503 -1 8 29.9 Lithuania 5,740 25 2 49 7 Indonesia 30,962 4 9 21.4 Moldova idsra Myanmaysa6,r5 68 7. Poland 53,874 13 1 32.8 countries 4,188,176 6.9 17.4 Papua New Romania 14,124 10 1 35.6 Papua New ~~~~~~~Russian Guinea 932 -3 2 31.5 Federation 65,387 4 1 21 1 G-7 countries 3,037,774 6.7 14.7 Philippines 28,496 8.7 39.9 Slovak Republic 13,978 10 6 65 8 Canada 226,372 6 7 32 1 Thailand 61,847 3 0 53.9 TaFikistan 1,290 1 0 22.0 France 307,429 5 5 23.5 Vietnam 15,059 17.0 45.8 TFYR Germany 457,102 5 1 24.6 Macedonia ~~~~~Italy 243,055 3.9 22 3 South Asia 77,776 6.7 12.3 cedn 28 Japan 3a24 3 223 Bangladesh 8,601 9 9 17.1 Turkmenistan 2,073 35 4 348 Jaa21,9 2 7 India 51,624 8 0 10.4 Turkey 41,460 6.4 29.7 United Kingdom 324,362 6 9 22 8 Nepal 1,047 7.1 20.8 Ukraine 15,959 5 0 42.2 United States 1,166,561 9 3 11.6 Pakistan 10,484 0.6 16.7 Uzbekistan 3,331 25 2 33 8 Si Lanka 6,020 74 2 33 2 Other industrial 1,150,401 7 3 33.3 Sri Lanka ,020 72 332 Middle East Australia 61,856 7 0 17.2 Lattn America 3S2,347 10.2 18.8 and N. Africa 106,531 1.3 19.2 Austria 64,325 6 1 34 2 Argentina 19,100 9 7 7.1 Algeria 11,775 5 2 20.4 Belgium' 168,485 38 4 73 3 Bolivia 1,600 6 2 19.9 Egypt, Arab Denmark 43,956 3 3 27 2 Brazil 55,573 9 6 11 1 Rep of 15,016 3.4 16.1 Finland 30,341 3.8 24 9 Chile 16,412 7 6 24.7 Iran, Islamic Greece 29,684 6 0 25.5 Colombia 11,826 9 8 13.9 Rep. of 16,665 -5 0 16.1 Iceland 2,066 3 4 27 4 Costa Rica S,995 12.9 37.3 Iraq .. ... . Ireland 51,300 9.7 49.7 Dominican Jordan 4,061 5.5 46.9 Korea, Rep of 141,096 71 33.4 Republic 8,963 17 4 43 9 Morocco 10,273 3.9 28.3 Netherlands 174,344 6.9 45 8 Ecuador 4,674 6 7 34.3 Oman 4,735 3.8 24.6 New Zealand 12,447 5.3 25 8 El Salvador 5,055 13.8 36.2 Saudi Arabia 28,427 0 8 l5 1 Norway 33,682 2 4 20.0 Guatemala 4,672 10 0 23 9 Syrian Arab Portugal Jamaica 2,906 5.9 37 3 Rcp 3,757 4.8 21.2 Spain 146,449 7 5 25.1 Mexico 168,440 J12.6 27.3 Tunisia 9,349 6.0 44.4 Sweden 62,331 S 4 29 7 Panama 6,890 3 4 67.6 Yemen, Rep of 2,473 1.9 26 6 Switzerland 89,251 3 2 36 3 Paraguay 2,793 3 4 36 4 Peru 7,408 6 9 14.5 Sub-Saharan Other high- Trinidad and Africa 76,253 4.8 22.3 income 515,462 7.4 67.6 Tobago 3,216 9 5 38.2 Angola 2,477 9.2 27.1 Bahrain 4,929 1.8 83.3 Uruguay 2,971 6 0 15.0 Botswana 2,258 3.6 34 1 Brunei 1,427 1 9 48 4 Venezuela, C6oe d'lvoire 2,741 -0.2 28.3 Hong Kong, R B de 16,677 4.4 14.1 Cameroon 1,359 -3.6 13.5 China 198,588 7.8 21.1 Ethiopia 1,019 -0.8 15 7 Israel 35,111 7 1 30.3 Europe and Gabon 1,034 3.5 18 8 Kuwait 6,764 3.0 19.8 Central Asia 265,272 2.5 30.6 Ghana 2,326 9.2 30.6 Qatar .- Armenia 841 -6 7 40 3 Kenya 3,279 0 3 27.9 Singapore 109,852 7 0 28.3 Azerbaijan 1,976 2 2 319 Madagascar 954 7.6 20 9 Taiwan, China 107,298 6 8 38.1 Belarus 8,149 6 0 26.0 Nigeria 10,598 2 7 25 7 United Arab Bulgaria 5,771 3.3 46.1 Senegal 1,351 1.5 29.2 Emirates 39,769 11 1 82.6 CIF is cost insurance and freight. a Includes Luxembourg Source- See Technical Notes 206 G LOB AL E CON OM IC IND I CATO RS Figure A3.6a Merchandise imports as share of GDP, 2001 (percent) 30 20 A -World 10i--U U Industrial Sub- East Asia South Latin Eastern Middle countries Saharan and Pacific Asia America and Europe and East and Africa the Caribbean Central Asia North Africa Sotirce World Bank data Figure A3.6b Annual growth rate of import volumes, 1992-2001 (percent) 15 10 World 5- Industrial Sub- East Asia South Latin Eastem Middle countries Saharan and Pacific Asia America and Europe and East and Africa the Caribbean Central Asia North Africa Souirce World Bank data 207 G LO B AL EC ONO MI C PROS PE CT S 2 0 0 3 Table A3.7 Direction of merchandise trade, 2001 (percentage of tworld trade) Low- and middle-income importers Latin High-income importers Middle Amefica All Sub East Europe East and low- Other All Other All Saha- Asia and and the and United midus- indus- high- high- ran and South Central North Carib- middle- Source of exports States EU-15 Japan trial rrial income income Africa Pacific Asia Asia Africa bean mcome World High-income economies 12.8 27.8 3.3 6.6 52.1 5.7 57.8 0.9 6.1 0.8 3.4 1.5 4.5 17.1 74.9 Industrial 11.0 26 4 2.4 6.3 47.3 4 4 51.8 0 8 3.7 0.5 3 3 1 4 4.3 13.9 65.7 United States . . 2 6 1.0 3 4 7.4 1.1 8.5 0 1 0 8 0 1 0 2 0.2 2 8 4.2 128 EU-15 3.7 20.4 07 2.2 272 1.4 286 05 0.9 02 29 08 09 62 348 Japan 2.2 t.1 ... 03 4.1 12 53 0.1 12 01 01 01 03 1 8 71 Other industrial 4 5 2 0 0 4 0.3 73 03 7.6 0 0 0.3 0 1 0.1 0 1 0 1 0.8 8.4 Other high-income 1.9 1 4 0.9 0 3 4.8 1.2 6 0 0 1 2 4 0.3 0 1 0.1 0.2 3 2 9.2 Low- and muddle- income economies 6.7 6.1 2.1 0.7 16.4 2.8 19.2 0.5 1.4 0.4 1.8 0.5 1.3 5.9 25.1 Sub-Saharan Africa 0.3 0.5 0.0 0.0 0 9 0 1 1.0 0 2 0 1 0 0 0 0 0.0 0 1 0 4 1 4 East Asia and Pacific 1.9 1 3 1.5 0 3 5.5 2.0 7.5 0.1 0 7 0.2 0 2 0.1 0 2 1 6 9.1 SouthAsia 0.3 03 0.0 0.0 07 01 0.8 00 01 01 00 00 00 03 1 1 Europe and Central Asia 0.3 0 8 0 3 0.0 1.7 0.3 2 0 0 1 0 3 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 6 2.6 Middle East and North Africa 0.3 0 8 0.3 0 0 1.7 0.3 2.0 0 1 0 3 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 6 2 6 Latin America andtheCaribbean 3.6 07 0.1 02 46 01 47 0.0 0.1 00 0.1 01 09 12 5.9 World 19.5 33.9 5.5 7.3 68.5 8 5 77.0 1.4 7.5 1.2 5.2 2.0 5.8 23.0 100.0 EU is European Union a. Expressed as a share (percent) of total world exports. World merchandise exports in 2001 amounted to some $6,000 billion b Other high-income group includes the Asian newly industrializing economies, several oil exporters in the Gulf region, and Israel. Souirce International Monetary Fund, Direction of Trade Statistics 208 G L C B A L E C O N O bt I C I N D I C A T O R S Table A3.8 Growth of current dollar merchandise trade, by direction 1992-2001 (average annual percentage growuth) F F ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Lowv- and n1dl-lnc.eome,Iportr5r } * fEDBEL | Ml~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~fddle AtoerLe AlliZ Sub East Europe East and loss - ~~fIi ~~ A~~iD Salia- As,a and and the aild @ilnited ais^hb f xfi ran and South Central North Canb- middle- Souirce of exports Stae ftis D OM Afnca l'actfic Asia Asta Africa beatt tnconic WI'd High-income cconomies DS7 g a 4I 9 1.7 9.1 5.2 8.2 0.4 8 7 7.0 4. Industrial D A LT 43 4L L3BL 1 6 8 6 2 4 8 1 0 3 8 7 66 United States .J 1DA4 *0 43 ga 43 3 8 9 4 4 0 3 0 0 4 9 9 8 2 EU-IS bril 1104 6 " 1 6 7 6 1 1 9 3 0 1 7 4 59 Japan lD k - ,-W D 1X8 -2 6 7 2 -1 0 -19 -2 5 3 2 43 2 Other industrial _ & hjU 6 S0 &A 2 2 7 6 0 5 8 1 4 3 4 6 1 46 7 Otherhigih-income 4 U .10 ZLT 7A '.T 26 100 121 115 16 80 94 4 Low- and middle- incomc cconomiCs W12' R h3Ih 12.8 15 6 11.0 9.5 5 5 11 2 11.0 Sub-SaharallAfrica @h2 i@ @d AU ?9B - 124 221 179 90 89 168 146 East Asia anid P'acific U t WJ aL0 'PA D AfT 16 4 16 4 14 6 12 2 8 2 22 0 15 1 South Asia > ' #.6 93 @dl 117 15S6 11 6 -2 3 4 8 24 3 8.4 L1-- Europe arid CentralAsia WP3 LE Z3J 4 3 160 185 78 -27 34 0.0 75 5 Middle East and I NorthAfrica ILj3 ^4 8ih f. 3.% Ml v 16 0 18 5 7 8 -27 34 00 75 Latin America atidtheCaribbean EIFA6 a9 &lA 61 @ 77 131 100 83 57 103 100 World f l il d< e . 4.3 10.1 7.0 8.6 1 4 9.2 7.9 LU is Euiropean Union Note Growth rates are compound averages Souirce Intcrnational Monetary Funid, Directoiz of trade' Statistics 209 G LO BA L E CON OM IC PRO SP EC TS 2 O 0 3 Table A3.9 Structure of long-term debt, 2000 Share of long-term debt (percent) concessional debt, nonconcessional debt at variable interest rates, nonconicessional debt at fixed interest rates Nonconcessional Nonconcessional Concessinnal Variable Fixed Concessionial Vanable Fixed All developing Europe and Central countres 18.7 40.3 41.0 Asia (continued) i Bulgaria 4 3 75 9 19.7 Asia 28.5 38.3 33.2 Czech Republic 1.8 274 70 9 East Asia 20.1 44.9 35.0 Estonia 1.6 23 6 74 8 China 20 9 26 4 52 7 Georgia 610 8 8 30 1 Indonesia 279 61.8 10.4 Hungary 1.2 17.7 81 0 Korea, Rep. of 1.8 53.8 44.4 Kazakhstan 3.6 16.8 79 6 Malaysia 6.1 60.7 33 2 Kyrgyz Republic 58.3 15 6 26.1 Myanmar 79 6 10.4 10.0 Larvia 5.5 60.4 34 1 Papua New Lithuania 3.2 21.0 75 8 Guinea 36.1 12.3 51.6 Moldova 19.3 45 0 35 6 Philippines 29.6 33 0 37 4 Poland 12.1 56 0 31.9 Thailand 14.9 52 0 33.1 Romania 3 4 41 9 54 7 Vietnam 68.2 16 6 15.3 Russian Federation I 0 3 19.7 80 0 Slovak Republic 3.9 22.6 73.6 South Asia S5.5 17.4 27.0 Talikistan 76.6 7.7 15.8 Bangladesh 97.9 00 2 1 Turkmenistan India 39.4 20.2 40.4 Turkey 5.9 45.3 48.7 Nepal 99.8 0.0 0 2 Ukraine 23.3 35 0 41.6 Pakistan 60.7 27.3 12.1 Uzbekistan 22 3 58 2 19.5 Sri Lanka 85 7 5 8 8.5 Middle East and Latin America 4.7 56.1 39.2 N. Africa 36.9 28.8 34.3 Argentina 1.5 45 5 53.0 Algeria 13.3 49.8 36 9 Bolivia 60.3 27.0 12 7 Egypt, Arab Rep of 84 5 6.2 9 3 Brazil 1.1 76 1 22.8 Jordan 56 1 30.2 13.7 Chile 1 0 55 2 43.7 Morocco 315 32 4 36 1 Colombia 3.1 60.8 36 1 Oman 16.7 30 6 52.7 Costa Rica 16.7 24.1 59 2 Syrian Arab Rep. of 93.0 0.0 7 0 Dominican Republic 42.7 33 7 23.6 Tunisia 26.8 20.8 52 4 Ecuador 16.7 29.9 53.4 Yemen, Rep of 95.9 1 8 2.3 El Salvador 38.9 34.4 26.7 Guatemala 40.3 30.1 29.6 Sub-Saharan Africa j 47.5 11.2 41.4 Jamaica 25 9 24.4 49.7 Angola 22 4 9.9 676 Mexico 0 8 44.5 54 7 Botswana 64.2 10 2 25 6 Nicaragua 53.6 22.2 24 2 C6te d'lvoire 39.1 46 6 14.3 Panama 5 6 45.1 49.3 Cameroon 54.6 11.0 34 4 Paraguay 34.4 44 0 21.7 Ethiopia 90 3 0 2 9.5 Peru 16.3 58 4 25.3 Gabon 39.6 9 5 50 9 Trinidad and Tobago 0.6 39.2 60 3 Ghana 82.2 4 6 13 2 Uruguay 3.5 51 0 45.5 Kenya 76.4 5 9 17 7 Venezuela, R. B de 0.2 60 3 39 5 Madagascar 66 9 5 0 28 1 Nigeria 4.4 6 0 89 6 Europe and Central Senegal 86.8 9 S 3 7 Asia 5.9 34.8 59.3 South Africa 0.0 20 2 79 8 Armenia 71.7 18 0 10 3 Sudan 50.0 17.9 32 2 Azerbaijan 50.4 23 4 26.3 Zambia 79 3 6 1 14 7 Belarus 12.0 59.6 28 3 Zimbabwe 46.5 21 2 32 4 Note- Nonconcessional debt data are available only for countries which report to the World Bank's Debtor Reporting System For aggregate figures, missing values are assumed to have the same average value as the available data. Source. World Bank data, see Technical Notes 210 G LO BA L EC ONO MI C IND I CATO RS Figure A3.9a Structure of long-term debt, by group, 2000 (percent) 80 = 1 ~Cncs;ional = 80- 60 40 20 Severely Moderately Severely Moderately Other indebted indebted indebted indebted countries low-income low-income middle-income middle-income countries countries countries countries Source: World Banik data. Figure A3.9b Structure of long-term debt, by region, 2000 (percent) 100 80 o co+l ssion ilH 60 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~- Variable me t 80 60 Sub-Saharan East Asia South Asia Latin Europe Middle Africa and Pacific America and and Central East and the Caribbean Asia North Africa Source: World Banik data. Figure A3.9c Top ten ratios of nonconcessional debt to GDP, 2000 (percent) 140 120 - 100- 80- 40 - Source: World Bank data. 211 G LO BAL EC ONO MI C PRO SP ECTS 2 0 03 Table A3.10 Long-term net resource flows to developing countries, 2000 (millions of dollars) Pnvate Official Total Percent D)ebt flo ss '"ilhson $ COP Trial (net) FDI Portfolio Total ODA Other All developing countries 261,133 4.3 225,846 8,288 166,691 50,867 35,287 38,088 -2,801 Asia 87,822 4.0 74,947 -14,686 55,223 34,411 12,874 10,918 1,956 East Asia 74.556 4.7 65,693 -18,721 52,130 32,285 8,863 6,649 2,214 China 60,525 5 6 58,295 -2.30)2 38.399 22,198 2,230 992 1,238 Indonesia -9,156 -6 0 -11.210 -7.039 -4.5S0 379 2,053 1,173 881 Korea, Rep of 13,875 3 0 13,215 -3,852 9,283 7,784 660 -73 733 Malaysia 3.411 3 8 3,229 1,027 1,660 542 182 52 131 Myanmar 244 . 188 -66 255 0 55 55 0 Papua New Guinea 335 9 6 128 -50 130 48 207 118 90 Philippines 2,401 3.2 2,459 140 2,029 290 -57 528 -585 Thailand -525 -0 4 -1,383 -5.793 3.366 1,044 858 1,129 -271 Vietnam 1,790 5 7 581 -717 1,298 0 1,209 1,195 14 South Asia 13,265 2.2 9,254 4,035 3,093 2,126 4,011 4,269 -258 Bangladesh 1,207 2 6 269 - 14 280 3 938 931 7 India 9,928 2 2 8.771 4,340 2.315 2,117 1,157 1,463 -306 Nepal 237 4 3 -4 -8 4 0 240 240 0 Pakistan 526 0 9 -53 -361 308 0 578 580 1 Sri Lanka 530 3 3 262 83 173 6 268 239 28 Latin America 99,315 4.9 97,304 12.839 75,088 9,378 2,010 3,245 -1,235 Argnina 16,719 5 9 16,620 4,504 11,665 450 100 -222 321 Boia 1,230 14.8 923 190 733 0 307 341 -34 Brazil 43,934 7 4 45,672 7,877 32,779 5.016 -1,738 340 -2,078 Chile 4,733 6 7 4,834 1, 141 3,675 1 8 -101 0 -101 Colomhia 3,312 4 0 3,130 728 2.376 26 182 119 63 Costa Rica S73 3 6 610 201 409 0 -36 -31 -6 Dominican Repuhlic 1,103 5 6 1,142 115 953 74 -40 -22 -17 Ecuador 1,172 8 6 904 194 710 0 268 98 170 El Salvador 467 3 5 338 153 185 0 129 56 73 Guatemala 415 2 2 178 -52 230 0 238 173 65 Jamaira 972 12 6 898 442 456 0 74 -8 81 Mexico 11,035 1 9 11,536 -5.267 13,286 3,517 -502 -80 -422 Nicaragua 797 38 5 395 141 254 0 401 429 -28 Panama 946 9 4 947 344 603 0 -1 -15 14 Paraguay 99 1 3 -16 -98 82 0 115 12 103 Peru 2,291 4 3 1,553 668 680 205 738 613 125 Trinidad and Tohago 633 8 2 673 23 650 0 -40 0 -39 Uruguay 719 3 6 574 276 298 0 145 -8 152 Venezuela, R B de 5,708 4 7 5,454 919 4.464 71 254 57 197 Europe and Central Asia 54,000 5 8 45,446 11,560 28,49S 5,391 8,553 8,138 416 Armenia 270 14 1 159 19 140 0 III 119 -8 Azerhaijan 305 5 8 175 45 130 0 130 168 -38 Belarus 125 1 2 122 32 90 0 3 26 -23 Bulgaria 1,363 11 4 1.114 107 1,002 5 249 337 -87 Czech Repuhlic 3,441 6 8 3,299 - 1,901 4,583 617 142 154 -12 Estonia 514 10 3 485 126 387 -29 29 48 -19 Georgia 207 6 8 155 24 131 0 52 64 -12 Hun ary 1,643 3 6 1,721 29 1,692 0 -78 11 -89 Kazai hstan 1,979 10 8 1,900 650 1,250 0 80 111 -31 Kyrgyz Republic 112 8 2 -65 -62 -2 0 177 178 -1 Latvia 669 9 4 581 176 407 0 86 50 36 Lithuania 910 8 0 799 269 379 151 til 63 48 Moldova 269 20 9 209 81 128 0 60 62 -2 Poland 13,413 8.5 13,19.5 2,982 9,342 871 218 470 -251 Romania 2,606 7 1 1,900 875 1.025 0 706 177 529 Russiani Federation 2,508 1 0 2,200 -1.589 2,714 1,075 308 661 -354 Slovak Republic 2.234 11 7 2,185 133 2,052 0 49 51 -3 Tajikistan 134 135S 64 40 24 0 70 70 0 Turkmenlistan . Turkey 1 2,21i7 6.1 11,416 7,733 982 2,701 801 37 763 Ukraine 169 0 5 927 332 595 0 -759 -785 26 Uzbekistan 303 2.2 18 -82 100 0 284 261 24 Middle East and N. Africa 1,470 0.2 1,074 -931 1,209 795 396 3,223 -2,827 Algeria -1,678 -3 1 -1,212 -1,226 10 4 -465 -81 -384 Egypt, Arab Rep of 2,312 2 3 1,967 114 1,235 619 345 541 -196 Iran ,Islamic Rep of -2,253 -2 2 -610 -649 39 0 -1,643 -11 -1,632 Jordan 807 9 6 455 -115 558 12 352 369 -17 Morocco -460 -1 4 -293 -449 10 147 -167 96 -263 Oman 69 0 5 57 23 23 11 12 21 -9 Syrian Arab Rep 68 2.1 107 -4 ill 0 -40 -14 -26 Tu.nisa 1,009 5 2 966 214 752 0 44 190 -146 Yemen, Rep of -12 -0 1 -201 0 -201 0 189 210 -21 212 G LOB AL EC ONO MI C IND I CATO RS Table A3.10 Long-term net resource flows to developing countries, 2000 (continued) (millions of dollars) Private Official Total IPcrcent Debt flowvs iMillions S GDP Total (net) FDI Portfolio Total ODA Other Sub-Saharan Africa 18,527 5.7 7,074 -494 6,676 893 11,453 12,563 -1,110 Angola 1,407 15.9 1,206 -492 1,698 0 201 230 -29 Borswana 11 0.2 27 -3 30 0 -16 10 -26 Cte d'lvoire 56 0.5 -47 -159 106 6 103 237 -134 Camiieroon 185 2.1 -21 -52 31 0 205 292 -87 Ethiopia 587 9.2 42 -8 50 0 545 565 -20 Gaboni -24 -0.5 142 -8 150 0 -166 9 -175 Ghania 483 9.7 71 -57 110 17 412 442 -29 Kenya 374 3.6 53 -61 111 4 32-1 403 -82 Madagascar 298 7.7 83 0 83 0 215 219 -3 Nigeria 706 1.7 907 -177 1,082 2 -201 113 -314 Senegal 349 8.0 106 -2 107 0 243 276 -33 Souta Africa 2,957 2.3 2,736 911 961 864 221 219 3 Sudan 563 5.0 392 0 392 0 171 173 -2 Zambia 778 24.0 191 -9 200 0 587 620 -33 Zimbabwe 108 1.5 29 -50 79 1 79 145 -66 FDI is foreign direct investment; ODA is official developmenit assistance. Souirce: World Bank data; see Techniical Notes. Figure A3.10a Distribution of long-term net resource flows, 2000 (percent) 100 ' 60- 40- 20 Sub-Saharan East Asia South Asia Latin Europe Middle East Africa and Pacific America and and Central and North the Caribbean Asia Africa Souirce: World Bank data. Figure A3.10b Change in share of private long-term flows, 1990-2000 (percent) 80 60 40__ O2-0~ - P P r- Sub-Saharan East Asia South Asia Latin Europe Middle East Africa and Pacitic America and and Central and North the Caribbean Asia Africa Sotirce: World Bank data. 21.3 Technical Notes The principal sources for the data in this ap- millions of current U.S. dollars, while growth pendix are the World Bank's central databases rates are based on constant price data, which and several International Monetary Fund are derived from current values deflated by databases, combined with data sourced from relevant price indices or unit value measures. the OECD and from Oxford Economics Inc. Effective market growth (EMG) in table A.3.5 (OEF), covering the industrial and other high- is the export-weighted growth of each coun- income economies. The cut-off date for data try's trading partner imports. updates'was November 15, 2002. Data revi- Tables A3.7 and A3.8. The IMF's Direc- sions and new releases since that time have not tion of Trade database serves as the underly- been incorporated in the tables. Regional ag- ing source for the bilateral trade share- and gregates are based on the classification of growth information highlighted in these tables. economies by income group and by region, fol- Growth rates are compound annual averages, lowing the Bank's standard definitions (see and are computed from current U.S. dollar country classification tables that follow). measures of trade flows. Debt and finance data (appendix ta- Table A3.9. Long-term debt covers public bles A3.9 and A3.10) cover the 137 countries and publicly guaranteed debt but excludes that report to the World Bank's Debtor Re- IMF credits. Concessional debt is that with an porting System (DRS), supplemented by data original grant element of 25 percent or more. for non-DRS countries, for which commercial Nonconcessional variable interest-rate debt market information has been utilized. Small includes all public and publicly guaranteed countries have generally been omitted from the long-term debt with an original grant element tables, but are included in the regional totals. of less-than 25 percent, whose terms depend Current price data are reported in U.S. dollars. on movements in a key market interest rate. This item conveys information about the bor- Notes on tables rower's exposure to changes in international Tables A3.1 through A3.4. Historic data interest rates. sourced from the databases noted above, while Table A3.10. Long-term net resource projections are consistent with those high- flows are the sum of net resource flows on lighted in chapter 1 and appendix 1. long-term debt (excluding IMF) plus non-debt- Tables A3.5 and A3.6. Merchandise trade creating flows. Foreign direct investment refers data is sourced from combined IMF, World to net inflows of investment from abroad. Bank, OECD, and'OEF sources. Merchandise Portfolio equity flows are the sum of country exports and imports exclude trade in services. funds, depository receipts and direct purchases Imports are reported on a cost-insurance-and- of shares by foreign investors. freight basis. Trade values are expressed in 214