Policy Research Working Paper 11037 Fiscal Policy Procyclicality and Volatility in Commodity-Exporting Emerging and Developing Economies Determinants and Implications for Growth Francisco Arroyo Marioli Garima Vasishtha Development Economics Prospects Group January 2025 Policy Research Working Paper 11037 Abstract Over the past few decades, fiscal policy has been about 30 restrictions on cross-border financial flows, and the use of percent more procyclical and about 40 percent more volatile fiscal rules, commodity-exporting EMDEs can increase in commodity-exporting emerging markets and devel- their gross domestic product per capita growth by about oping economies (EMDEs) than in other EMDEs. Both 1 percentage point every four to five years through the procyclicality and volatility of fiscal policy—which share reduction in fiscal policy volatility. Such policies should be some underlying drivers—hurt economic growth because supported by sustainable, well-designed, and stability-ori- they amplify business cycles. Structural policies, including ented fiscal institutions that can help build buffers during exchange rate flexibility and the easing of restrictions on commodity price booms to prepare for any subsequent international financial transactions, can help reduce both slump in prices. A strong commitment to fiscal discipline fiscal procyclicality and fiscal volatility. By adopting aver- is critical for these institutions to be effective in achieving age advanced economy policies on exchange rate regimes, their objectives. This paper is a product of the Prospects Group, Development Economics. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://www.worldbank.org/prwp. The authors may be contacted at farroyomarioli@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Fiscal Policy Procyclicality and Volatility in Commodity-Exporting Emerging and Developing Economies: Determinants and Implications for Growth 1* Francisco Arroyo Marioli and Garima Vasishtha Keywords: commodity exporters; emerging markets; fiscal policy; fiscal volatility; fiscal procyclicality; growth; institutions JEL Classification : E62; F41; F44; H30; H50 1 This paper was written within Prospects Group as part of the January 2024 Global Economic Prospects report. TTL: Garima Vasishtha. * Arroyo Marioli: World Bank, Prospects Group; farroyomarioli@worldbank.org. Vasishtha: World Bank, Prospects Group; gvasishtha@worldbank.org. The authors would like to thank Antonio Fatás, Ayhan Kose, Carlos Arteta, Carlos Végh, Franziska Ohnsorge, Graham Hacche, James Rowe, Jongrim Ha, Lawrence Schembri, Mirco Balatti, Timothy Lane, Valerie Mercer Blackman, and participants in various seminars for their helpful comments. Franco Diaz Laura and Muneeb Ahmad Naseem provided excellent research assistance. The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. I. Introduction Commodity-exporting emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs) face significant fiscal challenges: Government debt in these countries has grown rapidly over the past decade—from about 33 percent of GDP in 2010 to about 60.9 percent in 202, on average. Over the same period, their primary fiscal deficit (which does not include interest payments) averaged about three times that of commodity importers. Increased spending during the pandemic amplified the challenges confronting commodity- exporting EMDEs. The higher cost of servicing elevated debt levels, coupled with weaker growth prospects, is increasing the risk of debt distress among some of these economies (World Bank 2023). Along with the wide swings in commodity prices in recent years, these developments have brought to the fore the complex task of formulating fiscal policy in these economies (Figure 1.A). The main challenge faced by policy makers in commodity-exporting countries is coping with the swings in commodity prices. Commodities are important sources of export and fiscal revenues for almost two-thirds of EMDEs, including three-fourths of low-income countries (LICs) (Figures 1.B and 1.C; World Bank 2022). Shocks to commodity prices are often large and persistent. Commodity prices have undergone frequent cycles over the past five decades, with the average cycle lasting almost six years (Figure 1.D). Price slumps, on average, lasted somewhat longer (39 months) than booms (30 months), with prices falling and rising by 1 to 4 percent per month over the course of the average cycle, respectively (World Bank 2022). Commodity dependence makes it harder for policy makers to formulate appropriate fiscal responses to commodity price fluctuations. Fiscal policy tends to be more procyclical—that is, expansionary in good times and contractionary in bad times—in commodity-exporting EMDEs than in other EMDEs. 2 In commodity-exporting EMDEs, rising commodity prices can lead to procyclical increases in public spending and tax cuts. Conversely, declines in commodity prices can trigger procyclical tax increases and cuts in public expenditures as a result of reduced revenues from commodity production and exports. Moreover, because tax cuts and increases in public spending are generally easier to implement and more difficult to reverse, politically, than tax increases and reductions in public spending, government deficits and debt positions tend to ratchet up, deteriorating from cycle to cycle. This secular deterioration, in turn, will make it more difficult to implement countercyclical fiscal policy in bad times. In sum, the procyclical tendency of fiscal policy in commodity exporters can magnify the impact of commodity price movements on economic activity, lead to inefficient stops-and-starts in government investment and in the provision of government services, and introduce a bias toward a deterioration in fiscal positions. Fiscal policy also tends to be more volatile in commodity-exporting EMDEs than in other EMDEs. Swings in commodity prices often result in highly volatile commodity-related fiscal revenues in these countries, leading to more volatile business cycles, which historically move in tandem with commodity price cycles. 3 Over the past three decades, output volatility in commodity-exporting EMDEs was more than double that in commodity-importing ones. Revenues derived from the commodity sector are also prone to policies associated with rent-seeking behavior. In addition, fiscal policy volatility can act as a transmission mechanism for the “resource curse”—the term coined to describe how commodity abundance, if not 2 See Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh (2004) and Talvi and Végh (2005) for early contributions to empirical research on the procyclicality of fiscal policy. More recent contributions include Carneiro and Garrido (2016), Frankel, Végh, and Vuletin (2013), and Richaud et al. (2019), as well as studies documenting evidence for select groups of commodity-exporting countries, including Bova, Medas, and Poghosyan (2016) and Céspedes and Velasco (2014). 3 See IMF (2015a); Jacks, O’Rourke, and Williamson (2011); Richaud et al. (2019); and World Bank (2009, 2020, and 2022). 2 managed properly, can damage overall growth. 4 Moreover, country-specific evidence suggests that large swings in commodity prices can be socially harmful, as shown in such indicators as poverty indices, highlighting the need for policies that mitigate the adverse effects of such price shocks (Álvarez, García- Marin, and Ilabaca 2021; Estrades and Terra 2012). In the years ahead, the challenges associated with volatile and procyclical fiscal policies are likely to be compounded by sharp fluctuations in commodity prices as the impact of climate change on commodity markets becomes more pronounced. 5 The continuation of procyclical and volatile fiscal policies would be detrimental to growth and impede progress in achieving climate and other broader development goals. As the experience of recent decades shows, governments have difficulties in establishing macroeconomic policy frameworks that are effective in helping maintain steady growth in the face of commodity price swings (IMF 2015b; UNCTAD 2021; World Bank 2022). Against this backdrop, this paper addresses three questions: First, how different has fiscal policy been, in terms of its cyclicality and volatility, in commodity-exporting EMDEs relative to other EMDEs? Second, how have fiscal procyclicality and volatility affected economic growth in commodity-exporting EMDEs? And third, which policy interventions can help improve the quality of fiscal policy by reducing procyclicality and volatility? This paper makes several contributions to the literature on fiscal policy in commodity exporters. It is the first study to examine the implications of fiscal policy procyclicality and volatility together. The empirical literature treats the concepts of fiscal cyclicality and volatility as distinct. While closely following the literature in terms of the methodology for analyzing the two concepts, this paper goes beyond the literature in examining the linkages between cyclicality and volatility. Second, it provides comprehensive evidence on fiscal procyclicality and volatility for a larger sample of commodity exporters (agricultural, metals, and energy exporters) and commodity importers than previously examined. It also documents how fiscal policy challenges have manifested themselves in different EMDE regions; previous studies have covered either a geographically limited set of countries or mainly oil exporters. Third, it deepens the understanding of the implications of fiscal procyclicality and volatility for economic growth. To do so, it quantifies how procyclical fiscal policy responses have amplified business cycles in commodity-exporting EMDEs during periods of elevated commodity prices, taking a close look at the 2003–08 commodity price boom. It also quantifies the impact of higher output volatility on economic growth. Fourth, it presents a large menu of policies to reduce fiscal policy procyclicality and volatility. In addition, it illustrates the use of sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) and fiscal rules in coping with fiscal procyclicality and volatility by examining the experiences of a set of commodity-exporting countries. Insights from these cases complement the findings of the broader quantitative analysis and help identify best practices in the implementation of these fiscal frameworks and institutions. Our paper offers five main findings. First, fiscal policy has tended to be both more procyclical and more volatile in EMDEs than in advanced economies, and more so in EMDE commodity exporters than commodity importers. The average correlation between the cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending—our measure of fiscal cyclicality—is 0.40 for EMDEs and near zero for advanced 4 On the detrimental effects of fiscal policy volatility on growth see, for example, Afonso and Furceri (2008); Fatás and Mihov (2003, 2007, and 2013); and Medina (2010). On the “resource curse,” see Bleaney and Halland (2009) and Sachs and Warner (1995) for detailed discussions. 5 Climate change has significant implications for commodity markets as it implies severe alterations in weather patterns, affecting climate-sensitive industries such as agriculture and fishing. Droughts can reduce harvests, while floods can affect both harvests and transportation. Policies that address climate change can also generate gains for other commodities, such as metals that are used heavily in low-carbon technologies. 3 economies. Within EMDEs, the correlation is 0.46 for commodity exporters and 0.36 for commodity importers. Fiscal policy volatility, measured by the volatility of real government expenditure, is about 40 percent higher in EMDE commodity exporters than in other EMDEs. Moreover, among EMDEs, the larger the commodity sector, the more volatile fiscal policy has tended to be. Both fiscal procyclicality and volatility have generally trended downward in EMDEs in recent decades. However, procyclicality has fallen less among commodity-exporting EMDEs than in other EMDEs. Fiscal volatility has declined by nearly half in EMDEs over the past three decades, but it remains much higher among commodity exporters than in other EMDEs. Second, fiscal procyclicality has amplified the business cycle in commodity-exporting EMDEs. Because of its procyclical nature, fiscal policy in the average EMDE commodity exporter has increased the impact of commodity price shocks on output by more than one-fifth, relative to the counterfactual in which fiscal policy does not respond to the price shock. In contrast, fiscal policy in advanced-economy commodity exporters has, on average, offset the output effect of a commodity price shock by reacting countercyclically. When hit by a commodity price shock of the same magnitude, the change in output in the average commodity-exporting EMDE has tended to be more than three times larger than that in its average advanced-economy counterpart, because of the opposite responses of fiscal policy in the two country groups. Third, fiscal policy volatility has often amplified the business cycle and reduced growth. Results from a counterfactual exercise show that if the average commodity-exporting EMDE were to adopt the policies of an average advanced economy in three areas—exchange rates, capital flow restrictions, and the use of fiscal rules—it could have added about 1 percentage point in per capita growth every four to five years by reducing fiscal policy volatility. Fourth, procyclicality and volatility have been strongly interlinked in EMDEs, especially commodity exporters, and driven by similar factors. EMDEs with more procyclical fiscal policies have tended also to display more volatile fiscal policies. Procyclical fiscal policy amplifies the business cycle, which in turn exacerbates the volatility of output. That is, given a shock to output, a procyclical fiscal response further exacerbates the business cycle. Hence, the initial shock to output has larger overall economic impacts when there also is procyclicality, thereby amplifying volatility. Finally, structural policies can help reduce fiscal procyclicality and volatility. In particular, more stable governments, a stronger rule of law, greater capital account openness, fiscal rules to constrain government spending, and SWFs have all been associated with lower fiscal procyclicality. Fiscal rules and SWFs, essentially state-owned investment companies, have been most effective when surrounded by robust institutional frameworks. Stronger institutions and stricter constraints on fiscal policy have also been associated with less fiscal volatility. Specifically, the presence of fiscal rules, less constraints on international financial transactions, and flexible exchange rates are all associated with lower fiscal policy volatility. Medium-term expenditure frameworks can also help lower the procyclicality and volatility of fiscal policies by improving fiscal discipline. II. Fiscal policy procyclicality Because the concept of fiscal policy cyclicality is important to guiding actual policy, it is critical to define policy cyclicality in terms of policy instruments (such as government expenditure) rather than outcomes (such as, the fiscal balance). This paper follows the literature and measures fiscal cyclicality as the correlation between annual percentage changes in real (primary) government expenditure and real GDP: 4 a positive correlation indicates procyclicality, while a negative correlation indicates countercyclicality. 6 These correlations are calculated for 182 countries using annual data for 1980-2020. Economies are placed into two groups—“commodity exporters” and “commodity importers”—by applying the classification criteria used in World Bank (2022). An economy is classified as a commodity exporter if, on average in 2017–19, either its combined exports of all commodities accounted for 30 percent or more of its total exports or its exports of any single commodity accounted for 20 percent or more of its total exports. Economies are excluded if they reached either threshold only because of re- exports (imports that were exported without being changed). Based on these criteria, 92 economies are classified as commodity exporters of which 87 are EMDEs and five are advanced economies. Commodity importers are economies not classified as commodity exporters (Table 1). The panel is unbalanced due to lack of data for some countries for the whole sample period. II.1 Basic features of procyclicality The analysis of correlations produces four stylized facts. First, in the period 1980-2020, fiscal policy in EMDEs has been procyclical while that in advanced economies has been acyclical (Figure 2.A). The correlation between the cyclical components (derived using the Hodrick-Prescott filter) of real government expenditure and real GDP for EMDEs is 0.40, while that for advanced economies is slightly negative. Second, although fiscal policy in both commodity exporters and commodity importers has been procyclical among all EMDEs in the sample, commodity exporters are 30 percent more procyclical than commodity importers on average (Figure 2.B). The correlation between the cyclical components of real government spending and real GDP for commodity exporters is 0.46 compared with 0.36 for commodity importers, with both coefficients as well as the difference between them being statistically significant. Commodity exporters tended to have more procyclical fiscal policy than commodity importers regardless of their major commodity export—agricultural products, metals, or energy. This procyclical behavior has been widespread across all EMDE regions (Figure 2.C). Third, the degree and nature of fiscal procyclicality have varied across country income groups. Fiscal procyclicality in LICs and countries in fragile and conflict-affected situations (FCS) was higher than in lower- and upper-middle income countries, while in high-income countries fiscal policy was countercyclical (Figure 2.D). Fourth. fiscal procyclicality has declined over the past four decades. To examine the evolution of fiscal procyclicality, the sample is split into two subperiods: before and after 2006. This division reflects the observed increase in the willingness and ability of countries to pursue countercyclical fiscal policies following the 2007–09 global financial crisis (Alvarez and De Gregorio 2014; Végh and Vuletin 2014). Fiscal procyclicality in commodity exporters has been falling over the past decade-and-a-half. Nevertheless, procyclicality in commodity exporters still prevails and has fallen much less than in commodity-importing countries (which are, on average, acyclical since 2006) (Figure 2.E). The fraction of countries running procyclical fiscal policies has declined over the past few decades. This decline was more pronounced for commodity importers (from 33 percent in the mid-1990s to 24 percent in 2021) compared with commodity exporters (from 40 percent in the mid-1990s to 36 percent in 2021) (Figure 2.F). II.2 Determinants of fiscal procyclicality To assess how fiscal cyclicality has varied with macroeconomic and institutional features of countries, this section first compares fiscal cyclicality across different groups of EMDEs. It then presents a cross-country 6 For details about this measure, see Frankel, Végh, and Vuletin (2013) and Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh (2004). The analysis here uses the Hodrick-Prescott filter to detrend the time series. The results are robust to the use of alternative filters, such as the Baxter-King filter. Results are also robust to the use of nonparametric filters, as documented by Carneiro and Garrido (2016) and Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh (2004). 5 regression analysis to disentangle the roles of key factors in driving procyclicality. The country groupings are based on certain macroeconomic characteristics, including the degree of capital account openness, the exchange rate regime, and the level of external debt. In addition to these macroeconomic characteristics, the degree of fiscal procyclicality can depend on political economy considerations and institutional features. The choice of variables used to proxy for these features is guided by the literature on fiscal procyclicality. Restrictions on international financial transactions. Countries with more restrictions on the capital account tend to have more limited access to international financial markets, which makes the cost of borrowing more expensive. This may increase the procyclicality of fiscal policy by making the government’s access to funds particularly limited during recessions, forcing government expenditures to shrink, thus amplifying the economic downturn and the cycle. 7 And the data indeed show that fiscal policy in commodity-exporting countries with more capital account restrictions has tended to be more procyclical than in those with fewer restrictions (Figure 3.A).8 On average, the correlation between cyclical components of real government spending and real GDP for countries with more capital controls is 0.51 compared with 0.33 for countries with fewer capital controls, and the difference between the correlations is statistically significant. Exchange rate regime. Flexible exchange rates are often associated with greater fiscal discipline because of the immediacy of the repercussions of imprudent fiscal policies (Tornell and Velasco 2000). It is likely, then, that the degree of fiscal procyclicality is higher in countries with fixed exchange rate regimes. Indeed, the correlation between the cyclical components of government spending and GDP is higher (0.46) under fixed exchange rate regimes than under flexible exchange rates (0.36), although the difference between the two is not statistically significant (Figure 3.B). External debt. Fiscal cyclicality is found not to have varied significantly with the level of external debt over the sample period. The correlation between cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending is essentially the same for countries with low and high external debt. 9 Political economy factors. Extensive research has documented the role of political economy variables in driving fiscal procyclicality. Political pressures in good times tend to prompt policy makers to reduce primary surpluses, by reducing taxes or increasing spending. Given that more volatile primary surpluses offer more chances of fiscal appropriation, the more volatile output and therefore the tax base are, the more procyclical will fiscal policy tend to be (Talvi and Vegh 2005). The dispersion of political power—the so-called voracity effect, in which various fiscal claimants (including government ministries, provinces, and unions) attempt to appropriate resources in good times without considering the effects of their actions on other claimants—is another channel through which political 7 For details of this argument, see Kose et al. (2010). This result is in line with insights from real business cycle models, where a steeper upward-sloping supply of funds (which makes borrowing from the rest of the world more costly) implies a more procyclical fiscal policy, as exemplified in Fernandez et al. (2021). 8 The results shown in figures 4.3 and 4.4 are broadly similar when an alternative threshold (the lower and upper one-third of observations) is used to classify countries into “low” and “high” groups for capital account openness, political risk, control of corruption, and law and order. 9 The degree of fiscal procyclicality can also potentially vary with the stance of the business cycle. In some countries, the lack of access to international credit markets during recessions introduces an asymmetry in their fiscal policy reaction in bad times versus good times. This could also be because the size of fiscal multipliers has been found to depend on the stance of the business cycle, with multipliers in bad times being larger than those in good times (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012, 2013). This notion, however, is not supported by a comparison of procyclicality in expansions and recessions over the sample period under consideration. The difference in the measure of fiscal procyclicality in expansions (0.29) and recessions (0.23) is not statistically significant. 6 economy factors can affect fiscal procyclicality (Tornell and Lane 1999). As the intensity of such fiscal competition increases in good times, the rise in government spending could be greater than the windfall gains in revenues, resulting in procyclical fiscal expansion. The more claimants there are (that is, the more dispersed the power), the higher government spending may tend to be in good times. Quality of institutions. The quality of institutions plays an important role in the ability of countries to conduct countercyclical fiscal policy.10 Indeed, institutional factors, such as law and order, have been found to play a larger role than financial variables, such as financial openness and domestic credit to the private sector, in explaining differences in fiscal cyclicality between advanced and developing economies (Calderón and Schmidt-Hebbel 2008). Government stability and law and order can help reduce fiscal procyclicality by shrinking government discretion and extending the horizon of policy decision-making. To analyze the linkages between fiscal cyclicality and institutional quality, five country-specific indicators of institutional quality from the PRS Group database are used: political risk, quality of bureaucracy, control of corruption, government stability, and law and order (Table 2.A). The association between procyclicality and the presence of fiscal rules is also examined here because these rules are a significant part of the fiscal institutions in many commodity-exporting countries. The results indicate that in commodity exporters that rank higher on political risk, fiscal policies have tended to be more procyclical, with a correlation of 0.49 between the cyclical component of real GDP and real government spending, compared with a correlation of 0.28 for countries with lower political risk. The difference between the average correlations for the two country groups is statistically significant (Figure 4.A). Part of the explanation could be that governments in countries with higher political risk may be more focused on short-term outcomes to stay in power. Likewise, commodity-exporting countries with lower-quality bureaucracy have often implemented more procyclical fiscal policies than those with higher-quality bureaucracies, although the difference between the two country groups is not statistically significant (Figure 4.B). Better bureaucracy may be expected to allow for better, rules-based, policy management and to limit unproductive discretionary spending. Commodity exporters with better control of corruption have demonstrated lower fiscal procyclicality than those with weaker corruption control, and the difference between the procyclicality measures for the two country groups is statistically significant (Figure 4.C). Weaker control of corruption makes it easier to capture rents. Likewise, countries with more government stability have tended to demonstrate less fiscal procyclicality than those with less government stability—although the difference in cyclicality measures is not statistically significant (Figure 4.D). A more stable government allows for the formulation of fiscal policy with a longer horizon, weakening the incentive for procyclical policy. Better law and order has been associated with less procyclical fiscal policy (Figure 4.E). The difference between the procyclicality measures for countries ranked lower in the law-and-order index and countries ranked higher is statistically significant. Many commodity exporters have enacted fiscal rules, often in conjunction with stabilization funds—which essentially put aside revenue in good times that can be tapped in bad times. Fiscal rules may signal the intent of the government to dampen, if not eliminate, fiscal procyclicality as well as to safeguard long- term fiscal sustainability. Over the past 40 years, the presence of fiscal rules has been associated with lower procyclicality across the full sample of countries, although results are less clear for commodity exporters (Figure 4.F). Increased use of fiscal rules has not shielded EMDEs or commodity exporters from fiscal procyclicality, as evidenced by the continued procyclicality of fiscal policies in these countries after 10See, for example, Calderón, Duncan, and Schmidt‐Hebbel (2016); Carneiro and Garrido (2016); Céspedes and Velasco (2014); Frankel, Végh, and Vuletin (2013); and Jalles et al. (2023). 7 they adopted such rules. Nevertheless, there is evidence that some features of a second generation of fiscal rules—such as the use of cyclically adjusted targets and well-defined escape clauses, combined with strong legal and enforcement arrangements—have been associated with reduced procyclicality (Bova, Carcenac, and Guerguil 2014). The country cases examined in Section VI suggest that fiscal rules or SWFs are most effective in achieving their stated objectives when they are well-designed, closely linked to broader policy objectives, and supported by strong institutions and political commitment. Armed with the insights from the correlates of fiscal procyclicality established above, the remainder of this section uses cross-country regressions to identify the main drivers of fiscal procyclicality in commodity exporters. 11 The dependent variable is the correlation between the annual percentage changes of real government spending and real GDP. The explanatory variables are intended to capture the four explanations for the existence of procyclical fiscal policy described above: capital account openness (measured by an index of financial openness); political economy factors (measured by an index of political constraints, which reflects the extent to which policy changes are inhibited by institutional and political factors); macroeconomic stability (measured by the standard deviation of output); and institutional quality (measured by an index of control of corruption). The coefficients of each of these four variables are statistically significant and three of the four have the expected sign (Table 3). More open capital accounts and better control of corruption are estimated to have helped reduce fiscal procyclicality while greater output volatility has been associated with higher procyclicality. However, the coefficient of the political constraints index does not have the expected sign, suggesting either that the “voracity effect” did not hold or that the political constraints index fails to capture it. The variables are jointly significant when combined and explain about 18 percent of procyclical behavior across countries. 12 Robustness checks: In line with Lane (2003), GDP per capita, size of the public sector relative to GDP, and openness (sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP) are used as controls in the regression, one at a time. GDP per capita is significant at the 5 percent level but the two other control variables are not significant. In all three cases, the F-test for the joint significance of the four relevant explanatory variables is significantly different from zero at least at the 10 percent level. Cross-country regressions are also used to analyze the role of institutional variables in driving fiscal cyclicality, as highlighted by the correlations reported in the previous section. The roles of SWFs and fiscal rules are also explored. To capture SWFs, a dummy variable is included that takes the value of 1 if a country has an SWF, and 0 otherwise. SWFs can play an important role in reducing procyclicality by promoting the accumulation of government savings during commodity price booms, to be drawn down to some extent during price slumps (Asik 2017). The results show that greater government stability, better law and order, and the presence of SWFs and fiscal rules have all tended to reduce fiscal procyclicality (Table 4).13 Overall, the analysis therefore provides empirical evidence that better institutions are 11 For an empirical analysis of the drivers of fiscal procyclicality in OECD countries, see Lane (2003). For an analysis of the role of financial and institutional variables, see Calderón and Schmidt-Hebbel (2008) and Calderón, Duncan, and Schmidt-Hebbel (2010). Ilzetzki (2011) provides a novel political economy explanation based on successive governments disagreeing on the desired distribution of public spending and examines different theories of procyclicality by running numerical simulations in calibrated models. 12 In line with Lane (2003), and to check the robustness of our results, GDP per capita, size of the public sector relative to GDP, and openness (the sum of exports and imports as a share of GDP) were added as controls, one at a time. While GDP per capita was significant at the 5 percent level, the two other control variables were not. In all three cases, the F-test for the joint significance of the three relevant explanatory variables was significantly different from zero at least at the 10 percent level. 13 Although fiscal rules may reduce procyclicality, the existence of fiscal procyclicality may prompt policy makers to adopt fiscal rules. To account for this potential endogeneity, instrumental variable estimation (two-stage least squares) is used with bureaucracy quality (from the PRS database) as an instrument. 8 associated with lower fiscal procyclicality. These results are also corroborated by the country case studies (Section VI), which show that SWFs and fiscal rules are most effective in meeting their goals when supported by strong institutions. III. The effects of fiscal policy on output growth Procyclical fiscal policy amplifies the effect on output of a shock to economic activity—that is, “when it rains, it pours,” using the analogy of Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh (2004). Such shocks could originate from various sources—from the financial sector or from supply or demand shocks associated with external or domestic developments. 14 This section examines how increases in commodity prices have affected the behavior of fiscal policy and, in turn, output growth. Following Arroyo Marioli and Végh (2023), the total impact of the changes in commodity prices on output can be decomposed into two components. First, the “rains” component: in response to an increase in commodity prices, production rises in the commodity sector and other related sectors, and the associated increases in income generate further increases in private spending and output. The increases in output and spending, in turn, boost fiscal revenue, reducing the primary fiscal deficit. The second component depends on the response of fiscal policy. If the reduction in the fiscal deficit is conserved, fiscal policy will play a countercyclical role, dampening the increase in demand and activity. But if the reduction in the fiscal deficit leads the government to increase spending or lower taxes, fiscal policy will increase the effect of the shock on output. There will then be a “pours” component, with procyclical fiscal policy amplifying the business cycle. III.1 Methodology To estimate the effect of fiscal policy on output, the analysis proceeds in four steps. First, to quantify the effects of changes in commodity prices on output, panel regressions are used to obtain the response of real GDP to changes in country-specific commodity price indexes. 15 Results show that a 10 percent increase in commodity export prices increases output by 0.63 to 0.85 percent in EMDE commodity exporters and 0.18 to 0.26 percent in advanced-economy commodity exporters (Table 5). 16 Second, panel regressions are used to estimate a fiscal policy reaction function (that is, the response of government spending to changes in commodity prices). The results show that EMDEs increase government spending when commodity export prices rise, indicating a procyclical fiscal policy (Table 6). Specifically, a 10 percent increase in commodity export prices leads to an increase in government spending of about 0.6 percent to 0.8 percent. In contrast, advanced economies respond countercyclically: a 10 percent increase in commodity export prices elicits a reduction in government spending of about 0.7 percent to 1.2 percent. Third, an average fiscal multiplier is estimated for commodity exporters using a panel structural vector 14 Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh (2004) focused on net capital inflows, finding that such flows were associated with an increase in government expenditure in emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs), while net capital outflows were associated with a decline in government expenditure. A variety of other drivers could lead to procyclical fiscal behavior. 15 Two control variables are used: overall terms of trade (which includes terms of trade for all traded goods and services, not just commodities, using data from the IMF) to control for trade effects, and the lagged dependent variable to capture underlying growth unrelated to commodity prices. The country-specific commodity export price index is an index that weights commodity prices by their relevance in a country’s exports. This index is a better measure of a commodity price shock for a particular country than global commodity price indexes that might include goods not exported by the particular country. 16 In Table 5, the coefficient for EMDEs (0.085) in column (1) is about 3.5 times as much as the coefficient for advanced economies (0.024) in column (4). 9 autoregression (SVAR) model. 17 Finally, the ‘amplification’ effect (the “pours” component) of fiscal policy on output is obtained by combining the fiscal response in the second step with the fiscal multiplier obtained from the third step. The pours component represents changes in output growth that are due solely to changes in government expenditure in response to the initial shock. The “pours component” is then formally measured by: = ∆ ∗ ∗ ∗ (1) where is the commodity export price, is the estimated coefficient in the fiscal regression and is the ratio of government spending to GDP (computed as the average over the sample period for each country). Intuitively, changes in commodity export price () trigger a fiscal reaction (elasticity), which in turn affect GDP via the fiscal multiplier. The fiscal reaction is adjusted by the size of the government to measure the final impact in percentage points of GDP. 18 III.2 Impact of procyclical fiscal policy on output The results indicate that if an increase in the price of the exported commodity boosts output by 1.0 percentage point (the “rains” effect), procyclical fiscal policy in commodity-exporting EMDEs increases GDP by another 0.21 percentage point (the “pours” effect), boosting the total change in GDP to 1.21 percent (Figure 5.A). In contrast, fiscal policy in commodity-exporting advanced economies compensates for the cyclical effect by reacting in the opposite direction, reducing GDP by 0.65 percentage point. This leaves the net increase in GDP of 0.35 percentage point for advanced economies. These estimates suggest that, when faced with a commodity price shock of the same magnitude, the overall change in GDP can be more than three times bigger in EMDEs than in advanced economies solely because of the fiscal policy reaction. The above approach is applied to the commodity price boom of 2003–08 to illustrate the role of fiscal policy. During this period, commodity export prices increased about 76 percent for the EMDEs and 66 percent for the advanced economies in the sample. The analysis estimates the direct effect of the commodity price shock on output (the “rain” component) by applying the 2003-2008 cumulative price shock to the estimated parameters. The results indicate that the total effect on output to be 5.4 percent for EMDEs and 4.6 percent for advanced economies—that is, a difference of 0.8 percentage point (Figure 5.B). The procyclical response of fiscal policy in EMDEs (“pours” component) in another 1.1 percentage points to growth, bringing EMDE growth to 6.5 percent over this period. In contrast, fiscal policy in advanced economies reacted in a countercyclical fashion, subtracting about 3 percentage points from growth, bringing advanced-economy growth to 1.6 percent. In other words, of the 4.9 percentage points difference between total EMDE and advanced-economy growth in the sample, 4.1 percentage points (or 84 percent) can be explained by the responses of fiscal policy—procyclical in EMDEs and countercyclical in advanced economies. 17 The model is based on the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) identification method, employing quarterly data for GDP and government expenditure from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics database for the period 1990-2019. In computing the “pours” component, the value of the multiplier after four quarters is used (given by 0.88). 18 The fiscal reaction elasticity is estimated using a panel of 15 commodity exporters (4 advanced economies and 11 EMDEs). The fiscal multiplier is estimated for the same panel following Blanchard and Perotti (2002). Government size is represented by the average government expenditure as a share of GDP for each country. The availability of quarterly data is critical for the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) identification method. This method assumes that output responds to government spending within the period, but that government spending does not respond to GDP. In other words, all contemporaneous correlation is attributed to fiscal policy affecting GDP. See Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Végh (2013) for a detailed discussion. 10 To summarize, fiscal procyclicality amplifies the effect of commodity price shocks on the business cycle in EMDEs. In the sample period examined, fiscal policy in the average EMDE commodity exporter is estimated to have increased the effect of a commodity price shock on output by more than one-fifth. The results indicate that in EMDE commodity exporters fiscal policy has tended to amplify the business cycle, whereas in advanced-economy commodity exporters fiscal policy has tended to dampen it. IV. Fiscal policy volatility IV.1 Estimating fiscal policy volatility The framework used to estimate fiscal policy volatility is based on the approach in Fatás and Mihov (2013) and Arroyo Marioli, Fatás, and Vasishtha (2023) , which involves estimating a fiscal policy reaction function of the following form: = + + + (2) Where “Fiscal Policy” is a variable that captures the stance of fiscal policy. Four alternative measures of fiscal policy are used: primary expenditures (which exclude net interest payments), revenues, government consumption, and the primary budget balance (which excludes net interest). The first three variables are expressed in real (inflation-adjusted) terms and measured as log differences. The primary budget balance is expressed as the annual change of its ratio to GDP. “Economic Activity” denotes the cyclical stance of the economy and is represented by annual GDP growth. The alternatives—the output gap and the unemployment rate—are more difficult to construct or measure accurately for diverse economies. 19 summarizes the cyclical behavior of fiscal policy and indicates whether fiscal policy is countercyclical or procyclical. It is composed of both automatic stabilizers and the discretionary response of governments to economic fluctuations. 20 The residual, , captures changes in fiscal policy that are unrelated to the business cycle or any of the control variables. These decisions can be the result of political decisions (such as changes in tax rates or spending associated with the political cycle) or errors in policy (such as mismeasurement of the output gap). The uncertainty associated with the residual can be seen as generating excessive volatility in GDP and, possibly, reduced long-term growth. Following Fatás and Mihov (2013), the volatility of fiscal policy is measured as the standard deviation of the residual in the fiscal policy reaction function ( ). Annual data are used for the 1990–2021 period for 184 countries, including 148 EMDEs and 36 advanced economies. The choice of the sample period is based on data availability. Of these 184 countries, 94 are commodity exporters and the remainder as commodity importers. Among commodity exporters, only five are advanced economies. Among commodity importers, 31 are advanced economies and 59 are EMDEs. IV.2 Basic features of fiscal policy volatility The following stylized facts emerge from a comparison of the measures of fiscal policy volatility for EMDEs and advanced economies. First, over the past three decades, the volatilities of primary expenditures, government consumption, and revenues were all significantly higher in EMDEs than in advanced 19 HP-filtered GDP levels are also used as a measure of economic activity to check the robustness of the results. The results using this alternative measure are consistent with the baseline results. 20 The specification has potential endogeneity issues since fiscal policy could affect economic activity contemporaneously. While the literature has acknowledged these issues, it has made use of OLS in many instances because of the lack of an obvious instrument (for example, Aghion, Hemous and Kharroubi 2014; Alesina, Campante and Tabellini 2008; and Lane 2003). Studies that have explored a set of instruments to test the robustness of the results presented in these earlier papers find similar results (for example, Fatás and Mihov 2013). Given this, and for the sake of simplicity, the analysis in this paper makes use of OLS. 11 economies (Figure 6.A). The difference between the average volatility for these two groups of countries is statistically significant. Notably, the difference in the volatility of government consumption is larger than that of primary expenditures, highlighting the role of government consumption in fiscal policy volatility in EMDEs. The estimated volatility of the primary balance (as a percentage of GDP) is relatively smaller and closer between the two country groups than with the other fiscal policy indicators. 21 Second, commodity exporters exhibited more volatility in fiscal policy than commodity importers (Figure 6.B). The difference in the average volatility for commodity exporters and commodity importers is statistically significant. As in the case of EMDEs, government consumption demonstrates greater volatility than the other indicators, although only by a slight margin. Third, fiscal policy volatility declined somewhat in EMDEs over the past three decades. Volatility of government expenditure, consumption, revenue, and primary balance were all lower on average during 2007–2020 than in 1980–2006 (Figure 6.C). This reduction in fiscal policy volatility in EMDEs mirrors the increasing use of fiscal rules in these countries (Arroyo Marioli, Fatás, and Vasishtha 2023). In advanced economies, however, over the same period, revenue volatility declined while volatility of expenditures and primary balance increased (Figure 6.D). Fourth, government expenditures, consumption, and revenue tend to be more volatile in LICs than in other EMDEs. Over the past three decades, government expenditure, consumption and revenue were roughly twice as volatile in LICs as in other EMDEs (Figure 6.E). The degree of fiscal volatility has also varied across emerging market regions. On average, expenditure volatility in LICs, particularly FCS, over the past three decades was higher than that in lower- and upper-middle income countries. Fiscal volatility was the highest among commodity exporters in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), the Middle East and North Africa (MNA), and East Asia and Pacific (EAP) than in other emerging market regions (Figure 6.F). IV.3 Determinants of fiscal volatility Cross-sectional regressions are used to investigate the role of country-specific factors—such as institutions, policy variables, the extent and nature of commodity dependence, and GDP per capita—in driving fiscal policy volatility. Like the analysis of procyclicality, the exercise focuses on the spending side of the budget. While each of the four fiscal policy indicators used above contains information about fiscal policy, the variation in primary expenditures provides a more accurate perspective on the volatility of fiscal policy. Since the automatic stabilizer component of expenditures tends to be small, changes in primary expenditures tend to be driven by discretionary measures and changes in nondiscretionary spending that are unrelated to the business cycle. It is these changes in primary expenditure net of cyclical components (such as unemployment benefits) that are captured in the volatility measure used in the analysis. The findings indicate that commodity dependence can be a source of fiscal policy volatility by itself. Being both an EMDE and a commodity exporter explains up to 22 percent of the variation in fiscal policy volatility across countries (Table 7).22 That commodity exporters exhibit higher fiscal policy volatility even after 21 However, when comparing the volatility of the primary balance with the other fiscal variables, the average size of the government in EMDEs needs to be considered. For instance, a 1 percent increase in government spending will have a different impact on GDP in a country with a smaller government than in one with a larger government. Given that the average government size is about 30 percent, a 1 percent exogenous change in government expenditures only leads to a change in the primary balance of approximately 0.3 percent of GDP in the average EMDE. 22 For brevity, Table 7 only shows the regression results when primary expenditure is used as the dependent variable. The regression results with government consumption as the dependent variable are very similar. 12 their EMDE status is taken into account suggests that reliance on commodities in itself contributes to fiscal policy volatility. EMDEs and commodity exporters are heterogenous groups of countries that display substantial variation in their level of development as well as degree of commodity dependence. To account for these differences across countries, two additional variables are introduced into the analysis. GDP per capita is included to represent the level of development in each country. A second variable measuring resource rents—specifically, income from natural resources as a percentage of GDP—is introduced to capture the degree of commodity dependence. Resource rents are highly correlated with resource revenues as a share of GDP (Arroyo Marioli, Fatás, and Vasishtha 2023). The results indicate that the lower GDP per capita in EMDEs does not by itself explain the differences in fiscal policy volatility across countries because the presence of larger commodity sectors contributes to greater volatility in fiscal policy. Overall, these findings suggest that both the level of development and the degree of commodity dependence contribute to explaining fiscal volatility. Further, energy exporters display higher fiscal policy volatility than exporters of metals and agricultural commodities. Controlling for resource rents, however, the results indicate that commodity dependence is a more important determinant of fiscal volatility than the type of commodity exported (Table 8). A stable institutional environment and the use of sound fiscal rules can reduce fiscal policy volatility. The role of institutional factors in driving fiscal policy volatility is analyzed by including two additional variables often used in the literature: political constraints and control of corruption. These two variables are found to be significant and together help explain up to 40 percent of cross-country variation in fiscal policy volatility. Policy frameworks can also play an important role in driving fiscal policy volatility. The roles of three specific policy variables are examined: the capital account openness, exchange rate regime (floating versus fixed), and the presence of fiscal rules. The presence of a more open capital account, more flexible exchange rates, and fiscal rules are all associated with lower fiscal policy volatility. These explanatory variables can explain up to 71 percent of the cross-country variation in fiscal policy volatility. The estimates suggest that moving from a fixed exchange rate regime to a flexible one can lower expenditure volatility by 3 percentage points (Table 7). Although a flexible exchange rate regime is not feasible or appropriate for all EMDEs, countries with those regimes may have more room for the exchange rate adjustment needed to counteract the destabilizing effects of commodity prices on output. A more flexible exchange rate regime, in principle, facilitates a smoother cyclical adjustment to a terms-of-trade shock. For example, during the 2014-16 fall in commodity prices (mainly crude oil and natural gas), commodity-exporting countries such as Chile and Peru (two countries with flexible exchange rate regimes) were able to increase spending through countercyclical fiscal policy as they were equipped with sufficient fiscal space and the necessary medium- term fiscal frameworks to safeguard fiscal sustainability (Al-Sadiq, Bejar, and Otker 2021). 23 In contrast, countries with pegged regimes experienced a larger deterioration in their fiscal balance, on average, relative to those with flexible exchange rate regime. Pegged exchange rates remain the dominant exchange rate regime among EMDEs (Figure 7.A). While greater exchange rate flexibility can help build resilience to commodity price shocks, its macroeconomic implications need to be taken into account, particularly in cases where prices of a few key exports are globally determined, and exchange rate fluctuations may have adverse impacts on the balance sheets of public and private institutions. 23 Although a countercyclical fiscal policy response to a temporary commodity price shock is desirable under both fixed and flexible exchange rate regimes, these policies are more effective under a flexible exchange rate regime combined with inflation targeting when monetary policy complements fiscal policy by reducing inflation volatility (IMF 2012a). 13 The results also suggest that if the average degree of capital account openness in EMDEs were to be the same as in the average advanced economy, expenditure volatility in EMDEs would be reduced by 1.7 percentage points. In principle, economies with greater access to international capital markets should be better able to smooth the impact of commodity price fluctuations on output volatility, although markets may respond in a procyclical manner for some countries (with capital flows increasing during commodity price booms and declining during slumps) (IMF 2012a). Capital account openness in commodity exporters has increased over the past few decades, but it remains lower than in commodity importers (Figure 7.B). Measures to increase capital account openness always have to be considered with caution, in combination with consideration of the prudential and other measures that may be needed to avoid instability in the domestic financial system. In addition, establishing a fiscal rule can reduce expenditure volatility in EMDEs by 0.7 percentage point (from 10.8 to 10.1 percent). The significance of these three variables—that is exchange rate regime, capital account openness, and fiscal rules—in driving fiscal policy volatility remains even after accounting for the level of development and the extent of commodity dependence. Although the presence of an SWF is also associated with lower fiscal volatility, the result is not statistically significant. 24 IV.4 Links between procyclicality and volatility Fiscal procyclicality and volatility are intimately related concepts and often driven by similar factors, as highlighted by the preceding analysis. Intuitively, a more procyclical fiscal policy would be expected to result in a more volatile fiscal policy to the extent that it amplifies the business cycle, thus exacerbating the effect of the initial source of volatility. 25 The measures of volatility and procyclicality are positively correlated, a finding in line with some previous studies (Figure 8.A; IMF 2004). The correlation is significant for both commodity exporters and commodity importers. However, when EMDEs and advanced economies are considered separately, the correlation is significant only for EMDEs, suggesting that fiscal procyclicality is associated with more fiscal policy volatility only in EMDEs (which also tend to be procyclical). In advanced economies, because fiscal policy is countercyclical or acyclical on average, the volatility of fiscal policy is likely from other factors. Further, the correlation between fiscal procyclicality and volatility has declined for advanced economies from the 1980–2006 period to the post-2007 period, while it has remained unchanged for EMDEs and commodity exporters (Figure 8.B). High- and upper- middle-income countries present the highest correlation among country income groups (Figure 8.C). Finally, the Europe and Central Asia (ECA) and the Middle East and North Africa (MNA) regions show higher correlation than other EMDE regions (Figure 8.D). IV.5 Implications of fiscal policy volatility for growth The impact of fiscal policy volatility on per capita GDP growth is analyzed by estimating variants of a standard growth regression (Barro 1991). The benchmark specification is given by: 24 It is possible that the effect of establishing a sovereign wealth fund is captured by the other policy variables included in the analysis. For example, the decision to establish one may be correlated with volatility itself. 25 It is also possible that if fiscal policy is procyclical relative to the commodity cycle, it may end up being the main transmission channel from the commodity cycle itself. In countries where the commodity export sector is weakly linked with the rest of the economy, government expenditure could be the main link between the overall cycle and prices. However, in the analysis used here (which follows the empirical literature), fiscal volatility is defined as the volatility of changes in public expenditure that are not related to the business cycle (Fatás and Milhov 2013). Under this definition, the relation between the two is less obvious. 14 ∆ = ′ + ′ log ( ) + ′ + (3) where, ∆ is the average per capita GDP growth for country ; is the measure of fiscal policy volatility— the key regressor; is a vector of variables that have been found to have significant explanatory power for the cross-country variation in growth. Fiscal policy volatility is measured using primary expenditures. Equation (4.2.2) is estimated using both OLS as well as instrumental variables to address endogeneity concerns. Instruments used were political constraints and control of corruption (see Table 2.B for details). The controls included in the regression are taken from the specification of Fatás and Mihov (2013), which are based on the growth regressions of Sala-i-Martin, Doppelhofer, and Miller (2004). 26 The controls included are government size, initial GDP per capita, capital account openness, and the price of investment. Fiscal policy volatility reduces output growth by exacerbating macroeconomic volatility. Expenditure volatility is found to have significantly hurt per capita output growth (Table 9), which supports earlier research showing a negative association between macroeconomic volatility and economic growth (Kose, Prasad, and Terrones 2005; Ramey and Ramey 1995). The estimated impact of fiscal volatility on per capita growth is in line with other recent estimates (for example, Fatás and Mihov 2013). Applying the above estimates in a counterfactual scenario, if the average commodity-exporting EMDE were to adopt the policies of an average advanced economy in three areas—capital account openness, exchange rate flexibility, and use of fiscal rules—fiscal volatility would be reduced by roughly 3.1 percentage points—from 12.3 percent to 9.2 percent. This would result in an increase in the average per capita GDP growth rate for commodity-exporting EMDEs from about 1.4 to 1.7 percent per year. In other words, by adopting these policies the average commodity-exporting EMDE could have added about 1 percentage point in per capita growth every four to five years (Figure 9.A). Over the 30-year sample period of the analysis, an overall 7.6 percentage points would have been added to average growth in GDP per capita in EMDEs. V. Fiscal institutions and frameworks The results of the empirical analysis highlight the role of political pressures in driving fiscal policy procyclicality and volatility in commodity-exporting EMDEs. This section discusses how well-designed and credible institutional mechanisms—fiscal rules, sovereign wealth funds, and medium-term expenditure frameworks—can help foster fiscal discipline and counteract tendencies toward procyclicality. It also highlights the role of strong governance more generally in facilitating countercyclical fiscal policies in these economies. V.1 Fiscal rules Until the early 1990s only a handful of EMDEs had fiscal rules and virtually no LICs did. Since then, a growing number of EMDEs have adopted such rules—including commodity exporters, such as Chile and Indonesia (Davoodi et al. 2022). By the end of 2020, 43 of 96 commodity-exporting EMDEs had at least one fiscal rule in place (Figure 9.B). As of 2021, budget balance and debt rules were the most prevalent type of rules in commodity-exporting countries. Budget balance rules accounted for about 41 percent of fiscal rules followed by debt rules which were about 33 percent of total fiscal rules (Figure 9.C). Expenditure rules (15 percent) and revenue rules (11 percent) accounted for the rest. Among commodity exporters, the adoption of fiscal rules has been most prevalent in energy and agricultural exporters followed by metal exporters (Figure 9.D). 26For robustness, different specifications were estimated with a variety of controls, including the existence of a sovereign wealth fund. The results are not significant. Note that this variable is already included as an instrument for fiscal policy volatility. 15 Although fiscal rules were designed to be rigid to constrain government actions and promote compliance, these rules have been evolving, especially in response to economic crises (Budina et al. 2013). There are four main types of fiscal rules, based on the budgetary aggregate they aim to constrain (Davoodi et al. 2022): • Budget balance rules. The objective of a budget balance rule is to constrain the size of the deficit and thereby control the evolution of the debt ratio (for example, Indonesia, Mexico, and Nigeria). Because such rules do not set numerical limits on budgetary aggregates, they are typically considered procedural rather than numerical fiscal rules. If followed properly, they can help prevent debt sustainability issues. However, in some cases, budget balance rules can also induce procyclicality by forcing expenditures to follow revenues, which are usually procyclical. • Revenue rules. These rules set ceilings and floors on revenues and are aimed at boosting revenue collection and/or preventing an excessive tax burden. Most of these rules are not linked directly to the control of public debt because they do not constrain spending. Furthermore, setting ceilings/floors on revenues can be challenging because revenues often have a large cyclical component— fluctuating in line with the business cycle. Revenue rules alone could result in procyclical fiscal policy because floors generally do not account for automatic stabilizers (such as unemployment benefits) in a downturn and ceilings don’t account for them in an upturn. Revenue rules can, however, directly target the size of the government. • Expenditure rules. Expenditure rules set limits on total, primary, or current government expenditures to limit the procyclicality of fiscal policy (for example, Botswana, Chad, and Ecuador). Such limits are typically set either in absolute terms, or growth rates, and occasionally, as a percentage of GDP. The time horizon often ranges between three and five years. Expenditure rules can constrain spending during booms, when windfall revenue receipts are temporarily high and deficit limits are easy to comply with. Such rules, however, are not directly linked to the objective of debt sustainability because they do not constrain the revenue side. Moreover, expenditure rules do not allow much scope for discretionary fiscal stimulus during bad economic times. • Debt rules. These rules focus on long-term sustainability by setting an explicit anchor or ceiling for public debt (often as a percentage of GDP). A debt rule is relatively easy to communicate and, by definition, most effectively ensures convergence to a debt target. However, debt rules do not provide clear short-term guidance for policy makers because it takes time for budgetary measures to affect debt levels. 27 Moreover, fiscal policy may become procyclical if the economy is hit by shocks and the debt target, defined as a percentage of GDP, is binding. Conversely, when debt is well below its ceiling, such a rule does not provide binding guidance (Budina et al. 2013). Fiscal rules can help reduce the volatility of fiscal policy and deliver better fiscal outcomes. Fiscal rules leave less space for discretionary spending, which tends to be procyclical and to exacerbate the business cycle (thereby adding more fiscal volatility). Fiscal rules can also provide a strong signal of prudence in fiscal policy (Debrun and Kumar 2008). Well-designed fiscal rules have been found to help lower fiscal 27Debt levels can also be affected by developments outside the control of the government, such as changes in interest rates and the exchange rate, as well as “below-the-line” financing operations (such as financial sector support measures), which could result in large fiscal adjustments. 16 deficits and reduce both fiscal procyclicality and volatility. 28 The adoption of fiscal rules is associated with less procyclicality in fiscal policy. At the same time, fiscal rules can act as a constraint on the ability of incumbent politicians to generate political business cycles using fiscal and monetary expansions. Fiscal frameworks that do not have formal rules but focus on transparent and credible strategies backed by proper fiscal institutions could also provide a viable approach to support fiscal discipline (World Bank 2023). Although the use of fiscal rules has been associated with more fiscal discipline, only well-designed fiscal rules promote more fiscal discipline (Caselli and Reynaud 2020). 29 Additionally, while fiscal rules are associated with improved fiscal policy management, their success crucially depends on effective institutions and governance underpinned by the rule of law and strong accountability mechanisms (Ardanaz, Cavallo, and Izquierdo 2023; Bergman and Hutchison 2015). V.2 Sovereign wealth funds SWFs are special purpose investment funds or arrangements that are owned by the government and are designed to expand national wealth and stabilize business cycles. SWFs hold, manage, or administer assets to achieve financial objectives and employ a set of investment strategies. The objectives of SWFs depend on country-specific circumstances, which may evolve over time. SWFs include: 30 • Stabilization funds. These funds are established to insulate the economy from commodity price volatility—for example, the Economic and Social Stabilization Fund in Chile. Revenue flows into the funds when government receipts are above a benchmark and money can be withdrawn from the fund when government revenue is below the benchmark level. • Savings funds. The primary objective of a savings fund is to build wealth for future generations and ensure intergenerational equity in countries that rely on nonrenewable natural resources, such as oil. Examples include the Petroleum Fund in Timor-Leste and the Pula Fund in Botswana. These funds are characterized by fixed inflows of government revenue and discretionary outflows—reflecting a higher tolerance for short-term volatility and a focus on longer-term returns. Savings funds are established when a government can put aside funds for the future and be reasonably confident that the assets in the fund will not need to be liquidated in the short- and medium-run (Al-Hassan et al. 2018). • Financing funds. A financing fund combines the characteristics of a stabilization fund and a savings fund, such as the SWF of Norway. It is fully integrated into the government budget process. Typically, inflows to the fund come from the resource revenues of the government and the returns on the fund’s investments. The outflows are transfers to cover any non-resource budget deficit. As a result, the fund receives positive net transfers if, and only if, the government runs a budget 28 For empirical evidence on the importance of well-designed fiscal rules to deliver lower fiscal deficits, see Caselli and Reynaud (2020); Dahan and Strawczynski (2013); Debrun et al. (2008); and Fabrizio and Mody (2006). Badinger and Reuter (2017), Caselli and Reynaud (2020), Céspedes and Velasco (2014), and Martorano (2018) provide evidence on the association between fiscal rules and lower procyclicality while Badinger and Reuter (2017) show that fiscal rules also help lower fiscal policy volatility. 29 See, for example, Apeti, Basdevant, and Salins (2023); Bergman, Hutchison, and Jensen (2016); and Tapsoba (2012). It is important to note that establishing causality from fiscal rules to fiscal discipline is not straightforward because of endogeneity issues (more disciplined and prudent governments are more likely to adopt fiscal rules) and reverse causality issues (many fiscal rules are adopted after a crisis). 30 Other types of SWFs are reserve investment corporations and development wealth funds. These types of funds are not included in this analysis. 17 surplus when resource revenues are included. This is not necessarily the case for stabilization and savings funds (for example, that of New Zealand) because these funds are not linked to government budget deficits or surpluses (Al-Hassan et al. 2018). A key feature of the financing fund model is the fiscal policy guideline (or rule) which specifies the desired trajectory of the non- resource budget deficit that is to be financed by transfers from the fund. Over the past few decades, the number of SWFs established has increased rapidly, particularly by commodity-exporting countries. Many commodity exporters have established SWFs as a stabilization fund to channel windfall gains during commodity price booms to accumulate as savings that can be withdrawn during commodity price slumps to limit the impact on fiscal balances. Among the major emerging market regions, the MNA region ranks the highest in terms of total assets under management of SWFs—more than twice that in advanced-economy commodity exporters (Figure 9.E). In practice, the effectiveness of such stabilization funds in moderating fluctuations in government spending, and hence output, has varied across countries (Gill et al. 2014). Although poor fiscal governance has hampered the successful implementation of sovereign stabilization funds in many EMDEs, the overall experience has been positive for smoothing the path of government spending (Sugawara 2014). There is evidence that SWFs can be effective in reducing fiscal procyclicality in some countries (Coutinho et al. 2022). In oil-exporting countries, stabilization funds have been associated with reduced macroeconomic variability and lower inflation (Shabsigh and Ilahi 2007). An appropriate institutional framework and strong long-term political commitment, including transparent governance of the stabilization fund and prudent constraints on the discretion of fund managers, are critical for the effectiveness of these funds (Asik 2017; Bagattini 2011; Ossowski et al. 2008). Strong institutions help to shield these funds from political influences (Koh 2017; Mohaddes and Raissi 2017). In this context, sovereign wealth and stabilization funds work well to reduce government expenditure volatility in countries where fiscal rules are implemented (Sugawara 2014), but their effectiveness is hampered where there are inadequate controls and integration with the budget is limited (Le Borgne and Medas 2007). More broadly, cross-country evidence shows a strong causal link running from better institutions to less procyclical or more countercyclical fiscal policy in EMDEs (Frankel, Végh, and Vuletin 2013). These results are also corroborated by the country case studies presented in Section VI, which suggest that the efficacy of SWFs is positively correlated with the presence of strong institutions. V.3 Medium-term expenditure frameworks Medium-term expenditure frameworks (MTEFs) are intended to establish or enhance credibility in the budgetary process and to set out spending plans consistent with prevailing economic conditions and medium-term policy objectives (Raudla, Douglas, and MacCarthaigh 2022). Such frameworks can enhance clarity on the purposes of expenditures and help ensure a transparent budgetary process, where government agencies allocate public resources based on strategic priorities. MTEFs foster greater fiscal transparency and accountability by providing a clear basis for monitoring government performance against approved plans, making it easier to hold governments accountable for their fiscal policies. The number of countries with MTEFs has increased notably over the past three decades. Initially adopted by a few advanced economies in the early 1980s to address public overspending, MTEFs became widely accepted as integral components of fiscal governance throughout the 1990s and 2000s. Among EMDEs, MTEFs were introduced to strengthen public finance management and to realign expenditures consistent with long-term development needs (World Bank 1998). The adoption of MTEFs accelerated in the aftermath of financial crises, with the objective of reconciling short-term pressures with longer-term 18 priorities (Raudla Douglas, and MacCarthaigh 2022). 31 Evidence suggests that credible MTEFs can significantly improve fiscal discipline (Vlaicu et al. 2014; World Bank 2013). Robust implementation of these frameworks is closely related to linkages with broader economic and social policy objectives, to the reliability of the relevant data, and to the forecasting capability of the authorities (Allen et al. 2017). The success of these frameworks crucially depends on strong government ownership and support (Schiavo‐Campo 2009). For example, South Africa, a commodity exporter, introduced an MTEF when government debt was high, the central government was underspending, and provincial governments were overspending. With widespread support at the top levels of government, the underspending and overspending were both reduced following the introduction of the MTEF (World Bank 2013). MTEFs need clearly defined legal frameworks and strong supporting institutions to be effective. They can also complement other fiscal frameworks to achieve desired fiscal policy objectives. For example, combined with fiscal rules, MTEFs can improve fiscal balances and the quality of budget forecasts. More advanced MTEFs can also be associated with lower spending volatility and higher spending efficiency. Nevertheless, MTEFs may fail to meet their objectives where institutions are weak and where key government functions are hindered by capacity constraints in critical technical and administrative areas. For instance, the improvements in fiscal discipline following the adoption of MTEFs tend to be transient in nature, especially in the case of frameworks lacking comprehensive metrics for monitoring and evaluating fiscal performance. In addition, lack of fiscal transparency can impair budget credibility and increase uncertainty about fiscal policy and outturns in EMDEs. 32 V.4 Institutional quality and governance Resource abundance can be advantageous to a country if the government has a sound long-term plan for extracting the resources and a robust mechanism for using resource revenues to meet economic and social needs to achieve sustained economic growth. However, resource wealth can undermine institutions and longer-term growth by promoting rent-seeking, corruption, and the squandering of resources through unproductive spending, poor-quality investment, and the depletion of government savings. For mineral rich countries, there is also evidence that mineral wealth can provoke or fuel internal conflicts (Collier and Hoeffler 2004). In general, resource-rich countries with stronger economic and political institutions tend to have better macroeconomic and growth outcomes (Arezki and Bruckner 2010; Arezki, Hamilton, and Kazimov 2011; van der Ploeg 2011). Higher quality political institutions help limit procyclicality of fiscal expenditures (Ossowski et al. 2008; Sugawara 2014). The observed decline in fiscal procyclicality in EMDEs over the past decade and a half has been mainly attributed to the improved quality of institutions, as measured by indicators on law and order, bureaucracy quality, and corruption (Frankel, Végh, and Vuletin 2013). In LICs, the quality of budget institutions—measured through the quality of the various stages on the budget process and the number of checks and balances in place—tends to be positively associated with the ability of these countries to conduct countercyclical policies (Dabla-Norris et al. 2010). 31 Vlaicu et al. (2014) estimated that the number of countries with MTEFs increased from 11 in 1990 to 132 at the end of 2008. The lack of data makes it difficult to estimate the current number of countries with MTEFs. 32 On the role of institutions, see Filc and Scartascini (2010) and Schiavo‐Campo (2009). On the role of fiscal rules, see Hansen (2020) and von Hagen (2010). For evidence on the impact of MTEFs on spending volatility and efficiency, see Vlaicu et al. (2014) and World Bank (2013). Elberry and Goeminne (2021) provide evidence on how lack of fiscal transparency affects fiscal outcomes. 19 The case studies of Norway, Chile, and Botswana show that the quality of their institutions—which is higher than that of their peers—helped limit the negative impact of commodity price volatility (Bova, Medas, and Poghosyan 2016). These country cases also demonstrate that fiscal rules or SWFs work best when they are well-designed, closely linked to broader policy objectives, and supported by strong institutions and political commitment. In the absence of strong institutions and political commitment, fiscal rules and SWFs tend not to be followed closely, which reduces their effectiveness. VI. Do fiscal rules and sovereign wealth funds make a difference? Lessons from country case studies This section assesses the effectiveness of fiscal rules and SWFs in managing commodity price shocks in selected commodity-exporting countries. Specifically, it addresses the following questions: How do fiscal rules and SWFs differ among commodity-exporting countries? How have fiscal rules and SWFs helped in reducing fiscal procyclicality and volatility? To address these questions, the use of SWFs and fiscal rules in seven diverse commodity-exporting countries is analyzed: Argentina, Australia, Botswana, Chile, Indonesia, Norway, and Timor-Leste. The analysis aims to include a diverse set of commodity exporters both in terms of the types of commodity exports (agriculture, energy, and minerals) as well as the concentration of commodity exports (that is, single-commodity exporters as well as countries with a more diverse export portfolio). To draw useful insights for resource-rich countries considering adopting fiscal rules and SWFs to mitigate fiscal procyclicality and volatility, the section analyzes countries with well-functioning fiscal rules and SWFs, countries with mixed experiences, and countries without fiscal rules and SWFs. Finally, the sample includes both advanced economies and EMDEs in different geographical regions. VI.1 Australia, Chile, and Norway These countries have designed their SWFs to help manage the fiscal effects of fluctuations in commodity export prices and revenues. Australia and Norway have designed their funds for long-term purposes, while Chile has designed its fund for short-term purposes. These countries have also established fiscal rules and a strong institutional framework that allows them to reduce or avoid fiscal procyclicality (Arezki et al. 2012; Bauer 2014; Frankel 2011). The combination of good institutions, SWFs, and fiscal rules has enabled these countries to manage their commodity-based revenues and create sustainable frameworks. Australia combines well-developed fiscal frameworks with broad principles (for example, on debt sustainability) with more flexible numerical rules or guidelines. Chile and Norway also rely on more flexible guidelines and rules supported by strong institutions and transparency on fiscal plans, and are often regarded as countries with the most successful fiscal frameworks and institutions to manage natural resource wealth (Lam et al. 2023). Australia. Australia's commodity exports comprise iron ore, coal, gold, liquified natural gas, and animal meat. The country’s fiscal framework is based on the Charter of Budget Honesty Act 1998 (Commonwealth of Australia 2014), which provides for “constrained discretion,” that advocates a principles-based approach rather than a numerically oriented, rules-based approach. It adds transparency and discipline to the budget formation and execution process (Bhattacharyya and Williamson 2011; Chohan 2017). The Charter defines the principles of sound fiscal management as comprising several components, including an expectation that fiscal policy contributes to adequate national saving and to moderating cyclical fluctuations in economic activity, as appropriate (Chohan 2017). The country’s SWF, the Future Fund, was established in 2006 and accumulates revenue from budget surpluses for long-term purposes, such as 20 pensions (Figure 10.A). 33 The minister of finance may make certain discretionary transfers from time to time. Norway. Commodity exports of Norway are concentrated in crude oil and petroleum gas. The country has an SWF comprising two separate investment funds. • The Government Pension Fund-Global (GPFG), formerly the Petroleum Fund, was established in 1990 to collect revenue from oil-related income sources to support government saving and to promote an intergenerational transfer of resources (Velculescu 2008). In this way, the government’s revenue from petroleum production does not enter the government budget directly. Norway’s GFPG is the largest natural-resource-based SWF in the world with its latest annual holdings at more than US$ 1.2 trillion, equivalent to 256 percent of GDP at the end of 2022 (Figure 10.B). • The Government Pension Fund Norway (GPFN) saves surpluses of the national insurance scheme and held assets of US$ 32.7 billion, or 6 percent of 2022 GDP (Lam et al. 2023). Political will to turn nonrenewable resources into wealth for future generations paved the road for Norway’s fund. The GPFG is fully integrated with the state budget and builds on existing institutions to strengthen the budget process. It finances the non-oil budget without constraints from any inflow or outflow rules between the fund and the budget. Norway has consistently sustained budget surpluses over the past two decades (except for 2020), with net inflows to the GPFG accumulating over time. The central government in Norway has the so-called “bird-in-hand rule” or “spending rule” (established in 2001), which stipulates that the non-oil structural deficit, and thus withdrawals from the fund over time, should correspond to the estimated annual real return of the fund, which has been 3 percent since 2017. Norway’s spending rule implies that the non-oil budget, and hence the economy, are isolated from both the large variations in oil revenues that result from oil price fluctuations as well as the volatility in the value of the fund due to variations in stock prices. This, in turn, helps to dampen the cyclical swings in the economy. The linking of the structural, and not the actual, non-oil fiscal deficit to the expected real return on the assets of the wealth fund allows automatic stabilizers to work. Norway (unlike its Nordic peers) does not have a publicly funded independent body to monitor fiscal or other economic policy. Instead, it established a Model and Method Commission in 2011, which advises the Ministry of Finance. Chile. Chile is the world’s biggest copper exporter—the metal accounts for about half of the country’s total exports. Chile’s fiscal policy management has been anchored on the successful implementation of SWFs, fiscal rules, and the recent creation of a fiscal council. Chile’s SWFs comprise two types of funds. • The Economic and Social Stabilization Fund (ESSF) was established with the Fiscal Responsibility Law of 2006. The ESSF has been designed for short-term purposes, with the main objective of stabilizing fiscal spending and insulating the budget from economic downturns and volatile copper prices, thus reducing the need to issue debt. Provisions for contributions to and withdrawal from the ESSF are well established in the law and closely tied to the fiscal rules. The ESSF has followed its mandate successfully and helped Chile finance countercyclical fiscal policy when needed. During the pandemic, the government utilized the stabilization fund to provide fiscal support. 33The Future Fund has also received contributions from the proceeds of the sale of the government’s stake in Telstra in late 2006 and the approximately 2 billion shares in Telstra that remained after this sale process. Also, it received contributions from a combination of budget surpluses, proceeds from the sale of the government’s holding of Telstra, and the transfer of remaining Telstra shares (Al-Hassan et al. 2018). 21 • The Pension Reserve Fund (PRF) aims to accumulate resources on a longer-term horizon. The PRF was created to support the state guarantee of pension and disability benefits. The funds’ governance and assets management strategy match international best practices (Lam et al. 2023). Chile’s fiscal rule, in place since 2001, limits the growth of budgeted central government spending to an estimate of structural revenue growth. The rule’s operation is supported by two expert panels that estimate long-term copper prices and the output gap. According to the rule, the authorities can run a deficit larger than the target if: (1) in a recession, output falls short of its long-run trend, or (2) the price of copper is below its medium-term (10-year) equilibrium (Frankel 2011). The ESSF is closely linked to the structural budget balance rule and has followed international best practices to have a flexible inflow and outflow mechanism, a feature similar to the arrangement in Norway (Lam et al. 2023). In addition to the fiscal rule, in January 2018 Chile created the Autonomous Fiscal Council to replace the Advisory Fiscal Council established in 2013. The new fiscal council also continues to have legal independence, its own resources, and has a broader mandate. The presence of credible fiscal rules; the strong governance structures that provide the space for their implementation; and the recent creation of competent, independent, and adequately resourced fiscal councils have enabled Chile to develop some of the best fiscal management institutions among commodity-exporting EMDEs (Izquierdo et al. 2008). For example, in the aftermath of the 2009 global recession, Chile was able to conduct a countercyclical fiscal policy and maintain a low risk of debt distress. Government expenditures grew from about 23 percent of GDP in 2012–14 to about 25 percent of GDP in 2015–17 (Figure 11.A). This helped mitigate output volatility, with GDP growth declining by 2 percentage points between 2012–14 and 2015–17, compared with an average decline of 2.6 percentage points among other metal exporters (Richaud et al. 2019). Chile’s fiscal sustainability was maintained on account of its fiscal rule, which allowed the country to save a substantial proportion of commodity revenues into its SWF during the commodity supercycle (World Bank 2017). Part of these savings were drawn down to boost the economy in the wake of the global financial crisis. More recently, the SWF was crucial in financing a big fiscal stimulus package during the COVID-19 pandemic. VI.2 Botswana and Timor-Leste Botswana. Diamond mining is the dominant economic sector in Botswana. The government established a sovereign wealth fund—the Pula Fund— in 1994 to serve both as a savings fund and as a short-term stabilization fund. The main objective of the fund is to put aside part of the income from diamond exports to benefit future generations. Another objective is to provide a stabilization mechanism for the government budget and foreign reserves during an economic downturn or slump in mineral prices. For example, the Pula Fund helped stabilize revenue and output during the 2007–09 global financial crisis. During 2008–10, the fiscal deficit in Botswana averaged about 9.4 percent of GDP, as mining revenues declined, and expenditures surged because of an increase in infrastructure spending to offset the adverse effects of the global economic downturn and to boost long-term productivity (Figure 11.B). The government financed this deficit by drawing upon savings from the Pula Fund and issuing new debt (World Bank 2016). To prevent excessive spending and bolster fiscal sustainability, the government has established a set of fiscal rules, which have been mostly set in terms of non-binding political commitments. Botswana has four main rules, which target public spending, the fiscal balance, and debt: • An indicative expenditure rule, the Sustainable Budgeting Index (SBI) was established in 1994 to ensure that mineral revenue is directed toward investments and savings, rather than consumption (Apeti, Basdevant, and Salins 2023; Kojo 2010). The SBI computes the ratio of 22 recurrent spending (excluding development spending) over non-diamond revenue, with the objective of keeping the ratio below 1. Adhering to this rule sets aside diamond revenue to finance the accumulation of financial assets and development spending. • There is an indicative target on the composition of spending, which specifies that development spending should be at least 30 percent of total spending. • An indicative target of a nonnegative fiscal balance was established in 2003. • Foreign and domestic debt are each prohibited from exceeding 20 percent of GDP. Surplus fiscal savings are deposited into the Pula Fund, which invests in long-term instruments overseas, and dividends from these investments are paid to the Treasury. However, Botswana’s fiscal framework has limitations. The sustainable budgeting principle does not directly incorporate a sustainability concept, and the Pula Fund has been reducing its overall size with withdrawals that are far larger than its inflow (Basdevant 2008; Jefferis 2016). The Pula Fund is not governed by clearly defined withdrawal or deposit rules, with deposits determined by the size of the budget surplus and withdrawals determined by the size of deficits (Markowitz 2020). On balance, however, Botswana has run a fairly prudent fiscal policy, avoiding many pitfalls experienced by other commodity-dependent countries. The strength and stability of Botswana’s institutions have been key in achieving this success (Kojo 2010; Richaud et al. 2019). Timor-Leste. Offshore oil and gas reserves are the main sources of Timor-Leste’s resource revenues. The Petroleum Fund (PF) was established in 2005 to collect oil revenues and is managed by the central bank. The PF primarily invests in offshore assets, such as U.S. Treasury bonds. The PF’s only expenditures are transfers to the budget, payment of operational management fees, and refunds of overpaid taxes. The government has adopted two fiscal rules to guide the use of oil revenue although these rules are not binding. • The Estimated Sustainable Income (ESI), established in 2005, is a mechanism for integrating the Petroleum Fund and the budget. The ESI is calculated as 3 percent of total wealth plus the present value of projected future oil receipts. That combined amount is what the government is authorized to spend each year. The value of future oil receipts is determined using the U.S. Energy Information Administration's forecasts for West Texas Intermediate crude oil. Transfers exceeding the ESI are allowed only if the government provides a justification that is approved by Parliament. The requirement is designed to constrain the government’s ability to spend government resources without considering long-term fiscal sustainability (Apeti, Basdevant, and Salins 2023). • The second rule is a political commitment to maintain a ceiling on the cost of external debt at 3 percent per year. It requires the government to benchmark the costs of external borrowing against the average rate of investment returns of the PF. Channeling all oil revenues into the PF and requiring that the ESI rule is consistent with the sustainable use of funds should, in principle, mitigate the impact of oil price cycles on fiscal expenditure. However, the escape clauses have hindered the effectiveness of Timor-Leste’s fiscal frameworks. Until 2008, government spending of oil revenue was conservative and transfers to the budget to finance the non-oil budget deficit were lower than the ESI. As a result, the net assets of the Petroleum Fund grew rapidly from US$371 million in 2005 to US$4.2 billion in 2008, the equivalent of 647 percent of non-oil GDP. 23 However, beginning in 2009, the country started to withdraw funds from the PF in excess of the ESI to finance large infrastructure projects (IMF 2012b). This led to a significant slowdown in accumulation of assets, but the PF still reached a level of about US$19 billion in 2020. Since the global financial crisis, expenditures have followed oil prices closely (Figure 11.C). Additionally, systematic excess withdrawals have been authorized in recent years, even prior to the pandemic. Given the low expected remaining lifetime of the country’s oil fields, the PF is at serious risk of being depleted within the next decade (World Bank 2021).In sum, escape clauses and weak institutions have diminished the effectiveness of fiscal rules in both Botswana and Timor-Leste, even when the rules were well-designed for long-run sustainability. VI.3 Argentina and Indonesia Indonesia. The main commodity exports of Indonesia are crude oil, gas, coal, palm oil, and rubber. Indonesia established a fiscal rule in 2003, which stipulates a fiscal deficit ceiling of 3 percent of GDP and a debt ceiling of 60 percent of GDP. At that time, the government’s deficit was 1.7 percent of GDP, debt was at 57 percent of GDP, and the economy was well on its path to recovery after the Asian financial crisis. The aim of the fiscal rule was to solidify these gains and to promote future fiscal discipline by enacting these fiscal responsibility criteria into law (Blöndal, Hawkesworth, and Choi 2009). The rules have been respected and only temporarily lifted during the pandemic within legally pre-established norms. Although Indonesia’s fiscal rule has provided a solid nominal anchor and has safeguarded debt sustainability, fiscal spending has not been disconnected from the commodity price cycle (Figure 12.A; Ismal 2011). For example, over 1993−2008, fiscal policy in Indonesia was not countercyclical (IMF 2009). The factors underlying limited fiscal responses to output fluctuations originated from structural weaknesses in public finance management and a lack of budget flexibility. This weakness included a high dependence on revenue from natural resources, narrow and volatile tax bases, low discretionary spending, and problems with budget execution. Additionally, like many EMDEs, Indonesia relies on external financing which tends to be procyclical. Liquidity constraints, particularly during downturns, weaken the government’s ability to run an expansionary fiscal policy to offset the effects of an economic slowdown. For example, during the 2007– 09 global financial crisis, Indonesia’s external borrowing spreads increased sharply, by nearly 1,200 basis points, much higher than its regional peers—Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand (IMF 2009). Another factor contributing to fiscal procyclicality is the high subsidy component of the budget, particularly energy subsidies, which leaves little room to respond to the economic cycle. However, the subsidies bill has been declining since 2015 owing to a series of reforms. Argentina. The country’s commodity export basket is based on agricultural goods. Unlike the other countries analyzed here, Argentina has neither a sovereign wealth fund nor a set of fiscal rules. Fiscal policy in Argentina has been highly procyclical, with expenditures growing closely in line with commodity export prices during the commodity price cycle of the 2000s (Kaminsky 2010; Tenreyro 2012). The lack of strong institutions and fiscal rules contributed to a deterioration in fiscal outcomes once the commodity price boom ended (Figure 12.B). As a result, the country has faced persistent fiscal challenges in the past decade (IMF 2020). Taken together, the country cases reviewed above yield the following insights. First, SWFs and fiscal rules differ among countries in objectives and design. SWFs can have a long-term purpose (such as the accumulation of pension funds) or a short-term one (such as dampening the impact of temporary economic shocks). Some rules are designed to make an SWF sustainable, others to make them accessible when needed (Bauer 2014; Richaud et al. 2019). This aspect plays an important role in procyclicality because the criteria governing accessibility will determine the extent to which a government can access 24 funds (and spend them). The sustainability conditions might also impose a limit on the amount that can be used even in times of need. Second, when supported by well-designed fiscal rules and institutions, SWFs can help reduce procyclicality. International experience suggests that a strong political commitment to fiscal discipline, as well as strong institutions of good governance, are needed for SWFs to work well. Countries with good corruption control and law and order have been able to construct effective SWFs that reduce procyclicality by serving as a buffer against revenue volatility or as a source of financing during downturns. In the cases of Norway (oil) and Chile (copper), commodity revenues are channeled directly into the SWFs, severing links from resource revenue to government spending. These funds are then available for specific purposes under certain conditions, avoiding or limiting fiscal procyclicality. In other cases, despite the presence of well-designed rules, the existence of escape clauses and weak institutions can render SWFs less useful (Perry 2007). These observations are in line with the findings of the analysis in this paper, which shows that weak institutions limit the ability of governments to follow countercyclical fiscal policy despite having fiscal tools at their disposal (Figure 13). Finally, commodity-exporters without SWFs or robust fiscal rules are more prone not only to procyclical fiscal behavior but also to debt sustainability issues. In both Indonesia and Argentina—both countries without an SWF—fiscal policies have been procyclical. 34 While Indonesia has benefited from a set of rules aimed at debt sustainability, the absence of rules in Argentina has allowed more discretionary spending policies that have contributed to successive crises. VII. Conclusions Many EMDEs are commodity-dependent—in terms of fiscal and export revenues as well as economic activity. The challenges posed by this commodity dependence have again been apparent in recent years because of gyrations in commodity prices, resulting partly from geopolitical tensions. These challenges are likely to be exacerbated in coming years as commodity prices become more volatile during the transition from fossil fuels to more climate-friendly sources of energy. If not adequately managed, the response of fiscal policy to this increased commodity price volatility is likely to impede growth. This paper focuses on two features of fiscal policy in commodity-exporting EMDEs—procyclicality and volatility. Fiscal policy tends to be both more procyclical and more volatile in EMDEs than in advanced economies, and more so in commodity exporters than in commodity importers. Fiscal procyclicality and volatility amplify the impact of commodity price shocks on the business cycle in EMDEs, with detrimental effects on economic growth. The paper offers insights for policy makers in commodity-exporting EMDEs about the appropriate design of fiscal policies and institutional frameworks. Both institutional and policy factors play important roles in explaining the cross-country variation in fiscal policy volatility. Greater government stability, stronger rule of law, easier access to international financial markets, greater exchange rate flexibility, and the presence of fiscal rules and SWFs have all been associated with lower fiscal policy volatility and procyclicality. The broader macroeconomic effects of commodity price fluctuations also depend on the policy mix, particularly the interaction of fiscal policy with monetary and exchange rate policies (IMF 2012b; World Bank 2022). Additionally, the role that commodity revenues play in the budgets of commodity-exporting 34 Indonesia established an SWF in 2021 that leverages state assets as well as public and private investment for infrastructure spending. It is not designed for fiscal stabilization. 25 EMDEs and their impact on fiscal policy volatility suggests potential benefits from diversification of their economies, away from production of commodities. 35 35For a detailed discussion, see Bleaney and Greenaway (2001); Ghosh and Ostry (1994); Hesse (2008); Gill et al. (2014); Joya (2015); and World Bank (2022). 26 Figure 1 Commodities: price volatility and importance for exports and revenues A. Commodity price movements since 2020 B. Share of EMDE exports of key commodities Percent Percent of exports 15 70 10 60 5 50 0 40 -5 30 20 -10 10 Copper Zinc Oil Coffee Cotton Nickel Wheat Aluminum Natural gas Rice 0 Oil Copper Coffee Natural gas C. Resource revenues as share of total fiscal D. Duration of commodity booms and slumps revenues Percent of fiscal revenues Months Booms Slumps 70 80 60 60 50 40 40 30 20 20 10 0 Energy Agriculture Metals 0 Energy Metal Agriculture exporters exporters exporters Sources: UNU-Wider; UN Comtrade (database); WITS (database); World Bank. Note: EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies; LICs = low-income countries. A. Bars show the average month-on-month change in commodity prices from January 2020 to November 2023. Whiskers show the interquartile ranges. The commodities used (from the World Bank’s Pink Sheet database) are crude oil (average of West Texas Intermediate, Brent, and Dubai); natural gas index; coffee, Arabica; rice, Thai 5 percent; wheat, U.S. hard red winter; cotton, A Index; aluminum; copper; nickel; and zinc. B. Panel displays the median export share of oil, copper, coffee, and natural gas for commodity-exporting EMDEs. The number of countries is 20 for oil, 6 for copper, 4 for coffee, and 5 for natural gas. Bars represent medians, while whiskers indicate interquartile ranges. C. Unweighted average of resource revenues as a percentage of fiscal revenues for EMDE commodity exporters: 30 for energy, 14 for metals, and 10 for agricultural commodities. Whiskers show the interquartile range. D. Duration measures the average length (in months) of a phase (boom or slump). Whiskers indicate minimum and maximum ranges. 27 Figure 2 Procyclicality of government expenditures A. Fiscal procyclicality: EMDEs versus advanced B. Fiscal procyclicality: EMDE commodity economies exporters versus commodity importers Correlation Correlation Commodity importers 1.0 0.6 *** *** *** 0.8 *** 0.4 0.6 0.4 0.2 *** 0.2 0.0 0.0 Commodity Agriculture exporters exporters exporters exporters Energy Metal -0.2 -0.4 AEs EMDEs C. Fiscal procyclicality in commodity exporters, by D. Fiscal procyclicality in commodity-exporters, regions by income groups Correlation Correlation 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 -0.1 0.0 -0.2 -0.3 -0.1 SAR SSA LAC EAP ECA MNA AEs LICs FCSs LMCs UMCs HICs E. Shifts in fiscal procyclicality, 1980-2020 F. Share of countries with procyclical fiscal policy Correlation 1980-2006 2007-2020 Percent Commodity importers 0.8 *** *** 100 Commodity exporters *** 0.6 0.4 *** 80 0.2 60 0.0 -0.2 40 -0.4 20 -0.6 LICs Commodity Commodity FCS 0 exporters importers 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Végh (2023); International Monetary Fund; World Bank. 28 Note: AEs = advanced economies; EAP = East Asia and Pacific; ECA = Europe and Central Asia; EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies; FCS = fragile and conflict-affected situations; HIC = high-income country; LAC = Latin America and the Caribbean; LIC = low-income country; LMC = lower-middle-income country; MNA = Middle East and North Africa; SAR = South Asia; SSA = Sub-Saharan Africa; UMC = upper-middle-income country. Bars show average correlation between the (Hodrick-Prescott-filtered) cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending within groups. The sample period is 1980–2020. A.-E. Bars show average correlation between the (Hodrick-Prescott-filtered) cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending within groups. The sample period is 1980-2020. A.B.E. Whiskers show the 25th and 75th percentiles. Black asterisk indicates a statistically significant difference in means. A. Sample includes 36 advanced economies and 146 EMDEs. *** indicates that the difference between the average correlation for the two country groups is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. B. Sample of EMDEs includes 87 commodity exporters (38 agricultural, 31 energy, and 21 metals) and 59 commodity importers. *** indicates that the difference between the average correlation for the particular country group and that for commodity importers is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. C.D. Panels show the average of the procyclicality measure for the various country groups. E. For 1980–2006, the sample includes 90 commodity exporters, 91 commodity importers, 22 LICs, and 31 FCS. For 2007-2020, it includes 95 commodity exporters, 95 commodity importers, 21 LICs, and 31 FCS. F. Share of countries with procyclical policies based on five-year rolling windows. Sample has 184 countries. 29 Figure 3 Fiscal procyclicality and macroeconomic factors in commodity-exporters A. Procyclicality in commodity-exporters, by B. Procyclicality in commodity exporters, by degree of capital controls exchange rate regime type Correlation Correlation 1.0 1.0 0.8 *** 0.8 *** 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.2 -0.2 Low High 0.0 Fixed Floating Capital controls Exchange rate Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Vegh (2023); Chinn and Ito (2006); Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff (2022); World Bank. Note: Bars show average correlation between the cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending within groups. The cyclical components are derived using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Vertical lines show 25th and 75th percentiles. A. Based on Chinn-Ito index of financial openness. A country is classified as having high (low) capital account restrictions if its Chinn-Ito index score is below (above) the median. Sample has 36 countries with low capital controls and 54 countries with high capital controls. *** indicates that the difference between the means for the two country groups is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. B. Sample has 63 countries with fixed exchange rates and 29 with floating rates, based on the classification in Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff (2022). The difference between the means for the two country groups is not statistically significant. 30 Figure 4 Fiscal procyclicality, fiscal rules, and institutional factors A. Procyclicality and political risk B. Procyclicality and quality of bureaucracy Correlation Correlation 0.8 0.8 *** *** 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.2 -0.2 Low High Low High Bureaucracy quality Political risk C. Procyclicality and corruption control D. Procyclicality and government stability Correlation Correlation 0.8 *** 0.8 *** 0.6 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 -0.2 0.0 Low High High Low Control of corruption Government stability E. Procyclicality and law and order F. Procyclicality and fiscal rules Correlation Correlation 0.8 *** 1.0 *** 0.8 *** 0.6 *** 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.2 Without With rules Without With rules Low High rules rules Law and order Commodity exporters Full sample 31 Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Vegh (2023); International Monetary Fund; PRS Group (database). Note: Bars show average correlation between the (Hodrick Prescott-filtered) cyclical components of real GDP and real government spending within groups. Vertical lines show 25th and 75th percentiles. A. Countries with high (low) political risk are defined as those with political risk above (below) the sample median. Sample has 49 countries with high political risk and 24 countries with low political risk. *** indicates that the difference between the means for the two country groups is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. B. Sample has 48 countries with low bureaucracy quality and 25 with high bureaucracy quality. The difference between the means for the two country groups is not statistically significant. C. Sample has 45 countries with low control of corruption and 28 with high control of corruption. *** indicates that the difference between the means for the two country groups is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. D. Sample has 32 countries with high government stability and four with low government stability. The difference between the means for the two country groups is not statistically significant. E. Sample has 24 countries with high scores (above sample median) for the law-and-order index and 49 countries with low (below sample median) scores. *** indicates that the difference between the means for the two country groups is statistically significant at the 10 percent level or better. F. For commodity exporters, the sample includes 28 countries with fiscal rules and 20 countries without fiscal rules. The entire sample includes 58 countries with fiscal rules and 47 countries without fiscal rules. The difference between the means for the two country groups (with and without fiscal rules) is statistically significant (indicated by ***) for the entire sample but not for the sample of commodity exporters. 32 Figure 5 The amplification effect of procyclical fiscal policy on output A. “Pours” as a fraction of “rains” in commodity B. "Pours " versus "rains ": 2003-08 commodity exporters cycle Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Végh (2023); International Monetary Fund; World Bank. Note: EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies. A.B. The sample has 4 advanced economies (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and Norway) and 11 EMDEs (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Indonesia, Russian Federation, South Africa, and Ukraine). A. Panel shows the change in GDP (in response to a commodity price shock) explained by the reaction of fiscal policy (the “pours’ component) as a share of the direct effect of the commodity price shock on output (the “rain” component). The average of these shares for commodity-exporting EMDEs and advanced economies is shown by the blue bars. Whiskers shows the minimum and maximum range. B. The orange bars represent the fraction of the change in GDP, in response to a commodity price shock, explained by the reaction of fiscal policy to the shock, averaged at the aggregate level. The red bars show the direct effect of a commodity price shock on GDP. 33 Figure 6 Fiscal policy volatility A. Fiscal volatility: Advanced economies versus B. Fiscal volatility: EMDE commodity exporters EMDEs versus importers Percent Percent Commodity importers Advanced economies 16 Commodity exporters 10 EMDEs 14 8 12 10 6 8 6 4 4 2 2 0 0 balance Revenues consumption expenditures Primary Government Primary balance Revenues consumption expenditures Primary Government Primary C. Evolution of fiscal volatility in EMDEs D. Evolution of fiscal volatility in advanced economies Percent 1980-2006 2007-2020 Percent 1980-2006 2007-2020 14 6 12 5 10 4 8 6 3 4 2 2 1 0 0 balance Government Government consumption Primary Government expenditure balance Government Government consumption Primary Government expenditure revenue revenue E. Fiscal volatility: LICs versus non-LICs F. Expenditure volatility in commodity- exporters, by regions Percent LICs Non-LICs Percent 30 16 25 20 15 12 10 5 8 0 balance Government Government consumption Primary Government expenditure 4 revenue 0 SSA MNA EAP LAC SAR ECA AEs Sources: Arroyo Marioli, Fatás, and Vasishtha (2023); IMF WEO database; World Bank. 34 Note: AEs = advanced economies; EAP = East Asia and Pacific; ECA = Europe and Central Asia; EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies; LAC = Latin America and the Caribbean; LIC = low-income country; MNA = Middle East and North Africa; PPP = purchasing power parity; SAR = South Asia; SSA = Sub-Saharan Africa. A.B. Panels show weighted averages (A) and simple averages (B), by country group, of the standard deviations of the residuals obtained from regressing four dependent variables—log differences of real primary expenditures, real government consumption, real revenues, and the change in primary balance (percent of GDP)—on real GDP growth. Weights used are the PPP GDP shares in the respective group’s total GDP. Annual data for 36 advanced economies and 148 EMDEs over 1990–2021. C.D.E. Panels show the weighted averages of the standard deviations of the residuals obtained from regressing four variables—log differences of real primary expenditures, real government consumption, real revenues, and the change in primary balance (percent of GDP)—on real GDP growth. Weights used are the PPP GDP shares in the respective group’s total GDP. Annual data for 35 advanced economies and 142 EMDEs over 1980-2006, and 36 advanced economies and 144 EMDEs over 2007-20. Annual data for 22 LICs and 156 non-LICs. F. Panel shows the average (unweighted) volatility in commodity exporters in each country group. 35 Figure 7 Exchange rate regimes and capital account openness A. Exchange rate regime flexibility in EMDEs B. Capital account openness Index Commodity importers 1.0 Percent Hard peg Soft peg Floating Commodity exporters 100 0.8 80 0.6 60 0.4 40 0.2 20 0.0 0 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 1990 2019 1990 2019 Commodity exporters Commodity importers Sources: Chinn and Ito (2006); Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff (2022); World Bank. A. Panel shows the share of EMDEs with hard peg, soft peg, and floating exchange rate regimes, based on the classification in Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff (2022). B. Based on Chinn-Ito index of financial openness. The lines represent the average of the index in the represented year. Sample includes 98 commodity importers and 98 commodity exporters. 36 Figure 8 Fiscal policy volatility and procyclicality A. Correlation between fiscal volatility and B. Correlation between fiscal volatility and procyclicality procyclicality over time Correlation Percent 1980-2006 2007-2020 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 World Commodity Commodity EMDEs AEs exporters importers World AEs EMDEs Commodity Commodity exporters importers C. Correlation between fiscal volatility and D. Correlation between fiscal volatility and procyclicality, by income groups procyclicality, by regions Correlation Correlation 0.4 0.6 *** *** *** *** *** 0.3 *** *** 0.3 *** 0.2 *** *** 0.0 0.1 *** 0.0 -0.3 UMCs HICs LICs LMCs ECA MNA EAP AEs LAC SSA SAR Sources: International Monetary Fund; World Bank. Note: AEs = advanced economies; EAP = East Asia and Pacific; ECA = Europe and Central Asia; EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies; HIC = high-income country; LAC = Latin America and the Caribbean; LIC = low- income country; LMC = lower-middle-income country; MNA = Middle East and North Africa; SAR = South Asia; SSA = Sub-Saharan Africa; UMC = upper middle-income country. A.B.C.D. Bars represent the correlation between fiscal procyclicality and the measure of volatility that does not exclude the effect of the business cycle on fiscal policy changes. A.C.D. Blue diamonds and asterisks represent statistical significance. 37 Figure 9 Fiscal volatility, growth, and fiscal frameworks A. EMDE annual per capita growth B. Fiscal rules and SWFs Percentage points Number Commodity importers 2.0 80 Commodity exporters 70 1.5 60 50 1.0 40 30 0.5 20 10 0.0 0 EMDE growth With AE Total 1990 2010 2020 1990 2010 2020 policies Fiscal rules SWFs C. Types of fiscal rules in commodity exporters D. Share of fiscal rules, by type of commodity exporter Number Revenue rules Percent Expenditure rules 45 100 40 Debt rules 80 Budget balance rules 35 30 60 25 20 40 15 20 10 5 0 0 Agricultural Energy Metal 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 exporters exporters exporters E. Assets under management by SWFs in commodity exporters, by region, 2022 US$, billions 3,500 3,000 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 MNA AEs ECA EAP SSA LAC Sources: Davoodi et al. (2022); International Monetary Fund; Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute. 38 Note: AEs = advanced economies; EAP = East Asia and Pacific; ECA = Europe and Central Asia; EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies; LAC = Latin America and the Caribbean; MNA = Middle East and North Africa; SSA = Sub-Saharan Africa; SWF = sovereign wealth fund. A. The middle column in the panel illustrates how applying the average advanced-economy policies along three dimensions (exchange rate regimes, capital account openness, and fiscal rules) impacts GDP per capita growth in the average commodity-exporting EMDE. The last column shows the total commodity-exporting EMDE growth with these advanced-economy policies. B. Number of EMDES with fiscal rules and SWFs (sovereign wealth funds). C. Panel shows types of fiscal rules over time for commodity-exporting countries. The sample consists of four advanced economies and 44 emerging market and developing economies. D. Panel shows the share of EMDEs with fiscal rules according to commodity exporter type, as of 2021. E. Panel shows the amount of SWF assets under management in commodity-exporting countries, as of 2022. 39 Figure 10 Fiscal expenditure and SWFs in Australia and Norway A. Australia B. Norway Percent Fiscal expenditure Index Percent Fiscal expenditure $/bbl SWF SWF 120 50 140 300 Oil price (RHS) Commodity export price (RHS) 100 120 250 40 100 80 200 30 80 60 150 20 60 100 40 40 10 50 20 20 0 0 0 0 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Sources: Future Fund (website); International Monetary Fund; Norges Bank; World Bank. Note: bbl = billion barrels; SWF = sovereign wealth fund. A. B. Fiscal expenditure and assets under management of SWFs are expressed as percentages of GDP. 40 Figure 11 Fiscal expenditure and SWFs in Chile, Botswana, and Timor-Leste A. Chile B. Botswana Percent Fiscal expenditure $/mt Percent Index Fiscal expenditure SWF 40 10,000 SWF Copper price (RHS) Commodity export price (RHS) 35 80 140 8,000 30 70 120 25 6,000 60 100 20 50 80 15 4,000 40 30 60 10 20 40 2,000 5 10 20 0 0 0 0 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 C. Timor-Leste Index, 100 = 2008 Fiscal expenditure $/bbl 200 SWF 120 Oil price (RHS) 160 100 80 120 60 80 40 40 20 0 0 2008 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 Sources: Bank of Botswana; Fondo de Estabilización Económica y Social (website); International Monetary Fund; Timor-Leste Petroleum Fund (website);World Bank. Note: bbl = billion barrels; mt = metric ton; SWF = sovereign wealth fund. A.B. Fiscal expenditure and assets under management of SWFs are expressed as percentages of GDP. C. An index for fiscal expenditure and SWF assets under management was constructed starting in 2008. 41 Figure 12 Fiscal balance in Indonesia and Argentina A. Indonesia B. Argentina Percent Index Percent Index Fiscal balance Fiscal balance Commodity export price (RHS) Commodity export price (RHS) 20 140 6 120 15 120 4 100 100 2 10 0 80 80 5 -2 60 60 0 -4 40 40 -6 -5 20 -8 20 -10 0 -10 0 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 2021 Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Végh (2023); International Monetary Fund; World Bank. Note: EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies A.B. Fiscal balance as a percentage of GDP. Figure 13 Institutional quality and fiscal procyclicality Index Correlation Law and order Corruption control 7 Bureaucracy quality Correlation (RHS) 0.5 6 0.4 0.3 5 0.2 4 0.1 3 0 -0.1 2 -0.2 1 -0.3 0 -0.4 Australia Norway Chile EMDEs Sources: Arroyo Marioli and Végh (2023); International Monetary Fund; PRS Group (database); World Bank. Note: EMDEs = emerging market and developing economies. The institutional quality indexes give higher scores to countries with better metrics. “EMDEs” shows the simple average of 68 commodity-exporting countries across the 3 indicators from 1990-2019. The correlation is calculated between the GDP and the real government expenditure of a country after using the Hodrick-Prescott filter to remove the trend component of the time series. 42 Table 1 List of economies for analysis of fiscal procyclicality and volatility Commodity exporters Agriculture Metals Energy Argentina Armenia Algeria Belize Australia Angola Benin Botswana Azerbaijan Brazil Central African Republic Bahrain Burkina Faso Chile Bolivia Burundi Congo, Dem. Rep. Brunei Darussalam Cabo Verde Guinea Cameroon Chad Kyrgyz Republic Canada Comoros Liberia Chad Costa Rica Mauritania Colombia Côte d'Ivoire Mongolia Ecuador Ethiopia Mozambique Equatorial Guinea Fiji Namibia Gabon Guatemala Niger Ghana Guinea-Bissau Papua New Guinea Guyana Honduras Peru Indonesia Iceland Sierra Leone Iran, Islamic Rep. Kenya South Africa Iraq Lao PDR Sudan Kazakhstan Madagascar Suriname Kuwait Malawi Tajikistan Libya Mali Zambia Myanmar New Zealand Nigeria Nicaragua Norway Paraguay Oman Rwanda Qatar Senegal Russian Federation Seychelles Saudi Arabia Solomon Islands Timor-Leste Sudan Trinidad and Tobago Tajikistan United Arab Emirates Tanzania Togo Uganda Ukraine Uruguay Uzbekistan Note: Commodity exports of economies can change over time implying the possibility of re- categorization. 43 Commodity importers Albania Jordan Syrian Arab Republic Antigua and Barbuda Kiribati Taiwan, China Austria Korea, Rep. Thailand Bangladesh Latvia The Bahamas Barbados Lebanon Tonga Belarus Lesotho Tunisia Belgium Lithuania Türkiye Bhutan Luxembourg Tuvalu Bosnia and Herzegovina Malaysia United Kingdom Bulgaria Maldives United States Cambodia Malta Vanuatu China Marshall Islands Viet Nam Croatia Mauritius Cyprus Mexico Czechia Micronesia Denmark Moldova Djibouti Morocco Dominica Nepal Dominican Netherlands Egypt, Arab Rep. North Macedonia El Salvador Pakistan Eritrea Palau Estonia Panama Eswatini Philippines Finland Poland France Portugal Georgia Romania Germany Samoa Greece Serbia Grenada Singapore Hong Kong SAR, China Slovak Republic Hungary Slovenia India Spain Ireland Sri Lanka Israel St. Kitts and Nevis Italy St. Vincent and the Grenadines Jamaica Sweden Japan Switzerland Source: World Bank. 44 Table 2.A Variables for analysis of fiscal procyclicality Variable Description Source Government spending Real government expenditure IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) Political risk Index based on 12 components with varying weights: PRS Group (database) government stability, socioeconomic conditions, investment profile, internal conflict, external conflict, corruption, military in politics, religious tensions, law and order, ethnic tensions, democratic accountability, and bureaucracy quality. Bureaucracy quality Institutional strength and quality of the bureaucracy PRS Group (database) is a shock absorber that tends to minimize revisions of policy when governments change. In low-risk countries, the bureaucracy is somewhat autonomous from political pressure. Index measures the quality of bureaucracy from 0 to 6. Control of corruption A measure of corruption within the political system PRS Group (database) that is a threat to foreign investment by distorting the economic and financial environment, reducing the efficiency of government and business by enabling people to assume positions of power through patronage rather than ability, and introducing inherent instability into the political process. Index ranges from 0 to 6. Government stability A measure of both the government’s ability to carry PRS Group (database) out its declared program(s) and to stay in office. The risk rating assigned is the sum of three subcomponents: government unity, legislative strength, and popular support Law and order “Law” assesses the strength and impartiality of the PRS Group (database) legal system, while the “Order” element is an assessment of popular observance of the law. Capital account openness The Chinn-Ito index (KAOPEN) measuring a country’s Chinn and Ito (2006) degree of capital account openness; available from 1970-2019 for 182 countries. Exchange rate regime A dummy indicator, where “1” is a floating exchange Ilzetzki, Reinhart, and Rogoff rate regime and “0” is fixed. Classification codes 1-3 (2021) in the database have been classified as “0” and codes 4-6 as “1.” Openness Sum of exports and imports (percent of GDP) World Integrated Trade Solution (World Bank) Fiscal rules Covers four types of rules: budget balance rules, debt rules, expenditure rules, and revenue rules, applying to the central or general government or the public Davoodi et al. (2022) sector. SWF (sovereign wealth Dummy variable: “0” if a country does not have an https://www.swfinstitute.org/ fund) SWF and “1” if it has an SWF. fund-rankings/sovereign- wealth-fund 45 Table 2.B Variables for analysis of fiscal policy volatility Variable Description Source General government Consists of taxes, social contributions, grants IMF World Economic revenue receivable, and other revenue. Outlook (WEO) Primary balance Primary net lending/borrowing is net lending WEO /borrowing plus net interest payable/paid (interest expense minus interest revenue; percent of GDP) Primary expenditure Obtained by subtracting interest payments from WEO and authors’ general government total expenditures. Interest calculations payments are calculated as the difference between overall fiscal balance and the primary balance (all in percent of GDP). Government General government final consumption expenditure World Development consumption includes all government current expenditures for Indicators (World Bank) purchases of goods and services (including compensation of employees) and most expenditures on national defense and security; excludes government military expenditures that are part of government capital formation. Real GDP; real GDP WEO per capita Political constraints The Political Constraints Index (POLCON) measures POLCON data set (Henisz the extent to which policy changes are constrained 2000) by institutional and political factors. Control of corruption An index measuring corruption within the political International Country Risk system; ranges from 0 to 6. Guide (ICRG) Government size General government total expenditure (percent of WEO GDP) Investment price Price level of investment Penn World Table Capital account The Chinn-Ito index (KAOPEN) measuring a country’s Chinn and Ito (2006) openness degree of capital account openness; available from 1970-2019 for 182 countries. Openness Sum of exports and imports (percent of GDP) World Integrated Trade Solution (World Bank) Resources rents Sum of oil rents, natural gas rents, coal rents (hard World Development and soft), mineral rents, and forest rents. The Indicators (World Bank) estimates of natural resource rents are calculated as the difference between the price of a commodity and the average cost of producing it. Fiscal rules Covers four types of rules: budget balance rules, Davoodi et al. (2002) debt rules, expenditure rules, and revenue rules, applying to the central or general government or the public sector. SWF (sovereign Dummy variable: 0 if a country does not have an https://www.swfinstitute. wealth fund) SWF and 1 if it has an SWF. org/fund- rankings/sovereign- 46 Table 3 Drivers of fiscal procyclicality Dependent variable: Correlation between real government spending and real GDP (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Financial openness -0.25** -0.19 Corruption control -0.12*** -0.07 Political constraint index -0.47** -0.08 GDP volatility 1.58** 1.26 F-test ** Observations 92 74 92 97 72 R-squared 0.05 0.13 0.05 0.06 0.18 Source: World Bank. Note: Cross-sectional OLS regressions for commodity exporters. For regression (5), the F-test evaluates the joint significance of financial openness, corruption control, and GDP volatility. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent level, respectively. 47 Table 4 Institutional drivers of fiscal procyclicality Dependent variable: Correlation between real government spending and real GDP (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Government stability -0.09** -0.01 -0.07 Law and order -0.13*** -0.12*** -0.06 Fiscal rules -0.61*** -2.11*** -0.31** -1.26** Sovereign wealth -0.53** -0.37** -0.21 funds F-test *** *** Observations 137 137 106 194 83 83 83 R-squared 0.05 0.24 0.17 0.13 n/r 0.47 0.15 Source: World Bank. Note: Cross-sectional regressions for the full sample. The estimates in columns (1)-(4) and (6) are based on OLS regressions. The estimates shown in columns (5) and (7) are based on instrumental variables (two-stage least squares) regressions. ‘n/r’ means not reported by STATA. For regressions (6) and (7), the F-test evaluates the joint significance of the three institutional variables. The last row in columns (7) shows the centered R-squared. Overidentification tests do not apply to regressions (5) and (7) since equations are perfectly identified. In these regressions, the first-stage F-test of excluded instruments implies rejection of the null hypothesis of weak identification (p-value = 0.00) in both cases. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent level, respectively. 48 Table 5 Output growth and commodity prices Dependent variable: GDP growth (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EMDEs Full sample Commodity export price 0.085*** 0.063*** 0.080*** 0.024 0.018 0.026 index Terms of trade 0.029 0.026 GDP growth (t-1) 0.367*** 0.366*** Commodity export price 0.062** 0.046* 0.054** index x EMDE F-test *** *** *** Observations 381 364 370 533 436 518 Countries 11 11 11 15 15 15 Source: World Bank. Note: Panel least squares with country fixed effects. All variables are in log-differences. The estimates in columns (1)-(3) are based on the sample of emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs) only while those in columns (4)-(6) are based on the full sample that includes advanced-economy commodity exporters. F-test in columns (4)-(6) evaluates the joint significance of commodity export price index and the interaction of the index with the dummy variables for EMDEs. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10, 5, and 1 percent, respectively. GDP = gross domestic product. 49 Table 6 Government spending and commodity prices Dependent variable: Real government spending (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) EMDEs Full sample Commodity export 0.061* 0.08* 0.061* -0.123*** -0.072 -0.121*** price index Terms of trade -0.060 -0.072 GDP growth (t-1) 0.688*** 0.625*** Commodity export 0.184*** 0.158*** 0.183*** price index x EMDE F-test *** ** *** Observations 276 269 276 415 341 413 Countries 11 11 11 15 15 15 Source: World Bank. Note: Panel least squares with country fixed effects. All variables are in log-differences. The estimates in columns (1)-(3) are based on the sample of emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs) only while those in columns (4)-(6) are based on the full sample that includes advanced-economy commodity exporters. F-test in columns (4)-(6) evaluates the joint significance of commodity export price index and the interaction of the index with the dummy variables for EMDEs. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 percent, respectively. GDP = gross domestic product. 50 Table 7 Determinants of fiscal policy volatility: Cross-sectional regressions Dependent variable: Primary expenditure volatility (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) EMDE 4.930*** 1.756** -2.381* -0.398 0.536 -1.255 (0.657) (0.870) (1.266) (1.276) (1.151) (0.970) Commodity exporters 3.295*** -1.053 0.661 3.356*** 0.0398 1.082 (0.852) (0.845) (0.747) (1.134) (0.849) (0.753) Resource rents 0.376*** 0.281*** 0.543*** 0.402*** (0.0814) (0.0688) (0.180) (0.0678) GDP per capita -1.240*** -0.548 1.023 0.282 (0.423) (0.464) (1.091) (0.651) SWF -0.324 -0.349 (0.832) (0.703) Political constraints -11.27*** -3.596 3.963 (2.502) (3.224) (4.676) Control of corruption -1.997*** -1.836*** -0.761* (0.421) (0.570) (0.388) Fiscal policy rules -0.947*** -1.040** -0.694** (0.348) (0.411) (0.308) Capital account openness -7.312*** -4.256** -4.202** (2.574) (1.729) (1.666) Exchange rate regime -4.722*** -4.541*** -3.206*** (1.093) (1.294) (0.857) Constant 3.930*** 17.390*** 17.92*** 19.44*** 14.04*** 0.928 8.710 (0.460) (4.495) (1.305) (5.025) (2.836) (10.191) (5.579) Observations 178 177 133 132 93 93 77 R-squared 0.219 0.451 0.394 0.595 0.371 0.636 0.713 Source: World Bank. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. ‘EMDE’ is a dummy variable that takes the value 1 if a country is classified as an EMDE, and 0 otherwise. ‘Commodity exporters’ is a dummy variable representing whether a country is a commodity exporter or not. ‘SWF’ is a dummy equal to 1 if a country has a sovereign wealth fund and 0 otherwise. 51 Table 8 Determinants of fiscal policy volatility; by type of commodity Dependent variable: Primary expenditure volatility (1) (2) EMDE 2.900*** 1.794** (1.047) (0.867) Agriculture exporters 0.712 -0.592 (0.983) (1.036) Metal exporters 2.236* -0.136 (1.337) (1.353) Energy exporters 6.185*** -1.125 (1.625) (1.252) GDP per capita -1.243** -1.114** (0.523) (0.453) Resources rents 0.377*** (0.089) Constant 17.081*** 16.017*** (5.593) (4.818) Observations 177 177 R-squared 0.292 0.450 Source: World Bank. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. "Agriculture exporters," "metal exporters," and "energy exporters" are dummy variables that take the value 1 if a country is a net exporter of the respective commodity group, and 0 otherwise. 52 Table 9 Effects of fiscal policy volatility on GDP per capita growth Dependent variable: GDP per capita growth (1) (2) (3) (4) Fiscal policy volatility -0.022 -0.116*** -0.110*** 0.079* (0.060) (0.022) (0.036) (0.042) Government size 0.013 0.020 0.015 (0.012) (0.013) (0.012) Initial GDP per capita -0.659*** -0.767*** -0.774*** (0.138) (0.147) (0.138) Capital account openness 1.210*** 1.230*** 0.930*** (0.302) (0.314) (0.342) Investment price -1.481*** -1.548*** -1.546*** (0.392) (0.432) (0.318) Commodity exporter -0.734** (0.318) Constant 1.986*** 8.416*** 9.202*** 9.708*** (0.533) (1.157) (1.332) (1.284) Observations 177 161 128 128 R-squared 0.006 0.356 0.403 0.433 Source: World Bank. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Fiscal policy volatility in all specifications is measured using primary expenditures. The estimates in columns (1) and (2) are based on ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. Columns (3) and (4) is based on instrumental variables (IV) estimation, with the "political constraints" and "control of corruption" used as instruments. 53 References Afonso, A., and D. Furceri. 2008. “Government Size, Composition, Volatility and Economic Growth.” Working Paper Series 849, European Central Bank, Frankfurt. Aghion, P., D. Hemous, and E. Kharroubi. 2014. “Cyclical Fiscal Policy, Credit Constraints, and Industry Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 62: 41-58. Al-Hassan, A., S. Brake, M.G. Papaioannou, and M. Skancke. 2018. “Commodity-based Sovereign Wealth Funds: Managing Financial Flows in the Context of the Sovereign Balance Sheet.” IMF Working Paper 18/26, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Al-Sadiq, A., P. Bejar, and I. Otker. 2021. “Commodity Shocks and Exchange Rate Regimes: Implications for the Caribbean Commodity Exporters. IMF Working Paper 21/104, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Alesina, A., F. Campante, and G. Tabellini. 2008. “Why is Fiscal Policy Often Procyclical?” Journal of the European Economic Association 6 (5):1006-36. Allen, R., T. Chaponda, L. Fisher, and R. Ray. 2017. “Medium-Term Budget Frameworks in Sub-Saharan African Countries.” IMF Working Paper 17/203, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Alvarez, R., and J. De Gregorio. 2014. “Understanding Differences in Growth Performance in Latin America and Developing Countries between the Asian and the Global Financial Crises.” IMF Economic Review 62 (4): 494-525. Álvarez, R., Á. García-Marín, and S. Ilabaca. 2021. “Commodity Price Shocks and Poverty Reduction in Chile.” Resources Policy 70 (March): 101177. Apeti, A. E., O. Basdevant, and V. Salins. 2023. “Do Fiscal Rules Foster Fiscal Discipline in Resource-Rich Countries?” IMF Working Paper 23/088, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Ardanaz, M., E. A. Cavallo, and A. Izquierdo. 2023. Fiscal Rules: Challenges and Reform Opportunities for Emerging Markets. IDB Working Paper 1443, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. Arezki, R., and M. Bruckner. 2010. “Commodity Windfalls, Polarization, and Net Foreign Assets: Panel Data Evidence on the Voracity Effect.” IMF Working Paper 10/209, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Arezki, R., K. Hamilton, and K. Kazimov. 2011. “Resource Windfalls, Macroeconomic Stability and Economic Growth.” IMF Working Paper 11/142, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Arezki, R., C. A. Pattillo, M. G. Quintyn, and M. Zhu. 2012. Commodity Price Volatility and Inclusive Growth in Low-Income Countries. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Arroyo Marioli, F., A. Fatás, and G. Vasishtha. 2023. “Fiscal Policy Volatility and Growth in Emerging Markets and Developing Economies.” Policy Research Working Paper 10409, World Bank, Washington, DC. Arroyo Marioli, F., and C. A. Végh. 2023. “Fiscal Procyclicality in Commodity Exporting Countries: How Much Does it Pour and Why?” NBER Working Paper 3143, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Asik, A. 2017. “Effectiveness of Stabilization Funds in Managing Volatility in Oil-Rich Countries.” 54 Unpublished Manuscript, TOBB Economics and Technology University, Ankara, Türkiye. Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 1-27. Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2013. “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion.” In Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, edited by A. Alesina and F. Giavazzi, 63-102. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Badinger, H., and W. H. Reuter. 2017. “The Case for Fiscal Rules.” Economic Modelling 60 (January): 334- 43. Bagattini, G. 2011. “The Political Economy of Stabilization Funds: Measuring Their Success in Resource Dependent Countries.” IDS Working Paper 356, Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex, Brighton, U.K. Barro, R. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 407–43. Basdevant, O. 2008. “Are Diamonds forever? Using the Permanent Income Hypothesis to Analyze Botswana’s Reliance on Diamond Revenue.” IMF Working Paper 08/80, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Bauer, A. 2014. “Fiscal Rules for Natural Resource Funds: How to Develop and Operationalize an Appropriate Rule.” Policy Brief, Revenue Watch Institute, Vale Columbia Center on Sustainable International Investment, New York. Bergman, U. M., and M. Hutchison. 2015. "Economic Stabilization in The Post-crisis World: Are Fiscal Rules The Answer?" Journal of International Money and Finance 52 (April): 82-101. Bergman, U. M., M. Hutchison, and E. H. Jensen. 2016. “Promoting Sustainable Public Finances in the European Union: The Role of Fiscal Rules and Government Efficiency.” European Journal of Political Economy 44 (September): 1-19. Bhattacharyya, S., and J. G. Williamson. 2011. “Commodity Price Shocks and the Australian Economy since Federation.” Australian Economic History Review 51 (2): 150-77. Blanchard, O., and R. Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1329-68. Bleaney, M., and D. Greenaway. 2001. “The Impact of Terms of Trade and Real Exchange Volatility on Investment and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal of Development Economics 65 (2): 491-500. Bleaney, M., and H. Halland. 2009. “The Resource Curse and Fiscal Policy Volatility.” Discussion Paper 09/09, Centre for Research in Economic Development and International Trade, University of Nottingham, Nottingham, U.K. Blöndal, J., I. Hawkesworth, and H. Choi. 2009. "Budgeting in Indonesia." OECD Journal on Budgeting 9 (2). Bova, E., N. Carcenac, and M. Guerguil. 2014. “Fiscal Rules and the Procyclicality of Fiscal Policy in the Developing World.” IMF Working Paper 14/122, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Bova, M. E., M. P. A. Medas, and M. T. Poghosyan. 2016. “Macroeconomic Stability in Resource-Rich Countries: The Role of Fiscal Policy.” IMF Working Paper 16/36, International Monetary Fund, 55 Washington, DC. Budina, N., T. Kinda, A. Schaechter, and A. Weber. 2013. “Numerical Fiscal Rules: International Trends." In Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture, edited by M. Cangiano, T. Curristine, and M. Lazare. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Calderón, C., R. Duncan, and K. Schmidt‐Hebbel. 2016. “Do Good Institutions Promote Countercyclical Macroeconomic Policies?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 78 (5): 650-70. Calderón, C., and K. Schmidt-Hebbel. 2008. “Business Cycles and Fiscal Policies: The Role of Institutions and Financial Markets.” Working Paper 481, Central Bank of Chile. Carneiro, F., and L. Garrido. 2016. “Revisiting the Evidence on the Cyclicality of Fiscal Policy Across the World.” MFM Discussion Paper 16, World Bank, Washington, DC. Caselli, F., and J. Reynaud. 2020. “Do Fiscal Rules Cause Better Fiscal Balances? A New Instrumental Variable Strategy.” European Journal of Political Economy 63 (June): 101873. Céspedes, L. F., and A. Velasco. 2014. “Was this Time Different? Fiscal Policy in Commodity Republics.” Journal of Development Economics 106 (C): 92–106. Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2006. "What Matters for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Institutions, and Interactions." Journal of Development Economics 81 (1): 163-92. Chohan, U. W. 2017. “What Is a Charter of Budget Honesty? The Case of Australia.” Canadian Parliamentary Review 40 (1): 11-15. Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2005. “Resource Rents, Governance, and Conflict.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (August): 625–33. Commonwealth of Australia. 2014. “Charter of Budget Honesty Act 1998.” Office of Parliamentary Counsel, Canberra. Coutinho, L., D. Georgiou, M. Heracleous, A. Michaelides, and S. Tsani. 2022. “Limiting Fiscal Procyclicality: Evidence from Resource-Dependent Countries.” Economic Modelling 106 (January): 105700. Dabla-Norris, E., R. Allen, L. Zanna, T. Prakash, E. Kvintradze, V. Lledo, I. Yackovlev, and S. Gollwitzer. 2010. “Budget Institutions and Fiscal Performance in Low-Income Countries.” IMF Working Paper 10/80, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Dahan, M., and M. Strawczynski. 2013. “Fiscal Rules and the Composition of Government Expenditures in OECD Countries.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 32 (3): 484-504. Davoodi, H., P. Elger, A. Fotiou, D. Garcia-Macia, A. Lagerborg, R. Lam, and S. Pillai. 2022. "Fiscal Rules Dataset: 1985-2021." International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Debrun, X., and M. Kumar. 2008. "Fiscal Rules, Fiscal Councils and All That: Commitment Devices, Signaling Tools or Smokescreens?" Workshop proceedings, Banca d’Italia, “Public Finance,” Rome. Debrun, X., L. Moulin, A. Turrini, J. Ayuso-i-Casals, and M. S. Kumar. 2008. “Tied to the Mast? National Fiscal Rules in the European Union.” Economic Policy 23 (54): 298–362. Elberry, N. A., and S. Goeminne. 2021. “Fiscal Transparency, Fiscal Forecasting and Budget Credibility in Developing Countries.” Journal of Forecasting 40 (1): 144-61. 56 Estrades, C., and M. I. Terra. 2012. “Commodity Prices, Trade, and Poverty in Uruguay.” Food Policy 37 (1): 58-66. Fabrizio, S., and A. Mody. 2006. "Can Budget Institutions Counteract Political Indiscipline?" Economic Policy 21 (48): 689-739. Fatás, A., and I. Mihov. 2003. “The Case for Restricting Fiscal Policy Discretion.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4): 1419-47. Fatás, A., and I. Mihov. 2007. “Fiscal Discipline, Volatility and Growth.” In Fiscal Policy, Stabilization, and Growth: Prudence or Abstinence?, edited by L. Serven, G. Perry, and R. Suescun. Washington, DC: World Bank. Fatás, A., and I. Mihov. 2013. “Policy Volatility, Institutions, and Economic Growth.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (2): 362-376. Fernández, A., D. Guzman, R. E. Lama, and C. A. Vegh. 2021. “Procyclical Fiscal Policy and Asset Market Incompleteness.” NBER Working Paper 29149, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Filc, G., and C. Scartascini. 2010. “Is Latin America on the Right Track? An Analysis of Medium-Term Frameworks and the Budget Process.” IDB Working Paper 160, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. Fondo de Estabilización Económica y Social (website). Ministerio de Hacienda, Santiago, Chile. Accessed on August 31, 2023. https://www.hacienda.cl/areas-de-trabajo/finanzas-internacionales/fondos- soberanos/fondo-de-estabilizacion-economica-y-social Frankel, J. A. 2011. “A Solution to Fiscal Procyclicality: The Structural Budget Institutions Pioneered by Chile.” NBER Working Paper 16945, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Frankel, J., C. A. Vegh, and G. Vuletin. 2013. “On Graduation from Fiscal Procyclicality.” Journal of Development Economics 100 (1): 32-47. Future Fund (website). Australia’s Sovereign Wealth Fund, Future Fund Management Agency, Melbourne, Australia. Accessed on August 31, 2023. https://www.futurefund.gov.au/ Ghosh, A. R., and J. D. Ostry. 1994. “Export Instability and the External Balance in Developing Countries.” IMF Staff Papers 41 (2): 214-35. Gill, I. S., I. Izvorski, W. van Eeghen, and D. De Rosa. 2014. Diversified Development: Making the Most of Natural Resources in Eurasia. Washington, DC: World Bank. Hansen, D. 2020. “The Effectiveness of Fiscal Institutions: International Financial Flogging or Domestic Constraint?” European Journal of Political Economy 63 (June): 101879. Hesse, H. 2008. “Export Diversification and Economic Growth.” Commission on Growth and Development Working Paper 21, World Bank, Washington, DC. Ilzetzki, E. 2011. “Rent-seeking Distortions and Fiscal Procyclicality.” Journal of Development Economics 96(1): 30-46. Ilzetzki, E., E. Mendoza, and C. A. Vegh. 2013. “How Big (Small?) are Fiscal Multipliers?” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2): 239-54. 57 Ilzetzki, E., C. M. Reinhart, and K. Rogoff. 2022. “Rethinking Exchange Rate Regimes.” In Handbook of International Economics 6, edited by G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, and K. Rogoff, 91-145. Amsterdam: Elsevier. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2004. World Economic Outlook. October. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2009. “Indonesia: Selected Issues.” IMF Country Report 09/231, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2012a. World Economic Outlook: Commodity Price Swings and Commodity Exporters. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2012b. Macroeconomic Policy Frameworks for Resource-Rich Developing Countries. IMF Background Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2015a. World Economic Outlook: Uneven Growth: Short-and Long- Term Factors. April. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2015b. Fiscal Monitor: The Commodities Roller Coaster. A Fiscal Framework for Uncertain Times. Chapter 1. October. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2020. “Argentina: Technical Assistance Report-Staff Technical Note on Public Debt Sustainability.” IMF Country Report 20/83, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Ismal, R. 2011. “Assessing Economic Growth and Fiscal Policy in Indonesia.” East-West Journal of Economics and Business 14 (1): 53-71. Izquierdo, A., E. Talvi, L. Catão, E. Cavallo, and A. Powell. 2008. “All That Glitters May Not be Gold: Assessing Latin America’s Recent Macroeconomic Performance.” Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. Jacks, D. S., K. H. O'Rourke, and J. G. Williamson. 2011. “Commodity Price Volatility and World Market Integration Since 1700.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (3): 800-813. Jalles, J. T., Y. Kiendrebeogo, W. R. Lam, and R. Piazza. 2023. “Revisiting the Countercyclicality of Fiscal Policy.” IMF Working Paper 23/89, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Jefferis, K. 2016. “Public finance and mineral revenues in Botswana” Technical Report. Waves Partnership Botswana Program. Joya, O. 2015. “Growth and Volatility in Resource-Rich Countries: Does Diversification Help?” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 35 (December): 38-55. Kaminsky, G. L. 2010. “Terms of Trade Shocks and Fiscal Cycles.” NBER Working Paper 15780, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Kaminsky, G. L., C. M. Reinhart, and C. A. Vegh. 2004. “When it Rains, It Pours: Procyclical Capital Flows and Macroeconomic Policies.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 19: 11-53. Koh, W. C. 2017. “Fiscal Policy in Oil‐Exporting Countries: The Roles of Oil Funds and Institutional Quality.” Review of Development Economics 21 (3): 567-590. Kojo, N. C. 2010. “Diamonds are Not Forever: Botswana Medium-Term Fiscal Sustainability.” Policy Research Working Paper 5480, World Bank, Washington, DC. 58 Kose, M. A., E. S. Prasad, and M. E. Terrones. 2005. “Growth and Volatility in an Era of Globalization.” IMF Staff Papers 52 (Suppl 1): 31-63. Kose, M. A., E. Prasad, K. Rogoff, and S. J. Wei. 2010. “Financial Globalization and Economic Policies.” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by D. Rodrik and M. Rosenzweig, Vol. 5: 4283-362. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier. Lam, R. W., Y. Cao, A. Lagerborg, and A. Scipioni. 2023. “Chile Technical Assistance Report– Fiscal Considerations in Managing Stabilization Funds.” IMF Country Report 23/249, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Lane, P. R. 2003. “The Cyclical Behaviour of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the OECD.” Journal of Public Economics (87): 2661-75. Le Borgne, E., and P. A. Medas. 2007. “Sovereign Wealth Funds in The Pacific Island Countries: Macro- Fiscal Linkages.” IMF Working Paper 07/297, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Markowitz, C. 2020. “Sovereign Wealth Funds in Africa: Taking Stock and Looking Forward.” Occasional Paper 304, South African Institute of International Affairs, Johannesburg. Martorano, B. 2018. “Cyclicality of Fiscal Policy in Latin America Over the Period 1990‐2015.” Review of Development Economics 22 (1): 67-90. Medina, L. 2010. “The Dynamic Effects of Commodity Prices on Fiscal Performance in Latin America.” IMF Working Paper 10/192, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Mohaddes, K., and M. Raissi. 2017. “Do Sovereign Wealth Funds Dampen the Negative Effects of Commodity Price Volatility?” Journal of Commodity Markets 8 (December): 18-27. Ossowski, R., M. Villafuerte, P. A. Medas, and T. Thomas. 2008. “Managing the Oil Revenue Boom: The Role of Fiscal Institutions.” IMF Occasional Paper 260, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Perry, G. E., ed. 2007. Fiscal Policy, Stabilization, and Growth: Prudence or Abstinence? Washington, DC: World Bank. Ramey, G., and V. A. Ramey. 1995. “Cross-country Evidence on the Link Between Volatility and Growth.” American Economic Review 85 (5): 1138–51. Raudla, R., J. W. Douglas, and M. MacCarthaigh. 2022. “Medium‐Term Expenditure Frameworks: Credible Instrument or Mirage?” Public Budgeting & Finance 42 (3): 71-92. Richaud, C., A. G. M. Galego, F. Ayivodji, S. Matta, and S. Essl. 2019. “Fiscal Vulnerabilities in Commodity Exporting Countries and the Role of Fiscal Policy.” MTI Discussion Paper 15, World Bank, Washington DC. Sachs, J. D., and A. M. Warner. 1995. “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.” NBER Working Paper 5398, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Sala-i-Martin, X., G. Doppelhofer, and R. Miller. 2004. “Determinants of Long-Term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE) Approach.” American Economic Review 94 (4): 813–35. Schiavo‐Campo, S. 2009. “Potemkin Villages: The Medium‐Term Expenditure Framework in Developing Countries.” Public Budgeting & Finance 29 (2): 1-26. Shabsigh, G., and N. Ilahi. 2007. “Looking beyond the Fiscal: Do Oil Funds Bring Macroeconomic Stability?” IMF Working Paper 07/96, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. 59 Sugawara, N. 2014. “From Volatility to Stability in Expenditure: Stabilization Funds in Resource-Rich Countries.” IMF Working Paper 14/43, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Talvi, E., and C. A. Végh. 2005. “Tax Base Variability and Procyclical Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries.” Journal of Development Economics 78 (1): 156-90. Tapsoba, R. 2012. “Do National Numerical Fiscal Rules Really Shape Fiscal Behaviours in Developing Countries? A Treatment Effect Evaluation.” Economic Modelling 29 (4): 1356-69. Tenreyro, S. 2012. The Argentine Crisis in Retrospect. London School of Economics and Political Sciences. Timor-Leste Petroleum Fund (website). The Timor-Leste Institute for Development Monitoring and Analysis, Dili, Timor-Leste. Accessed on August 31, 2023. https://www.laohamutuk.org/Oil/PetFund/05PFIndex.htm Tornell, A., and P. R. Lane. 1999. “The Voracity Effect.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 22-46. Tornell, A., and A. Velasco. 2000. “Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates: Which Provides More Fiscal Discipline?” Journal of Monetary Economics 45: 399-436. UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). 2021. “Global Investment Trend Monitor 39.” World Investment Forum Factsheet Edition. October. https://unctad.org/system/files/ official-document/diaeiainf2021d2_en.pdf. Van der Ploeg, F. 2011. “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?” Journal of Economic Literature 49 (2): 366– 420. Vegh, C. A., and G. Vuletin. 2014. “The Road to Redemption: Policy Response to Crises in Latin America.” IMF Economic Review 62 (4): 526-68. Velculescu, D. 2008. “Norway’s Oil Fund Shows the Way for Wealth Funds.” IMF Survey Magazine 9: 600- 03. Vlaicu, R., M. Verhoeven, F. Grigoli, and Z. Mills. 2014. “Multiyear Budgets and Fiscal Performance: Panel Data Evidence.” Journal of Public Economics 111 (March): 79-95. Von Hagen, J. 2010. “Sticking to Fiscal Plans: The Role of Institutions.” Public Choice 144: 487-503. World Bank. 1998. “Public Expenditure Management Handbook.” Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2009. Global Economic Prospects: Commodities at the Crossroads. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2013. Beyond the Annual Budget: Global Experience with Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2016. Public Finance and Mineral Revenues in Botswana Technical Report. Washington, DC: World Bank. Available at https://econsult.co.bw/tempex/file/Mineral%20revenues%20and%20public%20finance_final_compress ed.pdf. World Bank. 2017. “The Republic of Chile: Systematic Country Diagnostic.” World Bank Publications. Washington, DC: World Bank. 60 World Bank. 2020. Commodity Markets Outlook: Persistence of Commodity Shocks. October. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2021. Timor-Leste Public Expenditure Review: Changing Course Towards Better and More Sustainable Spending. Washington, DC: World Bank World Bank. 2022. Global Economic Prospects. January. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 2023. Global Economic Prospects. June. Washington, DC: World Bank. 61