68168 Restoring the lustre of the European economic model INDERMIT S GILL MARTIN RAISER GOVERNMENT LABOR INNOVATION ENTERPRISE FINANCE TRADE Restoring the lustre of the European economic model INDERMIT S GILL MARTIN RAISER TOGETHER WITH: ANDREA MARIO DALL’OLIO, TRUMAN PACKARD, KASPAR RICHTER, NAOTAKA SUGAWARA, REINHILDE VEUGELERS, JUAN ZALDUENDO © 2012 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / International Development Association or The World Bank 1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000 Internet: www.worldbank.org 1 2 3 4 15 14 13 12 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The ï¬?ndings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Rights and Permissions The material in this work is subject to copyright. Because The World Bank encourages dissemination of its knowledge, this work may be reproduced, in whole or in part, for noncommercial purposes as long as full attribution to this work is given. For permission to reproduce any part of this work for commercial purposes, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750- 4470; internet: www.copyright.com. All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Ofï¬?ce of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org. ISBN (paper): 978-0-8213-8965-2 ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-8966-9 DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8965-2 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Gill, Indermit Singh, 1961– Golden growth: restoring the lustre of the European economic model / Indermit Gill and Martin Raiser; together with Andrea Mario Dall’Olio ... [et al.]. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 978-0-8213-8965-2 (alk. paper) — ISBN 978-0-8213-8966-9 (electronic) 1. Europe—Economic conditions—1945– —Econometric models. 2. Economic indicators— Europe. I. Raiser, Martin. II. Title. HC240.G523277 2012 330.94—dc23 2011045981 Design and typesetting by Zephyr www.wearezephyr.com Contents FOREWORD i ACKNOWLEDGMENTS iii OVERVIEW: RESTORING EUROPE’S LUSTRE 1 CHAPTER 1: THE EUROPEAN GROWTH MODEL 35 SPOTLIGHT ONE: EUROPE — CONVERGENCE MACHINE 71 CHAPTER 2: TRADE 87 CHAPTER 3: FINANCE 131 CHAPTER 4: ENTERPRISE 187 CHAPTER 5: INNOVATION 245 CHAPTER 6: LABOR 291 CHAPTER 7: GOVERNMENT 353 SPOTLIGHT TWO: GREENING EUROPE’S GROWTH 417 CHAPTER 8: GOLDEN GROWTH 433 SELECTED INDICATORS 457 GOLDEN GROWTH Boxes 4.5: Productivity drivers are similar outside the European Union ........216 1: The unmet precondition of the 4.6: The features of a global ï¬?rm .......218 common currency 4.7: The Swedish model .......................222 —labor mobility ............................... 29 5.1: Google—A uniquely 1.1: Europe’s economic model and its American innovation .................... 247 standard of living .............................38 5.2: Deï¬?ning innovation ...................... 249 1.2: Europe’s postwar consensus: 5.3: Is R&D/GDP a good measure of the social market economy ...........39 innovation performance? ............ 256 2.1: Volkswagen and Å koda...................93 5.4: Why don’t lagging countries do 2.2: Germany is not Europe’s China .... 94 more R&D? ......................................257 2.3: Scope of the goods trade data......95 5.5: Where does entrepreneurship 2.4: EU integration is a process ............ 97 flourish? ........................................... 264 2.5: Measuring the sophistication 5.6: Role of ï¬?nancial systems in of exports of goods ...................... 100 convergence and innovation ..... 269 2.6: How big should the Single Market 6.1: Is a flexible labor market for Services be? necessary for successful Clues from Canada ..........................111 monetary union? ............................310 2.7: Can liberalization of services 6.2: Do temporary contracts make contribute to productivity growth? labor markets flexible? ................. 313 Evidence from the 6.3: Denmark’s “flexicurityâ€?: increasing Czech Republic .............................. 112 contestability, the gentler way ...318 2.8: Measuring the sophistication of 6.4: Germany’s Hartz reforms: services exports is much more modernizing social welfare and difï¬?cult than for goods ................. 114 unemployment beneï¬?ts ...............319 2.9: Reviving the reform agenda for 6.5: Labor mobility is low even the European single market......... 117 in countries in the European 2.10: Facilitating the services trade neighborhood: in the Western Balkans .................120 the case of Ukraine........................327 2.11: Ukraine would gain a lot if it could 6.6: Beyond the white cliffs: get freer access to the European immigration to the Union’s agricultural market .......... 122 United Kingdom .............................. 331 2.12: (Not) extending the single market 6.7: The smarter North Americans? to the European Union’s eastern Immigration to Canada .................332 partners—the case of Georgia..... 123 7.1: Data and groupings ...................... 356 3.1: Economic adjustment in three 7.2: Transaction costs and small European economies .........143 government bureaucracies ..........363 3.2: Understanding the growth– 7.3: Europe’s tax burden is caused by vulnerability tradeoff ...................147 high labor and indirect taxes, in 3.3: Country experiences with spite of low corporate taxes ....... 366 macroprudential policies ..............151 7.4: Nordic social protection programs 3.4: The new European architecture seem to be different .....................372 for ï¬?nancial stability ...................... 152 7.5: The north performs better than 3.5: The pros and cons of debt-relief predicted in the models, and the interventions ................................... 157 south and the EU candidate 3.6: Facilitating private debt resolution countries worse ..............................373 without public resources .............. 173 7.6: Private social spending is 4.1: Is staying local now riskier? ........ 198 low in Western Europe, 4.2: Firms in Europe are becoming especially the south ......................375 more similar—in size ..................... 199 7.7: Randomized public health, 4.3: What do successful exporters Oregon............................................. 377 look like? ......................................... 207 7.8: Some countries have managed 4.4: What attracts FDI?— to reform pensions in spite of a Decent infrastructure and growing elderly population......... 382 good regulations ............................ 212 7.9: Debt and growth ........................... 384 7.10: Improving regional development policies—follow the Irish .............. 387 CONTENTS 7.11: Changes in behavior and 6: Much of Europe is becoming 1.8: Europe’s governments spend policies enable countries more productive, but the south more on R&D, the private to adjust to aging ...........................392 has fallen behind.............................. 12 sector spends less ...........................45 7.12: Reversal of private 7: Smaller ï¬?rms contribute half of 1.9: European governments account pension pillars ................................ 394 value added in the EU15 South, for the bulk of tertiary education 7.13: Long-term care policies for but just a third elsewhere ..............14 spending ........................................... 46 older populations in new 8: Western European investors have 1.10: Europeans work less and member states and Croatia ........ 397 been looking east, not south.........14 retire earlier...................................... 46 8.1: The structural prerequisites of a 9: Southern and Eastern Europe must 1.11: Employment protection is successful monetary union ......... 434 make it easier to do business ........ 15 higher in Europe .............................. 47 8.2: Internal mobility: Ireland and 10: Productivity growth in Europe’s 1.12: Wages in Europe are less the United States...........................440 larger economies has slowed differentiated than in 8.3: Managing ï¬?nancial foreign down since the mid-1990s............. 15 other regions.................................... 47 direct investment: 11: The United States specializes in 1.13: Social spending is higher Poland and Croatia ........................ 441 younger, more R&D-intensive in Europe ........................................... 48 8.4: Crisis-prooï¬?ng ï¬?nance: the products .............................................16 1.14: Redistribution through the tax Czech Republic and Canada ........ 443 12: Outspending the rest of and transfer system is more 8.5: Value-added leaders: the Slovak the world ..........................................18 pronounced in Europe .................... 49 Republic and Singapore ...............444 13: Europe’s pension systems have 1.15: Europe’s productivity leaders 8.6: Public service delivery: to support people for many are lagging behind the Finland and Singapore ................. 445 more years ........................................19 United States ..................................... 51 8.7: Labor legislation: Denmark 14: Europe’s labor force will shrink, 1.16: Southern Europe lags the EU15 and the United States...................446 while North America’s will grow North, and Eastern Europe is 8.8: Reducing private debt: Sweden by a quarter .......................................20 catching up to it ................................52 and the Republic of Korea ...........448 15: Europeans are less mobile, even 1.17: Europe’s population could shrink by 8.9: R&D policy: Switzerland and within their own countries .............20 a third over the next 40 years ......52 the United States...........................449 16: Governments in Europe are big ....22 1.18: European governments are the 8.10: Tertiary education: 17: Social protection explains the biggest in the world, and often the United Kingdom and difference in government size heavily indebted...............................53 the United States........................... 450 between Europe and its peers ..... 24 S1.1: Europe—the lifestyle 8.11: Immigration policies: Sweden and 18: Small differences in annual superpower .......................................73 Canada (and the United Kingdom pensions per beneï¬?ciary, S1.2: Decomposing the growth and the United States) ..................451 big in overall public in worker productivity ................... 76 8.12: Social security: pension spending ............................ 24 S1.3: Europeans work fewer hours Iceland and Japan .......................... 452 19: Western Europe has to reduce while Americans work more ........ 76 8.13: Reducing public debt: ï¬?scal deï¬?cits by 6 percent of GDP, S1.4: Convergence until the 1980s, Turkey and New Zealand ............. 453 emerging Europe by less ................26 divergence since ............................. 77 20: Greening production but not S1.5: Big increases in productivity during consumption .....................................28 the transition, especially in the Figures 1.1: Europe is the most open region in the world ..................................... 40 S1.6: former Soviet Union ....................... 77 Productivity got a big boost 1: In Europe, a rapid convergence 1.2: Convergence in incomes was faster from ICT in the United States, in living standards—not much in Europe than elsewhere .............41 not so much in Europe ................... 78 elsewhere ............................................4 1.3: In much of Europe, capital flows S1.7: Policy affects the pace and 2: Almost half of the global goods to high-growth countries ............. 42 composition of productivity trade involves Europe .......................6 1.4: Institutional quality varies a growth ............................................... 80 3: More trade in services in lot within Europe ............................. 42 S1.8: Information technology played a Europe, but apparently in 1.5: Business is expected to be bigger role in Eastern Europe ....... 80 more traditional activities ................8 socially responsible in Europe, S1.9: Growth has been greater in 4: In Europe, foreign capital has especially in the EU..........................43 Europe’s southern states ................81 boosted growth in emerging 1.6: Emerging European countries 2.1: Europe has the world’s busiest economies ...........................................8 are the best performers in goods trade .......................................91 5: European enterprises have emission reduction ......................... 44 2.2: The European Union does a delivered jobs, productivity, 1.7: The business climate varies brisk trade in services .....................92 and exports ....................................... 12 substantially across Europe .......... 44 2.3: The European Union’s new members are more important GOLDEN GROWTH partners for the EU15, the EU15 3.3: Foreign banks are emerging less for the new .............................. 94 Europe’s unique feature ............... 135 2.4: Machinery and transport 3.4: In Europe, capital flows to equipment are half of the exports countries with lower incomes .....136 of new member states ...................95 3.5: In Europe, capital also flows 2.5: Automobiles are a big part of to high-growth countries .............136 the goods trade in Europe ............ 96 3.6: Investments rose strongly 2.6: Intermediates are about half of the in Europe as external European Union’s trade, but two- balances improved......................... 137 thirds of the trade in Asia.............. 98 3.7: Emerging Europe’s real effective 2.7: New EU members are more exchange rates appreciated ........ 141 important for the EU15 for trade in 3.8: Emerging Europe showed rapid intermediate goods ........................ 98 economic adjustment but slow 2.8: Growing intra-industry ties in economic recovery ........................ 141 the east, but faster within the 3.9: The closer a country gets to the European Union ............................... 99 European Union, the more 2.9: Advanced and emerging Europe stable its bank ï¬?nancing ..............142 are trading more sophisticated 3.10: Fiscal positions became intermediate goods ....................... 101 procyclical in 2004–08 ..................145 2.10: Emerging Europe’s exports 3.11: Revenues lost to the Great have become more complex ....... 101 Recession, 2009 .............................146 2.11: Emerging Europe has 3.12: Countries showed varying developed sizable backlogs experiences with credit growth and in trade facilities.............................102 asset prices ....................................148 2.12: Services exports are growing fast 3.13: Emerging Europe is solvent, in the new member states...........107 the EU cohesion countries 2.13: Modern—more tradable—services less so ...............................................159 are growing faster almost 3.14: Greater debt exposure in everywhere .....................................107 Southern Europe, more 2.14: Internal trade tendencies in the equity exposure in the east ........159 European Union vary across 3.15: Most economies in emerging countries ......................................... 108 Europe are liquid ........................... 160 2.15: Western Europe does most 3.16: EU cohesion countries have higher of the internal trade in levels of public and private services, 2008................................ 108 debt than emerging 2.16: The single market works better European countries ........................ 161 for traditional services .................. 110 3.17: Credit to ï¬?rms 2.17: Services are contributing even grew faster than to households more to growth in Europe ............ 110 in most emerging 2.18: The European Union has a European countries ........................162 comparative advantage 3.18: Household indebtedness rose in in services .........................................113 emerging Europe, but remains 2.19: India and the United States below EU15 levels ..........................163 have more sophisticated 3.19: A few ï¬?rms in a few countries are services exports than the at risk in emerging Europe .......... 166 European Union .............................. 116 3.20: Only few households in few 2.20: European economies have emerging European countries are made trade easier .......................... 119 excessively indebted .................... 169 2.21: Professional services remain 3.21: Households in emerging Europe can tightly regulated ............................. 119 withstand economic shocks ........170 2.22: Not all countries are making trade 3.22: Some banks in some emerging in business services easier .......... 119 European countries are at risk .... 171 3.1: Fifteen years of ï¬?nancial 4.1: European enterprises did well integration show that in 1995–2009 .................................. 190 Europe is different ........................134 4.2: The east giving chase, 3.2: Capital flows in emerging the south falling behind ...............197 Europe are particularly large .......134 CONTENTS 4.3: In the EU12, most 4.23: In the EU15, size matters more than 5.13: The United States jobs created were in services country for exports .......................219 outperforms Europe on and construction ........................... 200 4.24: In a difï¬?cult business environment, management quality .................... 266 4.4: In the EU15, a loss of manufacturing ï¬?rms stay small and operate more 5.14: The United States has jobs, replaced by small service informally .........................................219 the largest venture capital enterprises.......................................201 4.25: Firms in Southern and emerging market in the world .......................267 4.5: Microenterprises in Europe are most likely to survive, 5.15: Most European countries produce the EU15 South cannot pay but shrink ........................................ 220 fewer graduates than the for skilled workers ........................ 202 4.26: In a better business environment, United States or Japan...................271 4.6: Productivity levels were lower ï¬?rms are less likely to shrink ...... 220 5.16: Europe is falling in the south and lower still 4.27: Better regulations create jobs behind the United States in in the east ....................................... 202 (regulatory quality, ï¬?rm size, and top university rankings .................271 4.7: The east has been catching up, the employment ratios, 2007) ............223 5.17: Science-business links are as south has been falling behind .... 202 A4.1: Correspondence between product strong in Europe’s top performers 4.8: In the EU12, manufacturing and market regulation indicator as in the United States ..................272 services are more productive, and principal components 5.18: The United States has construction less ............................203 analysis index .................................237 the largest market share for 4.9: Manufacturing drives productivity A4.2: Quality of regulations index international students ...................274 growth in the EU15 center, services based on Doing Business 5.19: Switzerland, Scandinavia, in the north..................................... 204 indicators, 2012 .............................. 238 and Germany are global 4.10: Exporting—Central 5.1: Mind the gap: convergence innovation leaders .........................274 Europe’s specialty ......................... 205 followed by slowdown in Europe’s 6.1: Self-reported measures of 4.11: The size and productivity productivity relative to the happiness are positively associated of ï¬?rms influence a country’s United States .................................. 248 with job satisfaction ..................... 296 exports, late 2000s....................... 206 5.2: Europe has a large innovation 6.2: People who work fewer hours 4.12: The south has become less deï¬?cit relative to both the United report higher levels of job attractive to foreign investors, States and East Asia’s high-income satisfaction ..................................... 296 the east more so ........................... 208 economies ...................................... 250 6.3: In advanced Europe, a clearer 4.13: Not all countries in emerging 5.3: Europe’s leaders invest as much tradeoff between preferences Europe are equally attractive for in innovation as the United for work over leisure .................... 297 foreign investors ........................... 208 States and Japan ............................. 251 6.4: In emerging Europe, a tradeoff 4.14: Foreign ï¬?rm are more 5.4: In Europe’s catching-up economies between work and leisure is productive and have innovation is not always R&D .....252 less apparent.................................. 297 faster productivity growth .......... 209 5.5: Innovation: another north- 6.5: The importance of work is 4.15: In the EU12, FDI is positively south gap in Europe...................... 254 only weakly associated with associated with productivity 5.6: Innovation matters much more the importance of family and jobs ........................................... 209 in “oldâ€? Europe than in “newâ€? in the EU15 ...................................... 298 4.16: In the EU12, infrastructure, Europe in explaining differences 6.6: In emerging Europe, the importance credit, FDI, and regulations are in productivity growth ..................255 of work and family are closely correlated with productivity ........ 211 5.7: The role of Yollies among leading associated ....................................... 298 4.17: In the EU15, ï¬?rms with a foreign innovators is bigger in the United 6.7: Europe’s approach is distinct— presence are more productive States than in Europe or Japan ....259 but there are differences and grow faster .............................. 213 5.8: Yollies spend the most on R&D within Europe ................................. 299 4.18: Investing abroad is related to and U.S. Yollies are the most 6.8: The decline in hours worked higher productivity growth..........214 R&D-intensive of all ï¬?rms ............259 was faster in Europe than 4.19: Northern and Continental Europe 5.9: Innovation-based elsewhere in the OECD .................302 get the bulk of FDI ......................... 215 growth sectors ...............................261 6.9: Europe has both productivity 4.20: In the EU15, FDI and regulations 5.10: Only the United States focuses leaders and laggards .....................302 are the closest correlates of its R&D efforts in innovation- 6.10: The decline in work participation productivity ..................................... 215 based growth sectors ...................261 has been faster in Europe ............302 4.21: Southern Europe underperforms 5.11: Europe has fewer Yollies in 6.11: Europeans are retiring at earlier the rest of the EU15 in all aspects innovation-based growth sectors, ages than they used to .................302 but access to credit........................217 but they are as R&D-intensive as in 6.12: The big reduction in the number 4.22: Microï¬?rms generate half the the United States............................262 of young European workers will employment and a third of the 5.12: The supply of innovation gets a happen before 2030 ......................303 value added in the EU15 South ...217 lot of attention, supply-demand 6.13: Aging in Europe is matched by interactions too little .................... 265 a “surplusâ€? of working-age GOLDEN GROWTH people in the Middle East 6.32: Language, housing, and health and North Africa ............................ 304 care are the main impediments 6.14: To keep the size of the labor force to mobility ...................................... 326 stable, Europeans have to work 6.33: European countries host fewer longer and more productively, but immigrants than other a demographic deï¬?cit of young OECD countries .............................. 329 people will probably persist ....... 305 7.1: Government size in G7 countries, 6.15: Better-educated people are 1960, 1990, 2000, and 2010 .........357 more likely to participate in 7.2: Government size, 1995, 2007, the labor market............................ 307 and 2010...........................................357 6.16: Skills are an important 7.3: Density of government size in constraint for many ï¬?rms in Europe ..............................................357 emerging Europe ........................... 307 7.4: Government size in 1995 6.17: Cognitive skills are adequate in and 2010...........................................357 most European countries ............ 309 7.5: Social spending determines 6.18: Minimum wages in the the size of governments ............. 358 newest EU member countries 7.6: Social transfers increased are increasing faster ...................... 311 fastest in the south .......................359 6.19: Employment protection is 7.7: Social spending increased converging through liberalization in the 2000s ................................... 360 in more rigid labor markets ......... 312 7.8: Government spending is higher 6.20: The wedge created by income in richer countries, and income taxes and social insurance growth is slower............................ 364 contributions is highest in Italy ...314 7.9: Growth is slower as 6.21: Labor costs have government gets bigger.............. 364 been rising quickly in the 7.10: Quality of government EU’s newer members ....................314 declines from north to south 6.22: In Emerging Europe, the tax and west to east ........................... 370 wedge for lowest-wage 7.11: Governments reduce inequality earners tends to be high ..............314 more in Europe ............................... 371 6.23: In much of the European 7.12: Private spending makes the United Union, membership in labor States the biggest health care unions has been declining ........... 315 spender in the world .................... 376 6.24: Informal self-employment is 7.13: Western Europe has good health most prevalent in Greece, and education outcomes ............. 377 Italy, Portugal, and Spain..............316 7.14: The south spends more on 6.25: In Europe, active labor programs pensions than others ....................381 are associated with higher labor 7.15: The burden of social transfers force participation.......................... 317 grew most in the south ............... 383 6.26: Rigid employment protection 7.16: The eastern partnership countries legislation is associated with increased social transfers lower employment rates .............. 317 the most .......................................... 383 6.27: Rigid laws and high taxes 7.17: Public debt rose everywhere are associated with higher during the crisis except in unemployment, active the emerging peers ...................... 384 labor programs with lower 7.18: Markets have learned to look unemployment ............................... 317 at ï¬?scal vulnerabilities ................. 385 6.28: Europeans are less mobile .......... 320 7.19: The biggest declines in 6.29: Europeans—especially in the east— growth will be in Europe ............. 386 are less internally mobile ............. 321 7.20: Spending on investment, 6.30: Low labor mobility can keep education, and health was unemployment high ......................323 protected during the crisis .......... 388 6.31: Greater labor mobility is 7.21: Large ï¬?scal adjustments are associated with higher rates not unusual ..................................... 389 of employment in Europe.............325 7.22: Illustrative adjustment needs, median, percentage of GDP .........392 CONTENTS 7.23: Illustrative adjustment needs and 2.4: EU services exports are more A6.2: Regression estimation results: projected increase in health and sophisticated than those of the rest employment rate .......................... 343 pension expenditures, median, of the world ......................................115 A6.3: Regression estimation results: percentage of GDP .........................392 3.1: Private imbalances in the East, unemployment rate...................... 344 7.24: Pensions are more a more complicated story in the A6.4: Regression estimation results: generous in Western South................................................ 106 long-term unemployment rate .. 345 Europe than elsewhere.................393 3.2: Precrisis use of macroprudential 7.1: Illustrative adjustment needs 7.25: Social insurance contribution policies in eight emerging by 2030, median, percentage rates in Europe are often high.....395 European countries ........................150 of GDP...............................................391 7.26: Raising the retirement age helps 3.3: Firm characteristics and use of bank A7.1: Political institutions stabilize pension spending.......... 396 credit in emerging Europe ............163 influence government size ......... 403 7.27: Public health spending has 3.4: Firm debt is held by the A7.2: Regression results for growth increased faster than GDP .......... 397 ï¬?nancially sophisticated and initial government 7.28: Young cohorts are shrinking in emerging Europe ...................... 164 expenditures, 1995 to 2010.........404 in Eastern Europe .......................... 398 3.5: Few households in emerging A7.3: Regression results for growth and S2.1: Europe is the world’s largest Europe have debt .......................... 168 initial government revenues in importer of carbon dioxide ......... 418 A3.1: Foreign savings and growth— Europe, 1995–2010 ........................406 S2.2: Advanced Europe has cut air EU12 and EU candidate A7.4: Regression results for growth and pollution in half since 1990 ......... 420 countries are different ..................177 initial social transfer spending in S2.3: Europe’s north is leading the A3.2: EU membership as an anchor Europe, 1995–2010 ........................406 push for cleaner energy ...............421 for institutional development .....178 A7.5: Regression results for growth S2.4: Western imports, 4.1: European enterprises, benchmarked and average public investment Eastern emissions ......................... 422 quantitatively and globally ..........192 spending in Europe, 1995–2010 ..406 S2.5: Germany, France, Sweden, A4.1: Sample composition ..................... 228 A7.6: Regression results of quality and Italy have helped business A4.2: Firm-level productivity growth, of government on initial by encouraging renewable 2003-08, EU12 countries .............. 229 government size ...........................408 energy ............................................. 425 A4.3: Firm-level productivity growth, A7.7: OLS regression results of S2.6: China now emits the most 2003-08, EU15 countries ............... 231 people’s values on initial carbon dioxide ............................... 428 A4.4: Firm-level productivity growth, government size ........................... 410 S2.7: But China’s per capita carbon 2003-08, non-EU countries ..........233 A7.8: Public spending helps improve dioxide emissions may not A4.5: Transition matrix of survival health, spending on public signiï¬?cantly grow beyond the ï¬?rms, by subregion (percent) ..... 239 schooling is less effective ........... 410 European Union’s ..........................429 5.1: A large share of companies A7.9: Regression results for log public in Europe innovate, less so pensions as a share of GDP ......... 411 in the east ........................................253 A7.10: Regression results for log social Tables 5.2: Europe specializes in sectors with transfers as a share of GDP ......... 411 medium R&D intensity, the United 8.1: Benchmark countries for 1: Relentless growth in the United States in high intensity ................ 260 selected policies ............................ 435 States, revival in Asia, and a 5.3: Average deal size of venture 8.2: Europe’s imperatives, instruments, postwar miracle in Europe ...............5 capital investment ........................ 268 and policy priorities ...................... 439 2: 30 questions, 30 answers...............30 5.4: United States universities 1.1: Strengths and shortcomings of produce more patents, and if Europe’s growth model ..................65 picked up by business, the S1.1: Relentless growth in the United patents have greater impact .......273 States, a miracle in Europe, and 6.1: Similar policies can lead to resurgence in Asia, 1820–2008......74 different outcomes ....................... 300 2.1: A greater variety of intermediate 6.2: Internationally, the Irish are goods are being traded ................. 99 the most mobile Europeans.........322 2.2: Western Europe drives much 6.3: Not a single market for of the services trade .................... 106 new members................................ 324 2.2: Western Europe drives much 6.4: The wealthier countries in of the services trade .................... 106 Europe attract fewer 2.3: The single market has increased high-skilled immigrants than services trade and FDI by about 25 countries in North America......... 330 percent ............................................ 109 A6.1: Regression estimation results: activity rate .................................... 342 GOLDEN GROWTH FOREWORD Foreword “Now grows together what belongs together,â€? former West German Chancellor Willy Brandt famously remarked in Berlin in November 1989. He was talking about German reuniï¬?cation, but his statement might well apply to European integration. Over the past 20 years, the European Union has grown by 12 Central European members and has helped millions get to high incomes. The single market now stretches from Lisbon to Å?ódź and from the North Cap to Nikosia. Trade and capital flows unrivaled in economic history have fueled the European convergence machine. Shared aspirations of Europeans in the east and the west, the north and the south, for prosperity that is both sustainable and socially inclusive have brought the continent together. This economic integration makes it difï¬?cult to view one part of the continent in isolation. So this report looks at Europe as a whole—from the Atlantic Ocean to the Azov Sea. It is unusual for a development institution like the World Bank to be writing about countries in Western Europe that reached high-income status many years ago. But the geographical scope of this report is appropriate, and not just because what happens in the west affects prospects in the east. It is appropriate because the European Union’s new member states in the east have undergone an unprecedented transformation over the past two decades—and their experiences have lessons for their western peers struggling with the structural exigencies of an integrated continent. It is also appropriate because the experience of Southern Europe with economic integration—and common monetary policy in particular—can help Central and Eastern Europe. The Polish authorities, who inspired the work on this report in preparation for their presidency of the European Union in the second half of 2011, understood from the outset that a report on European growth had to be about European integration. But it was also clear that it had to be about the lessons that Europeans can learn from each other and from successful countries in other parts of the world, to adjust better to an integrated Europe and a changing world. The Polish Presidency’s report to the European Council in October 2011, “Towards a New Consensus on Economic Growth,â€? previews some of this report’s conclusions. These, in turn, are informed by the successes of countries in Europe and around the world in policy areas that are pertinent today. The subjects range from regulating banks to reducing public debt; the countries range from the Czech Republic to Canada, and from Turkey to New Zealand. When work on this report started, the world was recovering from the global economic crisis. Growth had returned to Europe too, but it was fragile. As the report went to print, Europe was again in crisis. Poland is not a member of the eurozone, and this report is not about the euro. It is about the future of the European economic model. But as Radek Sikorski, the Polish foreign minister, said in Berlin in November 2011: “The biggest threat to the security and prosperity of Poland would be the collapse of the eurozone.â€? i GOLDEN GROWTH Equally serious, trouble in the eurozone prompted questions about the achievements of European integration. It should not. The message of this report for Europe is this: in reacting to the debt crisis, do not abandon the attractive features of the European model. The report distinguishes three main attributes of the European economic and social model. The ï¬?rst is economic and political enlargement. The second is the combination of enterprise and social responsibility. The third is a focus on social inclusion and solidarity. These attributes have produced a prosperity that has been shared between people and countries in a manner not seen before or elsewhere. They should be nourished. To be sure, though, some policies and institutions that have shaped Europe’s progress need to be changed. The analysis in this report unveils a graduated reform agenda. Some parts of the European model require smaller adjustments: these include trade and ï¬?nance, the two main drivers of the European convergence machine. Other parts require deep reform, such as labor and government. In between are enterprise and innovation, whose organization across the continent ranges from world class to mediocre. Three objectives should guide policy makers. First, the single market should be strengthened to unleash new drivers of productivity growth. Second, enlargement should continue and fully integrate the 100 million people in Southeastern Europe, and help another 75 million in the eastern partnership beneï¬?t from the same European aspirations and institutions. Third, Europe’s global economic influence, which has been enabled and shaped by the values of inclusion and enterprise, should be preserved. But this report is not just for Europe. It is also for people and policy makers outside the continent who follow Europe’s progress and are interested in its prospects. Its message for them is: don’t count Europe out. There are countries —both advanced and emerging—where the European model has been made to work, and the results are gratifying. Europe’s trials must not intimidate those working toward progressive goals; its successes should inspire them. The report draws inspiration and its title from the golden rule of economic growth, which requires that today’s decisions are viewed by later generations neither with regret nor resentment. The shared aspirations of Europeans for inclusive development have led to decades of success, and Europe’s development has been distinct. If they can learn the right lessons from the reforms in and outside Europe, its development will be distinguished. This would be good not just for Europe, but for the world as well. Marek Belka Philippe Le Houérou President, National Bank of Poland Vice President, Europe and Central Asia Chairman, World Bank/IMF Development Committee The World Bank ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Acknowledgments This report was written by a team led by Indermit Gill, Chief Economist, Europe and Central Asia Region, and Martin Raiser, Country Director for Turkey at the World Bank. The core team members were Andrea Maria Dall’Olio, Truman Packard, Kaspar Richter, Naotaka Sugawara, Reinhilde Veugelers, and Juan Zalduendo. The work was carried out under the overall supervision of Philippe Le Houérou, Vice President, Europe and Central Asia Region. Marek Belka, President, National Bank of Poland, and Chairman, World Bank– International Monetary Fund Development Committee, and Jean Pisani-Ferry, Director of Bruegel, provided their insights, encouragement, and guidance at all stages of this project. Many people participated in the writing of the report. The main authors and contributors were: · The Overview was written by Indermit Gill, with inputs from Naotaka Sugawara. · Chapter 1 (The European Growth Model) was written by Indermit Gill and Martin Raiser, with contributions from Naotaka Sugawara and Marc Teignier-Baqué. · Chapter 2 (Trade) was written by Indermit Gill and Yue Li, with contributions from Alberto Behar, Ileana Cristina Constantinescu, Caroline Freund, Susanna Gable Lundstrom, and Saurabh Mishra. · Chapter 3 (Finance) was written by Juan Zalduendo, with contributions from Zsolt Darvas and Naotaka Sugawara. · Chapter 4 (Enterprise) was written by Andrea Maria Dall’Olio, with contributions from Mariana Iootty De Paiva Dias, Naoto Kanehira, Federica Saliola, Minh Cong Nguyen, Raian Divanbeigi, Louise Grogan, and Miriam Bruhn. · Chapter 5 (Innovation) was written by Martin Raiser and Reinhilde Veugelers, with contributions from William Maloney and Naotaka Sugawara. · Chapter 6 (Labor) was written by Truman Packard and Johannes Koettl, with contributions from Indhira Santos, Basab Dasgupta, Claudio Montenegro, Isil Oral, and Lazar Sestovic. · Chapter 7 (Government) was written by Kaspar Richter, Ewa Korczyc, and Paul Walsh, with contributions from Bartosz Witkowski, Maciej Bukowski, Kamil Wierus, Hans Pitlik, Margit Schratzenstaller, Igor Kheyfets, and Martin Cumpa. · Chapter 8 (Golden Growth) was written by Indermit Gill and Martin Raiser, with contributions from Aleksandra Iwulska and Bryce Quillin. · Spotlight One (Europe—Convergence Machine) was written by Bryce Quillin. · Spotlight Two (Greening Europe’s Growth) was written by Uwe Deichmann. · The Selected Indicators tables were compiled by Naotaka Sugawara, who was also responsible for verifying the accuracy of statistics used or cited in the report. · The Country Benchmarks summarizing global good practice were written by Aleksandra Iwulska, with contributions from Bryce Quillin. iii GOLDEN GROWTH Elena Kantarovich oversaw the production of the entire report. Aleksandra Iwulska and Rhodora Mendoza-Paynor provided support. Santiago Pombo Bejarano and Paola Scalabrin generously made resources at the Ofï¬?ce of the Publisher available to the production team. Bruce Ross-Larson was the principal editor, leading a team at Communications Development Incorporated, with Jonathan Aspin, Rob Elson, Gary von Euer, Jack Harlow, Abigail Heald, Emily Schabacker, and Christopher Trott. Zephyr designed and typeset the report. Fidel Prokopovich created the graphics. This task received ï¬?nancial and technical assistance from the Research Support Budget of the World Bank and the Europe and Central Asia Regional Studies Program, for which the team is grateful to Jean-Jacques Dethier and Willem van Eeghen. The many background papers made possible by this ï¬?nancial support were written by Alberto Behar, Caroline Freund, Susanna Lundstrom Gable, Saurabh Mishra, Kamila Fialova, Mihails Hazans, Benno Torgler, Martin Brown, Zsolt Darvas, Philip Lane, Swati Ghosh, Naotaka Sugawara, Juan Zalduendo, Steen Byskov, Roumeen Islam, Gary Schinasi, Aleksandar Stojkov, and Holger Wolf. Staff of the central banks and banking supervision agencies in eight countries contributed excellent accounts of monetary and ï¬?nancial sector policies: Tomislav Galac, and Evan Kraft (Croatia); Jan Frait, Adam GerÅ¡l, and Jakub Seidler (Czech Republic); Andres Sutt, Helen Korju, and Kadri Siibak (Estonia); Adám Banai, Júlia Király, and Márton Nagy (Hungary); Frosina Celeska, Viktorija Gligorova, and Aneta Krstevska (former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia); MichaÅ‚ Kruszka and MichaÅ‚ Kowalczyk (Poland); Cristian Popa (Romania); and Turalay Kenc, Ibrahim Turhan, and Onur Yildirim (Turkey). All the background papers written for the report are available in the World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series. A panel of advisers chaired by Marek Belka provided guidance to the team at all stages of the project. For their interest, encouragement, and advice, the team is especially grateful to Irina Akimova, Antonio Borges, Ibrahim ´ Çanacki, Božidar Ä?eli c, Vitor Gaspar, Danuta Hübner, Adam Jasser, Michael John Hofmann, Jean-Pierre Landau, Jean Pisani-Ferry, Helga Maria Schmid, and Zoran Stavreski. Naturally, they are not responsible for any errors in the report, and its conclusions do not necessarily reflect their views. The work of the team would not have been timely or relevant without the sponsorship and discipline provided by the Polish Presidency of the European Union Council. PaweÅ‚ Samecki, Andrzej Raczko, and Agata Å?agowska at the National Bank of Poland, and MikoÅ‚aj Dowgielewicz, PaweÅ‚ Karbownik, Ë™ ´ MaÅ‚gorzata KaÅ‚u zy nska, and others at the Ministry of Foreign Affairs have been the report team’s strongest allies. The authors owe a special debt of gratitude ´ to MichaÅ‚ Krupi nski for fostering a most fruitful relationship between the Polish Presidency and the World Bank. Bruegel has been a valuable partner in this exercise from its very inception. The World Bank owes Zsolt Darvas, Jean Pisani-Ferry, André Sapir, Reinhilde Veugelers, and other colleagues at Bruegel an enormous debt. iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Colleagues at the European Commission generously gave their support and suggestions. The team would especially like to thank Marco Buti, Jean Claude Thébault, Michel Servoz, Vasco Cal, Philippe Legrain, and Margaritis Schinas. Reiner Martin and many colleagues at the European Central Bank’s Convergence and Structural Analysis Section provided useful feedback. Eurostat staff overseeing the Structural Business Statistics promptly and patiently responded to the team’s requests for information. Charles Roxburgh and Jan Mischke of McKinsey Global Institute provided advice at an early stage of the work and useful comments on a draft of the report. The team gratefully acknowledges their help. Many people at the World Bank have helped. Peter Harrold, Dirk Reinermann, Sebastian Stolorz, Mart Kivine, Thomas Laursen, Satu Kahkonen, Sophie Sirtaine, Lucio Vinhas de Souza, Lilia Burunciuc, Xavier Devictor, Kseniya Lvovsky, Markus Repnik, and Zeljko Bogetic have helped make the report better and engage policymakers more effectively. Bernard Hoekman, William Maloney, Aaditya Mattoo, Brian Pinto, and MichaÅ‚ Rutkowski provided constructive criticism and encouragement. Others who have helped in various ways include Theodore Ahlers, Pedro Alba, Richard Baldwin, Bruno Bonansea, Carlos Braga, Otaviano Canuto, Rinku Chandra, Gerardo Corochano, Uwe Deichmann, Michael Emerson, Marianne Fay, Ana Margarida Fernandes, Chorching Goh, Daniel Gros, Stephane Guimbert, Borko Handjiski, Bridget Harrison-Dowd, Jesko Hentschel, Stella Ilieva, Roumeen Islam, Gregory Jedrzejczak, Elena Karaban, Katarina Mathernova, Shigeo Katsu, ´ Andrew Kircher, Michael Klein, Dorota Kowalska, Jerzy Kwieci nski, Jeffrey Lecksell, Laszlo Lovei, Marco Mantovanelli, Martin Melecky, Marialisa Motta, Mamta Murthi, Evgenij Nadjov, Julia Nielsen, Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala, John Pollner, Jean Louis Racine, Ana Revenga, Alexander Rowland, Pablo Saavedra, Luis Servén, Kristyn Schrader, Maria Shkaratan, Emily Sinnott, Sándor Sipos, Emilia Skrok, Mark Thomas, Michael Toman, Mehrnaz Teymourian, Volker Treichel, Marina Wes, and Sally Zeijlon. Finally, the team is grateful to members of the Regional Management Team of the Europe and Central Asia Region for their feedback on earlier drafts of this report. The team thanks others who have helped in preparing and writing the report and wishes to apologize to anyone inadvertently overlooked in these acknowledgments. v GOLDEN GROWTH vi OVERVIEW Overview Restoring Europe’s lustre Fifty years ago, the American Economic Review published a short article titled “The Golden Rule of Accumulation.â€?1 In it, Edmund Phelps, an American economist, proposed a simple rule for a nation’s wealth to grow and provide the highest standard of living for its citizens—present and future. The rule essentially speciï¬?ed how much people had to work, save, and invest today so that future generations could be at least as well off as they were. The golden rule had European origins as well. The paper used the insights of economists from France, Hungary, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom.2 And just a few months before Phelps’ article was published, a German economist, Christian von Weizsäcker had submitted a dissertation that proposed the same rule.3 In 2006, the Nobel Committee awarded the prize to Phelps for “his analysis of intertemporal tradeoffs in macroeconomic policy.â€? 1 GOLDEN GROWTH Many economists still consider the golden rule the most basic proposition of optimum growth theory. It is the inspiration for the title of this report, and forms the roots of its policy prescriptions. Following the golden rule means that today’s Europeans work and consume just so much that future generations do not resent them for consuming too much, nor pity them for consuming too little. Keeping to the rule is perhaps the most telling sign of a country’s—or a continent’s—economic maturity. Europe’s growth is already different from other economies’ in two aspects, reflecting its cultural and demographic maturity. Perhaps more than others around the world, Europeans want economic growth to be smarter, kinder, and cleaner, and they are willing to accept less for “betterâ€? growth. The single word that summarizes these ideals might be “golden.â€? Europe’s growth will have to be golden in yet another sense. Economic prosperity has brought to Europeans the gift of longer lives, and the continent’s population has aged a lot over the last ï¬?ve decades. Over the next ï¬?ve, it will age even more: by 2060, almost a third of Europeans will be older than 65 years. Europe will have to rebuild its structures to make fuller use of the energies and experience of its more mature populations—people in their golden years. These desires and developments already make the European growth model distinct. Keeping to the discipline of the golden rule would make it distinguished. This report shows how Europeans have organized the six principal economic activities—trade, ï¬?nance, enterprise, innovation, labor, and government—in unique ways. But policies in parts of Europe do not recognize the imperatives of demographic maturity and clash with growth’s golden rule. Conforming growth across the continent to Europe’s ideals and the iron laws of economics will require difï¬?cult decisions. This report was written to inform them. Its ï¬?ndings: the changes needed to make trade and ï¬?nance will not be as hard as those to improve enterprise and innovation; these in turn are not as arduous and urgent as the changes needed to restructure labor and government. Its message: the remedies are not out of reach for a part of the world that has proven itself both intrepid and inclusive. A distinctive model It is common these days to hear Europeans calling for a “new growth model.â€? The public debt crisis has shaken conï¬?dence not just in the euro but in Europe.4 Aging Europeans are being squeezed between innovative Americans and efï¬?cient Asians, it is said. With debt and demographics weighing down European economies, the argument runs that they will not grow much unless they discover radically new ways. The end of complacency among Europeans is good, because developments in and outside the continent have made changes necessary. But loss of conï¬?dence could be dangerous. The danger is that in rushing to restructure and restart growth, Europe may throw out the attractive attributes of its development model with the weak ones. In fact, the European growth model has many strong points and enviable accomplishments. 2 OVERVIEW Between 1950 and 1973, Western European incomes converged quickly toward those in the United States. Then, until the early 1990s, the incomes of more than 100 million people in the poorer southern periphery—Greece, southern Italy, Portugal, and Spain—grew closer to those in advanced Europe. With the ï¬?rst association agreements with Hungary and Poland in 1994, another 100 million people in Central and Eastern Europe were absorbed into the European Union, and their incomes increased quickly. Another 100 million in the candidate countries in Southeastern Europe are already beneï¬?ting from the same aspirations and similar institutions that have helped almost half a billion people achieve the highest standards of living on the planet. If European integration continues, the 75 million people in the eastern partnership will proï¬?t in ways that are similar in scope and speed. It is no exaggeration to say that Europe invented a “convergence machine,â€? taking in poor countries and helping them become high-income economies. Over the last four decades, the countries in Europe experienced a convergence in consumption levels that is unmatched (ï¬?gure 1). Annual per capita consumption in the poorer parts of Europe grew by 4 percent while in the wealthier countries it increased at a still-impressive 2 percent. The rest of the world—except for East Asia—has seen little or no convergence. That is why the European model was so attractive. That is why European growth is unique. Given Europe’s diversity, it is not easy to identify a single “European growth model.â€? There are big differences in how Italy and Ireland regulate work and enterprise, and how Greece and Germany balance ï¬?scal policies and social objectives. There are big differences in what Spain and Sweden export, and how they regulate commerce. There are differences in how Portugal and Poland have regulated their banks, and not just because one of them shares a common currency while the other has one of its own. And there are differences in how Finland and France provide government services such as education and health. But these differences in speciï¬?cs do not rule out the existence of a common approach to economic growth and social progress. This approach consists of policies and institutions that govern trade and ï¬?nance, enterprise and innovation, and labor and government that have common elements. Together, these elements deï¬?ne an economic and social model distinctly European (chapter 1). These elements have been associated with Europe’s biggest successes since World War II: unprecedented regional integration, global economic power, and the attainment of the highest quality of life in human history. · Trade, ï¬?nance, and unprecedented regional integration. Europe’s rich and poorer economies are more integrated through trade in goods and services than in any other part of the world, resulting in quicker convergence in incomes and living standards. Private capital in all its forms—foreign direct investment (FDI), ï¬?nancial FDI, and portfolio funds—has flowed from richer to poorer countries, and from low- to high-growth economies. Trade and ï¬?nance —facilitated by the single market instituted by the European Union and its forebears—have fueled convergence in incomes and living standards. 3 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 1: In Europe, a rapid Europe convergence in living standards— not much elsewhere 6 (annual growth of consumption per Annual per capita consumption growth, 1970−2009, percent 4 Corr. = −0.80*** capita between 1970 and 2009, by n = 26 level of consumption in 1970) 2 *** Statistically signiï¬?cant at 1 percent. 0 Note: n = number of countries. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Penn World Table 7.0 (Heston, Summers, and Aten 2011); see chapter 1. East Asia 6 4 Corr. = −0.21 n = 15 2 0 Latin America 6 4 Corr. = −0.25 n = 22 2 0 0 3 6 9 12 15 Initial level of consumption per capita, 1970 PPP, thousands of 2005 international dollars · Enterprise, innovation, and global economic influence. Private enterprises are held accountable for proï¬?ts by shareholders, but are also more socially and environmentally responsible than companies in most other parts of the world. Research and development and tertiary education, recognized around the globe for their economic spillovers, are seen as a responsibility not just of ï¬?rms but also the state. Enterprise and innovation—aided by deep and comprehensive regional economic integration—enable Europe to account for about a third of world gross domestic product (GDP) with less than one-tenth of its population. · Labor, government, and high living standards. Workers in Europe are accorded strong protection against abuse by employers, and have unprecedented income security after job loss and in old age. European governments are the most decentralized and representative of local interests, 4 OVERVIEW and Europe has developed the most effective institutions for regional coordination in human history. Europe’s model of labor and government— facilitated by the growing consensus for continental cohesion and made affordable by its economic heft—has made the European lifestyle admired and envied around the world. What has Europe accomplished that other parts of the world could not? Which aspects of the model are no longer sustainable, either because of unanticipated changes in Europe and elsewhere or because some European countries have transformed themselves too fast? Which changes are needed now, and which can wait? These are the questions that this report asks. The short answers: Europe has achieved economic growth and convergence that is unprecedented (table 1 and spotlight one). Most countries in Europe are doing well in trade and ï¬?nance, many in enterprise and innovation, but far fewer are doing well in labor and government. So Europe needs many changes to make its governments and labor markets work better, fewer to foster innovation and productivity growth in enterprises, and fewer still to reform ï¬?nance and trade. These deï¬?ciencies are rooted in how some activities are organized—and they will need to be reorganized. Stalled productivity, declining populations, and growing ï¬?scal imbalances have made some changes urgent. But in addressing these shortcomings, Europeans should not forget the singular successes of their growth model. By fostering a regional economic integration unique in both depth and scope, Europe has become a “convergence machine.â€? By engineering entrepreneurial dynamism in the countries that balanced market forces and social responsibility, it has made “brand Europeâ€? globally recognized and valued. And by allowing a balance between life and work, it has made Europe the world’s “lifestyle superpower.â€? To continue the progress of the last ï¬?ve decades, Europeans now have to do three progressively tougher tasks: restart the convergence machine, rebuild Europe’s global brand, and recalibrate the balance between work and leisure to make their lifestyles affordable. Table 1: Relentless growth in the United States, revival in Asia, and a postwar miracle in Europe (average annual compound growth rates, GDP per capita, 1820–2008, US$ 1990 Geary-Khamis PPP estimates) Former Western Southern Eastern Soviet United Latin Year Europe Europe Europe Union States Japan East Asia America 1820–1870 1.0 0.6 0.6 0.6 1.3 0.2 –0.1 0.0 1870–1913 1.3 1.0 1.4 1.0 1.8 1.4 0.8 1.8 1913–1950 0.8 0.4 0.6 1.7 1.6 0.9 –0.2 1.4 1950–1973 3.8 4.5 3.6 3.2 2.3 7.7 2.3 2.5 1973–1994 1.7 1.9 –0.2 –1.6 1.7 2.5 0.3 0.9 1994–2008 1.6 2.7 4.0 4.2 1.7 1.0 3.9 1.6 Note: Regional aggregates are population-weighted; see spotlight one for details. Source: Maddison 1996; Conference Board 2011. 5 GOLDEN GROWTH The convergence machine An increasingly vigorous flow of goods, services, and ï¬?nance over the last ï¬?ve decades has fueled European growth. Europe’s economies are the most open in the world. Before the global crisis of 2008–09, half of the world’s approximately $15 trillion trade in goods involved Europe (ï¬?gure 2). Two-thirds of it was among the 45 countries discussed in this report. Financial flows have been equally vigorous. In 2007, for example, annual FDI in Europe exceeded $1 trillion. Big and growing trade and ï¬?nancial links facilitated by the single market form the core of the European convergence machine. Increasingly sophisticated trade During the last two decades, the new member states of the European Union have done especially well at taking advantage of the opportunities offered to them, integrating westward by trading goods and modern business services. During the last decade, the candidate countries of Southeastern Europe have been doing it through trade in merchandise and more traditional services such as travel and transport. This has helped enterprises in Western Europe too. With FDI and offshoring, enterprises in Western Europe such as Fiat, Renault, and Volkswagen have made themselves and eastern enterprises like Yugo, Dacia, and Å koda more efï¬?cient and sophisticated. Simpler tasks are being given to countries outside Europe; advanced Europe is getting emerging Europe to do more difï¬?cult things, and both regions are beneï¬?ting (chapter 2). Figure 2: Almost half of the global goods trade involves Europe (merchandise trade in 2008, US$ billion) Source: World Bank staff, based on WTO (2009); see chapter 2. 6 OVERVIEW The goods trade between advanced and emerging Europe has grown rapidly since the mid-1990s—when the European Union signed its ï¬?rst association agreements with Hungary and Poland—and this does not appear to be injuring trade with other parts of the world. Europe does a brisk goods trade with North America, Asia, the former Soviet Union, and Africa (ï¬?gure 2). But trade within the region has grown much more sophisticated over the last decade, aiding quick convergence in productive capacity and living standards. It is helping to create a bigger and stronger economic union between the European Free Trade Association (EFTA), the EU15, the new member states, the EU candidate countries, and even the eastern partnership economies. Factory Europe may not be expanding as fast as Factory Asia, but it has become smarter. And it could expand a lot too. With economic recovery and better trade facilities—especially information and communications infrastructure in the European Union’s new member states and the candidate countries—regional goods trade could double over the next decade. The trade in modern services in Europe is increasing too, but not fast enough for many Europeans. The benchmark for merchandise trade is East Asia, a developing region, but the European Union gauges the Single Market for Services against the United States, a developed country. Trading services is not easy: it often requires movement of people across borders, ease in establishing a local presence, and harmonious home–host regulations. Given all this, Europe’s trade in services does not seem stunted (ï¬?gure 3). But progress is mixed: travel and ï¬?nancial services have done well but transport and other business services—especially those involving new technologies and the Internet —have not. With reforms that make adopting newer technologies easier, better regulations, and greater mobility of workers, Europe’s trade in services could triple in size over the next decade. More important, productivity in the general services sector—which is about 70 percent of GDP in Europe—would increase. The opportunity that Europe might really be missing involves regional trade in agriculture. The European Union pays for its agricultural trade policies not just with the roughly €50 billion a year the European Commission spends on agriculture and rural development and their large indirect efï¬?ciency costs, but also through missed opportunities for closer economic integration with eastern partnership countries. In Georgia and Ukraine, a third of all workers still depend on agriculture for a living. Allowing better access to European farm markets would aid their development, win friends, and influence policies in the countries of the eastern partnership. Despite these weaknesses, the overall assessment of European trade is positive. In 2009, Europe’s merchandise trade was worth about $4.5 trillion, more than East Asia’s and North America’s combined. Its trade in services was worth $2.25 trillion, more than that of the rest of the world combined. Trade is the mainstay of the European economic model and its most attractive attribute. Finance that flows downhill Financial integration is the second part of the convergence machine. Finance has served Europe well. This may come as a surprise to those who blame the current crisis in the eurozone on banks that lent money to spendthrift 7 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3: More trade in services 100 Distribution of services exports, 2008, in Europe, but apparently in 90 more traditional activities Modern 80 (services exports in the European Other business Royalties/license fees Union, United States, and Japan, 2008) 70 Computer/information 60 Financial percent Note: The numbers in parentheses refer to the Insurance sum of traditional and modern service exports as 50 Communications a percentage of GDP. Traditional 40 Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Cultural/recreational IMF BOPS; see chapter 2. 30 Construction Travel 20 Transportation 10 0 (9.0) (9.9) (3.7) (3.0) EU15 EU12 United Japan States Figure 4: In Europe, foreign 8.0 capital has boosted growth 8 7.4 Real per capita GDP growth, in emerging economies 6.8 6.7 (current account deï¬?cits and per 6 capita growth, 1997-08, by groups of 5.2 percent 4.7 countries, percent) 3.8 4 3.5 Note: Average growth rates calculated using 3 2.9 2.5 four-year periods in 1997–2008. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on 1.9 2 IMF WEO; see chapter 3. 0 Current account Current account Current account Current account deï¬?cit: deï¬?cit: surplus: surplus: More than Less than Less than More than 10 percent 10 percent 10 percent 10 percent EU12 EU candidates Eastern partnership Non−European EME governments. But European ï¬?nance has a desirable attribute: capital of all types flows from richer to poorer countries, from low- to high-growth countries. Financial FDI—big investments by Austrian, French, Italian, and Swedish banks in Central and Eastern Europe—is a unique feature of Europe. In the east, it has helped (chapter 3). Figure 4 shows the relationship between economic growth and current account deï¬?cits in the new member states of the European Union, its candidates, the eastern partnership countries, and other emerging economies. An upward sloping arrow means that countries that ran smaller deï¬?cits or larger external account surpluses grew faster. In other words, a country grew faster if it lent 8 OVERVIEW rather than borrowed abroad. And for emerging economies outside Europe, this is indeed what we see: capital flows from poorer, high-growth countries to richer, low-growth countries (green arrow). Call this the “China syndrome.â€? In Europe, capital behaves the way it should: it flows from richer to poorer economies, and countries receiving more capital grow faster. The laws of economics have held in Europe. They hold more ï¬?rmly the more institutionally integrated the economies have become with Western Europe—by membership in the European Union or by signaling the intention to join. Belarus and Ukraine, for example, have done neither, and they look a lot like emerging market economies outside Europe, growing faster when they have external account surpluses (capital outflows) or smaller current account deï¬?cits. In 2008, when the ï¬?nancial crisis hit, people who were familiar with earlier crises in Asia and Latin America expected a massive pullout by western banks. It did not happen: foreign banks stayed, renewing 90 percent of the loans they had made, a much higher proportion than in previous crises. Of course, during the preceding boom some governments, enterprises, banks, and households abused the opportunities provided by this model of ï¬?nancial integration. And today, as western banks face pressures to offset losses in Southern Europe, they may have to sell their proï¬?table businesses in Eastern Europe. But the beneï¬?ts have been greater than the excesses, and some reforms can make the flows more stable and their beneï¬?ts even greater: better management of public ï¬?nance during booms in both advanced and emerging Europe, and more adept regulatory structures to crisis-proof private ï¬?nance. To grow at high and steady rates, economies in emerging Europe have not had to “become Asian.â€? Nor should they have to now. Restarting the convergence machine In the early 2000s, an important debate took place. For two decades, economists had been puzzled by the ï¬?nding that a country was able to invest only as much as what it could itself save. In theory, capital flows should allow savers in wealthier, or low-growth, countries to ï¬?nance investment in poorer, or high-growth, economies. They would get a higher return on their money, and these ï¬?nancial flows would allow the people in developing nations to save less and consume more, and invest more and grow faster. Unfortunately, it did not seem to happen; instead, there was a strong correlation between saving and investment across countries (Feldstein and Horioka 1980). But in the European Union between 1992 and 2001, especially the eurozone, research showed that something had changed. Greece and Portugal had run large current account deï¬?cits ï¬?nanced by foreign capital inflows; their savings had fallen, investment had increased, and their economies had grown (Blanchard and Giavazzi 2002). The question was whether policymakers—national governments, the European Union, and the European Central Bank—should welcome these growing imbalances, or worry about them. With the beneï¬?t of hindsight the answer is, of course, both. The capital inflows were the result of trade and ï¬?nancial integration, and they were supposed to make Greece and Portugal more productive and richer economies. Until about 2001, they did, and their living standards converged to those of more advanced 9 GOLDEN GROWTH European economies. But since 2002, labor productivity in Europe’s southern countries has been falling. The sheer volume of flows meant that inflows replaced domestic saving. Increasingly, though, they did not fund productive investment. Obviously, the borrowed money had not always been used well. It had flowed in on the belief that Greek and Portuguese debts would be serviced or repaid. By 2009, it was clear that this was going to be difï¬?cult. In the new member states, the same story was being played out, but with many more happy endings than sad. In countries such as the Czech Republic and Poland, foreign savings flowed into productive uses, and both Western European savers and Eastern European investors beneï¬?ted. In some others, ever larger flows began to ï¬?nance consumption, sometimes by the government but more often by households. In these countries, economic growth went into reverse during the global ï¬?nancial crisis. Restarting the convergence machine will not be difï¬?cult. The Single Market for Services is becoming more efï¬?cient, and national governments can accelerate the process by fully implementing the European Union’s Services Directive. For many services, measures to increase mobility of labor among countries will help greatly. For other more modern services that can be sold digitally, harmonious regulations may be much of what is needed. New member states of the European Union and the candidate countries in Southeastern Europe will have to continue easing the bottlenecks in transport and communication infrastructure and modern services, so that trade in manufactures can facilitate the production networks that have been growing in size and sophistication. The European Union can also help millions of people in the eastern partnership countries— whose combined GDP is less than $0.5 trillion—by giving better access to its $1 trillion market for food and other farm products. A lot of this is happening. It is ï¬?nance, the fuel for the machine, which needs more attention. Europe’s convergence machine needs a better regulator of ï¬?nancial flows. Finance flows in the right direction in Europe—proof positive of the soundness of the system. But the flows are erratic, flooding Europe’s less advanced economies when ï¬?nance is plentiful, and starving them of ï¬?nance when savers and investors in advanced countries become skittish. Financial flows could be made steadier through conservative ï¬?scal policies and prudential regulations, so that they do not suddenly stop when growth slows. Canada, the Czech Republic, Croatia, and Poland showed what can be done during good times, and Sweden and the Republic of Korea have shown ways to quickly get ï¬?rms and households out from under a debt overhang when boom-time ï¬?nances fuel excesses and cause busts (Iwulska 2011). “Europeâ€?—a global brand As convergence has slowed and even gone into reverse in parts of Europe, the entire region is getting a bad press. Europe’s best days are behind it, it is now said. High unemployment among young people, stagnant worker productivity, unsustainable public ï¬?nances, and archaic social protection and innovation systems that are unsuited for a globalized economy are all presented as symptoms of economic decay. But the heart of an economy is neither labor nor 10 OVERVIEW government—it is enterprise. Since the mid-1990s, during a period when Asia had a huge ï¬?nancial crisis and bigger recovery, and the United States had a spectacular technology boom and a massive ï¬?nancial crisis, European enterprise has quietly flourished. This is no mean achievement, because Europe expects much from its enterprises. Their shareholders expect them to add value and turn a proï¬?t, workers expect them to create jobs, and governments want them to bring in export earnings. Remarkably, over the last decade and a half, European enterprises have delivered all three (ï¬?gure 5). Between 1995 and 2009, job growth in advanced Europe outstripped that in the United States. The new member states of the European Union and the candidate countries engineered productivity increases that outstripped those in East Asia and Latin America. Exports of goods and services in advanced and emerging Europe rose faster than output, and exceeded the growth rates even of the heralded BRIC economies (chapter 4). German and Swedish manufactures, produce from France and the Netherlands, and British and Italian banks have global reach and reputation; Czech engineering, Estonian information technology, and Turkish construction companies are quickly acquiring them. These are not the signs of a region in decay. With Asian enterprises becoming more active globally, the next few decades might well require European enterprises to make changes in how and where they do business. For now, the numbers show that in aggregate, European enterprise has been a reliable component of the economic model. Southern enterprise falters But not all is well. Employment growth in the EU12 could have been quicker, productivity growth in the EU15 should have been faster, and EU candidate and eastern partnership countries should raise exports to levels seen in the rest of Europe (see top ï¬?ve bars in ï¬?gure 5). Perhaps most worrisome are the productivity patterns since 2002, which show that parts of Europe have been faltering (ï¬?gure 6). Northern countries such as Finland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom—and later the Baltic economies—have done well, and continental economies such as Austria, France, Luxembourg, and Germany—and later the Czech Republic, Poland, and others—have been doing well too. But countries in Southern Europe—Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain—have not. From 2002 to 2008, they created jobs, but mainly in cyclical activities like construction or in less productive enterprises (like micro and family ï¬?rms). And the productivity of their workers has been falling. A premature adoption of the euro by southern economies is sometimes blamed for this reversal of fortune. Others say that letting the formerly communist countries into the European Union so soon did not give the south enough time to become competitive. But perhaps the most likely explanation is that of all the economies in Europe, the entrepreneurial structures of Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain were least suited for the wider European economy. For one thing, a sizable part of net output in southern economies is generated in small ï¬?rms —almost a third of it in tiny enterprises (with fewer than 10 workers; ï¬?gure 7). 11 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 5: European enterprises EFTA 1.3 1.4 50.2 have delivered jobs, EU15 1.3 1.0 49.4 productivity, and exports EU12 0.4 3.0 57.5 (performance of European subregions EU candidates 0.6 3.6 31.2 and benchmark countries, 1995–2009) Eastern partnership −0.1 6.6 38.7 United States 1.2 1.6 11.2 Japan −0.1 1.2 13.4 China 1.0 7.8 26.7 East Asia 1.7 2.0 64.0 Latin America 2.4 0.4 23.2 0 1 2 3 0 2 4 6 8 0 20 40 60 Employment growth, 1995−2009, Productivity growth, 1995−2009, Exports, 2009, percent of GDP percent percent Note: Growth rates in employment and productivity are compound annual growth rates. Average values by group are shown. China and Japan are also included in the calculation of East Asia’s regional average. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on WDI and ILO (2010); see chapter 4. Figure 6: Much of 100 92 Europe is becoming Labor productivity, 2002, thousands of 2005 US$ 83 more productive, 80 71 75 71 66 but the south has 60 −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−− 63 60 63 61 61 60 fallen behind 49 45 35 (labor productivity 40 −−−−−−−−−− levels in 2002, 26 22 20 thousands of 2005 16 16 16 15 14 10 9 −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−− 7 US$) 5 0 NOR IRL DNK FIN GBR SWE LUX BEL AUT NLD DEU FRA ITA ESP GRC PRT SVN HUN SVK CZE POL EST LVA LTU ROM BGR EFTA EU15 EU15 EU15 EU12 EU12 EU12 North Continental South Continental North South 10.4 (labor productivity 10 Labor productivity growth, 8.9 growth, 2002–08, 7.6 2002−2008, percent 8 7.5 annual percentage 5.9 6.4 increase) 6 −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−− 4.7 4.8 4.2 4 2.5 2.3 3.1 −−−−−−−−−− EU15 South 3.6 1.9 expected 2 0.7 0.6 1.4 growth 0.9 1.3 0.8 0 −−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−− 0.4 −2 −−−−−−−−−− growth Actual −0.1 −0.6 −0.5 −0.1 −2.0 NOR IRL DNK FIN GBR SWE LUX BEL AUT NLD DEU FRA ITA ESP GRC PRT SVN HUN SVK CZE POL EST LVA LTU ROM BGR EFTA EU15 EU15 EU15 EU12 EU12 EU12 North Continental South Continental North South Note: For Belgium, Greece, and Norway, productivity levels refer to 2003 (top panel). In the bottom panel, the period considered varies: Belgium and Norway (2003–08); Greece (2003–07); and the Czech Republic, France, Latvia, Romania, and the United Kingdom (2002–07). The three lines in each panel show average values for countries covered by each line. Expected growth for EU15 South is obtained by computing gaps in productivity levels between EU15 South and each of the other two groups and then applying these shares to the difference in growth between the ï¬?rst (that is, EFTA, EU15 North, and EU15 Continental) and the third (EU12) groups. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat; see chapter 4. 12 OVERVIEW This is not an entrepreneurial proï¬?le suited for a big market. Unsurprisingly, with the expansion of the single market in the 2000s, foreign capital from the richer economies of Continental Europe quickly changed direction, going east instead of south as it had done in the 1990s (ï¬?gure 8). Did the south need more time to adjust, or did it squander opportunities? The latter seems more plausible. Ireland has shown that EU institutions and resources can be translated quickly into competitiveness. The Baltic economies are now doing the same. The chief culprits for the south’s poor performance were high taxes and too many regulations, often poorly administered. While these mattered less when its eastern neighbors were communist and China and India suffered the least business-friendly systems in the world, they are now crippling southern enterprise (ï¬?gure 9). But there are reasons to be optimistic. The sovereign debt crisis has led to a resumption of regulatory reform in these countries, and the experience of countries such as Latvia and Lithuania shows that the necessary improvements can be done over years, not decades. And they need to be done quickly. From 2003 to 2006, Europeans who felt that globalization was an opportunity for their enterprises fell from 56 to 37 percent (Morley and Ward 2008). By 2006, the share of people who felt it was a threat to European enterprises and employment was almost half. The Danes, Swedes, Dutch, and Estonians were the most positively disposed to globalization; the French, Greeks, Belgians, and Cypriots the least. It is not a coincidence that the countries where people are wary of competition have the worst business climate in Europe. Europe would get even more from its enterprises if it made doing business easier. Southern Europe must start doing this now, and Central and Eastern Europe should continue improving the investment climate. Otherwise, enterprises will remain small and unproductive—increasingly unable to attract foreign investors, incapable of taking advantage of a pan-European market that will only get bigger and more competitive, and progressively uncompetitive in global markets, where they have to contend with enterprises from East Asia and North America. A better business climate will help to stem the growth of imbalances within Europe, restart the convergence machine, and make European enterprises globally competitive. Countries such as Denmark, Germany, Finland, Ireland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom show how it can be done (Iwulska 2011). The north innovates But making it easier to do business will not be enough on its own. When productivity gaps were growing within Europe, the gap between the advanced economies of Europe and the United States started to widen after almost disappearing in the mid-1990s. Indeed, the 2000s were a decade of declining productivity in the EU15 relative to both the United States and Japan, the world’s next two largest economies after the European Union during that time (ï¬?gure 10). Between 1995 and 2009, labor productivity in the United States grew at 1.6 percent annually, in Japan at 1.2 percent, and in the EU15 at just 1 percent (ï¬?gure 5). 13 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 7: Smaller ï¬?rms contribute 100 44.3 38.9 27.0 41.3 34.6 26.7 Value added by ï¬?rm size, 2009, half of value added in the EU15 South, but just a third elsewhere 80 Large (250+) (contributions to value added by size 17.3 28.9 of enterprises, 2009) 24.9 60 percent 19.6 Medium (50−249) 22.7 17.3 23.8 Note: The numbers in parentheses are the total value added expressed in billions of constant 40 20.3 26.1 Small (10−49) 22.2 2005 U.S. dollars. The EU15 comprises Denmark, 17.5 16.4 Finland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom 31.9 (North); Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, and 20 Micro (1−9) the Netherlands (Continental); and Greece, Italy, 20.9 21.2 19.7 18.3 18.3 Portugal, and Spain (South). The EU12 comprises Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania (North); the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, the Slovak Republic, 0 North Conti− South Conti− South North and Slovenia (Continental); and Bulgaria and (1,393B) nental (1,214B) nental (49B) (23B) Romania (South). (2,793B) (263B) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on EU15 EU12 Eurostat; see chapter 4. Figure 8: Western European investors 100 have been looking east, not south FDI inflow share in Europe, (foreign direct investment inflows in 80 Europe, percent, 1985, 1995, 2005, and 56.2 EU15 North 2008) 60 77.1 79.2 79.4 EU15 Continental percent EFTA Note: The numbers in parentheses are the Emerging Europe 40 amount of inflows expressed in billions of U.S. dollars. 27.8 EU15 South Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on 1.0 UNCTAD (2010); see chapter 4. 20 10.3 12.4 21.9 16.0 10.5 8.1 0 1985 1995 2005 2008 (17.2B) (139.4B) (600.6B) (624.0B) Reassuringly, productivity in Northern Europe grew at 1.7 percent per year during the same period. What has the north done to encourage enterprise and innovation? Much of its success has come from creating a good climate for doing business. All the northern economies are in the top 15 countries of 183 in the World Bank’s Doing Business rankings; at 14th, Sweden is the lowest- ranked among them. They have given their enterprises considerable economic freedom. Their governments are doing a lot more. They have speeded up innovation by downloading the “killer applicationsâ€? that have made the United States the global leader in technology: better incentives for enterprise- sponsored research and development (R&D), public funding mechanisms and intellectual property regimes to foster proï¬?table relations between universities and ï¬?rms, and a steady supply of workers with tertiary education. Tellingly, Europe’s innovation leaders perform especially well in areas where Europe as a whole lags the United States the most. These features make them global 14 OVERVIEW 90 90.7 87.2 Figure 9: Southern and Eastern Europe 82.8 79.5 must make it easier to do business Quality of regulations, 2011, 76.0 74.4 74.5 0−100: higher, better 69.4 68.0 64.4 66.5 (principal components index of the 60 ease of doing business in 2011, scaled from 0 [poor] to 100 [excellent]) 30 Note: Averages are computed using principal component analysis. EFTA here comprises Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland. The EU15 0 USA JPN EFTA EU15 North Conti− South EU12 North Conti− South comprises Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Sweden, nental nental and the United Kingdom (North); Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands (Continental); and Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain (South). The EU12 comprises Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania (North); the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia (Continental); and Bulgaria, Cyprus, and Romania (South). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Doing Business; see chapter 4. 160 Figure 10: Productivity growth in Europe’s larger economies has slowed down since the mid-1990s 140 EU15 labor productivity Relative to (EU15 labor productivity, indexed to Japan the United States and Japan) 120 Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on 100 the OECD Productivity database; see chapter 5. 80 Relative to United States 60 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 leaders; combining them with generous government spending on R&D and public education systems makes their innovation systems distinctively European (chapter 5). For Europe’s larger continental economies that have reached or exceeded U.S. standards in physical, ï¬?nancial, and human capital, R&D and other innovation deï¬?cits are likely to be growth inhibitors. In dynamic Eastern Europe, countries need not invest much more in R&D and the production of knowledge. But they must still innovate through osmosis: they have considerable scope for the quick adoption of existing technologies, using FDI and trade links as conduits. The south is becoming slower in importing new technologies: FDI inflows and outflows have been falling since the economies in emerging Europe integrated with Continental and Northern Europe. For these increasingly service-oriented economies, reform of domestic regulations—not more R&D spending—may be the best way to speed up innovation. 15 GOLDEN GROWTH What has been more perplexing is Europe’s generally poor performance in the most technology-intensive sectors—the Internet, biotechnology, computer software, health care equipment, and semiconductors. Put another way, Korea; Taiwan, China; and the United States have been doing well in sectors that are huge now but barely existed in 1975. Europe has been doing better in the more established sectors, especially industrial machinery, electrical equipment, telecommunications, aerospace, automobiles, and personal goods. The United States has young ï¬?rms like Amazon, Amgen, Apple, Google, Intel, and Microsoft; Europe has the older like Airbus, Mercedes, Nokia, and Volkswagen. Europe’s young leading innovators (called “Yolliesâ€? for short) are as R&D- intensive as those in the United States. Europe just has a lot fewer Yollies. As a result, while more than a third of U.S. R&D spending is by Yollies, it is less than one-ï¬?fteenth in Europe. The United States focuses its R&D efforts on innovation-based growth sectors (ï¬?gure 11). Europe specializes in sectors with medium R&D intensity. Japan is showing other East Asian countries how productivity growth can be maintained in established industries such as automobiles and electronics, and Germany may be doing the same. With the size and diversity of the European economy, productivity growth will likely come both from doing what Japan has done and adopting parts of the American innovation system. But to do either, the common market will have to become more of a single economy. All European countries should have the friendly business climate that Denmark, Ireland, and Norway have. It is not a coincidence that the only large European economies that rival the United States and Japan in innovation are Germany and the United Kingdom, which were both ranked in the top 20 countries for ease of doing business in 2011. Many more European countries should have the universities like those in the United States and Japan, where more than one Figure 11: The United States specializes in younger, more R&D-intensive products United 10.2 (relative technological advantage 1.4 States 3.5 and R&D efforts by young and old innovation leaders in the United 4.4 States, Europe, and the rest of the 0.9 Europe world) 2.8 Rest of 2.6 Note: R&D intensity is measured as the 0.6 the world ratio of R&D spending to total sales, for 2.0 ï¬?rms established after 1975 (young leading innovators or “Yolliesâ€?) or before 1975 1.1 (“Olliesâ€?). The relative technological advantage Technology 0.5 Japan Yollies is calculated as the share of each region or 3.7 specialized Ollies country (say, Europe) in the R&D of a particular sector (say, the Internet) relative to the 1.5 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.3 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 share of Europe in world R&D; values greater Relative technological advantage R&D intensity than one indicate the region is technology- in innovation−based growth sectors (R&D to total sales ratio) specialized in the sector. Source: Bruegel and World Bank staff calculations, based on the European Commission’s Institute for Prospective Technological Studies R&D Scoreboard; see chapter 5. 16 OVERVIEW out of two people ages 30–34 have completed college; in Europe, only Ireland, Denmark, Norway, Luxembourg, and Finland exceed 45 percent. More countries will have to improve their business–science links to rival those in the United States and Japan; currently, only Switzerland and Scandinavia do as well. Burnishing the brand Perhaps the simplest and most reliable way to assess the innovation performance of a country is to see how much more productive its enterprises become every year—that is, how much better they are in buying, producing, and selling. During the last decade, two things have happened that should worry Europeans. The ï¬?rst is that since the mid-1990s, labor productivity in Europe’s advanced economies has been falling relative to that of the United States (and Japan). The second is that productivity in Southern Europe has been falling compared with that in both the advanced countries in Western Europe and the less well-off countries in emerging Europe. How can these gaps be closed? It depends on the gap. For reducing that between the south and the north, the most important steps involve improving business regulations. Countries in the EU12 South—notably Bulgaria—and Georgia have been showing that this can be done even in the poorest parts of Europe. For closing the transatlantic productivity gap, more is necessary. Leading European economies such as Switzerland, Sweden, Finland, Denmark, and Germany are showing what works. Following their example would mean giving up the ï¬?xation on public R&D spending targets, and focusing instead on improving competition among enterprises, increasing the private funding of universities, changing the way research is funded so that business-university linkages become stronger, and making the single market work for services so that Europe’s entrepreneurs view the entire continent as their domestic economy. There are reasons to be optimistic. During the last two decades, countries in the EFTA—Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland principally—have actually done better in improving productivity than the United States. Northern parts of the EU15—especially Denmark, Finland, Ireland, and Sweden—have also been doing well. The trouble is that their economies add up to less than $1.5 trillion in purchasing power terms, roughly the GDP of Spain or Texas and just a tenth of the European Union’s economy (see the Selected Indicators tables). If the rest of Europe could beneï¬?t from the dynamism of northern economies—by learning from them or leaning on them—Europe’s innovation goals might quickly be reached. Chapters 4 and 5 make it clear that preserving Europe’s global brand will be more difï¬?cult than restarting convergence. To stay competitive on world markets, Europe will have to make trade even more vigorous and ï¬?nance more durable so that the region eventually becomes a single economy. To help redress the continent’s growing productivity gaps, governments in Southern Europe will have to quickly improve the climate for doing business. The more dynamic countries in Eastern Europe will have to do all this as well as invest in infrastructure. To close the growing transatlantic productivity divide, continental countries must give their enterprises more economic freedom. Enterprises in the northern and EFTA economies—already among the world’s most innovative—will 17 GOLDEN GROWTH need fuller access to markets in the rest of Europe. Europe will have to become the top destination for those seeking higher education and the opportunity to become entrepreneurs. Only then can European enterprises stay globally competitive, and Europe become the place of choice of entrepreneurs from around the world. The lifestyle superpower In 2008, Europe was already the place of choice for tourists: of the busiest 20 international tourist destinations, more than half were in Europe. The United States had the might and China the momentum, but Europeans had the highest standard of living. Millions of people from around the world visited Europe to see and experience it ï¬?rsthand. In the 1990s, Japan’s Prime Minister Kiichi Miyazawa had promised he would make his country the “lifestyle superpower.â€? With average incomes still a quarter short of those in the United States, Europe had become one. Superpowers tend to spend a lot to protect their interests and project influence. To remain the political superpower, the United States spends almost as much on defense as the next 15 countries do together. To keep its status as the lifestyle superpower, Europe spends more on social protection than the rest of the world combined (ï¬?gure 12). The decline of work The hallmark of the European economic model is perhaps the balance between work and life. With prosperity, Americans buy more goods and services, Europeans more leisure. In the 1950s, Western Europeans worked the equivalent of almost a month more than Americans. By the 1970s, they worked about the same amount. Today, Americans work a month a year more than Dutch, French, Germans, and Swedes, and work notably longer than the less well-off Greeks, Hungarians, Poles, and Spaniards (chapter 6). Figure 12: Outspending the rest of the world Government expenditure, percentage of world total (general government spending on defense [United States] and social Military (n=124) Social protection (n=96) 2010 2004−09 protection [Europe], 2004–09, share of total world spending) Note: For social protection spending, due to the data availability, averages over United 2004–09 by country are used. Data cover general States Rest of 43% Rest of Europe government but, if unavailable, refer to central the world the world (n=36) government only. n = the number of countries 57% 42% 58% included in the calculations. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2011); IMF GFS; WDI; World Bank ECA Social Protection Database; and Weigand and Grosh (2008). 18 OVERVIEW Europeans have also cut the years they work during their (ever-lengthening) lives. Today, men in France, Hungary, Poland, and Turkey effectively retire more than eight years earlier than in the mid-1960s. The average European can also expect to live four years longer. By 2007, Frenchmen expected to draw pensions for 15 more years than in 1965, and Austrian, Polish, Spanish, Swiss, and Turkish men for more than a dozen. In Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development countries, only Korean, German, and Czech men work more years today than they did 50 years ago (ï¬?gure 13). American, Australian, and Canadian men also retire about four years earlier than they used to. But their countries have more favorable demographics than the typical European country (ï¬?gure 14). On current immigration and work participation trends, the 45 countries covered by this report will lose about 50 million workers over the next ï¬?ve decades, and have a workforce of about 275 million by 2060. In the 2030s alone, the labor force will fall by 15 million people. The decline will be most severe for the European Union (countries such as France, which have high fertility rates today, do better), but candidate and neighborhood countries will also lose workers. The exception is Turkey, where the labor force is projected to increase until 2060. Only with radical changes can Europe counteract the shrinking of its labor force. If participation rates in all countries were to converge with those seen in Northern Europe, or if the retirement age were to increase by 10 years across the board, the European labor force would increase marginally over the next 50 years. If female labor force participation converged with men’s, the labor force Figure 13: Europe’s pension systems have to support people for many more years (changes in life expectancy at 60 and effective retirement age, 1965–2007) 7.5 8 7.3 7.3 6.3 6.3 6.5 6.4 6.4 5.8 6.1 5.5 5.4 5.7 5.4 Change from 1965 to 2007, years 5.1 5.3 5.2 4.9 4.4 4.1 3.5 3.5 3.7 3.6 4 3.0 3.2 3.1 2.4 1. 6 1. 4 1. 6 0.8 0.1 0 −1. 0 −1. 2 −1. 3 −2. 1 −2. 6 −2. 9 −4 −3. 0 −3. 9 −4.0 −4.3 −4.5 −4.8 −4.9 −5.0 −5.1 −5.7 −6.1 −6.5 −6.8 −8 −7.5 −7.8 −7.8 −8.0 −8.9 Life expectancy at age 60, men −9.6 −12 Retirement age, men −11.1 −12.2 KOR DEU CZE SVK ISL NZL SWE CAN JPN AUS USA NOR BEL GBR DNK GRC NLD ITA FIN LUX PRT CHE IRL AUT MEX ESP FRA HUN TUR POL Source: OECD (2011); updated data from OECD (2006). 19 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 14: Europe’s labor force 30 will shrink, while North America’s Working−age population, 2010=0 will grow by a quarter 20 North America (projected cumulative change in working-age population, 2010–50, 10 percent) 0 Note: North America is Canada and the United Emerging Europe Western Europe States and North-East Asia includes China; Hong Kong SAR, China; Japan; Macao SAR, −10 China; the Republic of Korea; and Taiwan, China. North−East Asia Source: U.S. Census Bureau, International Data −20 Base; see chapter 6. 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 Figure 15: Europeans are less mobile, 3.1 Cross−border labor mobility, even within their own countries 3 working−age population (labor mobility, share of working age 2.2 percentage of 2.0 2000−05, 2 population that has moved, 2000-05) 1.0 1.0 1 0.8 Source: Bonin and others (2008); OECD (2005 and 2007); see chapter 6. 0.4 0.4 0.1 0 USA JPN AU S EU15 CAN EU27 CAN EU EU15 − − − − − − − − − 50 TL2− 8 NUTS−1 10 NUTS−2 Quebec Commuting 15 states level states/ regions provinces/ regions and across countries regions territories within territories within 9 other borders countries countries provinces would still decrease by 5 percent. But none of these changes would completely offset the loss of young workers. For that, Europe will need to integrate Turks into the European labor market and attract talented young workers from around the world. In one plausible scenario, Turkey could contribute 40 percent of the gains in the European labor force, and almost all of the increase in young workers. Fixing the European labor market will require a lot: increasing the competition for jobs, improving labor mobility within Europe, ï¬?xing how work and welfare interact, and rethinking immigration policies. These changes will not happen without a new social consensus, which has yet to be built. Perhaps the best way to start is to accelerate internal labor mobility in Europe. Mobility in the European Union is the lowest in the developed world (ï¬?gure 15). There are natural barriers to greater labor mobility associated with language and cultural differences, but there are also policy-induced obstacles. In most of the older EU member states, there are restrictions on the movement of workers from the new member states. Housing markets in many European countries can be inefï¬?cient and make moving expensive: the transaction costs of buying or selling a house can be high. Despite measures to ensure the portability of social beneï¬?ts across the European Union, including pensions and unemployment 20 OVERVIEW insurance, in practice it is limited because of cumbersome rules. Generous unemployment beneï¬?ts discourage workers from seeking jobs. Labor market signals can be muted by collective bargaining agreements that limit territorial wage differentiation. To make the single market work better, making labor more mobile should be a priority. For the countries that share the common currency, it is a prerequisite (box 1). Then, Europe has to make changes in how work is regulated and social security provided. Many countries in Western Europe had started to reverse the decline in work participation during the late 1990s and early 2000s; many in Central, Eastern, and Southern Europe now must do the same. The main attribute of the European economic model that needs to be reassessed is employment protection legislation, which is lowering participation and reducing employment in many countries. In countries such as Spain, it may be responsible for youth unemployment rates as high as 40 percent. Paradoxically, Europe has impending shortages of young workers and high joblessness among its youth. Denmark and Germany have shown how this can be remedied (Iwulska 2011). Other countries like Croatia, Moldova, Poland, Romania, and Turkey may have to learn quickly and carefully implement the lessons. The countries in emerging Europe will also have to decide—based on their cultural and political antecedents—whether to move toward greater job security and join countries such as Belgium and France, or toward greater flexibility and become more like the North Americans and East Asians. To have both as in Denmark, they will have to consider the greater ï¬?scal costs of “flexicurity.â€? At the moment, most countries have neither. While all this is being done, Europe’s policymakers could get people to appreciate the need for a new approach to immigration. Europe needs an immigration policy that is more driven by economic need. Today the debate is about how to best manage migration from North Africa. Tomorrow’s debate should be about the policies and practices that will make Europe a global magnet for talent. Countries like Sweden and the United Kingdom have been doing this, but not quite as effectively as Canada and the United States (Iwulska 2011). The precipitate promise of social protection Europe will have to make big changes in how it organizes labor and government. The reasons are becoming ever more obvious: the labor force is shrinking, societies are aging, social security is already a large part of government spending, and ï¬?scal deï¬?cits and public debt are often already onerous. In dealing with government spending, deï¬?cits, and debt, it is sensible to start by asking whether European governments are too big; that is, whether they spend too much. They are obviously bigger than their peers. In the EU15, governments spent 50 percent of GDP in 2009; in much of the rest of Europe, this share was about 45 percent—versus less than 40 percent in the United States and Japan, 33 percent in Latin America, and about 25 percent in emerging East Asia. A map of the world resized to reflect government spending instead of land area shows how Europe might look to outsiders (ï¬?gure 16). 21 GOLDEN GROWTH Governments in Europe spend between 7 and 10 percent of GDP more than their peers elsewhere—that is, countries at similar levels of per capita income. The difference is mostly the spending on social protection. For example, Western European governments spend about 10 percent of GDP more than the United States, Canada, Australia, and Japan. The difference in social protection spending is 9 percent of GDP (ï¬?gure 17). Figure 16: Governments in Europe are big (the world resized by government spending in dollars, 2009) Source: World Bank staff, using IMF WEO. There can be good reasons for having bigger governments. If governments are good at supplying essential social services, and if European society wants to redistribute more to protect the welfare of the elderly, inï¬?rm, or unfortunate, they should provide these amenities. If European populations are older and social security systems have to be bigger, that may be another good reason for high-spending governments. European societies have been more redistributive and to good effect—look at the impressive declines in poverty in Western Europe since World War II and in Eastern Europe since the end of the Cold War. But social services, social welfare, and social security have to be ï¬?nanced by taxes, and tax rates in Europe are the highest in the world. For example, the tax wedge in Korea—the amount that Korean employers pay besides wages when hiring workers—is about a third of what Belgian enterprises pay and half of the taxes paid by businesses in Greece and Turkey. The question that such numbers provoke: is big government a drag on growth in Europe? It appears it is. Over the last 15 years, a 10 percentage point increase in initial government spending in Europe has lowered annual growth by 0.6–0.9 percentage points. Countries with government spending-to-GDP ratios above 40 percent grow by 2 percentage points of GDP less than those with lower ratios (chapter 7). Of course, size is not the only feature that matters. What government does and how it ï¬?nances its activities is as important. European governments regulate the largest economic area in the world; encourage a vigorous exchange of goods, services, and capital; promote voice and accountability; provide or enable the provision of public goods; and redistribute wealth. Bigger governments are often better at doing these things, especially when social trust ensures that 22 OVERVIEW everybody plays by the same rules. As countries like Sweden show, such big governments can go together with thriving, dynamic economies. But it is not easy being like Sweden. What does it take? Make it so easy to register property, trade across borders, and pay taxes that the World Bank ranks the country one of the top 15 for doing business. Create the conditions that get four out of every ï¬?ve people of working age into jobs, and get almost everybody who works to pay taxes. Have an efï¬?cient government that provides high-quality social services, so taxpayers get their money’s worth. Institute the pension rules that make it difï¬?cult to retire before 65 and impossible until you reach your 60s. Cultivate the social trust that allows both a generous social safety net and a transparency in government so that abuse is minimal. The list is long. If a country can do all this, big government will not hurt growth. Europe’s governments will have to become more efï¬?cient, or become smaller. Fortunately, governments that have grown prematurely big have done so for just one reason: social protection. Europe’s states are not big spenders on either health or education. The variation among countries stems from a difference in spending on pensions and social assistance. Europe’s countries also differ in how they tax these beneï¬?ts; Northern European countries tax the social security beneï¬?ts of people with high incomes more than others in Europe do. After taxes are considered, the southern periphery is the biggest social spender in Western Europe. But the reason why Europe spends more than its peers on public pensions is the same in the north, center, and south. This is not because Europe has the oldest population (Japan’s is much older) nor because of higher pension beneï¬?ts (annual subsidies per pensioner are about the same in Greece as in Japan). It spends more because of easier and earlier eligibility for pensions (ï¬?gure 18). Fiscal consolidation should be a top priority in Europe during the next decade, and controlling the public expenses related to aging will remain the policy imperative over the next 20 years. Calculations done for this report suggest that Western Europe has to improve its primary balance—adjusted for the business cycle—by about 6 percent of GDP during this decade to reduce public debt to 60 percent of GDP by 2030 (ï¬?gure 19). Among the countries of Western Europe, the need for consolidating public spending is greatest in the south and lowest in the north. Among Europe’s emerging economies, with a lower public debt target of 40 percent of GDP, the adjustment needs are about 5 percent of GDP. They are lowest in the European Union’s new member states. Bigger adjustments will be needed in candidate countries and the economies of the eastern partnership, because many of them have not begun seriously reforming their social protection systems—pensions, unemployment insurance, and social assistance. Public spending related to aging includes the ever-increasing costs of providing health care for the elderly. Without comprehensive reforms to pensions and long-term health care, these costs could add more than 3 percent of GDP to the governments’ ï¬?scal imbalance during the next two decades. Governments in Europe that spend more than 10 percent of GDP on such beneï¬?ts may be risking underinvestment in activities that help economic growth—education, infrastructure, and innovation. Countries such as Serbia and Ukraine that already spend 15 percent or more on social security alone may be jeopardizing the welfare of generations. 23 GOLDEN GROWTH Recalibrating the work–life balance The European model of work provides income security more than any other, and some countries such as Austria, Denmark, Ireland, and Switzerland have adapted it to combine security with flexibility in hiring and ï¬?ring to foster both efï¬?ciency and equity in labor market outcomes. But for much of Europe, the imbalances between work and life need to be mitigated, as do the ï¬?scal imbalances that have emerged as a result of public spending to protect societies from the rougher facets of private enterprise. Figure 17: Social protection explains 50 Government spending, 2007−08, the difference in government size between Europe and its peers 40 percentage of GDP 20.1 (government spending, percentage of 16. 7 16. 9 12. 6 7.3 GDP, 2007–08) 30 11. 7 12. 2 12. 7 4.6 6.3 6.7 5.4 5.3 3.9 6.2 Note: “Social protectionâ€? includes beneï¬?ts 3.9 20 7.1 6.2 4.5 4.2 7.8 related to sickness and disability, old age, 7.1 4.9 7.4 survivors, family and children, unemployment, and housing. Western Europe comprises 10 17. 4 16. 6 18. 3 18. 1 16. 4 Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and 14. 8 15. 8 12. 7 Sweden (North); Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, 0 Switzerland, and the United Kingdom (Center); North Center South EU12 EU Eastern United Japan Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain (South). Western Europe cand. partner− States ship Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF GFS and IMF WEO. Social protection Educatio n Health Nonsocial spending Figure 18: Small differences in annual Western pensions per beneï¬?ciary, big in 12.6 Europe 12.7 South overall public pension spending (public pension spending in 2007) Western 12.1 Europe 14.1 Center Note: Median values by group are shown. Western Europe comprises Denmark, Finland, Western 10.6 Europe 12.8 Iceland, Norway, and Sweden (North); Austria, North Belgium, France, Germany, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom (Center); Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Japan 8.8 11.9 Spain (South). Anglo-Saxon comprises Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat and the OECD Pensions Statistics; see 4.2 Anglo− 11.1 Saxon chapter 7. 12 9 6 3 0 0 3 6 9 12 15 Public pension spending, Real public pensions per elderly, PPP percentage of GDP thousands of international dollars 24 OVERVIEW Since the mid-1980s, a billion Asian workers have entered the global marketplace. Over the same period, Europeans have been working fewer hours per week, fewer weeks per year, and fewer years over their lifetimes. It is worrisome that their productivity is not increasing as quickly as it should. In the European Union’s southern states, for example, productivity during the last decade fell by 1 percent each year, when—given productivity levels relative to those in Continental and Northern Europe—it should have increased by about 4 percent annually. It is also worrisome that in many parts of Europe, taxes bring in less than what governments spend. France and Germany, for example, have not had a ï¬?scal surplus since the 1970s; Greece expected a budget deï¬?cit of about 10 percent of GDP in 2011; and Hungary, Serbia, Ukraine, and many others have been struggling to contain budgetary imbalances. This will have to change. The reform of pensions and disability allowances will have to be the highest priority now, with costs of long-term health care soon becoming a pressing problem. Europe already spends twice as much on social security as Japan and the United States. There are some countries in Europe that are showing how to address these problems. Some such as Sweden are well known; others like Iceland could be studied more (Iwulska 2011). European societies will also have to modernize social welfare systems so that the disincentives to work are minimized. Denmark, Germany, and Ireland may inspire others how this can be done. But what needs to be done is not hard to see: Europeans will have to work for more years. From distinct to distinguished In 2007 An East Asian Renaissance, a report by the World Bank, introduced the notion of the “middle-income trapâ€? (Gill and Kharas 2007). It was about why countries seem to easily grow from low per capita income levels to middle income, but ï¬?nd it difï¬?cult to become and remain high-income economies. Later research identiï¬?ed about two dozen countries that have grown from middle income to high income since 1987. Some had discovered oil, like Oman and Trinidad and Tobago. But this can hardly be a development model for others to emulate, because it is a matter more of providence than policy. Some, like Hong Kong SAR, China; Singapore; and Republic of Korea, had translated peace into prosperity through export-led strategies that involved working and saving a lot and sometimes postponing political liberties for later. They had to be aggressive, like tigers, looking out only for themselves. But of the countries that have grown quickly from middle-income to high- income, half—Croatia, Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Latvia, Malta, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia—are in Europe. If you can be a part of the formidable European convergence machine, you do not need to be extraordinarily fortunate to become prosperous nor—like the East Asian Tigers—do you have to be ferocious. You just have to be disciplined. The inability of this convergence machine to continue to deliver rapid growth and an improved quality of life in the advanced economies of Western Europe has been recognized for some time. Europe’s policymakers have put together protocols and commitments to encourage innovation and dynamism. Policies that were a core component of Europe’s postwar growth model—or those that evolved from 25 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 19: Western Europe Required adjustment has to reduce ï¬?scal deï¬?cits 10 Cyclically adjusted primary balance, 2010−20 by 6 percent of GDP, 4.1 Changes in pensions and health care, 2010−30 emerging Europe by less 8 (illustrative ï¬?scal adjustment needs, 2010–30, 6 5.9 percentage of GDP) 3.1 3.6 3.1 4 2.0 7.0 0.9 3.6 2 3.4 2.8 3.2 2.8 3.0 2.5 0 0.7 Overall North Center South Overall EU12 EU Eastern candi− partner− dates ship Western Europe Emerging Europe Note: The ï¬?scal impacts of aging on pensions and health care systems are missing for EU candidate and eastern partnership countries. For this exercise, the sum of adjustment in health care spending is assumed to be the same as for the new member states. The adjustment in pension related spending is assumed to be the same as that for Southern Europe. Western Europe comprises Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and Sweden (North); Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom (Center); Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain (South). Overall Western Europe contains all the countries belonging to these three groups. Overall emerging Europe includes all countries from EU12, EU candidates, and eastern partnership. Source: Calculations by staff of the Institute for Structural Research in Poland and the World Bank, based on IMF WEO; see chapter 7. it—are not giving European economies enough flexibility to take advantage of new technologies that have led to high productivity growth in Asia and North America during the last 15 years. It is not that European product market regulation and employment protection became more stringent over time; they just became more costly. The Western European model that so effectively enabled catch-up has created “afterglowâ€? institutions that are hindering growth in a different age—an era of greater competition abroad and big demographic shifts at home. These institutions now need updating. In the states aspiring to become part of the machine, notably the candidates, potential candidates, and the Eastern Neighborhood, the afterglow structures will probably not preclude the beneï¬?ts that come from greater economic union. In the new member states too, these institutions may not yet prevent productivity gains if their ties with advanced Europe become stronger and sophisticated. In the western economies, the structures must quickly be made more flexible. Convergence to a rigid core may soon become unappealing. The European Union has a growth strategy, Europe 2020, which recognizes this imperative. Not all of the 45 countries covered by this report are in the European Union, but most share the aspirations of Europe 2020: economic development that is smart, sustainable, and inclusive. Europe’s way of life—and its growth ambitions—put a premium on combining economic dynamism with environmental sustainability and social cohesion. 26 OVERVIEW Europe’s economic model is already more environment-friendly than most. It has made production cleaner than any other part of the world except Japan, and will become the lowest per capita emitter of carbon dioxide by 2020. But it is still the largest importer of emissions (embedded in imported products—ï¬?gure 20), polluting not as much through production as by proxy. Europeans will need to do more on the consumption side to be considered truly green. It is a testament to European ideals that Europe is willing to pay the most to avert global warming while it is likely to be damaged least. There is reason to believe that Europe’s economic model can become greener without unduly sacriï¬?cing growth: Germany, France, and Sweden may already be showing the way. Social cohesion is the cornerstone of Europe’s economic model, but this aspiration must be realized in ways consistent with sound economic principles. It can be, because Europe has three priceless assets: the European Union’s single market, a momentum for regional integration, and the global influence that comes from being the generator of one-third of the world’s annual output. Inclusive development will be a natural outcome of measures to deepen the single market, expand the scope of regional economic integration, and preserve Europe’s global influence (chapter 8). This will require adjustments in all of the European economic model’s six components. The rules to guide policymakers—adapted from Phelps (1966)—might look something like the following: · Extend the beneï¬?ts of freer trade to those outside the European Union. Enlargement has made Europe stronger, and economic integration should be continued toward the east. The single market can be made deeper and wider at the same time. · Borrow from abroad only for investment. In Europe, where foreign ï¬?nance has been used for private investment, it has fueled growth and convergence. But relying on foreign capital to ï¬?nance consumption makes economies everywhere more vulnerable than dynamic. · Provide enterprises with the freedom to start up, grow, and shut down. Efï¬?cient regulation of enterprise trusts but veriï¬?es, makes compliance easy but punishes violation, and assesses risks and concentrates resources where risks are highest. · Use public money to catalyze private innovation, not substitute for it. Effective innovation policy sets the table for innovators to thrive by supporting inventions, mobilizing ï¬?nance, and bringing the power of choice and the resources of business into Europe’s universities. · Design labor laws to treat insiders and outsiders more equally. Regulations should not favor either those with jobs or those without. Seeing labor as a ï¬?xed lump to be divided among workers leads to poor rules for regulating work. · Consider government debt mainly as a way to ï¬?nance public investment. With high debt levels and modest growth prospects, public ï¬?nance should be premised on the expectation that future generations will not be much wealthier than today’s. Social protection, social services, and public administration should be ï¬?nanced with taxes and contributions, not sovereign debt. 27 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 20: Greening European economies do not have to become North American or East Asian to production but not keep to these rules. But Europe might learn a few lessons from them. From consumption North Americans, Europe could learn that economic liberty and social security have to be balanced with care: nations that sacriï¬?ce too much economic (net CO2 emission freedom for social security can end up with neither, impairing both enterprise transfers [territorial and government. To get this balance wrong could mean giving up Europe’s minus consumption way of life and its place in the world. From the Japanese, the Koreans, and the emissions], 2008) Chinese, Europe might learn that while the gifts of prosperity and longevity arrive together, they have to be unbundled: being wealthier means that Note: MtCO2 = million tons of Europeans do not have to work as hard as before, but living longer means carbon dioxide. having to work more years, not fewer. To do otherwise unjustly burdens future Source: World Bank staff, using data from Peters and others generations, and violates growth’s golden rule. (2011); see spotlight 2. Europeans can of course learn the easiest and most from each other. The countries in Europe that have instituted policies manifesting both cultural maturity and economic discipline have shown how a distinct growth model can be made distinguished (table 2). 28 OVERVIEW Box 1: The unmet precondition of the common currency—labor mobility The September 1961 volume of the American labor were quick to move within the monetary goods trade in the eurozone may reduce the Economic Review might well be the most union, the dilemma would disappear. need for labor mobility, but trade in services— influential issue of an economic journal ever. now three-quarters of Western Europe’s For a practical application of his ideas, A dozen or so pages after the article on output—itself often requires movement Mundell chose Western Europe, presaging optimum growth paths by Phelps is a short of people. So does keeping manageable today’s debates about the euro. “In Western communication from Robert Mundell that unemployment differences among countries. Europe the creation of the Common Market is outlines a theory of “optimum currency areas.â€? regarded by many as an important step toward In the decade before the global ï¬?nancial It states the conditions that the countries in eventual political union, and the subject of a crisis, European economic integration showed a monetary union had to have—or quickly common currency … has been much discussed. impressive progress. But for many countries, institute—to share a single currency proï¬?tably. One can cite the well-known position of J. E. the progress was unbalanced (box ï¬?gure In practical terms, it meant ensuring that the Meade, who argues that the conditions for 1)—more rapid in ï¬?nancial areas (interest rates single currency should not lead to persistently a common currency in Western Europe do and inflation) than in real sectors (trade and high unemployment rates in some parts of not exist, and that, especially because of the incomes). It was more balanced for the new the monetary union, nor to unacceptably high lack of labor mobility, a system of flexible member states. Poland, for example, became rates of inflation in others. In 1999, Mundell exchange rates would be more effective in more integrated in ï¬?nancial and real terms. The was awarded the Nobel Prize for “his analysis promoting balance-of-payments equilibrium EU candidate countries (represented here by of monetary and ï¬?scal policy under different and internal stability; and the apparently Croatia and Turkey) experienced just ï¬?nancial exchange rate regimes and his analysis of opposite view of Tibor Scitovsky who favors integration. But while integrating in monetary optimum currency areas.â€? a common currency because he believes that and ï¬?nancial aspects, Greece became less The conditions for a successful monetary union it would induce a greater degree of capital integrated within the EU15 in real terms. identiï¬?ed in the 1961 article can be distilled mobility, but further adds that steps must Labor mobility in Europe is the lowest in the to mobility of labor and capital among the be taken to make labor more mobile and to developed world. Mundell’s communication 50 member states. To understand why, imagine facilitate supranational employment policies.â€? years ago suggests that this will be a serious a fall in economic activity in one part of the The introduction of the euro undoubtedly problem for the eurozone. Increasing labor union (say the south) and a rise in another (say increased capital mobility in the eurozone; mobility may be a privilege in Europe, but it is the north). This would cause unemployment one can reasonably expect a single currency a prerequisite in the eurozone. Countries that to rise in the south, and inflationary pressures to greatly facilitate ï¬?nancial integration. The integrate their labor markets will be able to and balance-of-payments surpluses to single currency undoubtedly also facilitated share a single currency proï¬?tably. Others will increase in the north. If the central bank the exchange of goods. But a single currency have to deal with stressful tradeoffs between increases the money supply, it might help the cannot by itself increase people’s mobility. This inflation and unemployment. south but would aggravate inflation in the requires states to harmonize labor regulations, north. If it does not, high unemployment in the education and training arrangements, and Source: Mundell 1961; Sugawara and south would cause suffering. But if capital and social security and welfare systems. Growing Zalduendo 2010. Box ï¬?gure 1: More monetary and ï¬?nancial than real integration in Europe during the last decade (arrows begin in 1997 and end in 2008; the origin indicates complete nominal and real integration) 6 Note: The ï¬?gure shows the extent of economic Nominal integration (0 = full integration) Eastern partnership integration, using the theory of optimum currency areas (Mundell 1961). The vertical axis combines 5 in one index of dissimilarity three indicators of nominal integration—volatility of exchange rates, convergence in inflation rates, and convergence in 4 interest rates. The horizontal axis does the same with three indicators of real integration—extent of EU candidates synchronization in business cycles measured by 3 indices of industrial production, trade integration, Poland and per capita income. The origin in the ï¬?gure represents perfect economic integration, and the 2 arrows show the integration path of each country or group of countries in 1997–2008. EU candidates Czech Republic are represented by Croatia and Turkey; the eastern EU12 partnership countries by Armenia, Azerbaijan, 1 Belarus, Georgia, Moldova, and Ukraine; and the Ireland Greece EU’s new member states by Bulgaria, the Czech EU15 Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, 0 0 1 2 3 4 Romania, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia. Source: Sugawara and Zalduendo 2010. Real integration (0 = full integration) 29 GOLDEN GROWTH Notes 1 Phelps, Edmund. 1961. “The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen,â€? The American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4. (September, 1961), pp. 638-643. 2 Among the economists were Maurice Allais, Tjalling Koopmans, Joan Robinson, John von Neumann, Robert Solow, and Trevor Swan. 3 von Weizsäcker, Carl Christian. Table 2: 30 questions, 30 answers 1962. Wachstum, Zins und optimale Investitionsquote, Tübingen (Mohr-Siebeck), 96 Chapter 1: The European Chapter 2: Trade pages. growth model Is “Factory Europeâ€? as dynamic 4 The report covers 45 countries: the 27 member states of the What makes the European as “Factory Asiaâ€?? European Union, 4 countries in the economic model unique? European Free Trade Association Factory Asia is growing faster, (Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway, The principal components of but goods trade in Europe and Switzerland), 8 candidate Europe’s growth model—trade, is more sophisticated. and potential candidate countries (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, ï¬?nance, enterprise, innovation, Croatia, Kosovo, the former labor, and government—are Is the Single Market for Services Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, underachieving compared organized in unique ways. Montenegro, Serbia, and Turkey), with the United States? and 6 eastern partnership countries (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Have changes in Europe and the The single market is working Belarus, Georgia, Moldova, and rest of the world made a new Ukraine). quite well for traditional services economic model necessary? such as travel and transport, but Sluggish productivity growth, a it is underperforming in modern declining workforce, and growing services such as insurance, ï¬?scal imbalances have revealed information technology, and weaknesses of the European other business services. economic model, and the entry of a billion Asian workers into the global Is the Common Agricultural market is adding to the stress. Policy compromising Europe’s global leadership? Which parts of the European The European Union’s agricultural model should be preserved, policies hobble the extension and which changed? of the single market to its Many changes are needed in neighbors, and Europe is missing how governments and labor an opportunity to improve the markets are organized. Fewer lives of 75 million people in the changes are needed to foster eastern partnership countries. innovation, productivity growth, and job creation by enterprises, and fewer still to improve ï¬?nance and trade in Europe. 30 OVERVIEW Chapter 3: Finance Chapter 4: Enterprise Chapter 5: Innovation Why is ï¬?nance in emerging Europe What does Europe expect from its How much does Europe’s different from other regions? enterprises? innovation deï¬?cit matter? The prospect of membership in the Workers expect enterprises Europe’s innovation deï¬?cit matters European Union exerts a powerful in Europe to create jobs, most for the EU15, and so it policy and institutional pull, making shareholders to generate value also matters for the economies Europe unique and strengthening added, and governments to bring of emerging Europe because the link between foreign savings in sizable export earnings. they are closely integrated. and economic growth. How have European ï¬?rms done Why does Europe do less R&D How did some European economies in an enlarged Europe? than the United States, Japan, beneï¬?t more from international In most parts of Europe, ï¬?rms and the Republic of Korea? ï¬?nancial flows than others? have taken advantage of European enterprises do less R&D European economies that managed greater regional integration to than American ï¬?rms because to “boom-proofâ€? public ï¬?nances decentralize production, attract they tend to be in sectors that and “crisis-proofâ€? private ï¬?nancing foreign investment, and expand are not as innovation-oriented. without resorting to the costly self- the markets for their products. insurance seen in Asia beneï¬?ted What are the special attributes from foreign ï¬?nancial flows. Why did some parts of Europe of a successful European do better than others? innovation system? Is there evidence of a “debt In Western and Eastern Europe, The most innovative European overhangâ€? in emerging Europe industrial structures were better economies such as Switzerland that reduces growth and justiï¬?es suited for a single market; Southern spend a lot on R&D, but also government intervention? European enterprises have been share key attributes with the In emerging Europe, treasuries, slower to offshore activities and United States—tight business– enterprises, and households to attract foreign investors. university links, good management do not face a debt overhang, skills, and top universities. but in the eurozone’s periphery Which government policies this problem is acute, posing a help enterprises do better? What should European governments danger for banks everywhere. In advanced European economies, do to increase innovation? many governments have to Measures to fully integrate the streamline regulations to make Single Market for Services will doing business easier; in emerging provide the scale, more privately Europe, most have to improve funded universities will supply infrastructure and credit as well. the skills, and regulations that foster competition will create the incentives for European enterprises to innovate. 31 GOLDEN GROWTH Chapter 6: Labor Chapter 7: Government Chapter 8: Golden growth Is there a European work model? Are governments in Europe How can Europe make the single bigger than elsewhere? market more efï¬?cient? European economies generally have more stringent employment Governments in Europe spend Greater labor mobility and more protection and more generous about 10 percent of GDP more uniform national regulations for social beneï¬?ts than their peers than their peers, and this is almost modern business services are in North America and East Asia. entirely because they spend making the single market more on social protection. more efï¬?cient. Given demographic changes, how can Europe achieve a stable and Is big government a drag How can Europe maintain more productive workforce? on growth in Europe? the momentum for regional Increased participation can help Controlling for other differences, economic integration? stem the decline of the workforce, European economies with Sustaining economic integration but more competition for jobs, government spending greater requires making the single market greater mobility within Europe, than 40 percent of GDP have efï¬?cient, crisis-prooï¬?ng ï¬?nancial and measures to attract global had much lower growth rates flows, and facilitating production talent will still be necessary. during the last 15 years. networks through improved public services in emerging Europe. Are employment and social If big government impedes protection practices inhibiting labor growth, how do countries such What is needed to maintain participation and efï¬?ciency? as Sweden do so well? Europe’s global leadership? Employment protection gives Countries like Sweden have big To remain a global economic leader, too much power to those with governments, but they deliver Europe has to sustain regional jobs while banishing others to high-quality social services, make it integration, reduce public debt, the fringes of the labor market, easy for citizens and enterprises to reform social security, revamp and generous social beneï¬?ts comply with taxes and regulations, employment protection laws, weaken the incentives to work. and have high levels of social trust. and institute policies to attract talent from around the world. Is Europe taking full advantage How can governments be of the beneï¬?ts associated with made more efï¬?cient? internal labor mobility? Countries where government works Source: Chapters 1–8. Migration among and within have made their bureaucracies countries in Europe is still low, and leaner, ï¬?scal institutions more even intra-EU migration falls short reliable, public services competitive, of the European Union’s aspiration tax administration effective, and of a fully integrated labor market. citizens more empowered. How can Europe become a Should ï¬?scal consolidation be a global magnet for talent? top policy priority in Europe? Europe needs an approach to To respond to market pressures global talent with policies that link and aging populations, almost immigration to labor markets, and every country in Europe must make a business climate that rewards big ï¬?scal adjustments to reduce skills and entrepreneurship. public debt to precrisis levels. 32 REFERENCES References Blanchard, O., and F. Giavazzi. 2002. “Current OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- Account Deï¬?cits in the Euro Area: The End operation and Development). 2005. OECD of the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle?â€? Brookings Employment Outlook 2005. Paris: OECD. Papers on Economic Activity 2002 (2): OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- 147–186. operation and Development). 2006. Live Bonin, H., W. Eichhorst, C. Florman, M. Longer, Work Longer. Paris: OECD. Hansen, L. Skiöld, J. Stuhler, K. Tatsiramos, OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- H. Thomasen, and K. Zimmermann. 2008. operation and Development). 2007. OECD “Geographic Mobility in the European Economic Surveys: European Union 2007. Union: Optimising Its Economic and Social Paris: OECD. Beneï¬?ts.â€? IZA Research Report 19, Institute OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- for the Study of Labor, Bonn. operation and Development). 2011. Health Conference Board, The. 2011. “Total at a Glance 2011: OECD Indicators. Paris: Economy Database.â€? January 2011, The OECD. Conference Board, New York, NY. Available Peters, G., J. Minx, C. Weber, and O. at www.conference-board.org/data/ Edenhofer. 2011. “Growth in Emission economydatabase. Accessed September 3, Transfers via International Trade from 1990 2011. to 2008.â€? Proceedings of the National Feldstein, M., and C. Horioka. 1980. Academy of Sciences 108 (21): 8903–8908. “Domestic Saving and International Capital Phelps, E. 1961. “The Golden Rule of Flows.â€? The Economic Journal 90 (358): Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen.â€? The 314–329. American Economic Review 51 (4): 638–643. Gill, I., and H. Kharas. 2007. An East Asian Phelps, E. 1966. Golden Rules of Economic Renaissance: Ideas for Economic Growth. Growth: Studies of Efï¬?cient and Optimal With D. Bhattasali, M. Brahmbhatt, G. Investment. New York, NY: W.W. Norton. Datt, M. Haddad, E. Mountï¬?eld, R. Tatucu, E. Vostroknutova. Washington, DC: World Stockholm International Peace Research Bank. Institute. 2011. SIPRI Yearbook 2011: Armaments, Disarmament and International Heston, A., R. Summers, and B. Aten. Security. New York, NY: Oxford University 2011. “Penn World Table Version 7.0.â€? May, Press. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Sugawara, N., and J. Zalduendo. 2010. “How Pennsylvania, Pennsylvania, PA. Much Economic Integration Is There in the Extended EU Family?â€? ECAnomics Note ILO (International Labour Ofï¬?ce). 2010. 10/1, Ofï¬?ce of the Chief Economist, Europe Key indicators of the Labour Market, Sixth and Central Asia Region, World Bank, Edition. Geneva: ILO. Washington, DC. Background paper for this Iwulska, A. 2011. “Country Benchmarks.â€? report. Prepared for this report. Available at www. UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on worldbank.org/goldengrowth. Accessed Trade and Development). 2010. World January 23, 2012. Investment Report 2010: Investing in a Low- Maddison, A. 1996. “Macroeconomic Carbon Economy. New York, NY: UN. Accounts for European Countries.â€? In von Weizsäcker, C. 1962. Wachstum, Quantitative Aspects of Post-War European Zins und optimale Investitionsquote. Economic Growth, ed. B. van Ark, and N. (Dissertation). Tübingen: Mohr-Siebeck. Crafts: 27–83. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Weigand, C., and M. Grosh. 2008. “Levels and Patterns of Safety Net Spending in Morley, J., and T. Ward. 2008. “Perceptions Developing and Transition Countries.â€? of Globalisation: Attitudes and Responses Social Protection Discussion Paper 0817, in the EU.â€? Comparative analytical report, Human Development Network, World Bank, March 4, European Foundation for the Washington, DC. Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, Dublin. WTO (World Trade Organization). 2009. International Trade Statistics 2009. Geneva: Mundell, R. 1961. “A Theory of Optimum WTO. Currency Area.â€? The American Economic Review 51 (4): 657–665. 33 GOLDEN GROWTH 34 CHAPTER 1 Chapter 1 The European growth model When this report was being ï¬?nalized in late 2011, Europe was in crisis. The nations of Europe that had given up the most prized symbol of sovereignty—their currency—in exchange for the euro had the most troubled economies in the world. The countries that had ostensibly integrated the most were the ones deepest in trouble—surely a sign of a deeply flawed growth model. But if Aristotle were writing about the good life today, he could still consider Europe. Europeans live long and largely healthy lives. They work less than workers in other prosperous societies. European incomes are not as high as American incomes, but most European countries have high-income economies. They have built these economies with democratic and representative societies, sacriï¬?cing neither civil liberties nor basic needs. And along the way, they have looked after the unfortunate among them and helped poorer nations in the neighborhood. During the “Golden Age of European Growth,â€? the early 1950s to the mid- 1970s, Western European incomes converged toward those in the United States. From the mid-1970s to the early 1990s, the incomes of more than 100 million people in the poorer southern periphery—Greece, southern Italy, Portugal, and Spain—rapidly converged on those of advanced Europe. After the fall of the Berlin Wall, the European Union absorbed another 100 million people in Central and Eastern Europe. Incomes in these countries have converged quickly. As another 100 million people in the Balkan states and Turkey wait to enter the world’s most powerful association of nations, they are already beneï¬?ting from the aspirations and institutions that helped almost half a billion people achieve the highest standard of living in the world. What makes the European economic model unique? Have changes in Europe and the rest of the world made a new economic model necessary? Which parts of the European model should be preserved, and which should be changed? 35 GOLDEN GROWTH One could say without exaggeration that Europe had invented a “convergence machine,â€? taking in poor countries and helping them become high-income economies. In other parts of the world, middle-income countries had to be extraordinarily fortunate—ï¬?nding oil, for example—or unusually ferocious, such as the East Asian Tigers, to become wealthy. In Europe, they did not need to be either. European societies are not only among the wealthiest in the world but also among the most equal. Europeans beneï¬?t from near-universal access to social services, including universal health care and free primary, secondary, and in many countries, tertiary education. They are protected by an elaborate system of social insurance. Due to smaller wage differentials, higher and more progressive taxes, and more generous social transfers, income distribution in Europe is more equal than in the United States, Japan, and most emerging market economies. At the same time, Europe has become greener over the past two decades and—except for Japan—is more energy-efï¬?cient than other high- income countries. Perhaps most important, after two continental wars in the ï¬?rst half of the twentieth century, Europe has found peace through economic and political integration. This unique achievement is at the heart of Europe’s remarkable economic success after 1945 and the peaceful transformation of the countries in Central and Eastern Europe after the fall of the Berlin Wall. As economist Paul Krugman notes, “The Europeans have shown us that peace and unity can be brought to a region with a history of violence, and in the process they have created perhaps the most decent societies in human history, combining democracy and human rights with a level of individual economic security that America comes nowhere close to matchingâ€? (Krugman 2011). The citizens of Europe appear to appreciate these achievements. According to the Eurobarometer, a survey of EU citizens conducted twice a year, most Europeans are optimistic about the future. Other surveys ï¬?nd that Europeans lead not only long and healthy lives, but also happy ones (Veenhoven 2011). All this was keenly appreciated before the latest crisis. Europe’s economic and social conditions in 2011 provide a stark contrast to its achievements over the past six decades. Since 2009, Europeans have had to accept cuts in incomes and social spending, sparking angry protests in some countries. Markets fret over high sovereign debt, and question the inconsistencies between a shared currency and widening differentials in ï¬?scal discipline and entrepreneurial abilities among the members of the eurozone. Even more seriously, they question the ability of the worst-afflicted countries to grow their way out of the crisis. These concerns are not new. In 2002, the Lisbon Agenda had recognized Europe’s disadvantage in innovation and productivity growth relative to the United States and Asia. The global economic and ï¬?nancial crisis of 2008–09 left scars in Europe, especially in its periphery, and strained European institutions. The European Commission has repeatedly pointed to long-standing competitiveness issues across the region. European leaders today face the hard task of selling tough adjustment to a reticent population, reassuring markets 36 CHAPTER 1 and addressing deep-rooted competitiveness issues. There is little consensus on how to do this. But there is growing consensus that unless Europe learns to grow again, the European way of life and Europe’s place in the world are under threat. Recent developments can also be seen as a challenge to the integration at the center of Europe’s unique success. An increase in North African refugees after the Arab Spring prompted calls by French and Italian leaders to restrict the free movement of people between countries that are members of the Schengen Agreement. The fear of competition from workers from new member states in Eastern Europe is widespread even in countries facing acute shortages of qualiï¬?ed labor, such as Germany. High rates of youth unemployment in several European countries and persistent pockets of social exclusion stand in contrast with the ideals of European solidarity. Even as Europe’s new members in the east have rapidly caught up with their western neighbors, Europe’s southern economies have started to fall behind, prompting concerns that Europe’s latest enlargement may have been at the expense of the weaker among the EU’s older members. Coordinated action by banks and supervisors during 2008–09 avoided rapid deleveraging by parent banks that had expanded into Eastern Europe. However, the same outcome is not guaranteed if national supervisors focus on shoring up the domestic capital base of their banks at the expense of faster deleveraging abroad. Not surprisingly, support for further enlargement in the European Union is declining, though it runs higher among new members.1 Citizens of the EU’s neighboring countries, too, have started to doubt the EU’s attractiveness. Support for EU membership is falling in Turkey.2 Ukraine has reverted to a foreign policy that tries to balance commitment to integration with Europe and reintegration with the Russian Federation. In Serbia, polls indicate only a thin majority in favor of EU membership. The model of European integration and solidarity may not be coming apart at the seams, but it is fraying at the edges. Europeans have become less conï¬?dent that their development model can sustain improvements in living standards, and neighboring countries are cautious about joining an aging and ailing club. Although many people in the world admire Europe, some suspect the continent’s best days are past. After the achievements of the last six decades, Europe’s economy has lost some of its lustre. What makes Europe unique Although the end of European complacency is good, a loss of conï¬?dence in the European model may be dangerous. In a rush to rejuvenate growth, the positive attributes of the European development model may be abandoned along with the negative. By identifying the European growth model’s strengths and weaknesses, this report aims to reduce the risk of policymakers inadvertently discarding the best parts of Europe’s economic approach. It is fair to ask if it is possible to rigorously identify a growth model except in narrow technical terms deï¬?ning the interaction of technology, capital, and labor. 37 GOLDEN GROWTH This report takes a more practical approach by analyzing the six activities that are the principal components of an economic model: enterprise, labor, trade, ï¬?nance, innovation, and government. This approach is motivated by a broad concept of economic and social advancement (box 1.1). It is also fair to ask whether it is appropriate to assume a “European model.â€? There are differences in how Ireland and Italy regulate enterprise and labor, or how Germany and Greece balance ï¬?scal and social policies. There are differences in what Spain and Sweden export, and how they regulate trade in services. There are differences in how Poland and Portugal regulate their banks, and not just because one shares a common currency while the other has its own. There are differences in how Finland and France provide essential government services, and each approach has merits. Because of these differences, various subgroups of countries within Europe are analyzed and contrasted in subsequent chapters of this report.3 This chapter emphasizes what is common across different parts of Europe; the next six chapters identify what is different and why. But these differences in speciï¬?cs do not rule out common principles that together constitute a unique approach to economic growth and social progress. This common approach consists of policies and institutions that govern trade and ï¬?nance, enterprise and innovation, and labor and government. Together they deï¬?ne an economic and social model that is uniquely European. This report is premised on the belief that all parts of Europe—EU member states, candidates and potential candidates, and nations in the EU eastern partnership countries—share the aspirations that motivate a common European model, sometimes summarized as “the social market economyâ€? (box 1.2). This report identiï¬?es features of this model that should be preserved and those that must be changed, analyzes how change can occur, and presents examples from Europe and around the world that illustrate how countries have successfully made some of these changes. Box 1.1: Europe’s economic model and its standard of living Jones and Klenow (2010) propose a broad income inequality. of health care and social insurance that impact notion of the standard of living that captures what risks people take and how long they can The basic idea of Jones and Klenow can be not just the level of national income, but also expect to live. related to the practical approach taken in its distribution, how much of it is available for consumption, how much leisure people need this report to analyze Europe’s economic and Jones and Klenow note that their measure of to trade to achieve their level of consumption, social model. The activities of enterprises, economic welfare does not capture possible and how long they can be expected to live. their innovation and entrepreneurship, the tradeoffs between present and future Calibrating such a broad, consumption-based trade links between them, and their access to generations. It captures only the expected concept of welfare to existing data reveals ï¬?nance and skills determine the productivity welfare of consumers today and does that many European countries approach of an economy and its aggregate income not address environmental sustainability. levels of welfare in the United States, despite level. The organization of labor determines Intertemporally optimal or “goldenâ€? growth considerably lower levels of national income. how long people have to work to afford a paths have been analyzed by Phelps (1961), By contrast, the performance of emerging particular level of consumption and whether among others. Europeans today have to ï¬?nd markets in Asia and Latin America looks less such work is available for all. The activities ways to safeguard the high level of economic impressive than in Europe, because growth of government determine how much income welfare achieved over the last six decades there has often been associated with a is redistributed, what skills are formed in the while ensuring that future generations do not declining share for consumption and rising education system, and the access to and cost have fewer opportunities. 38 CHAPTER 1 Box 1.2: Europe’s postwar consensus: the social market economy The idea of the social market economy is For Eucken, government intervention to that often had lost private savings and assets simple: combine the efï¬?ciency of markets achieve social objectives would be limited as a result of war and economic turbulence. with social fairness, and combine economic to progressive taxation, basic social security, For Europeans, to make the market acceptable, freedom with basic social security. The and unemployment insurance. Müller-Armack the “animal spiritsâ€? of capitalism needed to be conceptual fathers of the social market saw a need for structural interventions to tamed. economy, such as Walter Eucken (1940) and achieve distributional objectives in addition to measures to safeguard market competition. The idea of the social market economy was the Alfred Müller-Armack (1947), were liberals basis for policy mainly in Austria and Germany, in the European sense of the term. They He explicitly referred to the reconciliatory role of the social market economy. Indeed, the and its corporatist application extended across emphasized the role of free markets in Scandinavia and the Benelux states. France need for social consensus after the ravages allocating resources and of private property chose a more interventionist model with the of the war and in the face of the communist and contract rights in organizing economic nationalization of strategic industries such as alternative developing in Eastern Europe led activity. Their positions ran counter to mining, transport, and ï¬?nance as well as large to government interventions beyond those the pervasive skepticism of markets and manufacturing companies such as Renault. originally foreseen by the fathers of the social private property in Europe during the Great market economy. In the German labor market, Common to all continental economies was Depression (Phelps 2007). But they also centralized wage bargaining was introduced the emphasis on a social consensus between emphasized the need for government activism and large companies adopted codetermination capital and labor. This was often organized to safeguard markets through competition in management. Across Europe, the 1950s by a state that supported high savings and policy and to deal with externalities through saw a rapid increase in social insurance and investment rates, which in turn led to the easy regulatory interventions. Private businesses transfers. Generous pay-as-you-go pension adoption of frontier technologies from the were expected to be responsible for the systems were put in place, beneï¬?ting from United States and resulted in quick income consequences of their activities—a kind of favorable postwar demographics and convergence (DeLong 1997; Eichengreen 1996; generalized “polluters payâ€? principle. reflecting the need to provide for a generation see spotlight one in this report). The principal components of the European growth model The organization of Europe’s main economic activities demonstrates what is unique about the European development model. · Trade. Richer and poorer economies are more integrated than in any other part of the world, resulting in quicker convergence in living standards than in incomes, which in turn is quicker than convergence in institutional quality. · Finance. Europe is the only region where private capital in all its forms— foreign direct investment (FDI), nonï¬?nancial and ï¬?nancial FDI, and portfolio funds—flows downhill from richer to poorer countries and from low-growth to high-growth economies. · Enterprise. Private enterprise is accountable to shareholders for proï¬?t, but it is also held more responsible for the social and environmental consequences of its actions than in other parts of the world. · Innovation. Research and development (R&D) and tertiary education, recognized around the globe for their economic spillovers, are viewed in Europe as primarily the responsibility of the state. · Labor. Workers in Europe enjoy the most effective protection against abuse by employers and the most generous wage, job security, and nonwage beneï¬?ts—such as unemployment insurance, paid leave, and pensions—of any workers in the world. · Government. National governments are more redistributive, and supranational coordination in Europe is the world’s most advanced. 39 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 1.1: Europe is the most open region in the world (trade, exports plus imports, as percentage of GDP, average of 2005–09) Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: WDI. One can—and should—ask whether these achievements are sustainable in today’s world, or whether some countries have applied some of these principles poorly. Before answering that question, though, it is useful to note that the European growth model has resulted in a deeper integration and quicker convergence between advanced and developing economies than in any other part of the world. European enterprises balance corporate mandates and social responsibility, and governments mobilize taxpayers to aid innovation. Despite considerable economic uncertainty, European workers still beneï¬?t from a high level of security, and no societies achieve better egalitarian outcomes in market economies. Trade and Finance: deeper integration and quicker convergence European economies are more integrated than any others in the world. Trade flows relative to gross domestic product (GDP) are much higher in European countries, especially in the new EU member states (EU12), than in other parts of the world (ï¬?gure 1.1).4 Among the 27 EU member states (EU27), trade openness is higher than in any other region, including East Asia. In the EU candidates and EU eastern partnership countries, openness is higher than in most other emerging market regions, though it is somewhat lower than in East Asia. The large share of trade in total GDP results from low barriers to the goods trade in the single market and falling trade barriers for both goods and services in the region, as well as the relatively small size of economies in the region, similar to the developments in East Asia. But the integration of richer and poorer countries facilitates a frenetic flow of goods and makes “Factory Europeâ€? different from the much-heralded “Factory Asia.â€? Europe’s most developed economies have been outsourcing more and more sophisticated tasks to their eastern neighbors, beneï¬?ting both sides in the process. The success in unifying national markets into a single European market has made Europe ambitious enough to consider many services as tradable within the region. But the Single Market for Services can be made a more efï¬?cient, potent source of growth in Europe (Monti 2010). 40 CHAPTER 1 Capital flows in Europe have been the largest—as a share of economic output— in the history of humankind.5 Labor mobility, while low, is picking up. This economic integration has resulted in quicker convergence in incomes than in other parts of the world (ï¬?gure 1.2). Outside Europe and East Asia, there is no relation between GDP per capita in 1970 and its growth rate between 1970 and 2009.6 European countries that were poorer in 1970 experienced higher growth than countries with higher GDP per capita in 1970. East Asia is the other region in the world where convergence in incomes has been observed, but the link between initial income per capita and subsequent growth is much less robust.7 Capital flows are fundamental to income convergence in Europe. In Europe, capital flows “downhill,â€? as predicted in economic theory (Lucas 1990). Outside Europe, capital flows “uphillâ€?—from poorer countries such as China to richer ones like the United States—a puzzling but well-established pattern (Prasad, Rajan, and Subramanian 2007). Outside Europe, many forms of capital go to low-growth countries (ï¬?gure 1.3).8 In other words, among many emerging markets outside Europe, high growth in incomes only happens when current account surpluses grow. This “allocation puzzleâ€? is not a problem in Europe.9 In Europe, consistent with the fundamental tenets of economic theory, capital flows to high-growth countries, principally those in Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe.10 This pattern is most noticeable in the European Union and those aspiring to join it. The EU eastern partnership countries (Belarus, Moldova, Ukraine, and others) look similar to other emerging markets. In sum, European integration has led to both a higher share of trade in output and to much larger ï¬?nancial flows from richer to poorer countries. Quicker convergence in living standards is the unsurprising outcome. This does not imply that living standards everywhere in Europe have converged. Some Figure 1.2: Convergence in incomes was faster in Europe than elsewhere (GDP per capita levels in 1970 and growth from 1970 to 2009) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Penn World Table 7.0 (Heston, Summers, and Aten 2011). 41 GOLDEN GROWTH regions, such as Italy’s Mezzogiorno, have persistently lagged. Europe’s Cohesion Funds are designed to help lagging regions catch up. This has not worked well everywhere, partly because national policies have differed with respect to using these funds. Where the focus has been on integrating leading and lagging regions through connective infrastructure, such as in Ireland, regional convergence has resulted. Where instead, funds have been spent on spreading out economic activity and bringing jobs to people in lagging regions through spatially targeted interventions, success has been rare (World Bank 2009). Convergence in Europe appears to have come from market-based integration, not from nonmarket mechanisms driven by solidarity. European integration has not, however, led to a similarly rapid convergence in the quality of institutions. There is considerable variance in institutional quality across Europe (ï¬?gure 1.4). A larger “pancakeâ€? in ï¬?gure 1.4 indicates better quality. The size of the pancake in the EU candidate countries or the EU eastern partnership countries is comparable with that in Latin America and smaller than in East Asia. Figure 1.3: In much of Europe, capital flows to high-growth countries (capital inflows (current account deï¬?cits) and per capita GDP growth, 1997–2008) Note: Each dot represents a four-year average during the period covered: 1997-2000, 2001-04, and 2005-08. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. Figure 1.4: Institutional quality varies a lot within Europe (indicators of property rights and contract enforcement, 2008–09) Note: Indicators used are: protection of intellectual property (Fraser), property rights (WEF), property rights (Heritage), contract viability (ICRG), and rule of law (WGI). Each indicator is rescaled and then ranges from 0 to 10 showing the higher, the better quality. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on data from The Fraser Institute (Gwartney, Hall, and Lawson 2010), WEF (Schwab 2009 and 2010), The Heritage Foundation (Miller and Holmes 2011), ICRG, and WGI (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2010). 42 CHAPTER 1 Figure 1.5: Business is expected to be socially responsible in Europe, especially in the EU (Responsible Competitiveness Index 2007, business action component) Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: MacGillivray, Begley, and Zadek 2007. International macroeconomics texts argue that the risks investors face in poorer countries depress risk-adjusted returns and discourage investment, preventing convergence. These risks may result from the lower quality of poor countries’ institutions (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001). The risks seem not to prevent convergence in Europe because EU membership—actual or prospective—may be an assurance of future institutional improvements. So far, this reassurance has worked to Europe’s advantage. The European debt crisis of 2011 is a reminder, however, that investors can lose conï¬?dence when the promise of institutional improvements is not kept. Countries in Europe do not need to be ferocious to converge. But the more institutionally integrated a European economy becomes, the less it can afford not to converge. Indeed, for the economies of the eurozone that share a common currency and hence are more tightly integrated than others, economic convergence is as much a prerequisite as it is a perk. Enterprise and Innovation: more responsible competition The social market economy model adopted in Europe after World War II relies upon business recognizing its social responsibilities. The extent to which this has happened varies across Europe. The business action component of the Responsible Competitiveness Index 2007 captures the efï¬?cacy of corporate bonds, the ethical behavior of ï¬?rms, the wage equality of workers doing similar work, the strength of audit and accounting standards, the extent of staff training, and the occupational fatalities in regions around the world (ï¬?gure 1.5). The highest-ranked countries are all European: Sweden, Denmark, Finland, Norway, Iceland, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Ireland, and Germany are all ranked higher than the United States, Japan, and most other countries in the world. The average of Europe’s advanced economies (EU15) is above that of Japan and East Asia. To the extent that the ranking reflects the preferences of investors and consumers, corporate responsibility is good for business in Europe. However, not all European countries are equal: Eastern and Southern Europe rank below East Asia and on a par with Latin America. Greater regulation makes European producers cleaner and greener than American producers, though Japanese producers are even greener and Eastern 43 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 1.6: Emerging European countries are the best performers in emission reduction (change in greenhouse gas emissions from the base year to 2009, percent) Note: Greenhouse gas excludes land use, land-use change, and forestry. The base year is, in most cases, 1990. Source: UN Framework Convention on Climate Change. Figure 1.7: The business climate varies substantially across Europe (principal component analysis index of Doing Business ratings, 2011) Note: Averages computed using principal component analysis (see chapter 4). Liechtenstein, Kosovo, and Malta are not covered by Doing Business, and are not included. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Doing Business. Europe lags behind the rest of Europe. European leaders embrace green growth as a driver of Europe’s future development model. According to the most recent data from the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, European countries have made the largest reductions in greenhouse gas emissions (ï¬?gure 1.6). For the former centrally planned economies, large reductions reflect their inefï¬?cient starting points. But Finland, Norway, Sweden, and Germany have achieved emission reductions as a result of investments in renewables and in energy-saving technologies, often spurred by strict emission controls or regulatory and tax measures designed to boost investment in alternative energy. Sweden is a leader in the use of biogas and Denmark in wind, while Germany and Spain have pioneered the use of subsidies to encourage renewable sources of energy. Spotlight two discusses the steps needed to make the European growth model even greener. 44 CHAPTER 1 Figure 1.8: Europe’s governments spend more on R&D, the private sector spends less (R&D expenditure, 2000–09) Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: UNESCO. While addressing social and environmental objectives, Europe’s approach to business regulation may make its enterprises uncompetitive. As described in greater detail in chapters 4 and 5, Europe’s leading economies have struggled to close the productivity gap with the United States, and enterprises in Southern Europe particularly seem to suffer from excessive and cumbersome regulation. A composite index of the quality of the investment climate, based on the Doing Business indicators developed by the World Bank Group, shows that Europe lags the United States and Japan (ï¬?gure 1.7). This has motivated calls for ambitious regulatory reform, such as in the EU’s Lisbon Agenda of 2002. Another concern is that Europe lags the United States in innovation – and this explains the persistent productivity gap – as Europe’s leading economies no longer beneï¬?t from the technological catch-up that drove growth during the ï¬?rst three postwar decades (Aghion and Howitt 2006). Europe’s approach to innovation assigns a bigger role to government for promoting scientiï¬?c research and tertiary education. Worries about Europe’s innovation shortfall have led to Europe-wide targets for R&D spending. This approach does not seem to be working (ï¬?gure 1.8). The bulk of the world’s R&D takes place in the United States, Western Europe, and Northeast Asia, but Europe is falling behind—due to the smaller role of the private sector in R&D spending. EU15 governments spend the same share of GDP on R&D as Japan and the United States, but European enterprises spend only about a third of what their U.S. and Japanese counterparts spend. The result is the same when the new member states are compared with emerging East Asia. Likewise, governments in Europe bear almost all of the expense of university education (ï¬?gure 1.9). Universities in many European countries are free, though the United Kingdom and several German states recently introduced or raised tuition fees. Universities are predominantly public in Europe, in contrast with the leading universities in the United States and, increasingly, Asia. Lower private ï¬?nancing of tertiary education in Europe may hinder the flow of new ideas from academics to business and contribute to lower private sector R&D investment. Much of the rest of the world (Brazil, India, and Russia, for example) has largely followed the European model of state-dominated university education, but 45 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 1.9: European governments account for the bulk of tertiary education spending (tertiary education expenditure, public sources, 2000–09, percentage of total expenditure on tertiary education) a. The group is represented by Moldova only. b. Data are available for Tunisia only. c. Data for China are from 1999. Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: World Bank Education Statistics (EdStats); and OECD Education Statistics. Figure 1.10: Europeans work less and retire earlier (labor use in Europe and other countries, average of 2005–09) Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: ILO 2010b; and Conference Board 2011. fast-growing East Asia is moving toward the U.S. blend of private and state universities. Europe must consider whether greater regulation and government participation in R&D will help or hurt enterprise and innovation, and widen or shrink the productivity gaps between the United States and the EU15, and between East Asia and the EU12. Labor and Government: greater security and equality Work conditions in Europe are better than in other parts of the world. Europeans work fewer hours a week, fewer weeks a year, and fewer years during their lifetime than workers in other regions. Roxburgh and Mischke (2011) estimate that the annual hours worked per capita in the EU15 is 733, about a month less than in the United States. The fewer work 46 CHAPTER 1 weeks a year account for half of this difference. The remaining half is due to the lower incidence of women working part-time (around 20 percent); a lower participation rate among 55–64-year-olds as a result of early retirement (15 percent); higher unemployment in Europe (6 percent); and other factors (around 10 percent). In a broader regional comparison, the EU15 stands out for low participation rates among 55–64-year-olds (both male and female) and a low number of hours worked during the year (ï¬?gure 1.10). The EU12 has particularly low participation rates in the 55–64-year-old age bracket, but longer annual average working hours. This pattern is repeated in the EU candidate countries, which also suffer from higher unemployment among youth. Economists believe that people prefer leisure to work if they can afford it. Europeans can afford time off to spend with their families, pursue hobbies, exercise, or simply rest, and most Europeans welcome this.11 But for some, less than full participation in the labor market may be involuntary. Young people and ethnic minorities such as the Roma are often excluded from the labor market, even when they are prepared to work. It is worrisome that several European economies, particularly those in the east and south, feature large informal Figure 1.11: Employment protection is higher in Europe (OECD employment protection index, 2008, and change since 1998) Note: The index is based on version 2 of the indicator. “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. Asiaâ€? refers to East Asia. Source: OECD Employment Database. Figure 1.12: Wages in Europe are less differentiated than in other regions (earnings ratio between top and bottom deciles, 2007–09) Note: The differential is measured by decile ratios (D9/D1 = wage level of the top 10 percent of workers divided by the level of the bottom 10 percent). “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. EU candidates are represented by Albania only. The data for 2001–2006 are used for France, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and Sweden (EU15), Hungary (EU12), and the Philippines (East Asia). For Albania, the period covered is 1995–2000. Source: ILO 2010a. 47 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 1.13: Social spending is higher in Europe (government expenditures on education, health, and social protection, 2005–09) Note: Social spending is a sum of education (707), health (709), and social protection (710) expenditures, as classiï¬?ed in the IMF GFS. Source: IMF GFS; and IMF WEO. sectors. Large shadow economies mirror inefï¬?ciencies in labor markets—for example, due to high marginal tax rates or rigidities due to labor regulations.12 The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) calculates an employment protection legislation index that includes three dimensions: the protection of individuals against unjustiï¬?ed dismissal, the burden of requirements to justify collective dismissal, and regulations on temporary employment, which is less secure than permanent employment (OECD 1999 and 2004, and Venn 2009). Turkey ranked the highest for employee protection in 2008, while workers in the United States were least protected. Non-EU industrial countries, including Japan, generally have weaker employment protections than EU countries (ï¬?gure 1.11). Within Europe, there is signiï¬?cant variation in employment protection. In Continental Europe and the south, employment protection legislation is more restrictive than in the north and the east. Although labor market reforms across Europe have narrowed differences in employment protection over the past decade, regional differences are still large and contribute to greater labor market segmentation in the south and the east.13 Europeans worry that measures to increase labor force participation will lead to a class of working poor. In fact, according to the OECD, the incidence of low pay in many European countries is much lower than in the United States—the EU15 average is around 15 percent compared with 25 percent in the United States (Japan is closer to the EU15).14 By the same token, wage incomes in the European Union are considerably more equal than those in the United States (ï¬?gure 1.12). The ratio of earnings in the ninth to the ï¬?rst decile is less than 2.5 in Scandinavia and below 3.5 in much of Continental Europe, but almost 5 in the United States. The greater flexibility of labor markets is not necessarily inconsistent with maintaining greater wage equality, as the Scandinavian countries show. An assessment of what others can learn from this experience is given in chapters 6 and 7. Europeans not only enjoy relatively high levels of employment protection, they also beneï¬?t from generous health services and support in their old age. Social spending on pensions, health, and education is relatively high in Europe (ï¬?gure 1.13). In most European countries, pension and health systems are managed by government and ï¬?nanced through mandatory payroll contributions or general 48 CHAPTER 1 taxes. The rise in pension spending explains the bulk of the increase in the size of governments in Europe, with health-related spending accounting for the remainder. Several European countries are implementing pension reforms, including increasing the retirement age, reducing early retirement beneï¬?ts, and reducing replacement rates. In many cases the EU’s new members and Eastern European neighbors spearheaded these reforms as they faced the challenge of rapid aging with far lower average incomes and productivity. Nonetheless, replacement rates in Europe tend to be considerably more generous than in other high-income countries, most notably Canada, Japan, and the United States. The comparison with Japan is particularly instructive because Japan is the one high-income country that shares Europe’s predicament of a labor force that is rapidly declining in size. In most European countries, pension reform remains unï¬?nished business. The large role of government in providing basic public services and the generosity of the social security system comes with a higher tax burden. Corporate tax rates decreased over the past two decades, leading to more uniform effective rates in Europe and among all developed countries. Personal income tax rates still vary from other parts of the world and even within Europe, especially when the new EU member states are included. Europe’s high payroll taxes and marginal income taxes lead to the largest difference in the world between gross and net wages. One implication of this gap is that the post-tax distribution of earnings is more equal in Europe (ï¬?gure 1.14). Another implication is that work incentives are weaker. As a share of their GDP, European countries do not have higher expenditures for health or education than other high-income countries. The role of the government in providing and ï¬?nancing these services, however, tends to be greater in Europe. On average, governments ï¬?nance three-quarters of all health Figure 1.14: Redistribution through the tax and transfer system is more pronounced in Europe (Gini indices, 2000s) a. For Australia and New Zealand, the latest available data are from 1994 and 1997, respectively. b. Japan’s data are from 1993. Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: WDI; and OECD Income Distribution and Poverty Database. 49 GOLDEN GROWTH spending in the EU27, but only 60 percent in high-income countries, and as little as 45 percent in the United States. Japan also has a high share of government expenditures in total health spending (81 percent). In education spending, Europe stands apart from the rest of the world. Governments in Europe ï¬?nance more than four-ï¬?fths of total education spending, compared with up to three- quarters in a few and half in most OECD countries. In most European countries, primary, secondary, and tertiary education is free, which explains the much larger government role in ï¬?nancing education. Given the substantial role of government in providing services and social security, government accountability is pivotal. But there is a delicate balance between the accountability desired by most European societies and the moral hazard from the aspirations of a common European project. Europe is a unique experiment in shifting from national to international redistribution and to a deeper political integration than anywhere else in the world. While it is difï¬?cult to discern a clear set of characteristics shared by every European country, a consistent pattern distinguishes Europe’s development model.15 Even if there were no such thing as a common European growth model, Europe would face common challenges that set it apart. There are variations in the severity of these challenges among European countries, but they are small relative to the differences with the Americas and Asia. It is these common challenges that motivate a study on restoring the lustre of the European growth model. The need for change External and internal developments are putting pressures on Europe—as exhibited in stalling productivity, shrinking workforces, and widening ï¬?scal imbalances. But the remedies lie in three interrelated challenges: making the most of modern services, both ï¬?nancial and nonï¬?nancial; closing productivity gaps, such as the one between the EU15 and the United States, and the growing divergence in productivity growth between Southern Europe and the rest; and dealing with an increasingly serious demographic drag, caused by a combination of aging and shrinking populations in many parts of Europe, including its emerging markets. Unexploited potential in modern services In developed economies, about three-quarters of national income is generated in the services sector. Europe’s internal trade in services is the largest worldwide at around US$4 trillion. And yet the Single Market for Services remains fragmented. The most integrated in Europe is the market for ï¬?nancial services, and this has brought ample beneï¬?ts (chapter 3). But even here, coordination among national regulators to oversee the activities of ï¬?nancial institutions operating across national borders may have been exposed as deï¬?cient during the recent crisis. The uncoordinated deleveraging of bank balance sheets in Europe’s emerging markets as a result of capital calls by national regulators could impose signiï¬?cant collateral damage on host countries’ economies. This would exacerbate downward economic pressures across 50 CHAPTER 1 Figure 1.15: Europe’s productivity leaders are lagging behind the United States (EU15 labor productivity, indexed to the United States and Japan) Note: The chart shows productivity levels in the core EU15 rather than the wider EU27. The EU’s new members (EU12) have been converging to the United States but are too small to fundamentally affect the picture for Europe as a whole. Note also the declining gap with Japan even during the recent decades, when Japan grew slowly. Once demographic “dragâ€? is subtracted, labor productivity growth in Japan compares well with Europe and is on a par with the United States between 1995 and 2005. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on the OECD Productivity Database. the continent. To avoid costly disintegration, further regulatory integration is called for. In other services, regulatory barriers prevent the beneï¬?ts of trade and integration from being fully realized (chapter 2). Digital services, such as Internet sales and IT support, are far less developed in Europe. For example, the United States accounts for around 80 percent of global e-book sales, but Europe for only 10 percent, mostly in the United Kingdom. The online music storage and sharing service Spotify is available in only 7 European countries, and iTunes is accessible in only 15 states. National regulations make it difï¬?cult for companies to operate Europe-wide, preventing efï¬?ciency and cost gains from being realized. After years of negotiations, Europe still does not have a single European patent, which increases the cost to innovators. Telecom services, biotechnologies, and pharmaceuticals are nationally regulated, leading to signiï¬?cant price divergence across Europe and reduced incentives for business to invest in R&D. In professional services, the mutual recognition of qualiï¬?cations remains incomplete, while contract law and professional liability and insurance requirements differ and create risks for cross-border sales, particularly by small and medium enterprises. The regulatory barriers hampering the development of services trade across Europe are economically signiï¬?cant. Some estimates put the gains from strengthening the Single Market for Services at 4 percent of the EU’s aggregate GDP (Monti 2010). About 70 percent of the productivity gap with the United States in the “oldâ€? members of the European Union is in the productivity of services (Roxburgh and others 2010). Lower productivity growth in distribution (retail, wholesale, transport, and logistics) accounts for a large share of Europe’s divergence in productivity from the United States and Japan since the mid-1990s (Jorgenson and Timmer 2011). Europe lags the United States in highly innovative industries such as biotech, the Internet, and medical services (chapter 5). Europe 51 GOLDEN GROWTH has gotten less out of the information technology revolution and risks missing out on biotech, the next important wave of business opportunities in the “New Economy.â€? Widening productivity gaps Growth in labor productivity in Europe’s advanced economies has fallen behind that in the United States (ï¬?gure 1.15). This growing gap with the world’s technology leader is in sharp contrast with the rapid convergence in labor productivity Europe experienced in the ï¬?ve decades after World War II. It prompted several European policy initiatives, starting with the Lisbon Figure 1.16: Southern Europe lags the EU15 North, and Eastern Europe is catching up to it (EU15 South labor productivity, indexed to EU15 North and EU12) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on the OECD Productivity Database. Figure 1.17: Europe’s population could shrink by a third over the next 40 years (population projections, 2010–50) Note: “EU15 S.â€? refers to countries in EU15 South, which are also included in the EU15 aggregates. “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on U.S. Census Bureau International Data Base. 52 CHAPTER 1 Agenda of 2002 and reinforced in Europe’s 2020 Agenda of 2010, all aimed at strengthening Europe’s competitiveness and productivity performance, while ensuring that economic growth in Europe remains socially inclusive and environmentally sustainable. The results of these efforts have been modest. Subsequent chapters in this report analyze what needs to be done. The growing gap with the United States is not the only productivity gap Europe needs to worry about. Within Europe, labor productivity growth until the mid-1990s tended to be faster in the relatively poorer countries. But over the past decade, the pattern has become more complex. While the new member states of the European Union in Central and Eastern Europe have grown fast and made good progress in closing the large initial productivity gap with the EU15, among the “oldâ€? members of the EU, productivity has diverged since the end of the 1990s (ï¬?gure 1.16). In particular, productivity growth in Europe’s southern economies—Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain—has been slower than in Europe’s north. These trends worsened in the ï¬?ve years leading up to the economic and ï¬?nancial crisis of 2007–08. But incomes have not matched labor productivity. The result has been a sharp divergence in unit labor costs within the eurozone and a corresponding increase in internal imbalances among its member states. Growing “Demographic Dragâ€? Over the next 50 years, with current policies, Europe’s labor force will decline by 50 million, with the largest part of the decrease happening between 2020 and 2040. The numbers are quite daunting, because there will be changes at both ends of the population pyramid. Due to low fertility rates, the labor force will decline by around 15 percent in the EU15 and by more than 30 percent in the EU12 and the EU eastern partnership countries, but it is likely to increase by 15 percent in the potential candidate countries. At the same time, the share of Figure 1.18: European governments are the biggest in the world, and often heavily indebted (government balance, government spending and public debt, percentage of GDP, 1970–2010) Note: “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries and “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries. Source: IMF WEO; European Commission’s annual macro-economic database (AMECO); and Abbas and others 2011. 53 GOLDEN GROWTH European ages 65 and older is projected to increase from less than 20 percent today to around 30 percent by 2050 (ï¬?gure 1.17). This contrasts markedly with predicted developments in the United States, India, and emerging markets in Latin America and North Africa. Although China and Japan also face a declining labor force, there are vast opportunities in China for productivity gains from capital deepening and from the structural transformation of the economy. Japan is most comparable with Europe in its demographic patterns, but it has managed the ï¬?scal implications of aging more prudently and has sustained higher rates of productivity growth than Europe. Europe will need to boost labor force participation and adjust its institutions to cope with the need for greater immigration if it is to achieve sustainable GDP growth (chapter 6). Demographic changes are straining Europe’s welfare systems. European countries have larger governments than countries in other regions, regardless of per capita income level (ï¬?gure 1.18). The differential is about 10 percent of GDP, and the main reason is that European governments spend more on social security, mostly on pensions (chapter 7). This is not because European societies are already much older than others at similar income levels. Rather, Europe has more pensioners because workers retire earlier. Europe’s social spending is large, though the continent is still relatively young. As Europeans live longer and populations age, this will need to change. The burden of implicit pension liabilities has been recognized for some time. Until recently, however, the large size of Europe’s governments and the increasing levels of public debt did not attract much attention. This has changed in the wake of the crisis, as European governments struggle to convince investors that they can and will redeem their debts. The need for ï¬?scal adjustments and debt reduction is now widely acknowledged. How to do this in a socially balanced way is perhaps the key challenge facing European policymakers over the coming decade. How to sequence and coordinate the adjustment in the context of large internal imbalances within Europe and the looming risk of a renewed recession is a key challenge over the coming months.16 An underdeveloped services market, a persistent gap to the world’s productivity frontier, an aging society, and the immediate need for ï¬?scal adjustment— together these conditions make economic growth the greatest imperative for Europe. The issue is not just higher material output. Intergenerational equity, sustainability, and global relevance are also at issue. Only a growing Europe will be able to maintain its attractive blend of ever-better living standards, individual rights and social security, and regional solidarity. Mending the model It is understandable that given half a century of success, many Europeans are inclined to preserve and defend their economic model rather than change and adapt. But it is clear that changes are necessary. Changes are needed for the European single market to deepen, for Europe to become an even bigger economic union, and for Europe to retain or regain its global economic leadership. 54 CHAPTER 1 The rest of this chapter introduces the key policy debates that frame the case for changing the various components of the growth model. The policy debates concern all of Europe, but the implications are often quite different across countries. Some parts of the model will require less adjustment than others. The structure of this report reflects these differences. A few salient points: · The structure of this report mirrors its main messages. Trade and ï¬?nance come ï¬?rst: they are the parts of the economic model that are the strongest and—except for the single market for some services—require the least change. Enterprise and innovation come second: they work well in some parts of Europe and poorly in others. Some countries need to change their policies just a little, others a lot. Labor and government come next: they require the most change in many countries. · The organization of the chapters also reflects their geographic focus. The debates about enlargement are best informed by discussing the experience of emerging Europe—the new member states of the European Union, the EU candidate countries in the Balkans, and the EU eastern partnership countries. The discussions of trade and ï¬?nance emphasize the economic relations between emerging Europe and the advanced EU15 economies. The debates about European competitiveness are centered on the European Union, with growing concerns about the competitiveness of enterprise in the southern states and weaknesses in the innovation fundamentals of the European Union. The discussion of enterprise and innovation is focused on the 31 countries in the European Union and European Free Trade Association. The debates about labor and government span all 45 countries in Europe: the European Free Trade Association, the European Union, the EU candidate states, and the EU eastern partnership countries. · This report tries to provide answers to the questions that are most pertinent for policymakers. The number of questions in each chapter increases as the report progresses from the strong points of the European economic model to its weaker aspects. But the debates addressed in chapters 2–7 span questions related to three of Europe’s biggest assets: the single market, the consensus for economic enlargement, and Europe’s global economic importance. Highlighting the priorities, chapter 8 notes countries in and outside Europe whose performance can be used as a benchmark by others. Trade: taking advantage of enlargement There are many who question whether enlarging the European Union to the east has beneï¬?ted Europe’s “oldâ€? member states, especially the ones in the south; there is not much debate about whether the new members have beneï¬?ted—they clearly have. A corollary of this concern is skepticism about the beneï¬?ts to current members of the European Union from further enlargement to include the western Balkans, Turkey, and Europe’s eastern neighbors, especially Belarus, Moldova, and Ukraine. The fears about trade integration with the east are centered on the relocation of production facilities to beneï¬?t from a qualiï¬?ed but cheaper labor force. The argument is often made that this leads to a loss of jobs in the west—that competition has harmed economies in “oldâ€? Europe. This report documents 55 GOLDEN GROWTH the spread of industrial networks as a result of EU enlargement and shows how the EU’s old members have indeed been increasingly offshoring activities to the newer ones. This has helped companies in Western Europe—in Austria, Germany, and others—become or stay competitive. Western Europe’s most successful economies have increasingly relied on suppliers in the east. And the new member states have been given increasingly sophisticated tasks in the process, which has turned them into global exporters in their own right. The same phenomena can be observed with a lag in the western Balkans and Turkey, where trade in industrial intermediates is catalyzing changes in the structure of exports. The conclusion of deep and comprehensive free trade agreements with the eastern neighbors would likely bring many of the beneï¬?ts that the customs union, concluded in 1995 between the European Union and Turkey, has brought to Europe’s second most populous country. But while enlargement has been a success for most, Europe’s southern economies have missed out on the beneï¬?ts of deepening integration. FDI that used to go southward has increasingly headed east. Neither has the south substantially increased its trade linkages with the new member states or the accession countries, with the notable exception of Greek and Italian banks expanding into the western Balkans. Enterprises in Greece, Italy, Portugal, and—to less extent—Spain tend to be too small to internationalize. The family business model needs updating as the European family grows ever bigger. If trade in manufacturing has been a motor of European integration, trade in services is less developed and more regulated in Europe, even inside the European Union. Services trade has grown signiï¬?cantly, as has the sophistication of services exports of both old and new EU member states. But services trade in the European Union is estimated to be only about half what it could be if the Single Market for Services were fully developed. Moreover, services trade in non-EU members is less impressive and remains primarily for traditional services, pointing to sizable gains from further liberalization of trade in services with non-EU members. Tapping this potential requires strengthening the capacity of EU candidate countries to adhere to European regulations in areas such as intellectual property rights and ï¬?nancial services. It will also require the European Union to accept the greater labor mobility required for trade in traditional services such as construction, transportation, and tourism. Europe’s global trade relations are characterized by the increasing proliferation of bilateral trade deals, custom-made for the particular sensitivities involved. For Europe, agriculture remains a policy area dominated more by politics than economics. The weakest part of Europe’s approach to trade is the high protection afforded by the Common Agricultural Policy, which distorts farming decisions and—unlike the rest of the components of the European economic model—helps neither poorer farmers nor poorer countries. (See chapter 2 for an argument that Europe would do well to reconsider its agricultural trade policies toward the economies of the EU eastern partnership, where many people are still farmers.) Trade is one of Europe’s strong points. European integration is a unique political and economic achievement, and enlargement represents opportunities for both 56 CHAPTER 1 old and new member states of the European Union. Making fuller use of these opportunities requires strengthening as well as extending the single market. Finance: managing quick capital flows Banks and ï¬?nanciers are not popular these days. There are questions about whether ï¬?nancial integration in Europe has gone too far. This report argues that ï¬?nancial integration has been at the core of one of Europe’s biggest achievements—the rapid convergence of incomes and living standards across the continent. These flows should not be slowed; Europe should just get better at managing them. Critics of ï¬?nancial integration in Europe point to the risk that excessive debt levels may slow down growth in the future, because new credit is not available while banks reduce exposure to repair their balance sheets. Easy ï¬?nance may have obscured structural weaknesses of economies and enterprises and led to a misallocation and waste of capital at the cost of European taxpayers, who now have to bail out the banks. And critics point to the shortcomings of Europe’s ï¬?nancial and regulatory architecture, with ï¬?nancial institutions that operate freely across borders while remaining under the supervision of national authorities. The criticism points to areas that need ï¬?xing. But this report argues that on the whole, ï¬?nance has been a boon to Europe despite some excesses. In supporting this conclusion, the report distinguishes between the emerging markets in Eastern Europe and the countries that joined the European Union during the 1970s and 1980s—the erstwhile “cohesion countriesâ€?—Ireland, Greece, Portugal, and Spain. The private sector credit boom in emerging Europe has not created a debt overhang. Corporate and household balance sheets are not excessively leveraged, and credit has gone to stronger companies and wealthier households. By and large, ï¬?nance has helped real convergence in Eastern Europe. Going forward, while commercial banks struggle with a large share of nonperforming loans, and credit growth may be subdued for some time, exchange rate flexibility in countries such as the Czech Republic or Poland and the political will to carry through an internal devaluation in places like the three Baltic states should mitigate the risks of a credit-less recovery.17 By contrast, debt levels in the cohesion countries are near or above the thresholds of sustainability and growth-friendliness. The debt overhang compounds the challenge of restoring competitiveness and growth, without which in turn debt sustainability is questionable. External borrowing in Europe’s south has typically gone hand in hand with a decline in domestic private savings. Except Ireland, where productivity growth was high throughout the boom, ï¬?nance in the cohesion countries has not promoted real convergence but instead has fueled the convergence of nominal incomes. Europe’s underlying productivity gap between north and south, more than its ï¬?nancial system, needs ï¬?xing. A peculiar feature of ï¬?nancial integration in Europe (both within the European Union and in some EU eastern partnership countries, such as Ukraine) is the predominance of ï¬?nancial FDI, most obviously manifest as foreign banks in emerging Europe. This has made ï¬?nancial flows more durable during the crisis, with rollover rates close to 100 percent compared with 60–65 percent during the East Asia crisis of 1997–98. This success was in part achieved thanks to 57 GOLDEN GROWTH spontaneous coordination among home and host regulators, banks themselves, and international ï¬?nancial institutions under the so-called “Vienna Initiative.â€? As the sovereign debt crisis in Europe has put renewed pressure on European banks, however, Europe needs to consider moving beyond coordination toward building a Europe-wide regulatory architecture that provides enforcement powers to supranational institutions such as the European Banking Authority. Managing quick capital flows successfully is likely to require national regulators to transfer some authority to the European level. At the national level, countercyclical ï¬?scal policy and macroprudential ï¬?nancial sector regulations would have helped economies in emerging Europe get the best out of western ï¬?nance. A lesson of the crisis is the need for European policymakers to act more forcefully to cool excessive domestic demand. There is a moral in the coincidence of the success of ï¬?nancial integration and an improved investment climate: where domestic competition was weak, ï¬?nance flowed into real estate and retail lending in the absence of a sufï¬?cient supply of creditworthy corporate borrowers. Financial integration can catalyze real economic integration when the right structural policies are in place—but it cannot substitute for them. In the meantime, the macroprudential architecture in Europe has also been strengthened in the course of the crisis, with the creation of the European Systemic Risk Board. Whether this is sufï¬?cient to prevent future excesses can be debated. Market signals in the course of 2011 were clear: yields came down for sovereigns in countries like Ireland and Latvia where macroeconomic policies have sharply unwound the excesses of the past; they did not where measures remained halfhearted or where political commitment to stay the course of adjustment was in doubt. The comparison of south and east provides lessons in how ï¬?nancial integration can foster convergence when managed well, and how it can destabilize all of Europe when the capital flows into unproductive activities. But this report concludes that closer ï¬?nancial integration between wealthier and less advanced economies in Europe is unique, and a strength of the European economic model. Enterprise: making structures better suited for an enlarged Europe Advocates of free, unregulated markets point to Europe’s modest growth performance over the past two decades, compared with those of the United States and East Asia, as an example of the stifling effects of excessive regulation. While the attempted regulatory harmonization in the 120,000 pages of the Acquis Communitaire is an admirable ambition, Europe is not considered an easy place to do business. Unless this changes, it is argued, Europe’s growth prospects look dim. In reality, there is considerable variation in the extent of government regulation of private enterprise across Europe. Regulation remains pervasive despite a decade-long process of gradual liberalization in the south and some Continental European countries, but is now lighter in the north and in some new EU members in the east. This report examines how these differences lead to differences in the health of Europe’s economies, taking a microeconomic 58 CHAPTER 1 approach to the assessment of enterprise performance. In particular, it examines how enterprises have done in achieving three objectives: adding value, creating jobs, and increasing exports. European enterprises do not do worse than their competitors in the United States and East Asia in these three dimensions. There are, however, big differences across Europe that result from how countries regulate enterprise. In the European Union, the north exceeds the performance of the United States in all three dimensions, Continental Europe does well in exports but less so in value added and employment growth, and the south has added jobs, but not value and exports. Productivity growth within the EU15 has begun to diverge in recent years. By contrast with the south, the EU’s eastern members and neighbors have done well in increasing productivity and exports, but less in creating jobs. The differences in the business environment and the performance of enterprises are linked. Cumbersome regulations, high tax rates, compliance costs, and weaknesses in contract enforcement keep enterprises small in the south. Smaller ï¬?rms often stay below the radar screen of inspectors or beneï¬?t from simpliï¬?ed requirements. Staying small often means staying nimble and limiting risks. But smaller ï¬?rms are also less attractive for foreign investors and face signiï¬?cant risks themselves in trading and investing internationally. And smaller ï¬?rms can ill afford the wages demanded by a highly educated workforce. These are all reasons why the south has experienced slower productivity and export growth than other regions in Europe, and they explain how fast job creation has coexisted with signiï¬?cant youth unemployment, often of university graduates. By contrast, enterprises in the north and in Europe’s continental economies have faced fewer obstacles in growing bigger. They have internationalized and have been able to attract and retain skilled labor. They have done so although regulations and taxes in Northern and Continental Europe remain more burdensome than in other high-income OECD countries. But compliance costs have been reduced, and predictability and evenhanded enforcement have helped ï¬?rms adjust. The recent success of enterprises in countries such as Finland, Germany, and Sweden indicates that the European economic and social model is not incompatible with competitive enterprise. In the east, deregulation and simpliï¬?ed tax systems have helped attract FDI from Estonia to Georgia. Good infrastructure, as in the Czech Republic, and a large domestic market, such as in Poland, have also helped. By internationalizing and becoming part of Austrian, German, and Swedish multinational production chains, Eastern European enterprises have beneï¬?ted from enlargement and have been rewarded with gains in productivity and world record export performance. Innovation: improving the structures that bring ideas to market Researchers who are worried that European enterprises are becoming less competitive relative to North American and East Asian ï¬?rms point to Europe’s 59 GOLDEN GROWTH weaker innovation fundamentals: competition, universities, and R&D funding. Policymakers in Europe have been focused on innovation for several years as reflected, for instance, in the Lisbon Strategy of 2002. This set a target for Europe to reach a level of R&D spending of at least 3 percent of GDP. Today, Europe as a whole remains quite distant from this objective and also lags the United States, the world’s innovation leader, in a number of aspects related to innovation. This report assesses what the main components of a European “innovation ecosystemâ€? might be. A composite indicator developed by the European Union covers public and private R&D investments, the quality of universities, linkages between research and business, access to ï¬?nance, protection of intellectual property rights, and access to a large market. The measure highlights the innovation gap between Europe and the United States. Among Europe’s major competitors (the United States, Japan, Brazil, Russia, India, and China), only Russia is falling behind in relative terms. The United States and Japan score better than the European Union and are widening the gap. Close up, the picture looks different. Switzerland, Sweden, Denmark, Finland, and Germany perform close to U.S. levels, but much of Southern and Eastern Europe lags well behind. The poor performance of some advanced European countries such as Italy, Spain, and—to less extent—France in various dimensions of innovation is of particular concern. Poorer economies can often grow fast even without much innovation by adopting frontier technologies. Europe’s own history up to the mid-1970s, and East Asia’s “flying geeseâ€? pattern of structural change and technological advance, are examples of catch-up growth. But closer to the technological frontier, institutions have to change to promote innovation. Studies suggest that competition, the quality of tertiary education, and the availability of venture capital ï¬?nance are the main ingredients of success at the frontier (for example, Aghion and Howitt 2006). Europe as a whole lags the United States in these dimensions, and Europe’s low-innovation economies lag behind its leaders in every one of them. One sign of Europe’s innovation gap is that it has too few young, leading innovators—ï¬?rms that have grown quickly to become large. Young ï¬?rms form the majority of leading innovators in the United States, and a substantial share of R&D in leading sectors. Europe does not specialize in R&D-intensive sectors such as aerospace, biotech, information technology, health care, pharmaceuticals, and telecommunications. Even in countries with strong national innovation systems such as Germany or Sweden, there are few young, fast-growing companies, and innovation-based sectors are poorly represented. Europe, like Japan, carries out the bulk of its R&D in traditional, old ï¬?rms. While this works for some—such as the well-known “export championsâ€? like ABB, Erikson, BMW, Mercedes Benz, BASF, or Siemens—Europe has few companies that match the dynamism of Apple, Amazon, Google, Facebook, or Microsoft. This report links this back to the fragmentation in the single market for digital services, which makes it more difï¬?cult for young innovators in Europe to grow to global scale. Europe did not get the same productivity kick as the United States out of the wave of improvements in information communications and technology over the 60 CHAPTER 1 last decade and a half. It will have to harness the power of the single market to do better when the next technological revolution comes along. Labor: getting more from work Europeans sometimes fear that Europe is running out of work. But it is workers that Europe is running out of. Addressing this misconception may be one of the most important tasks for European policymakers. Labor markets have long been recognized as one of Europe’s weaker points. Persistent unemployment during the 1980s and 1990s was perhaps the most widely discussed aspect of what some called “Eurosclerosisâ€?—the inability of Europe’s postwar institutions to adjust to a changing global economy (Giersch 1985). Motivated in part by the view that work in Europe was a pie of ï¬?xed size, policymakers made it easier for Europeans to retire earlier and to work fewer hours. Workers in Europe have responded to these incentives, not least because they enjoy social security. The generosity of social welfare and the high degree of protection afforded to workers in Europe are a distinguishing characteristic of the European economic and social model, setting the continent apart from other high-income economies. This report assesses the costs of this generosity, highlighting inconsistencies in the way work and welfare are organized in Europe. As part of ï¬?nancing generous social beneï¬?ts, the burden of payroll taxes has grown while the workforce that pays these taxes has declined. The laws make workers, once hired, feel secure. The same laws make employers think twice before hiring. High taxes and burdensome employment protection rules discourage job creation with the consequence that some Europeans—often the young—remain excluded from the labor market. Europe’s policies regulating work can be linked to the inefï¬?ciencies in the labor market, which in turn contribute to a loss of competitiveness and reduced ability of enterprises to innovate. The strains in Europe’s insider-outsider labor market have grown since economists ï¬?rst pointed out its inefï¬?ciencies in the 1980s. Youth unemployment rates of 40 percent such as in Spain are hardly compatible with the objective of social inclusion. At the same time, many Europeans fear that with globalization and European enlargement, their jobs are competed away through outsourcing and immigration. When the amount of work available is seen as a ï¬?xed pie, the inclination is to limit the number of eaters. The tension between insiders and outsiders has correspondingly grown. It need not be like this. Compared with the 1970s and 1980s, Europe has become better at creating jobs. Excluding some from the labor market is an anachronism in a continent facing a rapid decline in its labor force over the coming decades. If current patterns persist, Europe will have 30 million fewer young workers (ages 19–39) by 2060. Europe’s youth have to be brought into the economic mainstream. And even then, shortages of skilled labor remain likely. Encouragingly, a growing number of European countries have been changing their labor market policies. It will be reassuring for many Europeans that labor markets in Denmark and Germany have succeeded in combining high levels of income security for workers with stronger incentives to look for new 61 GOLDEN GROWTH opportunities, and with measures to lower the payroll tax and thus encourage employers to create jobs. It should also be reassuring that governments in Northern Europe have been successful in matching younger workers and jobs, though such policies are difï¬?cult to get right and can be expensive. Some parts of Europe are poised to do a lot better than others when it emerges from the current economic turbulence. These differences in prospects have consequences for workers. Europe’s single market is premised on the aspiration that labor can move freely in response to economic opportunities. In reality, Europeans move little both inside countries and across national borders. High regional unemployment rates motivate costly regional development policies that attempt to bring jobs to people, rather than encourage people to move to where the jobs are. Low levels of mobility are associated with high unemployment. Language barriers, family ties, and attachment to local culture make Europeans reluctant to move, yet these are not unique to Europe. Younger, educated, and ambitious Europeans would beneï¬?t from stronger signals from the labor market, better-functioning housing markets, and more easily portable health and social protection beneï¬?ts. In Europe’s economic powerhouses like Germany, enterprises are often short of skilled labor. In Spain and Italy, many university graduates are struggling to enter the labor market. Europe as a whole will beneï¬?t from higher labor mobility.18 Indeed, for countries that share a single currency, labor mobility may be the most important missing ingredient—one that could help make the eurozone an “optimum currency area.â€? Europe will also have to learn to compete for global talent. Europe offers much in the way of cultural richness and economic opportunity, yet talent from around the world is more likely to go to the United States because of better universities, more-accommodating labor markets, and institutions that are more welcoming (The Economist 2009). Europe has much to change in its approach to immigration. Government: making a representative state more efï¬?cient Seen from Asia or America, Europe is a region with big government. For many, big government is associated with bloated bureaucracies, high taxes, and wasteful government spending. Little wonder, it is said, that European economies have trouble growing. The recent ï¬?nancial turbulence in Europe, prompted by concerns over large public debts and persistent ï¬?scal deï¬?cits, has added weight to the arguments of those skeptical of large government. This report asks whether large governments are indeed harmful for growth. In Europe, this seems to be the case; countries with larger governments grow more slowly. And in Europe, governments are larger. This is primarily because of higher spending on social protection—most important, public pension systems. Population aging lies behind growing social security spending in all high-income and many middle-income countries, but the impact is highly variable. Rethinking the design and size of social security systems in Europe can draw on existing good practice, such as in Iceland or Japan, to deal with the 62 CHAPTER 1 demographic drag on economic growth. Many countries in Europe have already started to increase the retirement age and tighten eligibility criteria for public pensions. Others have introduced mandatory “second pillars,â€? which accumulate contributions in individual pension accounts, to encourage domestic savings and reduce the burden on public pay-as-you-go systems. Sweden and Switzerland are often seen as models in this regard, but as the experience of several Eastern European countries during the past three years demonstrates, sustaining these reforms can be politically difï¬?cult. Whatever route is chosen, those countries in Europe that have not done so yet must ï¬?nd ways to restrain spending on social security or risk growing ï¬?scal challenges. There are economies in Europe with large governments that do well. Sweden, for instance, hardly ï¬?ts the stereotype of a rigid, bureaucratized Leviathan, though government spending in 2010 was more than half of GDP. One reason that Scandinavian countries with large governments do so well is that public services are of high quality. This report considers their reforms to draw lessons for the rest of Europe and the world. But one asset that Northern European countries have that may be tough to replicate is a higher degree of social trust. Where the rule of law is weak and social trust is low, large government is likely to be harmful. So Southern Europe might have done better to keep government small, since it is difï¬?cult to make it efï¬?cient without the preconditions for compliance with taxes and regulations, high levels of work participation, and frugal use of social welfare. This is a lesson that emerging market economies in Europe with large public sectors, such as Ukraine’s, should learn. Whether or not large government is bad for growth and ï¬?scal austerity is seen as harming the short-term prospects of growth in Europe, for countries with large public debts ï¬?scal consolidation is a necessity. Neither higher taxes nor productivity increases are likely to keep the public ï¬?nances of these countries afloat at current spending levels. High-quality ï¬?scal consolidation strategies to reach sustainable paths for public debt are analyzed in chapter 7. There is ample room in Europe to cut spending without affecting social outcomes. Nonetheless, the political challenge of maintaining primary surpluses for several years is daunting. Some countries have room to adjust more gradually than others. And given the close economic links between European countries, those with ï¬?scal space could perhaps use it. Restoring Europe’s lustre In November 2008, as the consequences of the ï¬?nancial collapse gripped markets and policymakers worldwide, a senior U.S. government ofï¬?cial remarked: “You never want to let a serious crisis go to waste.â€?19 It is not clear whether the United States has used the crisis well. But three years later, the epicenter of economic turbulence lay not there but in Europe. The attention was focused on restoring the conï¬?dence of markets in European governments. But behind the market nervousness were doubts about the sustainability of Europe’s economic and social model. The European sovereign debt crisis could be seen as an opportunity to address these concerns quickly. 63 GOLDEN GROWTH This report was written with more deliberate adjustments in mind. That will indeed be the course of reform in the many countries that have responsibly applied the principles of the European growth model. But the countries that have strayed furthest from them will be forced to adjust abruptly. It should be a warning to the others. There have been changes in the world that necessitate a reexamination of the basic economic model. Since 2005, the contribution of developing countries to global growth has been greater than that of advanced economies, even though their share in global GDP is half that of the developed world. All advanced economies should reflect upon these shifts. This report is such a reflection for 45 countries in Europe. An unprecedented combination of enterprise, labor, trade, ï¬?nance, innovation, and government attributes makes the European growth model unique. The close economic ties between richer and poorer countries; the balance between proï¬?t and public interest in enterprise; the social contract that protects the poor, elderly, and unemployed; and the representativeness of government at continental, national, and local levels are unique and admirable. Europeans cherish these features and much of the world admires and tries to emulate them. This report concludes that the European economic model needs to be adjusted, not abandoned. The changes that have made it necessary for Europe to craft a new economic model are demographic, entrepreneurial, and ï¬?scal. Europe’s working population is expected to decline by about 15 percent by 2050, while that of the United States will grow by more than 25 percent. Asia’s productivity and competitiveness will allow its enterprises to outstrip all but the most innovative ones in the United States. It will especially pressure Europe, where productivity growth has been slowing since the mid-1990s and the service economy has been held back by fragmented regulation. The growing costs of social security and slowing economic productivity will squeeze Europe from two sides in the coming decade. The pressures may rise quickly. Debt burdens that seemed manageable at the borrowing costs of 2008 may be unbearable in the market conditions of 2012. Europe needs to change. The order of chapters in this report reflects the changes required in ascending order. Europe’s strong points are in trade and ï¬?nance. In the areas of enterprise and innovation, Europe has countries that do well in the world. But many European countries are struggling to generate and support entrepreneurial high achievers and innovators. The biggest need for change is in the areas of labor and government. Labor policies must be reoriented toward greater labor mobility, incentives to work, and more competitiveness and job creation in sectors where Europe lags behind. Almost everywhere, European governments are too big and inefï¬?cient in delivering services. They will have to become smaller or more efï¬?cient, whichever is quicker. Their weaknesses and strengths are summarized in table 1.1. The necessary changes will not be easy, but many European countries have already made progress, and others can learn from their experiences. Other parts of the world are dealing, or have dealt with, similar pressures, and Europe may learn from them too. Using more than 16 pairs of benchmarking briefs prepared for this report, chapter 8 provides accounts of successful experiences. 64 CHAPTER 1 Table 1.1: Strengths and shortcomings of Europe’s growth model Strengths Shortcomings Trade Highest share of trade in GDP of all regions in the world. Single Market for Services remains incomplete. Lowest barriers to trade in goods. Common Agricultural Policy reduces the benefits of Growing size and sophistication of production networks connecting emerging and trade integration for Europe’s eastern neighbors. advanced Europe. High degree of trade integration in traditional services. Fastest convergence in incomes and living standards in the world. Finance Capital flows downhill from countries with high incomes and low Boom-time excesses point to the need to ensure crisis-proof financial growth rates to countries with low incomes and high growth rates. integration and strengthen supranational regulation. Financial foreign direct investment has brought western know-how Cheap finance made Southern and Eastern Europe complacent about and finance to emerging Europe. external imbalances. Dependence on western banks to date has mitigated the effect of the crisis on emerging Europe. Enterprise Business bears more responsibility for social and Countries with more onerous business regulations have lagged in productivity environmental consequences of its activities than in any growth and exports. other part of the world. Growing gap in economic competitiveness between the southern states and the rest European enterprises have—by and large—generated is a source of instability in the eurozone. employment, productivity, and exports. European production has become greener but not its consumption. Variations in business regulation across Europe do not confirm a “race to the bottom.â€? Innovation Some European countries figure among the Europe’s private R&D spending is much less than in U.S. and Asia’s developed economies. top global innovators and exporters. Linkages between research institutes and business are weak because of overdependence on Established tradition of strong public support public funding. to universities and R&D institutes. Europe is not specialized in fast-growing high-technology sectors such as ICT and biotech. Europe has a proud tradition of innovation Europe has fewer leading innovating companies and few top universities globally. in engineering, pharmaceuticals, and clean Bank-dominated finance is ill suited for innovation. energy that could be harnessed for future innovation. Labor Greater post-tax earnings equality. Labor participation rates below those in U.S. and East Asian advanced economies. Strong income protection and Rapid aging will result in workforce falling by a sixth over the next 50 years. unemployment insurance systems. Generous eligibility raises concerns over the sustainability of social security. Good aggregate job creation Large informal sectors in some European countries and high youth unemployment point to problems of performance over past decade. labor market exclusion. Low labor mobility despite formally free movement of labor within Europe. Unfriendly immigration policies may keep global talent away. Government Most representative Government size is 10 percent of GDP greater than in other parts of the world, and public spending to GDP has risen and decentralized of all by about 5 percentage points during the crisis. regions. Pension burdens are high for a relatively young (but quickly aging) region. Broad coverage of Generosity of social welfare programs weakens incentives to work. public services and High marginal tax rates promote evasion and make Europe less attractive for enterprises and skilled workers. social security. Variation in quality of public services unrelated to government spending. Low post-tax income Unsustainable public debt in some countries, fiscal imbalances in many. inequality. 65 GOLDEN GROWTH To sustain its success in the twenty-ï¬?rst century, Europe will need to draw on the strength of its integrating institutions, especially the Single Market for Services. It will need to stimulate greater competition to push laggard enterprises to catch up with Europe’s best, and to free Europe’s high achievers to innovate and grow. It will need to reorganize work and government to deal with the imperatives of regional integration and global competition, while maintaining domestic cohesion. This will require greater flexibility and mobility of labor, efï¬?cient management of capital mobility, and a new balance between economic freedom and social security. All this is hard work. But the policymakers who address these imperatives will create a growing Europe. It will be a Europe that keeps its way of life and its place in the world, that radiates hope and again becomes an inspiration for others. It will be a Europe that has restored its lustre. Answers to questions on page 35 The principal components of Europe’s growth model—trade, ï¬?nance, enterprise, innovation, labor, and government—are organized in unique ways. Sluggish productivity growth, a declining workforce, and growing ï¬?scal imbalances have revealed weaknesses of the European economic model, and the entry of a billion Asian workers into the global market is adding to the stress stress. Many changes are needed in how governments and labor markets are organized. Fewer changes are needed to foster innovation, productivity growth, and job creation by enterprises, and fewer still to improve ï¬?nance and trade in Europe. 66 CHAPTER 1 Chapter 1: Annexes Annex 1.1: List of countries and regions EU15 EU candidate states Latin America (LAC) Austria AUT Albania ALB Argentina ARG Belgium BEL Bosnia and Herzegovina BIH Brazil BRA Denmark DNK Croatia HRV Chile CHL Finland FIN Kosovo KSV Colombia COL France FRA Macedonia, FYR MKD Mexico MEX Germany DEU Montenegro MNE Peru PER Greece GRC Serbia SRB Uruguay URY Ireland IRL Turkey TUR Venezuela, RB VEN Italy ITA Luxembourg LUX Eastern partnership states North America and Oceania Netherlands NLD Armenia ARM Australia AUS Portugal PRT Azerbaijan AZE Canada CAN Spain ESP Belarus BLR New Zealand NZL Sweden SWE Georgia GEO United States USA United Kingdom GBR Moldova MDA Ukraine UKR Africa EU15 southern states Algeria DZA Greece GRC European Free Trade Association Egypt, Arab Rep. EGY Italy ITA Iceland ISL Morocco MAR Portugal PRT Liechtenstein LIE South Africa ZAF Spain ESP Norway NOR Tunisia TUN Switzerland CHE EU12 Other Bulgaria BGR East Asia India IND Cyprus CYP China CHN Russian Federation RUS Czech Republic CZE Indonesia IDN Estonia EST Japan JPN Hungary HUN Korea, Rep. KOR Latvia LVA Malaysia MYS Lithuania LTU Philippines PHL Malta MLT Singapore SGP Poland POL Taiwan, China TWN Romania ROM Thailand THA Slovak Republic SVK Vietnam VNM Slovenia SVN 67 GOLDEN GROWTH Notes 1 In 2004, around 50 percent of EU15 citizens in income. This to some extent reflects model, including Austria, the Benelux states, supported the accession of additional nonsustainable borrowing for consumption France, and Germany; and a southern members to the European Union. In 2008, purposes, predicated on the assumption of model, including Greece, Italy, Portugal, and 47 percent of citizens in the EU27 supported almost “automaticâ€? income convergence Spain. Atkinson, Piketty, and Saez (2011) the accession of additional members, but in Europe. As the experience in Europe’s distinguish an English-speaking group support in all new member states except southern countries demonstrates, such an of countries in the evolution of income Latvia was above 60 percent, whereas the assumption is risky. Europe’s institutions distribution from Continental Europe. four biggest EU15 countries all had support make it easier for poorer economies to catch Eastern Europe is in many respects unique levels of about 40 percent or less. up. But persistent high income levels must given the persistent legacies of central be earned in Europe as elsewhere. planning. This chapter emphasizes the 2 According to Eurobarometer, it has fallen common aspects; the next six chapters from 66 percent in 2004 to just 52 percent in 8 Note that in this chart, Azerbaijan is excluded from the trend line for Europe identify cross-country differences in the 2008. because as an oil producer it runs principal components of the growth model. 3 Speciï¬?cally, this report distinguishes huge current account surpluses. Poorer 16 Although public debt levels are high in most between the EU15 (often called the “old developing countries are excluded from European countries, the sustainable level member statesâ€?) and the EU12 (the new the “rest of the worldâ€? trend line because of public debt differs signiï¬?cantly between members) and within these groups between ofï¬?cial flows play a much greater role and countries like Germany that is running subgroups of “Northern,â€? “Continentalâ€? the determinants of these flows are quite current account surpluses and countries like or “Central,â€? and “Southernâ€? European different. Greece with a large current account deï¬?cit. countries. Among the EU’s neighbors, 9 This puzzle was ï¬?rst formally noted by von Weizsäcker (2011) argues that for the report distinguishes countries that Gourinchas and Jeanne (2007). countries like Germany, the optimal public are advanced economies (the European 10 EBRD (2009) reached a similar conclusion. debt level has increased as demographic Free Trade Association members: Iceland, changes have led to a downward shift in Liechtenstein, Norway, and Switzerland) and 11 Gordon (2004) estimates that around the natural rate of interest. In a “closed those that are emerging markets. The report one-third of the gap in incomes per capita economyâ€? setting with public debt also distinguishes between candidates for between the EU15 and the United States held domestically, this implies a higher future membership in the European Union may be due to voluntary reductions in labor sustainable public debt level. Japan falls into (Turkey and the western Balkans) and supply in Europe. However, the remainder the same category. countries that are part of the EU eastern reflects regulations that reduce labor supply partnership (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, and should be seen as a welfare loss. In 17 Darvas (2011) examines recoveries following Georgia, Moldova, and Ukraine). Europe, this claim is considered debatable. banking crises and shows that in countries with flexible exchange rates, postcrisis 4 See annex 1.1 for a list of country 12 They also mirror low tax morale and low growth was higher, even when credit was abbreviations. conï¬?dence in public institutions (World subdued, than in countries facing the need 5 By far the largest capital flows, a substantial Bank 2011). While labor market regulations to adjust with ï¬?xed exchange rates. share of which in ofï¬?cial transfers, occurred and payroll tax rates do matter, general between East and West Germany. But institutional weaknesses are likely to 18 This argument assumes that the skills be at least as important in perpetuating provided by Spanish and Italian universities this is a special case of integration and informality. are the skills required by German convergence within one nation with employers. Increasing labor mobility in little relevance for regional integration 13 Most European countries also provide Europe also requires improved recognition experiences, perhaps except for the more protection against unemployment of professional qualiï¬?cations and arguably Democratic People’s Republic of Korea and than other OECD countries. Of the 15 OECD greater attention to quality in Europe’s the Republic of Korea. countries with replacement rates during education systems. 6 The lack of convergence globally is not what the ï¬?rst year of unemployment above the economists would expect. Neoclassical average (66 percent), 14 are EU member 19 Rahm Emmanuel, the White House chief of states. The United Kingdom, Ireland, and staff, in an interview with The Wall Street models of economic growth predict income Greece stand out for low replacement rates. Journal, November 19, 2008. convergence across countries. In Solow (1956), the long-run growth rates of per 14 The incidence of low pay is deï¬?ned by the capita income are purely driven by technical OECD as the share of full-time workers progress, while the level of per capita earning less than two-thirds of median income is determined by the “steady stateâ€? earnings. Low pay is thus a relative rather savings rate. Allowing for differences in than absolute concept and closely related to savings rates across countries, one obtains measures of the dispersion of earnings. the less demanding prediction of conditional convergence, which holds across a large 15 Other analyses suggest that instead of a range of countries (for example, see European model, there are several regional Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992). Europe has models within Europe. Roxburgh and seen unconditional convergence. Mischke (2011) identify a northern model, 7 Europe uniquely has also experienced which includes Ireland, the Nordic nations, faster convergence in consumption than and the United Kingdom; a continental 68 CHAPTER 1 References Abbas, S., N. Belhocine, A. El-Ganainy, and Gordon, R. 2004. “Two Centuries of Mankiw, N., D. Romer, and D. Weil. M. Horton. 2011. “Historical Patterns and Economic Growth: Europe Chasing the 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Dynamics of Public Debt—Evidence from a American Frontier.â€? NBER Working Paper Economic Growth.â€? The Quarterly Journal of New Database.â€? IMF Economic Review 59 10662, National Bureau of Economic Economics 107 (2): 407–437. (4): 717–742. Research, Cambridge, MA. Miller, T., and K. Holmes. 2011. 2011 Index of Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. Gourinchas, P-O., and O. Jeanne. 2007. Economic Freedom: Promoting Economic 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative “Capital Flows to Developing Countries: Opportunity and Prosperity. Washington, Development: An Empirical Investigation.â€? The Allocation Puzzle.â€? NBER Working DC: The Heritage Foundation. The American Economic Review 91 (5): Paper 13602, National Bureau of Economic Monti, M. 2010. “A New Strategy for the 1369–1401. Research, Cambridge, MA. Single Market: At the Service of Europe’s Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 2006. “Joseph Gwartney, J., J. Hall, and R. Lawson. 2010. Economy and Society.â€? Report to the Schumpeter Lecture – Appropriate Growth Economic Freedom of the World: 2010 President of the European Commission, May Policy: A Unifying Framework.â€? Journal of Annual Report. With C. Coyne, J. Dawson, 9, European Commission, Brussels. the European Economic Association 4 (2–3): H. Feldmann, J. Levendis, R. Sobel, and Müller-Armack, A. 1947. Wirtschaftslenkung 269–314. E. Stringham. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser und Marktwirtschaft. Hamburg: Verlag für Atkinson, A., T. Piketty, and E. Saez. 2011. Institute. Wirtschaft und Sozialpolitik. “Top Incomes in the Long Run of History.â€? Heston, A., R. Summers, and B. Aten. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- Journal of Economic Literature 49 (1): 3–71. 2011. “Penn World Table Version 7.0.â€? May, operation and Development). 1999. OECD Conference Board, The. 2011. “Total Center for International Comparisons of Employment Outlook 1999. Paris: OECD. Economy Database.â€? January 2011, The Production, Income and Prices, University of OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- Conference Board, New York, NY. Available Pennsylvania, Pennsylvania, PA. operation and Development). 2004. OECD at www.conference-board.org/data/ ILO (International Labour Ofï¬?ce). 2010a. Employment Outlook 2004. Paris: OECD. economydatabase. Accessed September 3, Global Wage Report 2010/11: Wage Policies Phelps, E. 1961. “The Golden Rule of 2011. in Times of Crisis. Geneva: ILO. Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen.â€? The Darvas, Z. 2011. “A Tale of Three Countries: ILO (International Labour Ofï¬?ce). 2010b. American Economic Review 51 (4): 638–643. Recovery after Banking Crises.â€? Bruegel Key indicators of the Labour Market, Sixth Phelps, E. 2007. “Economic Dynamism Policy Contribution 2011/19, Bruegel, Edition. Geneva: ILO. and the Social Market Economy: Are Brussels. Background paper for this report. Jones, C., and P. Klenow 2010. “Beyond They Reconcilable?â€? 2007 Annual Ludwig DeLong, J. 1997. “Post-WWII Western GDP? Welfare across Countries and Time.â€? Erhardt Lecture, Initiative Neue Soziale European Exceptionalism: The Economic NBER Working Paper 16352, National Bureau Marktwirtschaft, October 12, Berlin. Dimension.â€? Brad DeLong’s Website, of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Prasad, E., R. Rajan, and A. Subramanian. December. Available at www.j-bradford- Jorgenson, D., and M. Timmer. 2011. 2007. “Foreign Capital and Economic delong.net/Econ_Articles/ucla/ucla_ “Structural Change in Advanced Nations: Growth.â€? Brookings Papers on Economic marshall2.html. Accessed July 10, 2011. A New Set of Stylised Facts.â€? The Activity 2007 (1): 153–209. EBRD (European Bank for Reconstruction Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113 (1): Roxburgh, C., J. Mischke, B. Regout, D. and Development). 2009. Transition Report 1–29. Archetti, A. Chau, P. D’Aprile, A. Harbola, H. 2009: Transition in Crisis? London: ERBD. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. Proff, D. Schmautzer, M. Thomys, and A. Economist, The. 2009. “Going to America: 2010. “The Worldwide Governance Weber. 2010. “Beyond Austerity: A Path to A Ponzi Scheme that Works.â€? December 19, Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Economic Growth and Renewal in Europe.â€? Volume 393, Issue 8662: 41–44. Issues.â€? Policy Research Working Paper October 2010, McKinsey Global Institute, Eichengreen, B. 1996. “Institutions and 5430, World Bank, Washington, DC. London. Economic Growth: Europe after World War Krugman, P. 2011. “Eurotrashed.â€? The New Roxburgh, C., and J. Mischke. 2011. II.â€? In Economic Growth in Europe since York Times, January 16. “European Growth and Renewal: The Path 1945, ed. N. Crafts, and G. Toniolo: 38–72. Lucas, R. 1990. “Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Crisis to Recovery.â€? Updated research, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. from Rich to Poor Countries?â€? The American July, McKinsey Global Institute, London. Eucken, W. 1940. Die Grundlagen der Economic Review 80 (2): 92–96. Schwab, E., ed. 2009. The Global Nationalökonomie. Jena: Gustav Fischer. MacGillivray, A., P. Begley, and S. Zadek, Competitiveness Report 2009–2010. Giersch, H. 1985. Eurosclerosis. Kiel: Inst. für ed. 2007. The State of Responsible Geneva: WEF. Weltwirtschaft. Competitiveness 2007. London: Schwab, E., ed. 2010. The Global AccountAbility. Competitiveness Report 2010–2011. Geneva: WEF. 69 GOLDEN GROWTH Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the von Weizsäcker, C. 2011. “Public Debt Theory of Economic Growth.â€? The Quarterly Requirements in a Regime of Price Journal of Economics 70 (1): 65–94. Stability.â€? Paper presented at the CER-ETH Veenhoven, R. 2011. “Bibliography of Research Seminar, April 12, Zurich. Happiness.â€? World Database of Happiness, World Bank. 2009. World Development Erasmus University Rotterdam, Rotterdam. Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Available at worlddatabaseofhappiness.eur. Geography. Washington, DC: World Bank. nl/hap_bib/bib_fp.php. Accessed February World Bank. 2011. “In from the Shadow: 5, 2011. Integrating Europe’s Informal Labor.â€? World Venn, D. 2009. “Legislation, Collective Bank Report 63078-ECA, World Bank, Bargaining and Enforcement: Updating the Washington, DC. OECD Employment Protection Indicators.â€? OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 89, OECD, Paris. 70 SPOTLIGHT ONE Spotlight One Europe—convergence machine Economic growth has helped Europe rise from the devastation and misery of World War II to unprecedented wealth, technological sophistication, and the world’s best quality of life. Since the war, Western Europe’s output has tripled and Eastern Europe’s doubled. The European Union, itself an unprecedented achievement, is in many ways the world’s largest economy. European societies have developed market-based systems combining high levels of economic activity with equity and social inclusion. Growth rate 1950 to 1973 1974 to 1993 1994 to 2010 Western Europe converges toward Northern and Southern Europe converge Eastern Europe converges toward the the living standards of the United toward the income levels of Continental incomes and institutions of Western States Europe Europe Annual average growth of GDP per capita, percent < 0.9 1 – 1.9 2 – 2.9 3 – 3.9 >4 71 GOLDEN GROWTH These developments are all the more remarkable when considering the poor conditions—social, political, and economic—that prevailed at the end of what has been called Europe’s second Thirty Years’ War. From 1913 to 1950, the continent’s growth rate was half its long-run trend. Europe entered the twentieth century as the richest region in the world, but by mid-century, retaining this distinction was anything but assured. Fewer than six decades later, however, an American economist would write: In the second half of the twentieth century, the lives of Europeans were transformed beyond recognition. In 1950, many of the continent’s residents heated their homes with coal, cooled their food with ice, and lacked even rudimentary forms of indoor plumbing. Today, their lives are eased and enriched by natural-gas furnaces, electric refrigerators, and an array of electronic gadgets that boggles the mind. Gross domestic product per capita, what the income of a typical resident of Europe will buy, tripled in the second half of the twentieth century. The quality of life improved even more than suggested by this simple measure. Hours worked declined by one-third, providing an enormous increase in leisure time. Life expectancy lengthened as a result of improved nutrition and advances in medical science (Eichengreen 2007, p. 1). By 2008, on the eve of the ï¬?nancial crisis, Europe was the envy of the world. The United States had the might and China the momentum, but Europe had the highest living standards. Even with average incomes about a quarter short of the United States’s, Europe had become the “lifestyle superpowerâ€? that in 1992 Prime Minister Kiichi Miyazawa had promised to make Japan. Millions of people from around the world flocked to Europe to see this economic miracle and taste European life (ï¬?gure S1.1). This six-decade run of prosperity breaks neatly into three periods—each about two decades long—of changing economic growth patterns: · From 1950 until 1973, Europe exhibited historically high rates of economic growth, nearly full employment, and convergence to the United States. This period of accelerated growth—a “Golden Ageâ€? in Western Europe and a “Silver Ageâ€? in centrally planned Eastern Europe—ended for most of the continent in the early 1970s (Crafts and Toniolo 1996). · From 1974 until 1993, Northern and Southern Europe continued to converge to the levels of living in Europe’s core. Yet despite continued growth, Europe’s largest economies stopped catching up to the United States, the world’s technology leader. Meanwhile in the east, growth ï¬?rst slowed and then collapsed along with the Berlin Wall and central planning during the early 1990s. · With the signing of the ï¬?rst EU Association Agreements by countries in Eastern Europe in 1994, growth accelerated quickly in the east until the economic crisis in 2008. Convergence proceeded across the continent. This period saw more than a decade of convergence in living standards in the 12 new EU member states and the 8 Balkan economies aspiring to join them. In the south, convergence was reignited during this period, though at a slower pace than in the east. 72 SPOTLIGHT ONE These patterns evolved alongside, and were influenced by, growing economic Figure S1.1: Europe—the cooperation across Europe. Beginning with the 1949 Council for Mutual lifestyle superpower Economic Assistance in the east and the 1950 European Payments Union in (top 20 international destinations the west, the continent pursued near-constant—if not always linear—economic for tourists, 2007) integration. Political integration eventually followed, resulting in a European Source: World Bank staff, using data from the UN Union that merged east and west. The impetus for these regional agreements World Tourism Organization. was geopolitical, but the outcome was regimes that facilitated economic integration and growth, particularly in Western Europe. 1950 to 1973: golden, with a silver fringe Europe’s growth from the ï¬?rst few years of postwar reconstruction until the oil crisis of 1973 was its fastest ever recorded. Growth in real GDP per person was over 3.5 percent in Western and Eastern Europe and 4.5 percent in Southern Europe during this period (table S1.1). The average growth rate for all of Europe had not exceeded 1.5 percent in the previous 130 years. The expansion was even more remarkable because it came after four decades of subtrend growth below 1 percent caused by destruction and depression. For the ï¬?rst time in the twentieth century, Europe outperformed the United States (which grew at 2.3 percent) and every other major economy except Japan. Growth in every European country save the United Kingdom exceeded U.S. growth. Labor productivity growth was 2 percentage points higher a year in the west and 8 points higher in the south. The top performers in Western Europe (Austria, Germany, and Italy), Southern Europe (Greece, Portugal, and Spain), and Eastern Europe (Bulgaria and Romania) had growth rates that exceeded U.S. rates by 2 percentage points or more. The gap in GDP per capita between Western Europe and the United States closed from 48 percent in 1950 to 28 percent in 1973. A similar pattern of convergence occurred in Southern Europe, with the gap closing from 79 percent to 65 percent over the same period. Slightly slower growth in Eastern Europe resulted in a slower pace of convergence with the United States, with the gap falling from 78 percent to 70 percent. 73 GOLDEN GROWTH Table S1.1: Relentless growth in the United States, a miracle in Europe, and resurgence in Asia, 1820–2008 (average annual compound growth rates, GDP per capita, US$ 1990 Geary-Khamis PPP estimates) Western Southern Eastern Former Soviet Latin Period United States Japan East Asia Europe Europe Europe Union America 1820–1870 1.0 0.6 0.6 0.6 1.3 0.2 –0.1 0.0 1870–1913 1.3 1.0 1.4 1.0 1.8 1.4 0.8 1.8 1913–1950 0.8 0.4 0.6 1.7 1.6 0.9 –0.2 1.4 1950–1973 3.8 4.5 3.6 3.2 2.3 7.7 2.3 2.5 1973–1994 1.7 1.9 –0.2 –1.6 1.7 2.5 0.3 0.9 1994–2008 1.6 2.7 4.0 4.2 1.7 1.0 3.9 1.6 Note: Regional aggregates are population-weighted. Western Europe refers to Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, West Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom. Eastern Europe refers to Albania, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Yugoslavia. Southern Europe refers to Greece, Ireland, Spain, and Turkey. After 1989, West Germany becomes Germany, and the data reflect the newly independent countries in Eastern Europe that emerge from Czechoslovakia and Yugoslavia. Source: Maddison 1996; Conference Board 2011. At the beginning of World War II in 1939, per capita GDP was about $5,000 in Western Europe and $2,000 in Eastern and Southern Europe. By contrast, per capita GDP in the United States was more than $6,500. By the end of the war in 1945, per capita GDP had fallen to $4,000 in Western Europe and to under $2,000 in Eastern and Southern Europe. But by the ï¬?rst oil price shock in 1973, per capita income was more than $12,000 in Western Europe, just under $6,000 in Southern Europe, and around $5,000 in Eastern Europe. Per capita income in the United States also grew, from $11,700 after the war to around $16,500 in 1973. Europe’s productivity surge was multifaceted. From an accounting perspective, much of the surge in the 1950s reflected higher labor productivity, originating in capital deepening and heightened total factor productivity. Factors of production destroyed or misallocated as a result of the war were allocated more efï¬?ciently, incorporating new technologies and improved scale economies.1 Eichengreen and Vazquez (2000) describe a period of “extensive growth,â€? driven by additions to the stock of labor and capital and helped by stable returns to capital and labor. By imitating U.S. production practices and importing American technology, European countries experienced further productivity growth. Growth accounting reveals that in the 1960s labor productivity in most countries grew from both applying more capital (“capital deepeningâ€?) and improving total factor productivity (largely “technical progressâ€?; ï¬?gure S1.2, panel A).2 These patterns held across Western Europe and were even stronger in Southern Europe. By contrast, higher total factor productivity and (to a lesser degree) 74 SPOTLIGHT ONE more work drove the United States’s comparatively slower growth. Europe, unlike the United States, had countries to rebuild after the war and reallocated labor accordingly. This was a time of “classical catch-up.â€? Countries improved productivity by bringing unexploited technology into use rather than through innovation. Europe realized productivity gains by rebuilding destroyed capital and importing technology from the United States (Abramovitz 1986). After 20 years of war and economic depression, there was ï¬?nally room for large productivity gains. European countries also integrated into a relatively stable global economy. After World War II, policymakers tried to understand the sources of the global economic disorder of the 1930s and apply its lessons.3 A relatively liberal regime of international trade underpinned by ï¬?xed but adjustable exchange rates was one result. The Marshall Plan, which acted as a “structural adjustmentâ€? program and anchored postwar trade liberalization, may have initiated Europe’s commitment to trade. The Marshall Plan may have even helped create the early formal mechanisms of European integration (De Long and Eichengreen 1993). Beginning with the European Coal and Steel Community in 1951 and the European Economic Community in 1958, formal agreements led to signiï¬?cantly expanding intra-European trade. Europe’s trade openness may have both triggered more efï¬?cient allocation of investment and accelerated technology transfer from the United States. International integration’s importance is evident from growth patterns in Portugal and Spain, which were less closely integrated with other Western European countries until the mid-1950s and early 1960s. Spain saw no major acceleration until it entered technological aid arrangements with the United States in the early 1950s, and Portugal’s growth rate doubled after it joined the Bretton Woods system in 1960. In many countries, an “ever closer unionâ€? went hand in hand with a domestic political economy of growth that permitted high investment in those catch-up years (Eichengreen 1994). The social market economy led to moderated wage demands in exchange for commitments from ï¬?rms to reinvest proï¬?ts. The high postwar investment rates are derived from a complex network that bound labor’s participation in ï¬?rms’ production and investment decisions with relatively generous unemployment beneï¬?ts and limited industrial policy supports. Growth rates were lower in countries that did not strike these labor-ï¬?rm bargains—such as the United Kingdom. Despite a different economic philosophy, international integration proceeded apace in Eastern Europe. From a growth accounting perspective, the former Soviet Union’s pattern was similar to that of other parts of Europe, with productivity growth driving much of the postwar boom. The high rate of capital accumulation in the former Soviet Union’s postwar program did result in a large capital-deepening effect, though (Crafts and Toniolo 1996). Eastern Europe grew by different means: communism fueled an “extensive growthâ€? driven by more labor and capital instead of improved technology or efï¬?ciency. But multifactor productivity—crudely estimated since the data are deceptive—was lower in the communist countries than in any economy in Western Europe, even when compared with countries with similar per capita income levels, such as Ireland or Italy (Crafts and Toniolo 2008). 75 GOLDEN GROWTH 1974 to 1993: convergence in the north and south, collapse in the east Rapid postwar growth ground to a halt in the early 1970s. The slowdown was widespread and affected market and socialist economies alike. Growth rates across developed and developing economies were at least 2 percentage points lower from 1973 to 1990 than from 1950 to 1973 (table S1.1). The collapse of the Bretton Woods international monetary system and the ï¬?rst oil price shocks Figure S1.2: Decomposing the growth in worker productivity A. Big postwar increases in productivity, especially in the B. Productivity growth weakens across Europe, but outstrips south, percent, 1960–70 the United States, percent, 1970–90 Figure S1.3: Europeans work fewer hours C. Productivity growth drops below the United States, while Americans work more except in Northern Europe, percent, 1990–2003 (annual hours per worker, 1950–2009) * Data on human capital deepening are not available. Source: Conference Board 2011. Source: Crafts and Toniolo 1996 and 2008. 76 SPOTLIGHT ONE Figure S1.4: Convergence until the Figure S1.5: Big increases in productivity during the 1980s, divergence since transition, especially in the former Soviet Union (coefï¬?cient of variation of GDP per capita in Europe, (decomposition of labor productivity growth, 1950–2010, US$ 1990, Geary Khamis PPP estimates) percent a year, 1990–2006) Note: The aggregates illustrate the EC or EU membership for the identiï¬?ed Source: Iradian 2007. period regardless of whether that unit has been created or not. For example, the EU27 reflects data for Eastern European countries for 1950, though these countries did not join the European Union until 2004 or 2007. The aggregates reflect West Germany until 1988 when a uniï¬?ed Germany is added in its place. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Conference Board (2011). were associated with the interruption of the rapid trajectory of total factor productivity growth across Europe. Growth in the west fell from almost 5 percent in 1973 to 1.5 percent in 1974, and has yet to surpass 3.5 percent. The driver of the postwar boom—improved factor productivity—weakened across the region, along with capital accumulation and improvements in workers’ skills (ï¬?gure S1.2, panel B). Every country experienced declines in total factor productivity growth. Even so, from a longer historical perspective, growth in Western Europe was reasonably impressive, averaging 1.7 percent over a 20-year stretch. But convergence to U.S. income levels stopped. In 1982, Western Europe’s per capita income was about 77 percent of the United States’s. By 1990, it was 72 percent and by 1999, 69 percent. Although the United States also saw an interruption in growth that slowed productivity increases, it continued to accumulate capital and improve skills. Once again, Western Europe was falling behind the United States. The prospective cohesion countries were a bright spot. Since 1945, Southern Europe—the poorest part of noncommunist Europe—has consistently grown faster than the rest of Western Europe. The prospect of membership in the European Community generated incentives for structural reform. Southern Europe grew at an average annual rate of 2.3 percent, compared with less than 2 percent in Western Europe. Yet, even in the cohesion countries, growth dropped off steeply. 77 GOLDEN GROWTH The decline in Eastern European performance over this period was even steeper. Growth averaged just 0.8 percent in Eastern Europe and 0.9 percent in the former Soviet Union from 1974 until the end of central planning in 1990. During this period, the Soviet economy experienced an enormous decline in labor productivity, and total factor productivity growth may have even been negative over this period. Central planners ploughed back the earnings of large enterprises: investment-to-GDP ratio doubled from 1950 to 1970 while the capital stock grew 8.5 times. But the inefï¬?ciencies of heavy industrialization and forced capital accumulation became apparent by the 1970s (Crafts and Toniolo 2008). The collapse of central planning resulted in a free fall in output, and annual average compound growth from 1990 to 1993 was –3.5 percent in Eastern Europe and –6.5 percent in the former Soviet Union. Perhaps the simplest explanation for this decline across Europe is that the inputs for catch-up growth had been exhausted. As the technology gap between the United States and countries such as France and Germany narrowed, the low-hanging fruit of imported productivity gains was plucked. Southern and Northern European countries that were slower to integrate into the European economic system beneï¬?ted from productivity growth somewhat longer; they still had room to catch up to advanced Europe and the United States. It is also possible that the domestic and international institutions that so successfully supported rapid growth in Western and Southern Europe locked in a growth model that became progressively less suited to a changed global economy. The institutions that had underpinned extensive growth based on Figure S1.6: Productivity got a capital accumulation and imported American know-how were less suited to the big boost from ICT in the United intensive growth requirements of the period after the early 1970s (Eichengreen States, not so much in Europe and Vazquez 2000). (contributions to labor productivity growth, 1980–2005, percent per year) Source: van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer 2008. A. Labor productivity went up in the United B. Labor productivity fell in the EU15, States in the mid-1990s—and stayed high and ICT’s boost was small 78 SPOTLIGHT ONE Among these outdated institutions were the mechanisms that facilitated a wage restraint and reinvestment consensus. As the potential for catch-up growth was exhausted, the demands for higher wages increased amid heightened union activity. And investment slumped. Whether this regime could sustain the existing rate of productivity, much less develop into a dynamic innovation engine, was questioned. The United Kingdom’s relatively good performance during the 1970s and 1980s is sometimes attributed to the fact that it had not developed the same corporatist arrangements. The social market economy had started to show its weaknesses. It was good for countries catching up, but not for countries in the lead. It could take advantage of benign global conditions, but it would not adjust well to big changes in the world economy. A range of labor market practices that may have dampened growth accompanied the postwar settlement. Two seemingly contradictory developments are particularly noteworthy. The gap in per capita incomes between the United States and Europe increased, but Europe continued to close the gap in labor productivity. The combination of a persistent gap in GDP per capita and increasing output per hour worked reflected a decline in work: lower labor force participation rates and a drop in working hours. Over time, Europeans have worked fewer and fewer hours than Americans (ï¬?gure S1.3). In the 1950s, Western Europeans worked the equivalent of almost a month more than Americans. By the 1970s, they worked about the same amount. Today, Americans work an extra month compared with the Dutch, French, Germans, and Swedes, and work noticeably longer than less well-off Greeks, Hungarians, Poles, and Spaniards. Put differently, the ratio of hours worked per capita fell from 127 percent in the west and 131 percent in the south in 1950–73 to 91 percent and 97 percent by 1990–2009. The lower opportunity costs of unemployment in a social market economy, longer holidays, and lower female labor market participation may explain this. Or it may simply be that Europeans value leisure more than Americans—chapter 6 further investigates this (Blanchard 2004). But the effects of Europe’s declining work hours are clear: capital intensity increased as the slowing growth of labor led to a rise in real wages and a general substitution of capital for labor (van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer 2008). By the mid-1990s, many Western European countries had capital stocks per hour worked that were 10 percent higher than in the United States. When taken with the lower levels of multifactor productivity in Europe during this period, Europe’s seemingly superior labor productivity performance is worrying. Its cause may lie not in innovative enterprises but in labor market rigidities resulting from the postwar consensus (van Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer 2008). 1994 to 2009: convergence in the east The general decline in performance from the 1970s gave way to considerable diversity by the 1990s. Output in Europe began to vary from the early 1980s and continued to do so through the 1990s and early 2000s, particularly in the west and south (ï¬?gure S1.4). Between 1990 and 2009, Greece, Ireland, and the Netherlands experienced growth at or above 1989–2010 levels. By contrast, Denmark, Italy, and Switzerland experienced growth under 1.5 percent. 79 GOLDEN GROWTH For most of Western Europe, catch-up with the United States continued to slow between 1990 and 2009. The average gap in per capita output was almost unchanged from 1973 to 2008 and closed at a diminishing rate in Southern Europe. In most European countries, labor productivity was below the United States’s. Similarly, total factor productivity rates were lower in about three- quarters of European countries as European productivity continued to fall while the United States recovered. But again, the picture is varied. Denmark, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Norway, Sweden, and the United Kingdom had relatively rapid productivity growth during this period (ï¬?gure S1.2, panel C). In the newly independent countries of Eastern Europe, catch-up growth was based mainly on reallocating factors. After the massive collapse in output immediately after the end of central planning, Eastern Europe recorded faster GDP per capita growth than the rest of Europe and the United States. With the signing of the ï¬?rst EU Association Agreements in 1994 by Hungary and Poland, Eastern Europe began to integrate with the rest of Europe. This integration of markets and institutions propelled the convergence of east with west as Eastern Europe grew more than 4 percent from 1994 to 2008. Productivity growth reflected patterns from the Western and Southern European high-growth era and was driven by large total factor productivity gains, particularly in the Baltic Figure S1.7: Policy affects the pace and Figure S1.8: Information technology played composition of productivity growth a bigger role in Eastern Europe (sectoral contributions to labor productivity growth and (contribution of ICT to labor productivity growth, regulatory burden, 1995–2004, percent per year) 1995–2004, percent per year) Note: The “Reallocationâ€? identity reflects the effects of reallocations of Source: Alam and others 2008; Timmer, O’Mahony, and van Ark labor among sectors. The underlying Employment Protection Index was 2007. transformed so that it ranges from 0 to 1, where higher values reflect higher levels of protection. The Product Market Regulation Index ranges from 0 to 10, where lower values reflect higher levels of regulation. Source: Timmer, O’Mahony, and van Ark 2007 (for productivity data); Crafts 2006 (for Employment Protection Index); and Conway, Janod, and Nicoletti 2005 (for Product Market Regulation Index). 80 SPOTLIGHT ONE economies (ï¬?gure S1.5). The overindustrialization of the centrally planned economies had led to massive misallocations of labor, particularly in industry. The posttransition shift in workers from manufacturing to market services, small in the Soviet era, was major. From 1990 to 2005, the share of services in employment grew 16 percentage points in Eastern Europe and 9 percentage points in the former Soviet Union (Alam and others 2008). Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union also beneï¬?ted from some of the same gains from integration as Western Europe. Expanded trade and ï¬?nancial links between east and west anchored reforms at home, provided access to service and merchandise trade markets, and loosened the link between domestic savings and investment through capital flows. The United States’s ability to again outpace Europe in productivity growth reflected Europe’s inability to adapt to structural changes in the global economy. Productivity growth in services and industry required information technology. In the mid-1990s, innovations in information and communication technology (ICT) produced a highly productive and capital-deepening sector with large positive externalities for improving productivity across the economy. Labor productivity growth shot up in the United States from 1980–95 to 1995–2000. Productivity enhancements in the ICT sectors and large gains in capital deepening were not the only beneï¬?t—multifactor productivity in other sectors also grew. These spillover effects continued to drive total factor productivity growth in the United States during the early 2000s when the initial burst of ICT-speciï¬?c contributions to labor productivity began to diminish. By contrast, Western Europe’s labor productivity fell steadily during this period, with considerably smaller share contributions from ICT. By the early 2000s, Western Europe faced almost no measured productivity growth (ï¬?gure S1.6). What explains the reemergence of the productivity gap between the United States and Europe? And why did new information technologies’ power grow in North America but not in Europe? The components of the postwar 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 Figure S1.9: Growth has been greater in Europe’s southern states 600 (growth in real GDP per capita, 400 1945–2008, 1945=100) 200 Note: Western European aggregate reflects a 0 population-weighted average. Source: Maddison 1996; Conference Board 2011. 81 GOLDEN GROWTH Notes European model that led to higher employment protection probably prevented the development and exploitation of new technology. Higher employment 1 There are numerous studies protection correlates with lower overall productivity growth and ICT deepening that employ growth accounting approaches to understanding (ï¬?gure S1.7).4 Employment protections may deter investment in ICT equipment the components of economic because practices central to developing this technology—such as flexible growth in post war Europe. Some landmark studies include Denison working and hiring practices—are more expensive (Gust and Marquez 2004). (1967) and Maddison (1987). The higher-performing Western European economies that regulated their 2 In this picture, human capital formation plays only a small role labor markets more lightly (Finland and the United Kingdom) generated large and it is not clear whether this ICT-related productivity gains. In Finland, these effects were even larger than reflects the tendency of growth accounting to underestimate those in the United States. Likewise, heavy-handed general product regulation human capital or whether the may deter ICT capital investment, either directly or through a more general already high-quality human increase in costs.5 Some of the Eastern European countries without the legacy capital that persisted in Europe at the start of this period left little of the Western European model were able to start from scratch and better room for further contribution exploit ICT (ï¬?gure S1.8). Prospective EU member states should take note. to productivity. See Crafts and Toniolo (1996). Afterglow 3 Eichengreen (1994) makes the case for the domestic and international institutional underpinning of postwar growth. The nexus of political institutions and market practices that developed in 4 In a model ï¬?t with ordinary least Europe after World War II lifted the continent to the heights of global prosperity. squares: OVERALL PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH = 3.1 – 2.6 EMPLOYMENT European integration not only headed off conflict, but also anchored trade and PROTECTION INDEX (t = –2.0), factor liberalization that bound Europe and brought the world together. Modern where higher values on the Europe’s most attractive feature may be the prospects it offers poorer countries. employment protection index reflect higher levels of protection. The European economic model has served as a “convergence machine,â€? taking 5 In a model ï¬?t with ordinary least in low- and middle-income countries and helping them become high-income squares: OVERALL PRODUCTIVITY countries. The machine can even count the currently troubled EU15 southern GROWTH = 4.7 – 1.2 PRODUCT MARKET REGULATION INDEX states among its successes (ï¬?gure S1.9). (t = –2.4), where higher values on the regulation index reflect more The European convergence machine continues to anchor productivity-enhancing stringent regulation. reforms and policy integration across Europe and even into Central Asia. But 6 The term “afterglowâ€? is here this machine cannot continue to deliver rapid growth and improved quality adapted from some political science literature to refer to of life in the advanced economies of Western Europe. European policymakers institutions and obligations that have assembled protocols and commitments to encourage more innovation and governments continue to support dynamism. Yet, the policies at the center of Europe’s postwar growth model are even after such policies may no longer appear rational. For other not flexible enough for European economies to beneï¬?t from the technologies applications of the term and that supported high productivity growth in the rest of the world over the last concept see Lake (1993). 15 years. As Crafts and Toniolo (2008) note, the problem is not that European product market regulation and employment protections became more stringent, they just became more costly. The Western European model so effective in supporting catch-up has created “afterglowâ€? institutions that are hindering growth in a new era.6 In areas aspiring to become part of the machine—notably the Balkan states and the eastern partnership countries—Europe’s afterglow structures will probably not preclude the many beneï¬?ts of greater economic union. And as ties to advanced Europe become stronger and more sophisticated, the afterglow structures may not prevent productivity gains in the new member states. By contrast, these legacy structures must quickly become more flexible in Western Europe. Convergence to a rigid core will soon lose its appeal. Bryce Quillin contributed this spotlight. 82 REFERENCES References Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Eichengreen, B., and P. Vazquez. 2000. Ahead, and Falling Behind.â€? The Journal of “Institutions and Economic Growth Economic History 46 (2): 385–406. in Postwar Europe: Evidence and Alam, A., P. Anós Casero, F. Khan, and C. Conjectures.â€? In Productivity, Technology Udomsaph. 2008. Unleashing Prosperity: and Economic Growth, ed. B. van Ark, S. Productivity Growth in Eastern Europe and Kuipers, and G. Kuper: 91–128. Boston, MA: the Former Soviet Union. Washington, DC: Kluwer Academic Publishers. World Bank. Gust, C., and J. Marquez. 2004. Blanchard, O. 2004. “The Economic Future “International Comparisons of Productivity of Europe.â€? The Journal of Economic Growth: The Role of Information Perspectives 18 (4): 3–26. Technology and Regulatory Practices.â€? Labour Economics 11 (1): 33–58. Conference Board, The. 2011. “Total Economy Database.â€? January 2011, The Iradian, G. 2007. “Rapid Growth in Conference Board, New York, NY. Available Transition Economies: Growth-Accounting at www.conference-board.org/data/ Approach.â€? IMF Working Paper 07/164, IMF, economydatabase. Accessed September 3, Washington, DC. 2011. Lake, D. 1993. “Leadership, Hegemony, and Conway, P., V. Janod, and G. Nicoletti. the International Economy: Naked Emperor 2005. “Product Market Regulation in OECD or Tattered Monarch with Potential?â€? Countries: 1998 to 2003.â€? OECD Economics International Studies Quarterly 37 (4): Department Working Paper 419, OECD, 459–489. Paris. Maddison, A. 1987. “Growth and Slowdown Crafts, N. 2006. “Regulation and in Advanced Capitalist Economies: Productivity Performance.â€? Oxford Review Techniques of Quantitative Assessment.â€? of Economic Policy 22 (2): 186–202. Journal of Economic Literature 25 (2): 649–698. Crafts, N., and G. Toniolo. 1996. “Postwar Growth: An Overview.â€? In Economic Growth Maddison, A. 1996. “Macroeconomic in Europe since 1945, ed. N. Crafts, and G. Accounts for European Countries.â€? In Toniolo: 1–37. New York, NY: Cambridge Quantitative Aspects of Post-War European University Press. Economic Growth, ed. B. van Ark, and N. Crafts: 27–83. New York, NY: Cambridge Crafts, N., and G. Toniolo. 2008. “European University Press. Economic Growth, 1950–2005: An Overview.â€? CEPR Discussion Paper 6863, Timmer, M., M. O’Mahony, and B. van Ark. Centre for Economic Policy Research, 2007. “EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity London. Accounts: An Overview.â€? International Productivity Monitor 14 (Spring): 71–85. De Long, J., and B. Eichengreen. 1993. “The Marshall Plan: History’s Most Successful van Ark, B., M. O’Mahony, and M. Timmer. Structural Adjustment Program.â€? In Postwar 2008. “The Productivity Gap between Economic Reconstruction and Lessons Europe and the United States: Trends for the East Today, ed. R. Dornbusch, W. and Causes.â€? The Journal of Economic Nölling, and R. Layard: 189–230. Cambridge, Perspectives 22 (1): 25–44. MA: MIT Press. Denison, E. 1967. Why Growth Rates Differ: Postwar Experience in Nine Western Countries. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Eichengreen, B. 1994. “Institutional Prerequisites for Economic Growth: Europe after World War II.â€? European Economic Review 38 (3–4): 883–890. Eichengreen, B. 2007. The European Economy since 1945: Coordinated Capitalism and Beyond. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 83 GOLDEN GROWTH 84 CHAPTER 2 Trade and Finance Chapters 2 and 3 focus on the recent experience of the European Union’s 12 new member states, the 8 candidate countries, and the 6 economies of the eastern partnership. Focusing on the 26 economies of Central, Southeastern, and Eastern Europe while assessing the trade and ï¬?nance components of the European growth model is a deliberate choice: trade and ï¬?nancial flows are the main conduits for convergence. Advanced and developing countries are now connected through trade and capital flows everywhere in the world, but nowhere as closely as in Europe. Their experiences illustrate the model’s strongest aspects: just as people who become Americans can attain the highest incomes in the world, countries that become European quickly reach the highest standards of living. Trade is the principal channel through which prosperity is transmitted from the developed economies of Europe to the nearby emerging markets. Chapter 2 looks in turn at the trade in industrial goods, services, and agricultural goods and assesses how Europe has done. It identiï¬?es the policy reforms that can facilitate wider and deeper integration. As a region that generated almost half of global trade in 2008, Europe should be seen as the world’s trade hub, and admired for its openness. But Europeans are dissatisï¬?ed with the slow growth of trade in modern services such as Internet sales, and perhaps justiï¬?ably so. Actually, in one modern service—cross-border banking—Europe does rather well. Financial flows are often faulted for being too large, not too small. They are also seen as adding too much to economic vulnerabilities and not enough to economic growth. But chapter 3 shows that during the decade leading up to the global ï¬?nancial crisis, capital flows from Western Europe to the east helped more countries than they hurt. Analysts who expected during the crisis that foreign banks would head for the exits found that they were wrong—in Europe, capital does not behave as it has in the emerging markets of Latin America and East Asia. Western banks have neither fled, nor left the ï¬?rms and households in emerging Europe mired in debt. But the variety of experiences— captured in written contributions by central bankers from Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Poland, Romania, and Turkey—has left behind valuable lessons for how private ï¬?nance might be “bust-proofedâ€? and public ï¬?nance “boom-proofed.â€? Chapter 3 concludes that if these capital flows are managed well, Europe’s emerging economies do not have to “become Asian,â€? in terms of having to stockpile foreign reserves as the price of proï¬?tably participating in global ï¬?nancial markets. 85 GOLDEN GROWTH 86 CHAPTER 2 Chapter 2 Trade Å koda Auto used to be the butt of jokes in the 1980s: Why do Å kodas have rear- window heating? So your hands do not freeze while pushing them. In 1989, the company sold about 150,000 cars in the former Czechoslovakia, despite having a monopoly. In 1991, Volkswagen AG bought a 30 percent stake in Å koda Auto, and by 2000 it had taken over the company. The subsidiary initially made the simpler parts that VW required for its cheaper cars. Å koda now makes more complicated transmissions and even engines for its parent. But it still makes its own cars—more than 750,000 of them in 2010—in plants at home in the Czech Republic and in the Slovak Republic, Ukraine, the Russian Federation, and India. Å koda tops consumer satisfaction surveys in the United Kingdom and India, beating Ford, Honda, and Toyota and inspiring loyalty instead of derision. And the company made almost $2 billion in proï¬?ts for Volkswagen last year. Å koda’s success is symbolic of the progress in the manufacturing trade in Central and Southeastern Europe. German, Swedish, Swiss, French, and other manufacturers have been offshoring production, increasing the productivity of subsidiaries in emerging Europe and the proï¬?tability of their parents. Romania’s Dacia is doing the same for Renault. Italy’s Fiat has found it proï¬?table to look east too: it now owns two-thirds of Serbia’s Zastava Automobiles—known for producing the joked-about Yugo—and produces bestselling minivans in collaboration with TOFAS in Turkey. Asea Brown Boveri, the Swiss-Swedish engineering giant, produces electrical equipment in many plants in emerging Europe stretching from the Czech Republic to Russia, from Latvia to Croatia. Back-and-forth trade in parts and components is part of an increasingly sophisticated “Factory Europeâ€? that extends beyond the enlarged European Union to include Turkey, the former Yugoslavia, Ukraine, Belarus, and Russia. Is “Factory Europeâ€? as dynamic as “Factory Asiaâ€?? Is the Single Market for Services underachieving compared with the United States? Is the Common Agricultural Policy compromising Europe’s global leadership? 87 GOLDEN GROWTH But manufactured goods are no more than a quarter of Europe’s $16 trillion economic output. More than 70 percent of GDP—or almost $11.5 trillion—consists of services: wholesale and retail trade, tourism, construction, transport, communications, modern business services, and ï¬?nance. Europe’s annual trade in services—counting both cross-border services trade and foreign sales of afï¬?liates of multinational companies—is about $4 trillion. European policymakers view the vibrant U.S. market for services—coincidentally also valued at about $11.5 trillion—as the benchmark, and perceive the single market as falling short. Many of these services are inputs to the production of other goods and services. Some reduce the distance and time between producers and consumers and between suppliers and buyers; think of transportation, ï¬?nance, and communication. Others are direct inputs required for production and marketing—such as accounting, legal, and engineering services. Their quality affects productivity economywide. So trade and liberalization of services increase overall productivity. By allowing foreigners into communications, transportation, and banking, for example, the Czech Republic made these services more reliable, and improved the performance of “downstreamâ€? manufacturing sectors. European policymakers expect their economies to gain a lot through integration in services. Some of these services are traditional and difï¬?cult to trade without face-to- face contact; think of hotels, restaurants, and supermarkets. Europe actually does a brisk trade in these services. France, Spain, Italy, the United Kingdom, and Germany are among the top destinations for tourists, for example, and Sweden’s Ikea and the French Carrefour are global brands. Air transport has improved, and so have passenger trains, but international road and rail freight is inefï¬?cient. What vexes Europeans most, though, are what Baumol (1986) called “modern, progressive, and impersonalâ€? services—those that can be traded over longer distances—in which the Americans and Asians are doing so well. Asia and North America are seeing a burgeoning trade in “digital servicesâ€? such as Internet sales and IT support, and Europe is lagging. But in one part of the modern services trade—cross-border banking services— Europe may be doing better than any other part of the world. Banking is quickly becoming integrated into a single market in the European Union and even in the candidate countries. European banks have branches or subsidiaries overseas, and many are doing such a busy retail and wholesale trade in emerging Europe that some observers are worried about capital flows being excessive. This report is optimistic about banking in Europe, and chapter 3 elaborates. In other modern services—especially those that involve new information technologies such as the Internet—Europe is underachieving. A recent HM Government (2011) document notes: “Only 12 per cent of EU online trade is cross-border. Consumers in one part of the EU are often prevented from buying digital content from another. EU citizens can only access iTunes in 15 Member States and Spotify in seven. The beneï¬?ts [EU citizens] have shared by freeing up the airline industry have yet to be realised on the railways or in other forms of transport. These are just a few examples—there are many moreâ€? (p. 4). 88 CHAPTER 2 Another example is the rapidly growing e-book trade. Almost a third of all book sales—by value, not volume—are now electronic, and are increasingly read on media tablets such as Apple’s iPad and Amazon’s Kindle. Sales of media tablets are projected to exceed $50 million in 2011. In the United States, e-books are now outselling hardcover publications. But e-book sales are anemic in Europe, because regulations make it difï¬?cult to sell books Europe-wide. The story is often similar in other services. In transportation and communications, in engineering and accounting, in architectural and legal services, and in health and education, Europe’s services trade is segmented. To compare multicultural and multilingual Europe with the U.S. single market is unreasonable, but regulatory heterogeneity in Europe is excessive. ITunes users would think it is unreasonable. The third aspect of Europe’s trade that is often viewed by economists as less than satisfactory is that of agricultural goods. The sizable subsidies and other aspects of the Common Agricultural Policy have been criticized as helping neither equity nor efï¬?ciency in European and international agricultural markets. This chapter asks and answers the question: Is Europe taking advantage of economic enlargement? The short answer is that it is for manufacturing, somewhat less for services, and least for agriculture. Europe’s biggest success is the increasingly more sophisticated trade in goods spurred by a relocation of economic activity toward the new member states and EU candidate countries. In assessing trade as a principal component of Europe’s growth model, this chapter tries to answer three questions: · Is Factory Asia outcompeting Factory Europe? While Factory Asia is growing more quickly in size, the goods trade in Europe is becoming more sophisticated than in East Asia. Western Europe is not just giving the new member states of the European Union and other neighbors such as Serbia and Turkey a bigger share of its tasks, it is also giving them tougher things to do. The eastward expansion of Factory Europe is straining logistics—especially information and communications infrastructure—and it could grow even faster and further if this were ï¬?xed. · Does the Single Market for Services work as well as it should? While it is impossible to generalize for activities that add up to two-thirds of European GDP, the short answer is that it does not. Travel is well developed but transportation is not; the market for ï¬?nancial services is quite efï¬?cient, but other business services—especially those involving modern information technologies like the Internet—are not. For trade in nonï¬?nancial modern services, the solution lies not in trade facilitation but in better and more harmonized regulation of enterprises and improved labor mobility, issues taken up again in chapters 4 and 6, respectively. · Is the Common Agricultural Policy harming Europe? The brief answer is that it is, but not in ways commonly talked about. At about 33 eurocents per person a day, the ï¬?nancial cost of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) is small. But the subsidies go mostly to well-off farmers in richer France, Italy, and Germany. Despite Europe’s position as the largest importer of agricultural goods from the poor countries in Africa, the CAP may also result 89 GOLDEN GROWTH in Europe ceding the moral high ground to emerging economies in global trade talks. But Europe mostly pays for its agricultural trade policies not with the approximately $75 billion a year distributed for agriculture and rural development by the European Commission, but through missed opportunities for closer regional integration with eastern partnership countries, where more than a third of all workers still depend on agriculture for a living. These weaknesses notwithstanding, the overall assessment of European trade has to be a positive one. In 2009, Europe’s merchandise trade was worth $4.5 trillion, more than Asia’s and North America’s combined. Based on balance of payments accounts, its cross-border trade in services was worth $2.25 trillion, more than for the rest of the world combined. Trade between advanced and emerging Europe is growing bigger and noticeably more sophisticated every year, aiding quick convergence in productive capacity and living standards, and helping to create a bigger and stronger economic union. Trade is the mainstay of the European economic model, and its most attractive attribute. Europe: the world’s trade center With increasing frequency, Europe is portrayed in the press as a sluggish part of the world. When it comes to international trade, it is actually the busiest. In 2005, and even in 2009, Europe’s merchandise trade dwarfed North America’s and Asia’s. Nearly 45 percent of the world’s $10 trillion merchandise trade begins or ends up in Europe (ï¬?gure 2.1). Two-thirds of this trade is among European economies, making its regional trade the biggest in the world. This has not come at the cost of global trade relations. Europe also has thick trade ties with every other part of the world, importing more manufactured goods from Asia than the United States, and trading more with Africa than Asia or North America. Europe also imports and exports more farm products from poor countries than any other developed region. For services, Europe is again the global leader in trade. The data are difï¬?cult to come by and the magnitudes differ a lot depending on whether balance of payments information only is used, or the services trade is also imputed from reports by foreign afï¬?liates of companies. Based on balance of payments statistics, the value of cross-border services exports of the European Union and candidate countries was just under $2 trillion in 2007, and about $2.25 trillion in 2009. The value of the services trade rises further if the sales of services by foreign afï¬?liates of multinational ï¬?rms are added. For the European Union, the value of these sales was more than $2 trillion in 2008. So, total European services trade is worth around $4 trillion. According to the Trade in Services database, the EU15 accounted for one-third of global cross-border exports; the U.S. share was 13 percent (Francois, Pindyuk and Woerz 2009). The EU15 was also the biggest importer of cross-border services, with more than one-third of global trade. Europe’s services trade is more than half of the global trade in services, and more than half of this trade in services is within the European Union’s single market. But it is also clear that there is a lot less regional trade in services than in goods—the ratio between intra-EU and extra-EU exports for services was 1.3 90 CHAPTER 2 while the ratio for goods trade was 2.1 in 2008 (ï¬?gure 2.2). Western Europe is the largest contributor to the European Union’s exports in services, with more than 70 percent of total cross-border exports and some 95 percent of total sales by foreign afï¬?liates. Western Europe trades relatively more with economies outside the European Union, while Southern Europe and the new member states trade more within. Through the goods trade and direct investment, enterprises in the EU15 countries have become globally competitive. Although Asia is catching up, Europe is the world’s trade leader in industrial merchandise. Trade facilitation measures can increase the size and sophistication of this trade and increase the productivity in manufacturing in both advanced and emerging Europe. But Europe has yet to exploit such synergies in modern services. More trade in services will help increase productivity in an even bigger part of the European economy. Regulatory reform could increase services trade in the single market by multiples of the current $4 trillion. And the European Union could do a lot more to encourage the regional trade in agricultural produce with the eastern partnership. The next three sections of this chapter take up each of these three components of trade in turn. Figure 2.1: Europe has the world’s busiest goods trade (world merchandise trade, US$ billions, 2008) Source: World Bank staff using WTO 2009a. 91 GOLDEN GROWTH Factory Europe—a little bigger, a lot smarter A few years ago, Baldwin (2008) noted the rise of “Factory Asiaâ€?: “Like some gigantic, impossibly complex and wonderfully efï¬?cient factory, the region churns out millions of different products … by sourcing billions of different parts and components from plants spread across a dozen nations.â€? The Barbie doll, which is assembled in China and consists of pieces from many Asian countries, has been used to highlight the large and increasing fragmentation of production across borders in the region (Tempest 1996). Other products include cars, computers, and mobile phones (Gill and Kharas 2007). Such examples are no longer unique to Asia, if they ever were. Siemens has organized its activities in a global value chain, which includes engineering in Western Europe and assembly in Eastern Europe (Marin 2010b). Å koda in the Czech Republic makes high-tech components—including transmissions and engines—for Volkswagen (box 2.1). The production line for the Porsche Cayenne ends in Leipzig, Germany, but stretches out to the Slovak Republic (Watson 2010). This fragmentation is indicative of greater efï¬?ciency in production and trade, and is a source of productivity growth in both advanced and emerging Europe. Intermediates trade is likely to be especially helpful. Productivity growth in ï¬?rms is facilitated by access to cheaper or greater varieties of inputs. Being a part of a production chain catalyzes cooperation in technology and knowledge- transfer more than might be the case for trade in ï¬?nal products (Grossman and Helpman 1991; Dixit and Stiglitz 1977; Romer 1990; Frankel and Romer 1999). And the expansion of the European Union may affect patterns of intermediates trade to a greater extent than standard trade. This section takes the reader on a brief tour of Factory Europe. First, it looks at trade in ï¬?nished products. The European Union’s new member states have rapidly increased their trade both with the European Union and with the rest of the world. Indeed, while the EU15’s share of total trade with the new member Figure 2.2: The European Union does a brisk trade in services (cross-border service exports and sales of foreign afï¬?liates, current $ trillions, 2004 and 2008) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 92 CHAPTER 2 Box 2.1: Volkswagen and Å koda Intra-ï¬?rm trade with Eastern European monopoly in communist Czechoslovakia. The a cutting-edge 1.2TSI petrol forced-induction afï¬?liates is estimated to have helped German cars inspired jokes and derision. By 2007, its engine, the product of collaborative R&D, that ï¬?rms increase productivity by more than annual sales were up to 630,000, with plants could produce 77 KW. VW used to fear the loss 20 percent, and German offshoring within in places as far away as India, and cars that of intellectual property, limiting willingness Europe has raised the productivity of the had started to inspire loyalty. Before the global to share technology and know-how. But the subsidiaries almost threefold compared with crisis, its plans were to increase sales to more 1.2TSI is an example of how this has clearly that of local ï¬?rms. More imported inputs have than a million. Its rapid growth had made it an changed. raised ï¬?rm productivity in Hungary, driven to important part of VW’s strategy to outdo GM The Czech auto industry includes a broad and a large extent by access to increased variety and Toyota for global market share. complex supplier network within its borders. or complexity of inputs—not just volumes. Å koda has its own cars but also makes The simple parts of the production process Reductions in intra-ï¬?rm tariffs and input components for VW. Starting with the basics, shifted east 10 years ago and have continued tariffs associated with EU enlargement has VW helped Å koda transition into a market to move further east. The Czech Republic helped the offshoring relationship between economy. VW allowed Å koda to benchmark and the Slovak Republic have increased their German or Austrian ï¬?rms and their Eastern its production practices against those of presence in higher value-added activities that European afï¬?liates by raising their total factor plants in Germany. The quality of Å koda’s own are more complex technically. productivity. cars has improved, overcoming a reputation The relationship between Germany’s for bad quality, and some components are Volkswagen and the Czech Republic’s Å koda now shared in Å koda and VW cars. Å koda Source: Marin 2010a; Hansen 2010; Halpern, provides an inspiring example. Volkswagen now makes high-tech components for VW Koren, and Szeidl 2011; Ledgard 2005; Å koda (VW) acquired Å koda in 1991, and took over automobiles, including transmissions and Auto 2010; Watson 2010; Volkswagen 2009. its management 10 years later. In 1990, Å koda engines. One example is the Mlada Boleslav For a discussion of the car industry in Europe, sold 170,000 cars despite having enjoyed a engine plant. In 2009, the plant started making see Rhys 2004. states has increased, trade of the new members outside the EU15 grew even faster than their trade with the EU15, and so the relative importance of the EU15 has declined. The EU candidate countries seem to be following the same pattern with a lag of a few years. A typical example is the trade in motor vehicles, accounting for almost one-ï¬?fth of all exports by new member states. EU enlargement has created new markets for advanced economies in Europe and helped emerging Europe become more competitive, not just in Europe but worldwide. Germany is not the ï¬?nal assembly point for inputs imported from the east—in fact, both German (and Austrian, Belgian, Dutch, French, and Scandinavian) companies and their eastern subsidiaries are exporting successfully along a differentiated product range. This pattern is distinct from the role Japan and now China play in Asia (box 2.2). Second, an examination of intermediates trade shows that Factory Europe is not as large as Factory Asia, but it is becoming smarter more quickly. Trade in intermediates is a smaller proportion of total trade within Europe than within Asia. EU enlargement has led to a rapid increase in intermediates trade with the new member states, although once again, new members have increased their trade with non-EU partners even faster. Most important, however, intermediates trade within the enlarged European Union has become a lot more sophisticated and complex, at the same time as the sophistication and complexity of the EU15’s trade with the rest of the world has stagnated. EU enlargement has had a limited effect on the size of Factory Europe, but it has influenced its complexity. Factory Europe is becoming a bit bigger, but a lot more brainy. 93 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 2.2: Germany is not Europe’s China Gill and Kharas (2007) and others have goods to the rest of the world, including the trade deï¬?cits with the region and the rest of documented an interesting asymmetry European Union and United States, running a the world while Germany has trade surpluses in intra-Asian trade. They show that trade surplus with the rest of the world. The with both the region and the rest of the world. intermediates tend to be imported by question naturally arises whether the world’s Prima facie, there is no evidence of a large China from the rest of the region—from second-largest trader—Germany—has a similar economy in Europe playing the role that Japan Southeast Asia and from Japan and the newly relationship in Europe. once played in Asia, and that China is now industrialized economies in Northeast Asia—so Information on trade balances (including playing. that China runs a sizable trade deï¬?cit within intermediates) was analyzed in search of a the region. In turn, China exports ï¬?nished European analog. The new members have Source: Gill and Kharas 2007. The goods trade has grown most in the East Trade-to-GDP ratios have increased worldwide and Europe is no exception. For the EU15, the ratio rose from 45 to 54 percent from the late 1990s to the late 2000s. For the 2004 members, the ratio rose from 63 to 94 percent. For the 2007 entrants and potential members, the change was smaller, rising from 43 to 52 percent (box 2.3 explains the regional grouping used in this section). Trade within the EU27 also rose: the export-to-GDP ratio increased from 15 to 19 percent. But this masks an asymmetry within the union. Exports from the EU15 to the new member states as a share of total exports doubled over the period, reflecting how the 2004 members became increasingly important for advanced Europe (ï¬?gure 2.3). By contrast, the importance of Western Europe for the new members declined. The large and proximate markets to their west are still important destinations and sources of goods but—due in part to relatively slow GDP growth—the importance of those markets has been falling since 2000. The composition of the goods trade has changed too. For the 2004 members, machinery and transport equipment comprise more than a third of imports and almost half of exports (ï¬?gure 2.4). The proportion has risen, but the data indicate a shift away from the EU15 as a source of this product category. The patterns of Figure 2.3: The European Union’s new members are more important partners for the EU15, the EU15 less for the new (shares of regional trade for EU15 and EU10, 1996–2008) Note: The EU10 includes new member states joined the EU in 2004, except Cyprus and Malta. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. 94 CHAPTER 2 Box 2.3: Scope of the goods trade data This chapter considers trade in the European data; the Western Balkans (Albania, Bosnia BEC nomenclature is used unless stated Union’s 27 member states and the accession and Herzegovina, Croatia, the former Yugoslav otherwise, grouping products into countries, broadly deï¬?ned to include Ukraine. Republic of Macedonia, and Serbia—all at consumption, capital, and intermediate goods Of the European Union’s new members, the various stages of accession); Turkey (which has (Miroudot, Lanz, and Ragoussis 2009). Goods data are best suited for 8 of the 10 countries a customs union with the European Union and are classiï¬?ed according to “expert judgmentâ€? that joined the European Union in 2004. These is an ofï¬?cial accession candidate); and Ukraine and may not fall neatly into one category. countries are Czech Republic, the Slovak (even though it has neither). This is a diverse For example, it is not obvious whether fruits Republic, Slovenia, Hungary, Poland, Latvia, group, so it is sometimes necessary to look should be classiï¬?ed as consumption or Lithuania, and Estonia. This is mainly because at subgroups or individual countries within intermediate goods. But this approach has the data coincide with their accession years this category. Data going back to 1996 are the advantage of covering a wide spectrum (since the mid-1990s) and formal membership. used when available for the 2004 members of goods trade. In contrast, studies identifying The group is called “EU10,â€? “new members,â€? or potential members, except for Bosnia and parts or components can only reliably do so “2004 members,â€? or the “new member states.â€? Herzegovina, which started reporting in 2003. for a subset of sectors (for example, Kaminski For comparison, the nine Asian countries in and Ng 2005; and Kimura, Takahashi, and The group known as the “potential membersâ€? Kimura, Takahashi, and Hayakawa (2007) Hayakawa 2007). or accession countries includes Bulgaria and are considered to be China, Hong Kong SAR Romania because they joined only in 2007, (China), Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Philippines, close to the end of the period of available the Republic of Korea, Singapore, and Thailand. Source: Behar and Freund 2011. trade in machinery and transport are thus illustrative of the general pattern: EU15 trade has shifted eastward, while the new members’ trade has become global. Interestingly, the pattern seems to repeat itself in the EU candidate countries. The share of machinery and transport equipment in exports from the 2004 entrants rose from 30 to 50 percent between 1995 and 2002, and then stopped growing. But these exports are still growing fast in Romania, Bulgaria, Turkey, and the other countries in the Balkans—from a share in total exports of about 10 percent in 1995 to 30 percent by 2008. The fastest-growing subcomponent of machinery and transport equipment trade includes cars and other road vehicles. For the new members who joined in 2004, the proportion of motor vehicles in total exports continued rising even after overall machinery export growth flattened out and reached almost Figure 2.4: Machinery and transport equipment are half of the exports of new member states (sector shares of 2004 entrants’ trade, 1996–98 and 2006–08) Note: The category of agriculture and raw materials includes products with codes 0–4 in Standard International Trade Classiï¬?cation (SITC), Revision 2. Period averages for the years 1996–98 and 2006–08 are shown. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. 95 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 2.5: Automobiles are a big part of the goods trade in Europe (share of road vehicles in exports of emerging Europe, 1996–2008) Note: Passenger cars (code 51 in Broad Economic Categories (BEC) classiï¬?cation) are shown. In the right panel, data for “potential membersâ€? are linearly interpolated between 1999 and 2005. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. 20 percent, the highest ratio in the world. For the 2007 members and the EU candidate countries, the increase in the share of motor vehicle exports is even faster (ï¬?gure 2.5). Candidate countries have seen a large rise in both exports and imports, mainly because of Turkey.1 EU enlargement and integration may be helping Europe’s carmakers maintain global competitiveness in the same way as Factory Asia helped Japan’s and the Republic of Korea’s. The parallel patterns in the new member states and EU candidate countries illustrate a more general point: enlargement is a process and its economic impact is felt long before the ï¬?nal accession act is signed (box 2.4). Trade liberalization is usually a precursor to enlargement. Turkey even joined a customs union with the European Union in 2005. For the eastern partnership countries, deep and comprehensive free trade agreements are negotiated as a key step toward closer integration. In the new member states and in the candidate countries, the prospect of membership has often catalyzed a ï¬?rst round of deep structural reforms, which in turn have attracted foreign investment and facilitated deeper trade integration. Trade in intermediate goods has grown more One way to compare Factory Europe with Factory Asia is to look at regional trade in intermediates. This matters because intermediates trade may be a particularly potent source of economic growth. Productivity within a ï¬?rm is increased by improved access to inputs that are cheaper or more plentiful, of higher quality, and greater in variety, as well as through the technology and knowledge they embody (Grossman and Helpman 1991; Dixit and Stiglitz 1977; Feenstra, Markusen, and Zeile 1992). International trade can provide more or cheaper inputs, or these inputs may embody a higher level of technology than locally available ones. When they are part of a supply chain, relationships between producers and consumers of intermediates are likely to be closer. So there are more opportunities for transfers of better production methods and other know-how than is the case for consumption goods. One should expect a link between fragmentation—manifest in trade in intermediates—and productivity growth. 96 CHAPTER 2 The proportion of the EU27’s output traded across borders as intermediates increased, but Asia overtook it in 2004 (ï¬?gure 2.6, left panel).2 Emerging Europe experienced a rapid increase, including with non-EU trade partners. For the 2004 members, for example, the share of intermediates trade in GDP rose from 15 to almost 25 percent. At 21 percent, Asia’s ratio is lower despite having doubled since 1995. Factory Asia has been growing fast. In Factory Europe, mostly the eastern wing has been growing. The share of intermediates in total trade in Europe is no higher than in the late 1990s. Asia has seen a steady increase (ï¬?gure 2.6, right panel). This is true for trade within the region as well as trade with the rest of the world. The share of intermediates within EU27 exports to the world has stayed at about 50 percent, while import shares have risen marginally from 55 to 57 percent. Asia’s share in worldwide intermediates exports fell marginally to 50 percent, but its import shares rose from 64 to 73 percent. In Europe, the shares of intermediates inputs in exports and imports have been roughly constant, at about 50–55 percent for the EU15, 55–60 percent for the 2004 entrants to the European Union, and 60–65 percent for the 2007 entrants and the EU candidate countries. These numbers suggest that—outside Asia—the increases in fragmentation may be more modest than popularly believed.3 The aggregate patterns presented mask asymmetries and geographical shifts. The new members form an increasingly important market for EU15 intermediate products (ï¬?gure 2.7). The EU15 is sourcing more of its intermediates from the new members, but there was a slowdown since the early 2000s. The importance of the EU15 as a source of imports for the new members is falling: the new members now import less than half of their intermediates from the EU15. Box 2.4: EU integration is a process The recent expansion of the European Union Association agreements. Trade In 1998, the Ukraine–European Union eastward is formally marked by the addition agreements are nested in association partnership and cooperation agreement of 10 members in 2004 and the further agreements, which are typically aimed at was signed, though association agreement addition of 2 members in 2007. But formal aligning legislation with the European Union negotiations are still under way. In 2000, enlargement comes toward the end of a longer and recognizing intellectual property rights. the prospects of joining the European Union integration and harmonization process. Many For the Balkans, for example, this comes as were mooted for Balkan countries in Zagreb, concrete measures are taken well before the part of a stabilization and association process. including any intention to sign stabilization accession year. These come through two main Tellingly, an objective is “to encourage the and association agreements. In 2004, the mechanisms, which are often negotiated and countries of the region to behave towards each former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia signed implemented in parallel: other and work with each other in a manner a stabilization and association agreement, comparable to the relationships that now becoming the ï¬?rst (West) Balkan country to Trade agreements. While the European exist between EU Member Statesâ€? (European do so. Others soon followed: Croatia in 2005, Union has many different kinds of motivations Commission 2010). It includes integration into Albania in 2006, Montenegro in 2008, and for agreements, one form is especially regional infrastructure networks. Bosnia and Herzegovina in 2008. designed for countries applying to join it, and In the mid- to late 1990s, countries that Integration with the European Union should this intention is made explicit. These introduce eventually became part of the EU27 signed not be viewed as a discrete change upon free trade in almost all industrial products Association Agreements with EU (for example, membership. The process of actual reforms but not agriculture. As part of the process, Hungary in 1994, Romania and Bulgaria in precedes formal entry, sometimes by more countries must relinquish all other bilateral 1995, and Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and than a decade. trade agreements. Slovenia in the late 1990s). In 1995, Turkey signed an association agreement, and formed a customs union on December 31, 1995. Source: Behar and Freund 2011. 97 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 2.6: Intermediates are about half of the European Union’s trade, but two- thirds of the trade in Asia (share of intermediates trade in GDP and total trade, 1996–2008) Note: Trade in intermediates is deï¬?ned by the BEC nomenclature. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade; and WDI. Figure 2.7: New EU members are more important for the EU15 for trade in intermediate goods (intermediate goods trade shares, EU15 and EU10, 1996–2008) Note: Trade in intermediates is deï¬?ned by the BEC nomenclature. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. More variety in the intermediate goods trade The trade between Fiat and its afï¬?liates in Serbia and Turkey, or between Å koda and Volkswagen, is classiï¬?ed as intermediates intra-industry trade, which has been growing substantially in and near the European Union. The intra-industry trade in intermediates between the new member states and the EU15 is higher than between average trade partners in the rest of the world. The Grubel-Lloyd index for intermediates has risen by 22 percent, higher than for all products (ï¬?gure 2.8). The Grubel-Lloyd index for intra-industry trade in intermediates between the new member states and the EU15 rose by about 30 percent; by contrast, the index for trade between the EU15 and the rest of the world actually fell. The growing intra-industry trade is best understood as driven by increased “horizontal differentiation,â€? which is manifest in greater variety (Jones and Kierzkowski 2005). An alternative interpretation of growing intra-industry trade is the fragmentation of production. But as seen above, the evidence for increased fragmentation within Factory Europe is ambiguous. By contrast, 9 of 13 EU15 countries—Belgium and Luxembourg excluded—increased the variety of 98 CHAPTER 2 Table 2.1: A greater variety of intermediate goods are being traded (variety of intermediate goods sent from 2004 members to the EU15) 1996–98 2006–08 Average EU15 imports 1718 1807 Average new member state exports 1482 1591 Aggregate EU15 imports 2997 2942 Aggregate new member state exports 2914 2924 Note: The ï¬?rst two rows (“averageâ€?) show simple averages across corresponding groups and the third and last rows (“aggregateâ€?) do region-wide values, using either EU15 import data or 2004 members’ export data. Harmonized Commodity Description and Coding System (HS) 1996 six-digit trade data are used, and from them, intermediate products are chosen using the HS–BEC concordance information. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. intermediates that they sourced from the new members. Similarly, 7 of 10 new members increased the variety of goods sent to the EU15 from 1482 to 1591. So, while the picture for the European Union as a whole is mixed, more EU15 countries are receiving more varieties from more 2004 members (table 2.1). By contrast, the variety of goods shipped by the new members to the world as a whole fell. The variety of goods imported by the EU15 from the world also fell. In other words, a bigger share of EU15 intermediate varieties is coming from the new members, and a larger share of new members’ intermediate varieties is destined for the EU15. The rise in variety is not conï¬?ned to intermediates. The variety of consumption goods exported by the new members to the EU15 rose as much as that of intermediates. But the variety of consumer goods sent to the world as a whole also rose, so the relatively greater variety in the trade with the EU15 (compared with trade with the rest of the world) is a development in the intermediate goods trade, not the trade in ï¬?nal goods.4 Figure 2.8: Growing intra-industry ties in the east, but faster within the European Union (intermediate intra-industry trade index, 1996–2008) Note: Intermediate intra-industry trade is measured with SITC (Revision 2) four-digit trade data, and the SITC–BEC concordance information is used to select the SITC products that are classiï¬?ed by the BEC as intermediates. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade. 99 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 2.5: Measuring the sophistication of exports of goods The ï¬?rst measure of trade complexity is the Revision 2 goods classiï¬?ed by the Broad website add the website (www.economics. sophistication of intermediate products, Economic Categories as intermediates. To harvard.edu/faculty/nunn/data_nunn) constructed by adapting the method in distinguish these measures of intermediates and mapped to four-digit data using the Hausman, Hwang, and Rodrik (2007). The sophistication from those for all goods, we appropriate concordance information. Of most sophistication of each product is estimated by use the terms I_Prody and I_Expy. We also interest is the fraction of intermediates using using the GDP per capita of those countries produce an analog for imports and refer to it as differentiated inputs; the technique makes use that export it. Every product’s share in I_Impy. Mishra, Lundstrom, and Anand (2011) of a further concordance to Broad Economic each country’s total exports is calculated. develop a similar procedure for services trade, Categories–deï¬?ned intermediates categories to This share for the country is standardized which is used in the next section. construct the index of relationship-speciï¬?city by dividing it by the average share of this of intermediates (RSI). product for all countries. The key step is that The second measure of trade complexity is this is multiplied by the GDP per capita of the relationship-speciï¬?city of products. This The two measures provide alternative that country. Summing across all countries measure was developed by Nunn (2007), accounts of the complexity of the products gives the sophistication of that product, or who constructed the fraction of each product being traded. The RSI, which is affected by its “PRODY.â€? The sophistication of a country’s exported by a country that was itself made the rule of law and other behind-the-border export basket, or its “EXPY,â€? is calculated by with differentiated inputs within the country. factors, accounts for the complexity of multiplying the sophistication of each product The higher the fraction, the less regulated the production chains within a country. It therefore by the share of that product in the country’s process by which the good was put together. does not matter whether these chains are exports and summing across all products. The Because this requires more relationships, complete (exports of ï¬?nal goods) or part of averages of GDP per capita and exports over this gives the relationship-speciï¬?city of the a broader chain (intermediates). Therefore, 2001–03 are used, and the sophistication of product. Nunn’s measures use input-output even if cross-border trade in all goods is products is held ï¬?xed so that any changes over data to construct the share of each product that considered, the RSI still provides information time are due to changes in the export basket uses differentiated inputs as deï¬?ned by Rauch about the complexity of the steps needed to from year to year. (1999). make those goods. The sophistication measure incorporates the complexity of trade across The main adaptation of this measure for this The measures for three-digit International countries. report restricts this to only the four-digit Standard of Industrial Classiï¬?cation data Standard International Trade Classiï¬?cation are taken from Nunn’s Harvard University Source: Behar and Freund 2011. Emerging Europe’s goods trade is getting sophisticated In addition to greater horizontal differentiation, is there also evidence for increased vertical differentiation, which would imply improved quality of inputs traded? Yes. Both the measure of export sophistication and the measure of relationship-speciï¬?city show that trade within Europe is becoming more complex, while trade with non-European partners seems to be declining in complexity (box 2.5). The sophistication of intermediates exports from the new member states to the EU15 rose by about 15 percent from 1996 to 2005 but has remained flat since then (ï¬?gure 2.9). The sophistication of EU10 intermediates exports to the EU15 rose faster than to the world. For EU15 intermediates exports to the world, sophistication follows an inverted U-curve and the measure in 2008 is roughly the same as in 1996. By contrast, the sophistication of EU15 exports to the 2004 members has risen by 7 percent over the period despite a slight decline since 2004. Echoing the earlier pattern shown for the trade in ï¬?nished products, changes in the nature of intermediates received by the new members are similar regardless of whether they come from the EU15 or the rest of the world. By contrast, from the perspective of the EU15, the new members are becoming an increasingly sophisticated source and market relative to other regions. And this seems to be the case for both the 2004 members and the EU candidate countries. This is largely because of Turkey: both the size and sophistication in its trade are at the highest levels and have shown the clearest upward trend. The other countries in this group—including Bulgaria and Romania—have not seen an increase in the sophistication of trade. 100 CHAPTER 2 The second measure of complexity is based on the relationship-speciï¬?city of intermediates (RSI): the fraction of differentiated inputs embodied in exports. The RSI for the world’s exports fell while that of the new members rose by 7 percentage points to 70 percent for all goods and by 6 percentage points to 67 percent for intermediates. For intermediates exports in particular, the new members’ exports have a higher RSI than do those of the world as a whole. EU candidates and the 2007 entrants have less complex exports, but Bulgaria and Romania have experienced a large increase.5 Joining the European Union has allowed the 2004 and 2007 members to produce more relationship-speciï¬?c goods, and the EU15 can now source more relationship-speciï¬?c products from them. Figure 2.10 shows a rise in the RSI of 6 percentage points to 69 percent for intermediates and by 5 percentage points to 72 percent for all goods, but a decline in the relationship-speciï¬?city of imports from other countries. Trade within Europe is becoming more sophisticated, while Europe’s trade with the rest of the world is becoming less complex. Enterprises in advanced Europe are giving emerging Europe more difï¬?cult things to do. Factory Europe is more spread out and much smarter today than it was two decades ago. Figure 2.9: Advanced and emerging Europe are trading more sophisticated intermediate goods (EXPY for intermediate goods, US$ thousands, 1996–2008) Note: Trade in intermediates is deï¬?ned by the BEC nomenclature. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade; and WDI. Figure 2.10: Emerging Europe’s exports have become more complex (relationship-speciï¬?city index of exports, 1996–98 and 2006–08) Note: Intermediates export is deï¬?ned by the BEC nomenclature. See box 2.5 for the construction of the index. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UN Comtrade and Nunn 2007. 101 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 2.11: Emerging Europe has developed sizable backlogs in trade facilities (ports efï¬?ciency, customs regimes, regulatory efï¬?ciency, and IT infrastructure, 2009–10) Note: The x-axis in each panel shows per capita GDP, PPP, in logs. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on the latest available data (Dutta and Mia 2011; IMD 2010; Schwab 2011; and WDI) to update estimates in Wilson, Luo, and Broadman 2010. A growing backlog in trade facilities The new member states and candidate countries are doing well to become part of the production networks centered in Germany and other EU15 economies. But many of them have now developed a sizable backlog in trade facilities: in particular, the airports and ports, customs regimes, regulations, and IT infrastructure needed to make the goods trade hassle-free. Except for a few countries, most emerging European countries do not do well, especially in port efï¬?ciency and in IT technology (ï¬?gure 2.11). The ï¬?rst round of gains in size and sophistication of merchandise trade seems to have come from lowered divisions between emerging Europe and the big (and growing) market in Western Europe. With eurozone growth prospects uncertain and the composition of trade changing to become increasingly sensitive to transport costs, the next round of gains will depend on how much economic distance is shortened. Sizable trade gains—more from greater exports than an increase in imports— can be had if the port efï¬?ciency, regulatory regimes, and IT infrastructures in the new and candidate member countries are improved by even just half the distance to the EU15 average. The greatest absolute trade gains come from cutting the gaps in port efï¬?ciency and IT infrastructure. Most of these trade gains result from greater exports. 102 CHAPTER 2 Priorities for investments in improving trade facilitation infrastructure are not the same for the new member states and the EU candidates. Among the four most important trade facilitators, IT infrastructure improvements will lead to the largest gains in both groups of countries (Wilson, Luo, and Broadman 2010). Simulations suggest that about 40 percent of the trade gains across the region will come from improved information and communication technology (ICT). For the new members of the European Union, another 35 percent improvement will come from investments in air and maritime port efï¬?ciency. The results for the candidate members suggest more widely dispersed gains with investments in port efï¬?ciency, customs regimes, and regulatory policy of similar importance. Improvements in each dimension result in about 20 percent of the total trade gains. Public investment programs and EU development programs should consider these results. Improvements in port facilities and IT infrastructures are likely to be more costly than reforms of customs regimes and regulatory policy. For EU candidate countries, the latter should continue to have high priority, given ï¬?nancing constraints. The eligibility for additional EU ï¬?nancing after accession increases the scope for ambitious investments in transport and IT infrastructure. In all countries, the private sector has a role to play in the funding and operation of infrastructure facilities. Service Europe—not yet a single market The Internal Market Strategy for Services expects eventually “to make the provision of services between member states as easy as within a member stateâ€? (OECD 2007, p. 75). For a multilingual, multicultural region with diverse political and legal precedents, this is a tall order. Indeed, while in assessing its performance in the goods trade Europe measures itself against East Asia, a developing region, its benchmark for trade in services is the United States, a developed country. For more than half a century, European policymakers have been trying to reduce the costs of cross-border transactions and foster the integration of the internal market. For the goods trade, they have largely succeeded. For services, the single market is still a work in progress and—given the nature of regulatory reforms needed to make it work efï¬?ciently—it is likely to remain one for a while. Too much attention to export performance risks neglect of efforts to make service markets more open, which may well be the wider channel for productivity improvement. Most services are still not tradable through digitized means, so foreign direct investment (FDI) and the movement of people is the biggest part of internationalization, and the channel through which productivity growth is induced, both in services themselves and in “downstreamâ€? industries. Productivity is what’s key, not trade. Given that the lion’s share of output and employment is in services, many of which will remain nontradable, the focus should be on improving markets for services, hence raising the average productivity of enterprises. Indeed, the performance of business services can explain a good part of aggregate productivity differentials among advanced economies (Inklaar, Timmer, and van Ark 2007). 103 GOLDEN GROWTH This is discussed in detail in chapter 4. This chapter discusses the progress in the services trade. Until recently, economists treated “nontradablesâ€? as almost synonymous with services, recognizing the special difï¬?culties in crossing borders to provide services: “Because, by deï¬?nition, services are a flow and so are not storable, their exchange frequently requires the proximity of supplier and consumerâ€? (Francois and Hoekman 2010, p. 648). The requirement of proximity entails additional costs—the “proximity burdenâ€? of the services trade. The questions to be answered are: Has technology reduced this proximity burden? How much has the single market program helped? These questions are taken up in turn. The services trade in the European Union is growing The internal market of the European Union is more important than third countries for trade in services. But the internal market for trade in services has been less integrated than for goods. Services exports within the European Union have grown slower than exports to third countries in recent years despite the implementation of the Services Directive and other initiatives to push forward regional integration in services. The European Commission passed the Services Directive in 2005, aiming to eliminate regulatory barriers to a Single Market for Services. But from 2004 to 2008, intra-EU exports grew at 13 percent, while extra-EU exports grew at 14 percent. Nonetheless, the EU10 and the candidate countries integrated faster within the internal market than with the rest of the world. Services exports from the EU10 members to other EU member countries achieved an annual growth rate of 24 percent, 6 percentage points higher than the rate of their exports to third countries. For the candidates, the difference was 10 percentage points. The prospect of joining the European Union seems to facilitate market entry in services. Trade in services through establishment-based transactions or sales by foreign afï¬?liates is a big part of the services trade. As in the United States, establishment-based transactions are the most important channel for Western European companies to sell services, while cross-border trade remains the dominant channel for other members (table 2.2, top panel). The sales by afï¬?liates of the Western European members were some 46 percent higher than cross-border services exports (table 2.2, bottom panel). For their intra-EU exports, the value of establishment-based transactions was also about 45 percent higher than that of cross-border exports. By contrast, the sales by the afï¬?liates of companies in both Southern EU members and the EU10 were less than one-third of their cross-border exports. But there was little additional integration of Western Europe with other members through establishment- based transactions. Between 2004 and 2008, the sales by afï¬?liates in EU members grew at a meager 0.4 percent while the sales by afï¬?liates located in third countries increased by 3 percent. Transportation and travel remain dominant in the European Union’s services exports. While services were traditionally regarded as nontradable, transportation and travel had always been the exceptions. Western Europe accounts for 70 percent of total exports in transportation and over half of total exports in travel. For the members of Southern Europe, travel is the most important services export. In 2008, the value of exports in travel accounted 104 CHAPTER 2 for 40 percent of total services exports by Southern Europe and almost one-third of total exports in travel by the European Union. For the EU10 members and candidate countries, the two also stand out as the leading services export sectors. Financial and other business services are now becoming the drivers of EU service exports. Financial services cover ï¬?nancial intermediation and auxiliary services, except those of insurance enterprises and pension schemes. Other business services consist of professional and management consulting services; research and development services; and technical, trade-related, and other business services (UN 2011). These services were traditionally not tradable, partly due to the “proximity burdenâ€? and partly due to heavy regulations. The rapid advance of information and computer technology over the past decades has spurred trade in these sectors by reducing the “proximity burden.â€? Regulatory simpliï¬?cation and harmonization with international standards have also helped. Services are becoming more tradable— especially modern services Services exports by Europe and developing countries almost tripled between 1997 and 2007. Services exports have changed qualitatively. They have increasingly become a ï¬?nal export that is directly consumed. Because many services can now be stored and traded digitally, they are not subject to many of the traditional trade barriers (such as transport costs, border delays, physical inspections, and so on) that physical exports have to overcome. Services not only have become more tradable, but they can also be increasingly unbundled: a single service activity in the global supply chain can now be fragmented and done separately at different geographic locations. The new member states have been especially successful in growing services exports since the mid-2000s—not quite star performers like India or China, but high performers compared with the rest of the world (ï¬?gure 2.12, left panel). Figure 2.12 (right panel) graphs the tradability of services between 1986 and 2008. In Europe, there are three developments of note. First, the share of service value added that is traded rose from 10 to 15 percent. Second, the share of services traded in the new member states has increased erratically, but now is almost double its share at the beginning of the transition. Third, the EU candidate countries have seen a drop in the share of services traded since the late 1990s, likely due to rapid expansion of domestic services such as construction, transport, travel, retail trade, and government services, rather than a drop in services exports. What is also clear from international comparisons is that aside from India, trade is a bigger part of the services economy in Europe than in any other part of the world. The increased tradability is mainly due to new technologies that have changed the nature of many services from “traditionalâ€? to “modern.â€? Traditional services require face-to-face contact, while modern services can be delivered over longer distances. Modern services, such as banking and ï¬?nancial services, telecom support, and technical support, are now more “impersonalâ€? and tradable across borders. But technological progress has also helped such 105 GOLDEN GROWTH traditional services as tourism, retail trade, education, and health care take advantage of new information and communication technologies, exploit the potential for fragmentation and scale economies, and become more productive. Table 2.2: Western Europe drives much of the services trade (cross-border exports, 2008) EU members Candidate countries Western Europe Southern Europe EU10 Value of exports (current $, billions) EU members Western Europe 560 97 41 16 Southern Europe 189 26 7 5 EU10 57 6 13 3 EU candidate countries 33 8 5 3 Share in total exports (percent) EU members Western Europe 42 7 3 1 Southern Europe 56 8 2 1 EU10 52 6 12 3 EU candidate countries 45 11 7 4 (sales by foreign afï¬?liates, 2008) EU members Other countries Candidate High and Western Southern countries Middle EU10 upper middle Europe Europe income income Value of exports (current $, billions) EU members Western Europe 514 271 226 34 839 42 Southern Europe 55 8 11 5 13 4 EU10 2 0 7 3 1 1 Share in total exports (percent) EU members Western Europe 26 14 12 2 43 2 Southern Europe 56 8 11 5 13 4 EU10 13 1 54 19 9 5 Note: The top reports numbers from balance of payments data, and the bottom from establishment accounts. EU candidate countries include EU members that joined in 2007 (that is, Bulgaria and Romania). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 106 CHAPTER 2 Cross-border trade in modern services has been growing faster (ï¬?gure 2.13). In the EU15, the rate of growth of trade in modern services is 15 percent, higher than that in the United States. The growth in the new member states is even higher at 25 percent. But EU candidate countries saw a contraction in modern services trade, and rapid growth in traditional services. The share of service value added as a percentage of GDP is high in the EU15, followed by EU new member states and EU candidate countries.6 This is normal, given their per capita incomes. But in most European economies total productivity growth is faster than predicted by growth in output of services. In other words, services output growth contributes less to overall growth in GDP per capita than might be expected given the share of services in GDP. This is consistent with the ï¬?nding reported in chapter 1 that a gap in services accounts for the largest part of the difference in overall productivity between Europe and the United States. It also explains the focus of European policymakers on deepening the market in services as a core element of Europe’s future growth strategy (for example, Monti 2010). (services exports, 1998–2009, 1998 = 100) (exports as percent of service value added, Figure 2.12: Services 1986–2008) exports are growing fast in the new member states Source: IMF BOPS; and WDI. Figure 2.13: Modern— more tradable—services are growing faster almost everywhere (annual growth in modern and traditional services trade, 2000–08) Note: Modern services include communication, insurance, ï¬?nance, computers and information, royalties and license fees, and other business services. Traditional services are transport, travel, construction, and personal, cultural, and recreational services. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF BOPS. 107 GOLDEN GROWTH The single market is delivering—but not for modern services The services trade in the European Union is now a $4 trillion business, and more than half of this is in the internal market (ï¬?gure 2.14). For the smaller economies in the east and south, the internal trade is actually more than two-thirds of the total. There has been progress toward deeper integration of services in the European Union (European Commission 2002). Not surprisingly, Western Europe accounts for almost 80 percent of the internal services trade (ï¬?gure 2.15), and more than half of the sales within the internal market by foreign afï¬?liates took place in Western Europe.7 But the EU10 and the EU candidate countries appeared to integrate faster into the single market. Exports of the EU10 to the internal market grew at 24 percent annually, 6 percentage points higher than their exports to the rest of the world. For the accession countries, the difference was 10 percentage points. As discussed in the previous section for goods trade, integration is a gradual process and precedes actual accession—the prospect of joining the European Union seems to facilitate market entry by the accession countries. Figure 2.14: Internal trade tendencies in the European Union vary across countries Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. Figure 2.15: Western Europe does most of the internal trade in services, 2008 Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 108 CHAPTER 2 Table 2.3: The single market has increased services trade and FDI by about 25 percent (estimates of the effect of the Single Market for Services on trade and FDI, 1992–2006) Source Data Time Methodology Effect (percent) Gravity model without country-pair fixed Cross-border trade 1999–2002 32 effects Gravity model with Cross-border trade 1999–2006 33 country-pair fixed effects Fink (2009) Gravity model without country-pair fixed Outward FDI 1992–2005 30 effects Gravity model with Outward FDI 1999–2005 18 country-pair fixed effects Gravity model without country-pair fixed Cross-border trade 2002–05 11 Straathof and others effects (2008) Gravity model with Outward FDI 1994–2004 22 country-pair fixed effects Source: World Bank staff. The single market program has promoted deeper integration of services. Straathof and others (2008) and Fink (2009) both show that the single market program reduces trade costs and leads to more bilateral trade between members, both as cross-border trade and foreign direct investment.8 Services trade flows and FDI within the European Union are 10–30 percent higher compared with their trade with third countries and trade by the rest of the world (table 2.3).9 Enlargement, especially in 2004, has promoted deeper integration of new members with the European Union, and most of the increase in services trade does not seem to have come at the expense of third countries. But the single market works a lot better for trade in traditional than in modern services. Transportation and travel, two traditional sectors, dominate the European Union’s cross-border services trade. Their levels of integration—or the working of the single market—differ a lot. For travel, more than two-thirds of exports were transactions within the European Union; for transportation, only half of total exports were oriented toward the internal market (ï¬?gure 2.16). For business services—which include the ICT-facilitated digital trade that is so fragmented in the European Union—the internal market accounts for just two-ï¬?fths of the trade. Financial services integration is taken up in chapter 3; this chapter looks more closely at transportation, information and communications technology, and other business services to see how the single market can be made to work better. Europeans are dissatisï¬?ed with the Single Market for Services While the internal trade in services has been growing, the progress is considered unsatisfactory for several reasons. First, services are a large fraction of the economy but a small share of trade. In the EU15, services are more than two- thirds of total value added and about three-quarters of employment. In the new member states that joined in 2004, services are more than 60 percent of value added and employment. More than half of labor productivity growth between 109 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 2.16: The single market works better for traditional services (Intra-EU Share of service exports, percent, by type of service, 2008) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. Figure 2.17: Services are contributing even more to growth in Europe (sector shares in economic output, 1995–99 and 2000–08) Source: WDI. 2000 and 2006 in EU15 countries was in services, but services are just one-ï¬?fth of total intra-EU trade. Even after accounting for the sales by foreign afï¬?liates, services were just one-third of total intra-EU trade in 2008. Services are an ever larger slice of the European economy, and a still larger part of its economic growth (ï¬?gure 2.17). New developments in information and communication technology have increased both the tradability of and productivity growth in services, traditionally considered less tradable and a productivity laggard. So trade in services appears underdeveloped—less than 10 percent of service value added is currently exported, compared with 90 percent of goods value added. The second reason is that services trade within the European Union has not grown as quickly as the internal trade in goods. In terms of simple statistics, the exports of goods within the internal market are more than double the exports of members to third countries. By contrast, the exports of services within the internal market are only 20–40 percent higher than the exports to third countries, depending on the measure used. The evidence suggests that 110 CHAPTER 2 Box 2.6: How big should the Single Market for Services be? Clues from Canada Regional trade in goods in East Asia is a its GDP of $14.8 trillion). In other respects, for travel-related services. When differences common benchmark for Europe. But when it Canada is a better benchmark. Linguistic, in regulations are accounted for, language comes to trade in services, policymakers in the legal, and cultural divisions hamper trade in matters only for travel and commercial European Union compare their progress to that most services more than does distance. So for services. The strictness of product market of countries like the United States or Canada, Europe, it may be instructive to see how much regulations in the origin country reduces trade not to continents or regions such as North the French- and English-speaking provinces of in commercial services, while destination America or East Asia. If there were a Single Canada trade despite the divisions. country regulations affect travel and trade in Market for Services in Europe as in the United government services. In 2000, services trade as a share of GDP in States or Canada, how much would trade in There is considerable unexploited potential for Canada was almost 9 percent of GDP, more services go up—would it increase 20 percent, both goods and services trade in the European twofold, or twentyfold? And how much would than twice the ratio for the EU. Given the fact Union. If the EU market functioned like that of this increase productivity? that size matters for goods and services trade Canada, intra-EU goods trade would be three (larger countries and provinces trade more), Lejour and de Paiva Verheijden (2007) provide times as high as it was in 2000, and services and the European Union’s GDP was about 10 answers to the ï¬?rst question by analyzing trade between three and ï¬?ve times as much. times that of Canada in 2000, the share of the services trade among Canadian provinces Given that not all differences in language and services trade in the European Union should between 1997 and 1999, and among OECD legislation can be eliminated, a reasonable be greater, not smaller. Smaller distances in countries between 1999 and 2001 (box objective over the next few years might be Europe relative to Canada would make this a doubling of intra-EU cross-border trade in ï¬?gure 1). It was impossible to do something ratio even bigger for the European Union, services by 2020. Using 2007 statistics, this analogous for the United States: reliable data while linguistic differences would make it would mean an increase in intra-EU services for trade in services among U.S. states are smaller. trade of about €660 billion, or around $1 simply not available. Sizewise, comparisons with the United States are more apt: in 2011, Looking more closely, GDP size matters trillion (roughly $100 billion a year). A threefold roughly the same amount for trade in travel, increase would mean that services exports the value added in services in the European transport, commercial, and government within the European Union would rise by €1.3 Union was $11.4 trillion (70 percent of its GDP trillion, or about $2 trillion. of $16.2 trillion), almost exactly the same services. Distance matters more for as that in the United States (77 percent of commercial and transport services, and least Source: Lejour and de Paiva Verheijden 2007. Box ï¬?gure 1: Language differences hamper services trade more (effects on trade between Canadian provinces, 1997–99) 1.8 Goods Services 1.6 Source: Lejour and de Paiva Verheijden 2007. 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 Density at Density at Distance (-ve) Division— Division— destination origin linguistic (-ve) adjacency (-ve) the effect of the single market is greater for goods than services, when it might be expected to be the other way around.10 New technologies have resulted in rapid growth of “modern impersonal services,â€? such as information technology, business-related services, medical records transcription, call center operations, education services, and entertainment production services. More and more 111 GOLDEN GROWTH services can now be stored and traded digitally, and they have become similar to manufactured goods in that they beneï¬?t from technological advancement and their costs depend on economies of scale, agglomeration, and division of labor. More important, these sophisticated services provide an opportunity for innovative, high-tech jobs. The third reason is that trade in services within the European Union has not been growing faster than services trade to third countries. Cross-border exports in the internal market grew at 13 percent annually between 2004 and 2008, while the exports to third countries grew at 14 percent. The difference led to a 3 percentage point decline in the ratio between intra-EU and extra-EU exports. Foreign afï¬?liate sales within the European Union have been more volatile than sales to third countries, and the ratio between intra-EU and extra-EU sales dropped by 9 percentage points over the same period. A useful thought experiment to gauge the potential gains of deeper integration is to estimate the extra scope for intra-EU trade if the internal market were to function like the interstate trade in services in some benchmark countries. As federal countries, Canada and the United States are the obvious benchmarks. The level of income and role played by the services sector in both economies are comparable to those of the European Union. Their interprovince/interstate market could be taken as having the maximum possible integration. Regulatory barriers are low in both countries. According to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Canada’s regulatory regime was rated 0.95 and the United States’ at 0.84 in 2008, compared with the most restrictive regime in Europe rated at 2.60 and the most liberal one at 0.84. Although provinces/states have their own rules and organizational legacies, the federal government in both countries provides a framework for regulating services. The Box 2.7: Can liberalization of services contribute to productivity growth? Evidence from the Czech Republic The debate on the welfare effects of trade in foreign hands by 2001. the positive views of liberalization varied and investment liberalization has traditionally between 56 percent of respondents who Anecdotal evidence suggests that services centered on goods. The literature conï¬?rms evaluated accounting and auditing services seem to have become more reliable after productivity gains in many cases. Services to 87 percent of respondents asked about allowing foreign entry. Moreover, these liberalization is another potential source of foreign providers were at the forefront of telecommunications. productivity gains—working through the introducing innovations. For example, Ceska same channels. The evidence, however, has Analysis of data from a panel of manufacturing Sporitelna, an Austrian-owned bank, installed ï¬?rms over 1998–2003 conï¬?rms that allowing been scarce—even more so when it comes 1,080 ATMs across the country. It was also to plant- or ï¬?rm-level evidence. But a recent foreign entry into services industries is the key the ï¬?rst bank to offer transaction ATMs and study by Arnold, Javorcik, and Mattoo (2011) channel through which services liberalization became the market leader in remote banking. on the Czech Republic’s services liberalization contributes to better performance of Cash flow management tools, multimodal in the late 1990s helps to shed some light on “downstreamâ€? manufacturing sectors. transport services, and digital services in the issue. Liberalization is captured in four ways: an telecommunications were also introduced by foreign companies. index of policy reforms, the share of foreign- In 1998, the Czech Republic adopted a more owned ï¬?rms in services output, the share of friendly approach to foreign direct investment, Results of a World Bank survey of 350 Czech private ï¬?rms in services output, and the extent including services. In telecommunications, ï¬?rms provide more systematic support. The of competition. There is a strong correlation for example, a third mobile operator entered share of positive perceptions ranged from between services sector reform and the the market in 2000 with 100 percent foreign 55 percent of the respondents when asked productivity of local producers relying on ownership, and one existing mobile company about the quality of accounting and auditing services as intermediate inputs. attracted a controlling stake by a foreign services to 82 percent for telecommunications. investor. In banking, 90 percent of assets were With regard to the variety of products offered, Source: Arnold, Javorcik, and Mattoo 2011. 112 CHAPTER 2 Figure 2.18: The European Union has a comparative advantage in services (revealed comparative advantage, services and goods, 1990–2009) Note: The index greater than one means the country has a comparative advantage in the activity. Source: Lundstrom Gable and Mishra 2011. best guess is that intra-EU cross-border services trade could double or triple if the internal market functioned as well as the Canadian market for services (box 2.6). Allowing greater foreign competition in services has helped to increase productivity in downstream manufacturing, that is, activities that rely on efï¬?cient provision of services. The experience of the Czech Republic illustrates these beneï¬?ts (box 2.7). Could trade in modern services drive growth? As Europe looks for new ways to increase incomes and productivity, it could better facilitate both the goods and services trade. The potential is believed to be greater for services trade. Whereas increasing trade volumes in niche products or services fuels economic growth, growth can also be achieved by improving the sophistication of goods and services exports. Export “qualityâ€? in goods and services helps economic growth or at least is associated with growth—what you export matters. While growth in manufacturing is still an important track for many countries, services exports may be an additional or even alternative channel. For the services-dominated economies in Europe, it may even be a big part of the solution to the search for an “export-oriented growth model.â€?11 This raises the question of how far the specialization in services can go in Europe, given the globalization of services and the competition from Asia. That is, does Europe have a comparative advantage in services? The revealed comparative advantage in goods and services—deï¬?ned as the shares of the goods and services category in a country’s export basket compared to their shares in the global export basket—are informative in assessing this. The EU15 has a revealed comparative advantage in services, and the gap between goods and services is increasing (ï¬?gure 2.18). The new member states also appear to have a comparative advantage in services; the gap with goods was sizable in the 1990s but is now at the same level as in the EU15 economies. EU candidate countries had a comparative advantage in services until the early 2000s; now they have a comparative disadvantage.12 113 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 2.8: Measuring the sophistication of services exports is much more difï¬?cult than for goods It is not straightforward to apply the weighted income value of services exported EXPY. So while constructing the Services EXPY, Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik (2007) by a country, computed as the weighted PRODY values of a service export are allowed methodology, developed for measuring the sum of PRODYs; the weights are the share of to vary from year to year. Hence, an increase in sophistication of exported goods, to measure the particular service in the country’s total dynamic EXPY can be due to either an increase how sophisticated services exports are. services export basket. in the PRODY of a service or an increase in the Service PRODYs, reflecting the income share of high PRODY products in the export Trade data come from the IMF Balance of level associated with each category of basket. Payments statistics, available for more than services produced in a country, must ï¬?rst be 190 countries from 1990 to 2007. Due to data The second reason is that countries are calculated. In technical terms, PRODY j is the availability, the sample has just 100 countries. exporting higher-value services, but the income associated with the service j, and is GDP data are from the World Development services exports themselves are increasing constructed by using the service export share Indicators. in sophistication due to information and of a country i in world’s export of service j, communication technology. Many richer divided by the sum of shares of j in world There are two differences for the services countries are exporting services, boosting the exports of j across all countries exporting EXPY compared with the measure for goods PRODYs of some service export categories. that service. The ratios are multiplied by the exports: a high level of aggregation and the Since the data are much less disaggregated exporting countries’ per capita income (Y) need for dynamic PRODYs. First, services for services, using static PRODY would not and the result is summed for all countries. In export data are less detailed than for goods. capture the higher PRODY service exports that effect, the PRODY is the weighted average of There are only ten categories of services are subcategories of the broader groups in per capita GDPs, where the weights represent exports, compared with several hundred for Balance of Payments data. The dynamic EXPY the revealed comparative advantage in service goods. If a country—within a broad services incorporates this because it allows the PRODYs j for each country. PRODYs are constructed for export category—moves from a low PRODY to change over time. each service category and are by construction subcategory of services to one with a higher the same for all countries. EXPY is then the PRODY, this does not show up in the static Source: Lundstrom Gable and Mishra 2011. Trends in productivity seem to back this assessment. Service productivity is many times higher in the EU15 than in emerging Europe. This can be explained by a more efï¬?cient service sstructure and workforce in the EU15 and by the type of services produced there. Services productivity has increased globally over the last decade, even for already high-productivity service economies such as those in the EU15. The growth in services productivity in the European Union’s new member states has been highest, while EU candidate countries are catching up with higher-income countries more slowly.13 However, the services exports of the European Union are less sophisticated than those of India or the United States. Applying the technique used to measure the sophistication of goods production and exports is not easily extended to services, because data are much less disaggregated for services (box 2.8). But with services accounting for such a large proportion of GDP and hence of aggregate productivity growth, it is useful to analyze whether there is a link between the sophistication of services exports and GDP growth. On average, the PRODYs for modern services are higher and their growth has been greater, despite higher initial levels. The EU15 has 43 percent of its export basket in modern services, the EU12 has 26 percent, and the EU candidate countries 11 percent. The world average is 21 percent. Due to the high PRODYs for modern services, EU15 EXPY is to a large extent explained by the high share of modern services, especially ï¬?nancial services. For the new member states and the EU candidates, the EXPY is still determined more by traditional services (table 2.4). 114 CHAPTER 2 Table 2.4: EU services exports are more sophisticated than those of the rest of the world (PRODYs, 1990–95, 1996–99, and 2000–07, and PRODY values and shares by service and country group) World 2007 services export share (percent) 2007 EXPY share New New EU candi- EU candi- 1990–95 1996–99 2000–07 World EU15 member World EU15 member dates dates states states Traditional services Transportation 8,161 9,629 11,990 21 19 32 18 8 5 10 8 Travel 7,433 7,851 8,999 41 22 30 58 6 3 5 15 Construction 14,510 10,534 10,464 2 2 3 3 8 7 12 20 Personal, cultural, and 14,510 10,534 10,464 1 1 3 2 10 5 30 26 recreational Modern services Communications 6,261 6,320 7,584 4 2 3 4 5 3 5 9 Insurance 8,167 11,306 13,630 2 2 0 1 9 9 2 5 Financial 18,590 23,063 25,743 3 9 3 1 20 33 10 4 Computer and information 14,916 20,092 18,797 2 5 3 1 12 16 10 6 Royalties and license fees 10,263 13,293 14,707 1 3 1 0 12 10 6 2 Other business services 7,883 9,437 13,162 15 26 19 9 10 9 9 5 Note: Government services are not included. Source: Lundstrom Gable and Mishra 2011. Services exports in the European Union are becoming more sophisticated. Figure 2.19 shows the evolution of Services EXPY. All groups start out with more or less the same level of sophistication in the beginning of the 1990s, and diverge in the late 1990s. The EU15 made the largest jump in the late 1990s, while the new member states continued an already strong trend though at a lower level than the EU15. The EU candidate countries and the eastern partnership countries dropped in Services EXPY in the late 1990s and have not been able to catch up since. Compared to non-European peers, however, the EU15 has fallen behind. The services PRODY of the United States has been higher than that of the EU15 since the early 2000s. This is consistent with the growing productivity gap in services with the United States highlighted in chapter 1 as one of Europe’s key challenges. India has seen a big increase in PRODY, and China has been closing the gap as well. In general, countries with a high Services EXPY also have a high goods EXPY. European economies have more sophisticated exports than the median country, somewhat more so for goods exports than for services. To what extent has higher services trade sophistication been reflected in faster economic growth? Lundstrom Gable and Mishra (2011) ï¬?nd evidence of an association between growth and services trade sophistication for a global sample. In Europe, the correlation is especially strong for the European Union’s new member states. 115 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 2.19: India and the United States have more sophisticated services exports than the European Union (service EXPY, 1990-2007 (left), and shares in service EXPY, 2007 (right)) Source: Lundstrom Gable and Mishra 2011. Making the single market work for services Services are where most economic regulations are concentrated (Conway and Nicoletti 2006). Mainly, this is due to the difï¬?culty in evaluating the quality of services. The consumer cannot be certain about the quality of services until after they have been consumed, and sometimes not even then. The production and consumption of services also cannot easily be separated in place and time, making it difï¬?cult to standardize services products. In the case of complex services (such as professional services), the consumer may not have the knowledge to make a judgment about the services even after consumption. Regulations are necessary to address this problem of “asymmetric information.â€? They may also be needed because of the externalities associated with some services (for example, in the ï¬?nancial sector) and the need to provide equal access to essential services such as transportation and utilities. Homogenize regulations Because of cumbersome regulations, services providers have to overcome many barriers to be able to export: outright legal discrimination (as with exclusive rights to domestic providers), implicit restrictive regulations (for example, licensing based on domestic qualiï¬?cations), and lack of transparency and nonlegal barriers like language and culture. Some countries require services providers to meet an “economic needs testâ€? to show that—even if they will provide better choice and value for consumers—they will not undercut or destabilize local competitors. These tests leave room for arbitrary enforcement. Businesses ï¬?nd it costly just to ï¬?nd out what the legal and administrative formalities are. For example, an engineering company may end up spending 3 percent of annual turnover on researching the differing legal requirements in just two other member states of the European Union where it wanted to supply services (World Trade Organization 2009b). These hurdles discourage services exports. Nicoletti and others (2003), among others, ï¬?nd that high regulation intensity between OECD countries depresses trade in services. Moreover, they ï¬?nd that the impact is greater than for trade in goods. A unique character of services further compounds the issue. Services are often partly produced where they are consumed. The production process uses inputs 116 CHAPTER 2 Box 2.9: Reviving the reform agenda for the European single market Enlargement and creation of the single market Paradoxically, overall enthusiasm for a single beneï¬?t from greater mobility due to better has proved beneï¬?cial for all EU members. market declined even more during the recent information about amenities in other member European enterprises found it easier to trade ï¬?nancial crisis, while in fact Europe needs a states. goods and services across borders. Yet, the strong internal market now more than ever The report recognizes the discrepancies in how single market is far from efï¬?cient. Small and before. medium enterprises face difï¬?culties when different countries imagine a fully functioning A recent report by Mario Monti (2010, p.37) for single market. New strategies proposed in recovering foreign liabilities. EU citizens have the European Commission points out that the the report seek a common ground between to re-register a car and pay taxes every time “single market is Europe’s original idea and the Anglo-Saxon preference for competition, they move to a different country. unï¬?nished businessâ€?. It lists the completion the variety of experiences among Nordic Although the services sector in Europe of the single market as a prerequisite for countries, the ambitions of emerging Europe, contributes substantially to GDP growth and economic growth in Europe. For the common and the concerns of social market economies. job creation, the reform agenda for creating digital market, the report recommends an But before new strategies are drafted and a Single Market for Services is far from introduction of a pan-European licensing implemented, Europe would beneï¬?t from complete. Technological transformation has market, EU copyright law, and European fully reinforcing laws already passed. On left Europe’s market for modern services Union–wide online broadcasting as well as average more than half of EU directives are well behind that of its global peers. At the improvement of the business environment not implemented on time by the member same time, political and social support for cross-border e-commerce. Development states. The full implementation of the Services for it seems to have lost momentum. The of the European digital market by 2020 could Directive alone could yield between €60 and attention given to policies for strengthening yield around 4 percent of the European Union’s €140 billion. a European single market differs considerably GDP. EU customers would beneï¬?t from greater across the European Union’s member states. integration of retail banking. Workers would Source: Monti 2010. from both exporting and importing countries, which does not apply to goods. As a result, providers who want to export are subject to the regulations of both countries. Mirza and Nicoletti (2004), for example, ï¬?nd evidence that policy factors affecting the use of inputs in the exporting and importing country both have impact on the same flow of traded services between the two countries, and the effects are of similar scale. Nicoletti and others (2003) ï¬?nd similar problems using regulations in exporting and importing countries to evaluate regulation intensity. The differences between trading partners’ regulatory regimes hinder the growth of the single market. Each member has its own qualiï¬?cation criteria, implying additional compliance costs every time a ï¬?rm wants to expand to a new country. The importance of regulatory harmonization has been supported by recent studies. Kox and Lejour (2005) show that high heterogeneity in domestic regulations, together with the level of regulatory intensity, depresses cross-border trade in services. Kox and Lejour (2007) show that harmonization or mutual recognition by countries could lead to a 13–30 percent increase in trade. Notably, both studies suggest that eliminating explicit legal barriers is not sufï¬?cient either to promote either cross-border trade or to attract foreign direct investment in services. Remove regulatory barriers Much like tariffs on trade in goods, stringent regulations also shield domestic ï¬?rms from foreign pressure and reduce the competitiveness of domestic providers in regional and world markets. Firms also have little incentive to innovate. Existing studies consistently illustrate that a high level of regulation in exporting countries is also associated with low bilateral trade flows in services (for example, Mirza and Nicoletti 2004; Kox and Lejour 2005). Services 117 GOLDEN GROWTH liberalization tends to foster productivity growth in the broader economy (Francois and Hoekman 2010). The European Commission (2002) did a comprehensive inventory of the internal regulatory barriers that hinder cross-border trade and prevent the commercial presence of foreign services providers. Services providers hit internal barriers at every stage of the business process. The report also discovered that many barriers are “horizontalâ€?—that is, they affect a wide range of activities. It identiï¬?ed a wide range of barriers to services providers at every stage of business operation: from distributing services, selling services, and dealing with after-sales issues for cross-border trade, to establishing a business, using inputs, and promoting business for exporting through commercial presence. The distribution of services is affected by residency or nationality requirements, which prevent provision from home countries. Small and medium enterprises (SMEs) are hit the hardest. A recent report done for the European Commission reported that the gains from implementing the Services Directive are close to €500 billion (box 2.9). There are many examples of companies that ï¬?nd it almost impossible to set up subsidiaries in other EU member states. Some actually ï¬?nd it harder to get established in the EU15 than in the new member states. This report also documents that all services providers encounter, at least, barriers at one stage of the business process; often they encounter them at several or even at all stages. Many barriers are horizontal. One common feature is a “single regime,â€? in which the national government applies the same regulations to both cross- border services trade and sales through commercial presence. A single regime may lead to duplication of requirements and disproportionate burdens for the second category because it already complies with home regulations. Legal uncertainty is another problem. SMEs often do not have sufï¬?cient resources to meet these requirements or to afford the extra legal assistance costs. Monti (2010) provides the example of cross-border enforcement of judicial awards, which can cost as much as €2,000 even for pure formalities. As a result, SMEs are either dissuaded from cross-border activities or are at a clear competitive disadvantage compared to domestic operators. Those from less developed EU members are particularly disadvantaged. SMEs often do not consider expanding to other member states, even if their services are not market-speciï¬?c and have export potential. There is a lack of trust and a natural resistance to deal with services providers from other member states. The OECD product market regulation indicators help to measure regulatory barriers (OECD 2011). They quantify the barriers to several services sectors and network industries, offering a good basis to compare regulation of services. According to the latest (2008) indicators, the EU member and candidate countries have removed many of the obvious restrictions to trade and foreign investment. But they have been slow to improve domestic regulations, which affect the services trade and investment more. Administrative hurdles, barriers to entry, and restrictions to competition in domestic markets remain a concern of many European countries, especially Turkey, Poland, and Greece. 118 CHAPTER 2 Figure 2.20: European economies have made trade easier Note: The indicators range from 0 to 6, with 6 the most restrictive. In panels for changes, negative numbers indicate liberalization. Source: OECD 2011. Figure 2.21: Professional services remain tightly regulated (product market regulation indicators for regulations in professional services, 2008) Note: The indicators range from 0 to 6, with 6 the most restrictive. Source: Conway and Nicoletti 2006; and OECD 2011. Figure 2.22: Not all countries are making trade in business services easier (changes in product market regulation indicators for regulations in professional services, 2003–08) Note: A negative number indicates liberalization. Source: Conway and Nicoletti 2006; and OECD 2011. 119 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 2.10: Facilitating the services trade in the Western Balkans The share of services in the economy has been transport at 14 percent and construction at progress in all aspects except the movement increasing in the Western Balkans (Albania, less than 5 percent. From modern services, of natural persons. Tedious work authorization Bosnia and Herzegovina, Kosovo, the former communications service exports are the procedures and nonrecognition of professional Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Montenegro, largest, but they are still less than 5 percent qualiï¬?cation mean that none of the CEFTA and Serbia). It now accounts for about 70–75 of services exports. Exports of computer and countries offers “freedom of employment.â€? percent of GDP in every country except Serbia, information and communication technology Other problems: where services are still less than 60 percent. (ICT) services have been on the rise, but • In construction, the main problem is Travel, transport, construction, real estate, concentrated in Croatia, Serbia, and FYR that companies have to establish a local and wholesale and retail trade are the largest Macedonia. Business services are 8 percent of presence; only Bosnia and Herzegovina service sectors. total services exports, but poor statistics make allows cross-border provision. it difï¬?cult to analyze their composition and Trade in services has been increasing too. • In road transport (three-quarters of the direction. Services exports averaged €16 billion a year transport business), bilateral relations still in 2007–09 and were 10 percent of GDP in the Western Balkan countries are disadvantaged affect trade. landlocked countries but about 20 percent or vis-à-vis the EU15 and the new member states more in Albania, Croatia, and Montenegro. because they do not have full access to the • ICT services are the most open of all the Tourism receipts are three-quarters of services European Union’s markets. In fact, companies traded services; the biggest problem may exports in Croatia and Montenegro. The face problems even when trying to export to be enforcing intellectual property rights. average ratio of services imports to GDP is other signatories of the Central European Free Aside from these barriers, service exporters about 10 percent, with Albania (18 percent) at Trade Agreement (CEFTA), which replaced 32 now face the hassles that all entrepreneurs the high end and Bosnia and Herzegovina (5 bilateral agreements in 2007, and eliminated have to deal with: enforcing contracts percent) at the low end. most barriers to trade in manufactures and and dealing with product, labor, and land farm products. regulations. But perhaps the biggest While the size of services exports in the impediment to the development of the Balkans is similar to those of the EU15 and In assessing what can help trade in services services trade in the Western Balkans now is the new member state economies, the between the six CEFTA countries, a recent getting the same access to the large EU market sophistication of exports differs. Traditional World Bank study looked at ï¬?ve areas: market that Bulgaria, Romania, and the other new services dominate: travel accounts for two- access, commercial presence, performance member states enjoy. thirds of total services exports—concentrated requirements, protection of rights, and in the coastal countries—followed by movement of people. The region has made Source: Handjiski and Sestovic 2011. The majority of the EU members were rated as having a fairly open regime toward foreign business (ï¬?gure 2.20). But regulatory regimes for services tend to be more restrictive. Professional services remain tightly regulated, with legal services the most restrictive (ï¬?gure 2.21). Exclusive rights are reserved for lawyers in a majority of the countries. In addition to a law degree, practical experiences and professional examinations are also widely demanded. Concerning conduct regulation, only 2 countries of 22 allowed sole practitioners. Advertising by legal professionals is prohibited or regulated in most countries. There are six types of regimes to govern prices, ranging from minimum prices on some to all legal services, to maximum prices on some to all services. Some countries such as Luxembourg have actually tightened controls on professional services since 2003 (ï¬?gure 2.22). Implement the services directive The European Parliament and the Council adopted a directive on services in the internal market in 2006 (generally referred to as the “Services Directiveâ€?) to eliminate barriers to the “freedom to provide services within the communityâ€? and the “freedom of establishment.â€? It was designed to serve as a new legislative impetus for deeper integration. It has a relatively wide coverage.14 When the draft was proposed by the European Commission in January 2004, the Services Directive was regarded as ambitious and far-reaching.15 120 CHAPTER 2 Its expected beneï¬?ts were subjected to a number of assessments. Because of the wide scope of the Directive, particularly in its draft (not the ï¬?nal) form, these assessments serve as illustrative estimates of the potential gains of deeper integration of services. How big are the likely gains from homogenizing regulations and reducing regulatory barriers? Researchers have used two approaches to answering this question: evaluate the effects of proposed legislative reforms, and compare the single market with the internal market of benchmark countries. Both suggest that deeper integration through dismantling the regulatory barriers can yield signiï¬?cant trade gains. Kox and Lejour (2006) focus on other commercial services, excluding transportation and travel, to be close to the scope of the Services Directive. The assumption is that the Services Directive will be fully implemented. Explicit barriers to trade and direct investment are expected to be reduced substantially, while barriers to competition are only moderately reduced. Their results indicate that cross-border trade in commercial services in the European Union could increase by 30–60 percent, while the foreign direct investment stock in services might rise by 20–35 percent. Copenhagen Economics (2005) evaluates the effects of the Services Directive on trade in regulated professional and business services and distributive trade. The analysis indicates that the Services Directive will reduce the existing barriers to service provision by more than 50 percent. The direct policy impact—intra-EU trade enhancement—is between 1.0 and 9.4 percent for cross-border trade and between 1.3 and 2.7 percent for foreign direct investment, for the three sectors included. The analysis also predicts gains in employment and well-being. As highlighted by Monti (2010), however, poor implementation and poor enforcement of EU directives regulating the single market continue to hamper the realization of these gains. Improve the services trade among candidate and partner countries For the non-EU economies in Europe, the problems are more severe. Services exporters have trouble accessing the EU markets. They also have difï¬?culties accessing other nearby markets, as a recent World Bank report documents (box 2.10). Even the services traders in the former Yugoslavia—who have shared language and legislation for decades—now have trouble accessing regional markets. The typical barriers that exporters face relate to movement of natural persons (such as work permits for professionals and unskilled labor), licensing procedures (licenses issued in the home country are not recognized by the importing country), and recognition of professional skills and diplomas (qualiï¬?cations obtained in the home country are not recognized). The difï¬?culty of such barriers differs by activity: they present a signiï¬?cant obstacle to ï¬?rms and individuals in construction, transport, legal, and health sectors, but not for ICT ï¬?rms, banks, or telecommunications companies. For them, the agenda includes facilitation of trade in traditional services (construction, transportation, and travel) as well as attempts to revive trade in modern services with the economies of the European Union. 121 GOLDEN GROWTH The Common Agricultural Policy—cheap, but not worth it The European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has been subject to a lot of criticism for its wastefulness (it absorbs around one-third of the European Commission’s annual budget, costing about €50 billion annually), poor targeting of beneï¬?ts (larger farms in richer EU countries beneï¬?t more than small farms and poorer EU countries), and weakening of Europe’s position in international trade talks. Moreover, EU agricultural subsidies are contributing to maintaining the European Union’s position as a global net exporter of food, thereby discouraging the expansion of production in locations with much lower production costs and potentially contributing to higher global food prices as a result. The criticism is well founded but probably a little exaggerated. At least in money terms, the CAP is relatively cheap, and the policies have been improved over time to become less distortional. It has progressively focused on supporting rural development or ecological objectives, such as organic farming, and helping the European Union’s new members to comply with elaborate food safety regulations. And the European Union is the world’s largest importer of agricultural commodities from the world’s poorest countries, though this is because of special trade preference—despite the CAP, not because of it. But perhaps the biggest cost of the CAP to Europe is that it limits the opportunities resulting from economic integration with its eastern neighbors, which have among the largest underused land resources in the world. Ukraine has about 42 million hectares of land suited for agriculture, of which only 30 million hectares are actually used; by comparison, the United Kingdom, one of the world’s top 20 agricultural exporters in 2010, has a total of 12 million hectares. Between 1990 and 2000, the land under cultivation in Ukraine actually fell by about 2 million hectares as agricultural production decreased. About 30 percent of Ukraine’s workers are on farms that are quite efï¬?cient, other than Box 2.11: Ukraine would gain a lot if it could get freer access to the European Union’s agricultural market Ukraine’s exports in 2008 were about $70 percent to 5–15 percent, with the exception the European Union. A full liberalization of billion—about 36 percent of its GDP. The of sugar, for which the tariff was 80 percent cereals and processed food imports will give European Union is Ukraine’s largest export but has been reduced to 50 percent. Ukraine’s Ukraine immediate beneï¬?ts of more than $350 market, but its share has dropped from 40 wheat exports to the European Union face a million annually, or about 0.6 percent of GDP. percent in 2002 to 29 percent in 2008. The tariff of 10.5 percent, and its barley and maize Agricultural output and land use would rise by Russian Federation is the second-largest exports a tariff of about 6.5 percent. Sunflower about 6 percent, mainly to grow more wheat, export market, with a share constant at about seeds are not subject to a tax, but sunflower maize, and oilseeds. Ukrainian sunflower- and 24 percent. The combined share of Turkey, the oil faces a 6.5 percent tariff. However, the beet-processing industries would face more Arab Republic of Egypt, India, and Kazakhstan nature of EU import tariff calculations and competition from EU producers, but even has gone up from 7 percent to 17 percent. exemptions means that ad valorem tariff rates Ukraine is just 1 percent of the European fluctuate a lot. Again, observed tariffs on considering this, Ukraine would gain $200 Union’s (third party) imports. barley imports from Ukraine were 16 percent million each year. This is not a large amount, between 2003 and 2007, but have fallen to but the agricultural reforms that the trade Barley, wheat, maize, and sunflower seeds are might encourage would also bring Ukraine zero since. Ukraine’s main agricultural exports. In the ï¬?ve institutionally and economically closer to the years leading up to World Trade Organization A “deep and comprehensiveâ€? free trade European Union. accession in April 2008, Ukraine reduced agreement between Ukraine and the European import tariffs on most goods from 15–66 Union will help Ukraine a lot more than it will Source: Chauffour and others 2010. 122 CHAPTER 2 Box 2.12: (Not) extending the single market to the European Union’s eastern partners—the case of Georgia Messerlin and others (2011) argue that the · Bad commercial policy for the European markets in agriculture and services and European Commission’s current approach Union and Georgia. It would lead to an without EU aid. to trade with Georgia serves neither the expansion of the trade between Georgia European Union nor Georgia well. According to and non-EU countries. Georgian consumers The study’s conclusion: The European Union the analysis in the report, it is: would be induced to import what Georgian should not inadvertently discourage Georgia producers could no longer sell because of from continuing its successful domestic · Bad development policy for Georgia. It reforms. It should open negotiations with EU norms; and their low incomes would requires Georgia to adopt and implement Georgia without further delay since it has induce them to turn to imports from many imprecisely identiï¬?ed EU internal more than satisï¬?ed the relevant subset of non-EU sources that are less expensive market regulations that go beyond trade- preconditions. More broadly, a pro-growth than those from the European Union. To related matters, many of which do not DCFTA process would mean asking Georgia survive, producers who would not be able make sense for Georgia and other eastern to do things as and when its income reaches to sell their products any more on Georgian partners. The regulatory changes imposed markets under EU norms would sell them sensible thresholds. In general, the European on Georgia are equivalent to taxing to foreign markets not observing EU norms, Commission’s DCFTA doctrine should be made producers—endangering its growth and the thereby artiï¬?cially boosting Georgia’s clearer, coordinated better among EU agencies sustainability of its ï¬?ght against corruption, exports to non-EU countries. (since DCFTAs involve a lot more than trade), which is crucial for economic growth. The and adapted to the circumstances of the preconditions in sanitary and phytosanitary · Bad foreign policy for the European Union. partner. measures may double the price of many Preconditions are being imposed on a food products purchased by the third of country that is granted no EU membership Georgians who live in poverty. A better set perspective. They would make the EU deep of conditions would focus on infrastructure, and comprehensive free trade agreement which is probably the binding constraint for (DCFTA) partners appear like EU member growth in Georgia. states but without full access to the EU Source: Messerlin and others 2011. for beet sugar. The European Union is still Ukraine’s largest export market, but just barely. Its share has been falling during the last decade, as Central European countries that have joined the European Union replace Ukrainian farm products in the common market (box 2.11). The European Union, Russia, and Ukraine have accounted for more than 80 percent of Belarus’s exports over the last decade, and about 90 percent of imports. Russia’s share in Belarus’s exports has been declining—from 65 percent in 1998 to 32 percent in 2008—but its share in imports has been stable. During this time, the European Union’s share in overall exports has increased from 16 to 43 percent. Agricultural exports are a different story. While Russia’s share in agricultural exports has stayed between 83 and 93 percent during the last decade, the European Union’s share has fallen. For dairy products, one of Belarus’s main farm exports, the decline was from 48 percent in 2000 to almost zero in 2008 (World Bank 2009). Much of this decline may be the result of Belarus’s own sanitary and safety policies rather than the European Union’s demands, but the result is the same: the prospects for the 30 percent of Belarussians who depend on agriculture for a living remain poor. The European Union’s approach to Moldova shows how it can be done. Moldova is the most rural and agricultural economy in Europe. More than half of its population is rural, a third of its labor force is in farming, and agriculture accounts for about a ï¬?fth of GDP. Agricultural output is still about a third below its pretransition level. Perhaps helped by its small size—its trade is just 0.1 percent of the European Union’s trade—Moldova is doing better than Belarus and Ukraine in accessing the European Union’s single market for farm products. But the European Union’s share in its agricultural exports is just 123 GOLDEN GROWTH about 36 percent, about half of this due to the European Union’s enlargement and Moldova’s long-established trade with Romania and Poland. Moldova has one of the most liberal trade regimes among developing countries, but trade is hampered by a poor domestic environment for doing business and capacity shortfalls in meeting the European Union’s sanitary and quality standards. Moldova needs the European Union’s assistance, and will get it through a deep and comprehensive free trade agreement. If Moldova shows how the European Union’s trade policies should be designed, Georgia’s experience may well illustrate the opposite. Agriculture accounts for about half of Georgia’s labor force, and about a third of Georgians live below the poverty line. Farm exports could be a potent source of growth for Georgia, and the country is negotiating a deeper economic partnership with the European Union, with agricultural trade as a special focus. Messerlin and others (2011) point out that “Georgia’s own trade policy is more open towards the EU than vice versa, and Georgia has achieved governance reforms on a par with some of the old and new EU member statesâ€? (p. i). The European Commission is viewed as insisting on a difï¬?cult set of preconditions before negotiating, which it has not done for either Ukraine or neighbors in the southern Mediterranean. These may hurt Georgia’s poor, and not really improve Georgia’s growth prospects (box 2.12). Trade—the mainstay of the European model This chapter asks whether Europe is taking advantage of enlargement through trade in manufactures, services, and agricultural products. The short answer is that it is doing so for industrial goods and traditional services, but it could do a lot better for modern services and agricultural produce. Trade in industrial goods has spread most quickly, not just to the European Union’s new members but also to European Free Trade Association economies such as Switzerland, candidate countries such as Turkey, eastern partnership nations such as Ukraine, and even nations further aï¬?eld such as Russia. Trade in agricultural goods has grown in the European Union and with the candidate countries, but it has not grown as much with the eastern partnership. The trade in modern services has increased mostly just within the European Union. In reaching this conclusion, this chapter tried to answer three questions. First, is “Factory Europeâ€? as dynamic as “Factory Asiaâ€?? Yes, but in ways that are quite different. Factory Europe is growing bigger, but more noticeably it is getting smarter. Spurred by the need to compete globally, industrialists in Austria, France, Germany, Sweden, and other advanced countries are offshoring activities to their cheaper, less developed neighbors. These activities—and the goods trade between emerging and developed Europe—have been becoming more sophisticated, as Western Europe transfers progressively tougher tasks to countries in Central, Southern, and Eastern Europe. The beneï¬?ts extend not just to the new member states of the European Union such as the Czech Republic and Estonia, but also to the EU candidates such as Serbia and Turkey, and even the eastern partners such as Georgia and Ukraine. EU enlargement has had a limited effect on the size of Factory Europe, but it has changed its conï¬?guration. Enlargement has led to an increase in Factory 124 CHAPTER 2 Europe’s complexity. The European Union’s internal trade in intermediate goods has become more sophisticated and has been using more relationship-speciï¬?c inputs. Factory Europe has become brainier. New members’ exports embody more complex and more time-sensitive relationships. As this trade has become bigger and more sophisticated, their trade facilities—ports, airports, customs regimes, and ICT infrastructure—have become strained. In particular, reducing infrastructural deï¬?cits in ICT is likely to result in sizable trade gains. Second, is the Single Market for Services underachieving compared with North America? The answer is that for traditional services, such as travel and construction, it is not. But it is for modern services such as communication, insurance, ï¬?nance, computers and information, royalties and license fees, and other business services—with the notable exception of banking. Technology has made them more productive and tradable. As in the rest of the world, European economic growth is increasingly composed of services. Services dominate growth in EU15 countries and, to less extent, in the new member states and candidate and partner countries. Within the European Union, trade in modern services is growing. But outside—in the Balkans and the eastern partnership—trade in modern services has stagnated. An educated estimate is that with the right policy measures, the trade in services can double in value within the decade, and possibly even triple. But for this to happen, the trade in modern services must be greatly facilitated. Ideally, services exporters should have to satisfy product market regulations in just one (current or aspiring) member state. Ideally, the qualiï¬?cations of professionals should be certiï¬?ed in just one country. Ideally, at least within the European Union, the movement of natural persons should be unfettered. For all these reasons, the single market is not likely to become as uniï¬?ed a market for services as those in the United States or Canada in the foreseeable future. But with appropriate changes in product market regulations, vendors of digitally tradable services might soon be able to treat Europe as a single market. Third, is the Common Agricultural Policy compromising Europe’s credibility in global trade talks? The European Union has followed increasingly enlightened trade policies toward the least developed countries of the world. But the European Union’s agricultural policies are hobbling its efforts to extend the beneï¬?ts of the single market closer to home—especially to eastern partners such as Georgia and Ukraine. The Common Agricultural Policy is popular among EU citizens, who appear to believe that 33 eurocents a day is a small price to pay for maintaining the livelihoods of the 15 million farmers and farmworkers in the European Union. In the eastern partnership countries—Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Moldova, and Ukraine—this number may be even more, because more than a third of their people depend on agriculture. The European Union is missing the opportunity to improve their lives, and win the hearts and minds of 75 million eastern partners. Increasing the trade in modern services is not easy because it requires improving and harmonizing regulations, in both exporting and importing countries. Addressing these barriers will require a consensus and measures to reassure skeptical consumers and workers (Monti 2010). Large gains may 125 GOLDEN GROWTH be had in noncontroversial areas such as digital trade. Between 1998 and 2003, many countries in Europe showed that product markets can be made more competitive. The momentum for market regulation was lost during the boom years between 2004 and 2008. Now it should be regained. As chapter 3 discusses, Europe has shown that trade in one modern service—banking—can grow quickly and contribute to economic growth. Answers to questions on page 87 Factory Asia is growing faster, but goods trade in Europe is more sophisticated. The single market is working quite well for traditional services such as travel and transport, but it is underperforming in modern services such as insurance, information technology, and other business services. The European Union’s agricultural policies h bbl Th E U i ’ i lt l li i hobble the extension of the single market to its neighbors, and Europe is missing an opportunity to improve the lives of 75 million people in the eastern partnership countries. 126 CHAPTER 2 Notes 1 By this measure, Turkey’s exports are more 5 Romania (28 percent) and Bulgaria (13 13 Eschenbach and Hoekman (2006) propose than ten times those of the next biggest percent) had the biggest rises. The RSI that countries in Eastern and Central Europe exporter in this category (Romania), which measure appears to capture the effects of that undertook productivity-enhancing in turn are much bigger than the third- deeper integration beyond a customs union. service reforms, such as reforms of ï¬?nancial biggest. Turkey’s car exports more than and infrastructure services, have attracted tripled, and its share went from 0.7 to 6.7 6 The sample consists of Albania, Croatia, the more FDI and had higher economic growth. percent. Entry into the customs unions in former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Fernandes (2009) conï¬?rms this, and shows 1996 may have had a lot to do with this. For Montenegro, and Turkey. that the large service productivity gap the other countries, cars are a small part of between the EU15 and the new member exports and unimportant for the region’s car 7 Other factors compound the estimation problems. Characteristics of third countries states is shrinking as the latter catch up. trade. may determine bilateral trade flows, similar Moreover, this effect is stronger the further 2 This measure divides by GDP to control to the trade in goods (Anderson 1979). an activity is from the technological frontier, for total output (supply capacity), but The formation of a Free Trade Agreement suggesting that liberalization of services can within-region calculations arguably should may target existing policy issues between speed catch-up. be divided by the square of GDP to account countries that are hard to observe (Baier for total demand as well. Doing so does not 14 The Services Directive excludes ï¬?nancial and Bergstrand 2007). Taking advantage services, electronic communications affect the main conclusions. of panel data, recent studies are able to services, most transport services, health mitigate the influence of these and other care, services provided by temporary 3 Data issues preclude ï¬?rm conclusions, unobserved factors. however. Numerous studies, using different work agencies, private security services, time periods, and with different sectoral and 8 Previous studies are based on shorter audiovisual services, gambling, certain different country focuses, come to varying time series, which restricts the choices social services provided by the state, and conclusions. Hummels, Ishii, and Li (2001) of methodology, and the results are less services provided by notaries and bailiffs. report a declining share in intermediates consistent. See, for example, Ceglowski trade in OECD countries between 1970 and 15 The draft was more ambitious than the (2006) and Walsh (2006 and 2008). Directive that was ï¬?nally issued. Most 1992, while Yeats (2001) reports an increase. 9 The wide range of the estimate is mainly important, the draft proposed the “country Miroudot, Lanz, and Ragoussis (2009), and due to the poor quality of data for services of originâ€? principle, which was dropped from Curran and Zignago (2009) ï¬?nd constant trade. Data availability changes over the the ï¬?nal directive. shares of intermediates in total trade in OECD countries and Europe respectively years, and the match between credit and since 1995. Baldwin and Venables (2011) debit data is poor. question the reliability of trade data and prefer ï¬?rm-based analyses. Firm-level 10 Straathof and others (2008) study the effect for goods and for services and ï¬?nd a single data show increasing fragmentation of market effect of some 30 percent for trade production among German and Austrian in goods, but only 10 percent for cross- companies as they outsource production border trade in services. Trade in goods toward the new member states, but micro within the European Union is about 30–60 studies for other Western European ï¬?rms percent higher than trade with or between are few. Halpern, Koren, and Szeidl (2011) third countries (see Fidrmuc and Fidrmuc show that Hungarian ï¬?rms have increased 2003, Lejour, Solanic, and Tang 2006, the import of intermediates, but the source Baldwin and Rieder 2007). of these imports cannot be ascertained in their analysis. 11 Hausmann, Hwang, and Rodrik (2007) have proposed that it is not just specialization but 4 Martínez-Zarzoso, Voicu, and Vidovic also the sophistication of exports of goods (2011) also ï¬?nd a rise in the variety of that matters for growth. To examine this intermediates exported from six Central phenomenon for service exports, Mishra, and Eastern European countries to the Lundstrom, and Anand (2011) propose an European Union at the same time as a fall analogous index for studying service export in the varieties exported to non-EU OECD sophistication. In a background paper for countries. But for imports, the results are this report, Lundstrom Gable and Mishra not the same. They ï¬?nd a rise in the variety (2011) show how different parts of Europe of imports in these six countries from the are faring in the services trade. European Union at the same time as there is a fall in the variety of imports from non-EU 12 Kandilov and Grennes (2010) argue that for OECD countries. some types of services and destinations, Central and Eastern Europe are effective competitors for Asia. 127 GOLDEN GROWTH References Anderson, J. 1979. “A Theoretical Foundation Conway, P., and G. Nicoletti. 2006. for the Gravity Equation.â€? The American “Product Market Regulation in the Non- Economic Review 69 (1): 106–116. Manufacturing Sectors of OECD Countries: Arnold, J., B. Javorcik, and A. Mattoo. 2011. Measurement and Highlights.â€? OECD “Does Services Liberalization Beneï¬?t Economics Department Working Papers Manufacturing Firms? Evidence from the 530, OECD, Paris. Czech Republic.â€? Journal of International Copenhagen Economics. 2005. “Economic Economics 85 (1): 136–146. Assessment of the Barriers to the Internal Baier, S., and J. Bergstrand. 2007. “Do Market for Services.â€? Report prepared Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase for the Enterprise Directorate-General, Members’ International Trade?â€? Journal of European Commission, Copenhagen International Economics 71 (1): 72–95. Economics, Copenhagen. Baumol, W. 1986 “Productivity Growth, Curran, L., and S. Zignago. 2009. Convergence, and Welfare: What the Long- “Evolution of EU and Its Member States’ Run Data Show.â€? The American Economic Competitiveness in International Trade.â€? Review 76 (5): 1072–1085. CEPII Working Paper 2009-11, Centre d’Études Prospectives et d’Informations Baldwin, R. 2008. “Managing the Internationales, Paris. Noodle Bowl: The Fragility of East Asian Regionalism.â€? The Singapore Economic Dixit, A., and J. Stiglitz. 1977. “Monopolistic Review 53 (3): 449–478. Competition and Optimum Product Diversity.â€? The American Economic Review Baldwin, R., and A. Venables. 2011. 67 (3): 297–308. “Relocating the Value Chain: Off-shoring and Agglomeration in the Global Economy.â€? Dutta, S., and I. Mia, ed. 2011. The Global Department of Economics Discussion Paper Information Technology Report 2010–2011: 544, University of Oxford, Oxford. Transformation 2.0. Geneva: WEF. Baldwin, R., and R. Rieder. 2007. “A Test of Eschenbach, F., and B. Hoekman. 2006. Endogenous Trade Bloc Formation Theory “Services Policy Reform and Economic on EU Data.â€? CEPR Discussion Paper 6389, Growth in Transition Economies.â€? Review of Centre for Economic Policy Research, World Economics 142 (4): 746–764. London. European Commission. 2002. “The State of Baumol, W. 1986. “Productivity Growth, the Internal Market for Services.â€? Report Convergence, and Welfare: What the Long- from the Commission to the Council and the Run Data Show.â€? The American Economic European Parliament, prepared under the Review 76 (5): 1072–1085. ï¬?rst stage of the Internal Market Strategy for Services, COM(2002) 441, European Behar, A., and C. Freund. 2011. “Factory Commission, Brussels. Europe? Brainier but Not Brawnier.â€? FREIT Working Paper 312, Forum for Research in European Commission. 2010. “The Western Empirical International Trade. Background Balkan Countries on the Road to the paper for this report. European Union.â€? Available at ec.europa. eu/enlargement/enlargement_process/ Ceglowski, J. 2006. “Does Gravity Matter accession_process/how_does_a_country_ in a Service Economy?â€? Review of World join_the_eu/sap/history_en.htm. Accessed Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv) 142 December 24, 2011. (2): 307–329. Feenstra, R., J. Markusen, and W. Zeile. 1992. Chauffour, J.-P., M. Ivanic, D. Laborde, “Accounting for Growth with New Inputs: M. Maliszewska, and W. Martin. 2010. Theory and Evidence.â€? The American “Impact of a Free Trade Agreement Economic Review 82 (2): 415–421. between Ukraine and the European Union on Ukraine’s Agricultural Sector.â€? Paper Fernandes, A. 2009. “Structure and presented at the 14th Annual Conference Performance of the Service Sector in on Global Economic Analysis, “Governing Transition Economies.â€? Economics of Global Challenges: Climate Change, Trade, Transition 17 (3): 467–501. Finance and Development,â€? June 16–18, Fidrmuc, J., and J. Fidrmuc. 2003. 2011, Venice. “Disintegration and Trade.â€? Review of International Economics 11 (5): 811–829. 128 CHAPTER 2 Fink, C. 2009. “Has the EU’s Single Market Inklaar, R., M. Timmer, and B. van Ark. 2007. Lundstrom Gable, S., and S. Mishra. Program Led to Deeper Integration of EU “Mind the Gap! International Comparisons 2011. “Service Export Sophistication and Services Markets?â€? GEM Working Paper July of Productivity in Services and Goods Europe’s New Growth Model.â€? Policy 2009, Groupe d’Economie Mondiale, Paris. Production.â€? German Economic Review 8 Research Working Paper 5793, World Bank, Francois, J., and B. Hoekman. 2010. (2): 281–307. Washington, DC. Background paper for this “Services Trade and Policy.â€? Journal of Jones, R., and H. Kierzkowski. 2005. report. Economic Literature 48 (3): 642–692. “International Trade and Agglomeration: Marin, D. 2010a. “The Opening Up of Eastern Francois, J., O. Pindyuk, and J. Woerz. 2009. An Alternative Framework.â€? In Growth, Europe at 20—Jobs, Skills, and ‘Reverse “Trends in International Trade and FDI in Trade, and Economic Institutions, ed. T. Maquiladoras’ in Austria and Germany.â€? Services.â€? IIDE Discussion Paper 200908-02, Palokangas, B. Jensen, D. Bös, G. Corneo, Bruegel Working Paper 2010/02, Bruegel, Institute for International and Development R. Hjerppe, and J. Honkatukia: 1–16. Journal Brussels. Economics, Rotterdam. of Economics, Supplement 10. Vienna: Marin, D. 2010b. “Germany’s Super Springer. Competitiveness: A Helping Hand from Frankel, J., and D. Romer. 1999. “Does Trade Cause Growth?â€? The American Economic Kaminski, B., and F. Ng. 2005. “Production Eastern Europe.â€? VoxEU.org, June 20. Review 89 (3): 379–399. Disintegration and Integration of Central Available at www.voxeu.org/index. Europe into Global Markets.â€? International php?q=node/5212. Accessed December 30, Gill, I., and H. Kharas. 2007. An East Asian Review of Economics and Finance 14 (3): 2011. Renaissance: Ideas for Economic Growth. 377–390. Martínez-Zarzoso, I., A. Voicu, and M. With D. Bhattasali, M. Brahmbhatt, G. Datt, M. Haddad, E. Mountï¬?eld, R. Tatucu, Kandilov, I., and T. Grennes. 2010. “The Vidovic. 2011. “CEECs Integration into E. Vostroknutova. Washington, DC: World Determinants of Service Exports from Regional and Global Production Networks.â€? Bank. Central and Eastern Europe.â€? Economics of CEGE Discussion Papers 125, Center for Transition 18 (4): 763–794. European, Governance and Economic Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. 1991. Kimura, F., Y. Takahashi, and K. Hayakawa. Development Research, University of Innovation and Growth in the Global 2007. “Fragmentation and Parts and Göttingen, Göttingen. Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Components Trade: Comparison between Messerlin, P., M. Emerson, G. Jandieri, Halpern, L., M. Koren, and A. Szeidl. 2011. East Asia and Europe.â€? The North American and A. Le Vernoy. 2011. An Appraisal of “Imported Inputs and Productivity.â€? CeFiG Journal of Economics and Finance 18 (1): the EU’s Trade Policy towards Its Eastern Working Paper 8, Center for Firms in the 23–40. Neighbours: The Case of Georgia. Brussels: Global Economy, Budapest. Kox, H., and A. Lejour. 2005. “Regulatory Centre for European Policy Studies. Handjiski, B., and L. Å estović. 2011. Barriers Heterogeneity as Obstacle for International Miroudot, S., R. Lanz, and A. Ragoussis. to Trade in Services in the CEFTA Region. Services Trade.â€? CPB Discussion Paper 49, 2009. “Trade in Intermediate Goods and Washington, DC: World Bank. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Services.â€? OECD Trade Policy Working Paper Hansen, T. 2010. “Tariff Rates, Offshoring Policy Analysis, The Hague. 93, OECD, Paris. and Productivity: Evidence from German Kox, H., and A. Lejour. 2006. “The Effects of Mirza, D., and G. Nicoletti. 2004. “What is and Austrian Firm-Level Data.â€? Munich the Services Directive on Intra-EU Trade and So Special about Trade in Services?â€? GEP Discussion Paper 2010-21, Department of FDI.â€? Revue économique 57 (4): 747–769. Research Paper 2004/02, Leverhulme Economics, University of Munich, Munich. Kox, H., and A. Lejour. 2007. “Trade in Centre for Research on Globalisation and Hausmann, R., J. Hwang, and D. Rodrik. Economic Policy, University of Nottingham, Services and the Dissimilarity in Domestic 2007. “What You Export Matters.â€? Journal of Nottingham. Regulation.â€? Updated version of Kox and Economic Growth 12 (1): 1–25. Lejour, 2005. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Mishra, S., S. Lundstrom, and R. Anand. HM Government. 2011. “Let’s Choose Economic Policy Analysis, The Hague. 2011. “Service Export Sophistication and Growth: Why We Need Reform to Unlock Economic Growth.â€? Policy Research Working Ledgard, J. 2005. “Škoda Leaps to Market.â€? Europe’s Potential.â€? Pamphlet prepared by Paper 5606, World Bank, Washington, DC. Strategy+business, Issue 40, Autumn. the British Prime Minister’s Ofï¬?ce, March, Lejour, A., and J.-W. de Paiva Verheijden. Monti, M. 2010. “A New Strategy for the HM Government, London. 2007. “The Tradability of Services within Single Market: At the Service of Europe’s Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K.-M. Yi. 2001. Economy and Society.â€? Report to the Canada and the European Union.â€? The “The Nature and Growth of Vertical President of the European Commission, May Service Industries Journal 27 (4): 389–409. Specialization in World Trade.â€? Journal of 9, European Commission, Brussels. International Economics 54 (1): 75–96. Lejour, A., V. Solanic, and P. Tang. 2006. “EU Accession and Income Growth: An Empirical Nicoletti, G., S. Golub, D. Hajkova, D. IMD (International Institute for Mirza, and K.-Y. Yoo. 2003. “The Influence Approach.â€? CPB Discussion Paper 72, CPB Management Development). 2010. IMD of Policies on Trade and Foreign Direct Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy World Competitiveness Yearbook 2010. Investment.â€? OECD Economic Studies 2003 Analysis, The Hague. Lausanne: IMD. (36): 7–83. 129 GOLDEN GROWTH Nunn, N. 2007. “Relationship-Speciï¬?city, Watson, N. 2010. “Car Industry: Incomplete Contracts, and the Pattern of Manufacturers in a Drive Forward at Trade.â€? The Quarterly Journal of Economics Expense of West.â€? Financial Times, 122 (2): 569–600. November 29. OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- Wilson, J., X. Luo, and H. Broadman. 2010. operation and Development). 2007. OECD “European Accession and the Trade Economic Surveys: European Union 2007. Facilitation Agenda.â€? Journal of International Paris: OECD. Commerce, Economics and Policy 1 (2): OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- 227–249. operation and Development). 2011. “Product World Bank. 2009. “Belarus – Agricultural Market Regulation Database.â€? OECD, Paris. Productivity and Competitiveness: Impact Available at www.oecd.org/economy/pmr. of State Support and Market Intervention.â€? Accessed May 20, 2011. World Bank Report 48335-BY. World Bank, Rauch, J. 1999. “Networks versus Markets in Washington, DC. International Trade.â€? Journal of International WTO (World Trade Organization). 2009a. Economics 48 (1): 7–35. International Trade Statistics 2009. Geneva: Rhys, G. 2004. “The Motor Industry in an WTO. Enlarged EU.â€? The World Economy 27 (6): WTO (World Trade Organization). 877–900. 2009b. “Trade Policy Review: European Romer, P. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Communities.â€? Record of the Meeting – Change.â€? Journal of Political Economy 98 (5, Addendum, April 6 and 8, Geneva. Available Part 2): S71–S102. at www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tpr_e/ tp314_e.htm. Accessed December 30, 2011. Schwab, E., ed. 2011. The Global Competitiveness Report 2011–2012. Geneva: Yeats, A. 2001. “Just How Big is Global WEF. Production Sharing?â€? In Fragmentation: New Production Patterns in the World Å koda Auto. 2010. Å koda Auto Annual Economy, ed. S. Arndt, and H. Kierzkowski: Report 2009. Mladá Boleslav: Å koda Auto. 108–143. New York, NY: Oxford University Straathof, B., G.-J. Linders, A. Lejour, and J. Press. Möhlmann. 2008. “The Internal Market and the Dutch Economy: Implications for Trade and Economic Growth.â€? CPB Document 168, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, The Hague. Tempest, R. 1996. “Barbie and the World Economy.â€? Los Angeles Times, September 22. UN (United Nations). 2011. Manual on Statistics of International Trade in Services 2010. New York, NY: UN. Volkswagen. 2009. Volkswagen AG Annual Report 2008. Wolfsburg: Volkswagen AG. Walsh, K. 2006. “Trade in Services: Does Gravity Hold? A Gravity Model Approach to Estimating Barriers to Services Trade.â€? IIIS Discussion Paper 183, Institute for International Integration Studies, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin. Walsh, K. 2008. “Trade in Services: Does Gravity Hold?â€? Journal of World Trade 42 (2): 315–334. 130 CHAPTER 3 Chapter 3 Finance In the boom years leading up to the ï¬?nancial crisis of 2008–09, Western European banks moved aggressively into emerging Europe.1 Austrian, Italian, and Swedish banks were especially active; Belgian, French, and Greek banks a little less. Almost 80 percent of the banking sector in some countries that looked to Europe for trade and ï¬?nance—such as Bulgaria, Croatia, the Czech Republic, and FYR Macedonia—were foreign-owned. It was big business. In 2007, Austria’s Raiffeisen and Erste banks had, directly or through their subsidiaries, about $300 billion in assets in emerging Europe, equivalent to almost 80 percent of the country’s gross domestic product (GDP). A ï¬?fth of the loans of Sweden’s biggest bank, Swedbank, were to customers in the Baltics. Italy’s massive Unicredit Group had the biggest stake in the banking systems of Central and Southeastern Europe, spanning 17 countries. Belgium’s KBC and France’s Société Générale were also active. Greek banks came a bit late but, on the eve of the crisis, Alpha, National Bank of Greece, and Piraeus Bank held sizable stakes in the Balkans. By mid-2009, many economists viewed this eastern expansion as a big mistake. Analysts who had covered crises in East Asia and Latin America saw emerging European economies as bubbles. Fears were rife that Western Europe’s banks would walk away from these subsidiaries, leaving inexperienced regulators to clean up the mess. Experts put out assessments viewing the close ties with foreign ï¬?nance as the result of policies that were inadequate to offset the misfortune of being too close to Western Europe. Few pundits felt that this ï¬?nancial integration might have been good for growth or to Eastern Europe’s advantage to be near—physically and ï¬?nancially—a developed system of banks, or even that some of these savings-starved countries had instituted policies good enough to get the best from Western European ï¬?nance. A massive pullout was expected. Why is ï¬?nance in emerging Europe different from other regions? How did some European economies beneï¬?t more from international ï¬?nancial flows than others? Is there evidence of a “debt overhangâ€? in emerging Europe that reduces growth and justiï¬?es government intervention? 131 GOLDEN GROWTH It did not happen. These banks have all stayed, tolerating big losses in 2009 as incomes fell and bad debts mounted. Swedbank’s Baltic Banking Unit cut its staff by a third and reported losses of about $200 million in the ï¬?rst quarter of 2010. Unicredit and Raiffeisen also suffered big losses. But by late 2010, Raiffeisen’s quarterly proï¬?ts in the region had risen to $500 million and Swedbank was generating proï¬?ts from its Baltic business. Today, Eastern Europe accounts for about a tenth of the portfolios and proï¬?ts of Unicredit, Raiffeisen, Erste, Swedbank, and SEB. The head of Raiffeisen Bank International expects Western European banks to stay and grow in Eastern Europe: “The region still has a lot of catching up to do to reach the economic level of Western Europe. We will continue to beneï¬?t from this process at least in the next one and a half to two generationsâ€? (Hansen 2010). This chapter asks and answers the question: Has ï¬?nancial integration in Europe happened too fast? The answer is a qualiï¬?ed no. The chapter shows that ï¬?nance in Europe has an enviable and unique feature—that capital flows downhill, as economic textbooks argue it should. Financial flows of all types go from richer, slower-growth countries to less developed fast growers. This close integration of the wealthy and the dynamic is an underappreciated attribute of the European economic model. The answer is qualiï¬?ed because emerging Europe, by being integrated, is now vulnerable to the consequences of prolonged uncertainty and potential ï¬?nancial deleveraging in the eurozone, and because ï¬?nancial integration in a few countries led to excesses and misallocation of resources. The chapter discusses how the risks can be better managed going forward. Three questions follow. · Why is emerging Europe different from other regions such as East Asia and Latin America? The answer lies in the powerful pull of accession to the European Union. The implication is that the closer a country gets to the European Union in its policies and institutions, the more it stands to beneï¬?t from ï¬?nancial integration. Perhaps the expectation of stronger institutions sufï¬?ces to spur economic growth. · What helped some European economies—such as the Czech Republic, FYR Macedonia, Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Turkey—get more out of the largest international ï¬?nancial flows in history than others during the years preceding the crisis? The main lesson is that external imbalances have to be managed, not eliminated. A blend of conservative economic policies—including cyclically sensitive ï¬?scal and macroprudential policies for managing systemic risk—will help to keep growth sustainable. Policymakers should do what they can to “boom-proofâ€? public ï¬?nance and “crisis-proofâ€? private ï¬?nance. · In other countries that did not manage these flows as well, is there evidence of a “debt overhangâ€? that justiï¬?es government intervention? Evidence in this chapter should persuade the reader that, for the most part, economies in emerging Europe are both liquid and solvent, and that treasuries, enterprises, and households are not facing a debt overhang that could become a drag on activity. Some banking sectors in emerging Europe 132 CHAPTER 3 might well face challenging times ahead. But the dependence on foreign banks has so far been a blessing as banking flows to the region have been remarkably stable. There are risks, but these originate primarily in the dependence on Western European banks that have large exposures in some EU cohesion countries, such as Greece, from where trouble could easily spill over into emerging Europe. Thus, the chapter concludes, foreign capital is an enviable development opportunity integral to Europe’s income-convergence engine. This strong conclusion comes with three caveats. First, it is based on an analysis of emerging Europe’s experience over the past decade. The chapter contrasts the experience of the “EU cohesion countriesâ€? (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain) with developments in emerging Europe. It does not analyze the experience of the cohesion countries in detail. However, as later chapters show, heavy regulatory barriers and an overextended public sector are more likely candidates to account for the woes of Europe’s south today. Second, the chapter suggests that the closeness to Western European ï¬?nance led in some cases to excesses. Therefore, external imbalances need to be managed to avoid a buildup of vulnerabilities, and the chapter provides some guidance on how to do so. To recover quickly and manage the next boom, policymakers must clearheadedly assess what led to the misuse of proximity to Western European ï¬?nance—and strengthen their preemptive and prudential arsenal. But managing external imbalances is not the same as self-insurance. Indeed, the latter is not the lesson policymakers in Europe should take away from the crises: Europe’s emerging economies should not “become Asian.â€? Third, the balance sheets of banks in Western Europe are strained by the sovereign debt problems faced in the eurozone. Since many of these banks are active in emerging Europe, they could be forced to deleverage from noncore markets; addressing the problems in the eurozone is thus crucial for all of Europe. Europe is unique Worldwide, ï¬?nancial integration progressed rapidly from the late 1990s. The sum of foreign assets and liabilities as a share of GDP—the ï¬?nancial equivalent of trade openness indicators—increased greatly. But the rise was not uniform. There is sharp widening of the interquartile range (the gap between the top and bottom 25 percent of the distribution) in some of the country groups (ï¬?gure 3.1). Europe stands out as a region that experienced a deepening in ï¬?nancial integration, in particular the EU cohesion countries (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain) and the EU12 and EU candidate countries. Among emerging markets and the EU eastern partnership the increase is less steep. Financial flows in Europe are different The types of capital that emerging Europe received are different. Foreign direct investment (FDI) was higher than in other emerging markets (ï¬?gure 3.2). Banking and other flows, which recorded a sharp increase in the EU12 and EU candidate countries in 2005–08 relative to the preceding four-year period, also played a key role. To a lesser degree, this is also the case in the EU eastern partnership. Intracompany debt-creating flows from parent corporations and 133 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.1: Fifteen years of ï¬?nancial integration show that Europe is different (percentage of GDP) Note: Financial integration is measured as foreign assets plus liabilities. The interquartile range reflects the region between the top and bottom 25 percent of the distribution among the countries in the group. Source: Updated and extended version of dataset constructed by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2007. Figure 3.2: Capital flows in emerging Europe are particularly large (percentage of GDP; period average of group median values) Note: “EU coh.â€? refers to the EU cohesion countries, “EU cand.â€? refers to EU candidate countries, “E. prtn.â€? refers to EU eastern partnership countries, “LACâ€? refers to the Latin America and the Caribbean region. CA stands for current account and FX is foreign exchange. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. banks in Western Europe to their subsidiaries in emerging Europe have FDI-like features: this type of capital flow (referred to in this chapter as ï¬?nancial FDI) combines the risk-sharing features of FDI and the lower costs of debt ï¬?nancing. Another feature of emerging Europe is the role of foreign banks in corporate governance. Western European banks increasingly dominated credit in emerging European countries and weakened the link between governments and the enterprise sector. Failure to do so earlier had resulted in a history of quasi-ï¬?scal bailouts during the 1990s. In the new member states of the European Union, the share of foreign ownership in banking system assets (through both branches and subsidiaries) increased early in the decade and today accounts for over 80 percent of total banking system assets (ï¬?gure 3.3). The EU candidate countries 134 CHAPTER 3 EU12 EU candidates Figure 3.3: Foreign banks are 80 emerging Europe’s unique feature 60 (percentage of banking system assets, median values) 40 20 0 1997 2001 2005 2009 1997 2001 2005 2009 Eastern partnership East Asia and Latin America 80 60 40 20 0 1997 2001 2005 2009 1997 2001 2005 2009 Source: Claessens and van Horen 2012. followed the same path with some delay, but today foreign banks hold close to 80 percent of total banking system assets. Foreign banks are less dominant among the EU eastern partnership countries.2 Capital flows in the right direction in Europe Economic theory posits that because poor countries have low capital-labor ratios they should also have high expected rates of return to capital, making investment more attractive. Poor countries also typically save less. This mix—high investment, low savings—should lead to large current account deï¬?cits (capital inflows from abroad are just their mirror image). Yet, for most of the developing world, the evidence that capital flows downhill is limited (Lucas 1990). Three explanations are possible for this lack of absorption of foreign capital. First, the policy framework of recipient countries does not always support the absorption of foreign savings. Countries like China, for instance, accumulate foreign exchange reserves to prevent an appreciation of the real exchange rate.3 Second, the experience of some emerging markets with capital account crises and sharp reversals in external imbalances and growth might lead to more cautious economic policies, such as the self-insurance policies of some East Asian and Latin American countries after the crises of the late 1990s. Third, differences in risk-adjusted returns to capital and low total factor productivity might also constrain the absorption of foreign capital. In other words, the quality of economic policies and institutions might affect the returns to capital. Whatever the reason, just being poor or rich is not enough to explain the direction of capital flows. Surprisingly, capital does not flow to high-growth countries either.4 High growth reflects actual marginal productivity and should therefore lead to an increase in capital flows to those countries that have higher 135 GOLDEN GROWTH growth rates—and thus higher productivity. But this is not the case in most developing regions. The exception is Europe, where foreign capital appears to flow toward poorer countries (ï¬?gure 3.4)5 and those with higher growth rates (ï¬?gure 3.5, left panel).6 But classifying countries in line with their political proximity to the European Union (EU12, EU candidates, and EU eastern partnership) suggests that there is also signiï¬?cant heterogeneity among those countries. Capital has flowed to high-growth countries in the ï¬?rst two groups, but in the less integrated EU eastern partnership countries, the pattern is similar to that of other emerging markets (ï¬?gure 3.5, right panel). In Europe, ï¬?nance supports growth—and more so the closer countries get to the EU It is then worth asking: Why is Europe different? The answer lies in the model of economic convergence—how poorer countries are provided with the instruments for catching up to their richer neighbors. Classifying countries in line with their political proximity to the EU (EU12, EU candidates, EU eastern partnership countries) proves to be instructive.7 Figure 3.4: In Europe, capital flows to countries with lower incomes Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. Figure 3.5: In Europe, capital also flows to high-growth countries (current account deï¬?cits and per capita income growth, 1997–2008) Note: Average values calculated using 3 four-year periods in 1997-2008 are shown. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. 136 CHAPTER 3 To draw lessons from emerging Europe’s ï¬?nancial integration experience and its links to growth, it is necessary to understand the role of foreign savings, which provide a composite measure of net foreign capital flowing into a country. The empirical work in this section draws on Stojkov and Zalduendo (2011) which shows that foreign savings support growth in many—but not all—emerging European countries (table A3.1). The varying strength in the relationship between the EU12 countries and EU candidate countries reflects a combination of early EU accession and faster transition to a market economy. And, countries where EU membership prospects are still distant—the EU eastern partnership— behave much like emerging markets outside Europe. So far, foreign savings have not supported their growth. How can the foreign savings-growth link be explained? The evidence shows that foreign savings in the EU12 and EU candidate countries seem to have enabled the pursuit of investment opportunities that would otherwise have remained unfunded. Emerging Europe experienced a notable rise in investment as external imbalances increased in the decade before the crisis (ï¬?gure 3.6). Adding investment as an explanatory variable makes the EU-speciï¬?c foreign savings and growth link no longer important. Including savings, however, does not have such an effect among the EU12 and EU candidate countries. In contrast with results from a range of other developing economies (for example, Figure 3.6: Investments rose strongly in Europe as external balances improved (saving-investment balances, unweighted averages as percentage of GDP, 1993–2008) Note: The averages are not presented for some years in the early 1990s because at least one observation is missing. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO; and WDI. 137 GOLDEN GROWTH Aizenman, Pinto, and Radziwill 2007), foreign savings do not seem to substitute for domestic savings in some of the countries in emerging Europe. For countries in or close to the European Union, investment is no longer resource-constrained. The European Union as a “Tractor Beamâ€? There is no doubt that ï¬?nancial intermediation is crucial for foreign savings to support growth. Households borrow from future income streams for consumption smoothing and ï¬?rms borrow to pursue investment opportunities. In either case, the ï¬?nancial system needs to intermediate the foreign ï¬?nancing that makes consumption smoothing and investment possible. Two alternative explanations exist as to what makes ï¬?nancial intermediation effective. One relates to “thresholds in ï¬?nancial developmentâ€? that improve the flow and quality of information and enhance a country’s absorptive capacity (Blanchard and Giavazzi 2002). Another relates to “ï¬?nancial frictionsâ€? and how they affect intermediation. These frictions are, in turn, linked to the institutional development of individual countries. Both insufï¬?cient ï¬?nancial development and weak institutions can reduce absorption and cause capital inflows to boost unsustainable private and public consumption or asset-price bubbles that weaken the link to growth.8 To examine why the EU12 and the candidate countries have largely avoided these drawbacks, indicators of ï¬?nancial and institutional development are added by Stojkov and Zalduendo (2011) to a growth equation to explore their impact on the underlying foreign savings–growth link among EU-speciï¬?c country groups.9 The results suggest that there are EU-speciï¬?c factors at play. The importance and magnitude of the EU-speciï¬?c foreign savings interaction remain unchanged when ï¬?nancial development is used to construct a threshold variable on ï¬?nancial development, suggesting that it is not the driver of the foreign savings–growth link (table A3.2). Slightly different is the conclusion reached using measures of institutional development. The impact of the EU-speciï¬?c foreign savings interactions weakens as institutional development increases, suggesting that institutional development features might be operating. But the weakening is limited, and the EU-speciï¬?c foreign savings interactions remain important. That institutional development indicators do not eliminate these EU-speciï¬?c effects might reflect that EU membership (actual or potential) acts as an anchor for expectations of improved institutional quality, even if actual improvements materialize slowly. The European Union behaves much like a space station, with its rules of accession acting as a “tractor beamâ€? as it exerts a powerful institutional pull, while countries like Germany may have the pulling power of big spaceships.10 Disentangling these pull factors is a subject for future research. Even so, European integration appears to be a determinant of growth for countries in and near Europe when they begin their transition toward the European Union. Beneï¬?ts for many, excesses for some With the beneï¬?t of hindsight, excess ï¬?nancing was a problem before the global crisis, and it hurt some emerging European countries. The abrupt declines in real GDP must be recognized and included in any assessment of the effectiveness of 138 CHAPTER 3 ï¬?nancial integration. These declines raise the question of whether the positive dynamics described above are inherently unsustainable. Reassuringly, even when episodes of “excessive growthâ€? are excluded from the analysis, the association between foreign savings and growth remains (see Stojkov and Zalduendo 2011).11 The results are not linked to the unusually high growth rates—or to the unsustainable external imbalances—of the precrisis period. A key challenge for policymakers is thus not to avoid ï¬?nancial integration, but to understand which policy mix contributes to turning this opportunity into a sustained growth dynamic and how the tail risks can be effectively mitigated. This is the focus of the next section. Because the lessons of prudence apply to all countries, the next section covers not only emerging Europe but also, albeit less thoroughly, the EU cohesion countries. Prudence when ï¬?nance is plentiful Macroeconomic outcomes in emerging Europe improved in the late 1990s. After many years with large ï¬?scal imbalances and high and volatile inflation, economic stability was reestablished.12 In turn, ï¬?nancial integration in the early 2000s increased economic interdependence and raised the credibility of policymakers by anchoring institutional development to structures known in Western Europe. In the eurozone, the elimination of currency risks led to a sharp fall in borrowing costs for the EU cohesion countries and a corresponding acceleration of foreign borrowing by private and public sectors. In some emerging European countries, there was also an acceleration in credit growth to the private sector, albeit from low initial levels. Emerging Europe is not the same everywhere Against this general background, important differences emerged across countries in the region. To examine these differences, emerging European countries can be classiï¬?ed along two dimensions. The ï¬?rst is institutional: EU12, EU candidates, and the EU eastern partnership. The EU cohesion countries are identiï¬?ed separately, because they are the subject of current interest. The second dimension is monetary, using the exchange rate regime of each country (based on the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions [AREAER] classiï¬?cation): flexible (group 1), intermediate (group 2), and ï¬?xed (group 3).13 The analysis distinguishes two four-year periods prior to the crisis: 2001–04 and 2005–08 (table 3.1, bottom panel, shows the changes in savings-investment balances between these two periods and includes a sample of emerging markets outside Europe). Three broad conclusions emerge from this comparison: · External imbalances in emerging Europe were largely private. Public sector imbalances declined in most countries. This is also the case among EU cohesion countries with the notable exception of Greece and Ireland. However, the improvement in public savings–investment balances is also misleading, as it also reflects buoyant tax revenues during the boom. 139 GOLDEN GROWTH Table 3.1: Private imbalances in the East, a more complicated story in the South (saving–investment balances, average of median values, 2001–04 versus 2005–08) Emerging Europe EU Cohesion Exchange rate regime Regional classiï¬?cation East classiï¬?cation LAC Asia Greece Ireland Portugal Spain EU EU eastern Flexible Intermediate Fixed EU12 candidates partnership (group 1) (group 2) (group 3) 2005-08 National savings (S) 20.1 15.4 30.5 21.1 21.1 18.2 9.4 21.4 15.4 21.1 29.0 18.0 Public 3.0 3.3 7.1 4.3 3.0 3.7 -2.6 1.4 12.5 4.0 6.3 4.9 Private 17.1 12.1 23.4 16.7 18.2 14.5 12.0 20.0 2.9 17.1 22.8 13.1 National investment (I) 28.5 24.7 32.9 27.2 26.1 31.8 21.3 26.2 21.6 30.2 28.8 22.9 Public 4.3 3.8 4.8 4.5 3.7 4.6 2.9 4.4 2.4 3.8 6.9 5.3 Private 24.2 20.9 28.1 22.7 22.4 27.2 18.3 21.8 19.2 26.4 21.9 17.6 (S-I) public -1.2 -0.5 2.3 -0.1 -0.8 -0.9 -5.5 -3.0 10.1 0.2 -0.6 -0.4 (S-I) private -7.2 -8.9 -4.7 -6.0 -4.2 -12.7 -6.3 -1.8 -16.3 -9.3 0.9 -4.5 Current account -8.4 -9.4 -2.4 -6.1 -4.9 -13.6 -11.9 -4.8 -6.2 -9.1 0.3 -4.8 ∆ (2005-08 minus 2001-04) National savings (S) 0.6 -0.6 10.0 2.3 1.7 -1.2 -7.3 -2.0 -1.4 -2.1 2.0 2.5 Public 1.9 2.6 2.8 3.0 1.9 0.6 -1.3 -3.1 1.0 0.9 1.1 2.8 Private -1.3 -3.2 7.2 -0.6 -0.2 -1.8 -6.0 1.1 -2.3 -3.0 1.0 -0.4 National investment (I) 3.2 3.6 9.5 5.2 1.9 8.6 -1.9 3.0 -2.2 3.0 3.9 3.6 Public 0.9 -0.2 0.5 0.1 0.1 1.6 -0.6 0.5 -0.9 0.3 0.2 0.4 Private 2.3 3.7 9.0 5.1 1.8 7.0 -1.3 2.5 -1.2 2.7 3.6 3.3 (S-I) public 1.0 2.7 2.3 2.9 1.7 -1.0 -0.6 -3.6 1.9 0.6 0.8 2.5 (S-I) private -3.6 -6.9 -1.9 -5.8 -2.0 -8.8 -4.8 -1.4 -1.1 -5.7 -2.7 -3.6 Current account -2.6 -4.2 0.5 -2.9 -0.3 -9.8 -5.4 -5.0 0.8 -5.1 -1.8 -1.2 Note: The exchange rate classiï¬?cation is based on three groups of countries: group 1 (flexible or independent floating; Albania, Armenia, Czech Republic, Moldova, Poland, and Turkey); group 2 (intermediate, including basket, peg within bands, crawling peg, crawling band, and managed floating; Azerbaijan, Belarus, Croatia, Georgia, Hungary, FYR Macedonia, Romania, Serbia, Slovak Republic, and Ukraine); and group 3 (ï¬?xed, which includes countries with no legal tender, currency boards, and conventional pegs; Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Montenegro, and Slovenia). LAC stands for the Latin American and the Caribbean region. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF 2010; and IMF WEO. · Countries in emerging Europe with ï¬?xed exchange rates recorded a sharper decline in their current account and private savings–investment balances, due to lower private savings and a rapid increase in public and private investment. · Institutional characteristics, as argued in the previous section, influence the observed evolution of public and private sector balances. The EU cohesion countries are distinguished by a decline in national savings, much lower increases (or in the case of Portugal and Greece, declines) in national investment, and, with the exception of Portugal, substantial deterioration of their current accounts. EU12 and EU candidate countries by contrast show stable or moderately increasing national savings and increases in investment. EU eastern partnership countries display increases in both savings and 140 CHAPTER 3 investment, and improvements in their current account positions despite a small deterioration in private savings–investment balances. These differences have consequences for assessments of solvency and liquidity as discussed in the next section. Did rapid capital inflows cause excessive exchange rate appreciation in emerging Europe, as many skeptics feared? Real exchange rates appreciated gradually in most emerging European economies, consistent with the “Balassa-Samuelsonâ€? effect in developing countries (ï¬?gure 3.7).14 But, as noted by Bakker and Gulde (2010), in several European countries wage inflation exceeded productivity gains. The loss of competitiveness led to further capital inflows to cover resulting current account imbalances. Where this happened, sustainability was at risk. Some have blamed ï¬?xed exchange rate policies for the loss in competitiveness precrisis and the sharply differentiated impact of the crisis on growth. On closer inspection, the inconsistency of ï¬?xed exchange rate regimes with other policies—ï¬?scal policy in particular and generally complacent policies in the presence of massive external imbalances—are more important drivers of the boom-bust cycle that some emerging European countries experienced. Figure 3.7: Emerging Europe’s real effective exchange rates appreciated (2007=100) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF 2010; and IMF IFS. Domestic demand and current accounts Foreign ï¬?nancing and credit Figure 3.8: Emerging Europe showed rapid economic adjustment but slow economic recovery Note: The label colors reflect the EU12, EU candidate, and EU eastern partnership country groups. Also included for reference are EU cohesion countries. Data on credit include the domestic banking system only, and for most countries, are for May 2011. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF IFS; and IMF WEO. 141 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.9: The closer Group index (median values) Country index (median values) a country gets to the European Union, the more stable its bank ï¬?nancing (banking flow stocks to emerging markets, quarterly data; t = 100) Note: The ï¬?gures are based on quarterly data released on July 2011. Values are exchange rate adjusted. Crisis timing date is deï¬?ned in parentheses. Asian crisis countries are Indonesia, the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand. The group index is based on aggregate group values, and the country index is the median value of the values of individual countries within the group. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on BIS Locational Banking Statistics. Unusually liquid global markets during the precrisis period certainly would have strained the toolkit of any government authority. But the presumption that a convergence-driven “new Europeâ€? was at hand resulted in complacency on the part of bankers and bureaucrats in some emerging European countries. There are also differences in private credit developments—the engine fueling large private imbalances—and the corresponding external imbalances. The countries most affected by the crisis in terms of declines in domestic demand were also those with the largest precrisis external imbalances (ï¬?gure 3.8, left panel). In addition, countries that heavily depended on foreign funding to extend credit (for example, those with high loan-to-deposit ratios) are also those where private sector credit growth was slowest during the recovery (ï¬?gure 3.8, right panel). This suggests that excesses left unmanaged caused the crisis to have a deeper and potentially more lasting impact. Against this background, three small European economies faced similarities before the crisis, but policy responses were dictated by differences in initial conditions, such as the choice of exchange rate regime, the feasibility of introducing capital controls (for example, Ireland is precluded from doing so as an EU member), and the existence of a lender of last resort (box 3.1). So indeed some of the precrisis developments increased vulnerabilities, in particular in the years immediately preceding the crisis. At the same time, bank ownership structures in emerging Europe proved to be a source of stability. While some foreign banks took too many risks in the precrisis period, the crisis did not lead to a sharp reversal in cross-border flows; in fact, banking flows linked to Western European banks have been more stable than during the East Asia crisis (ï¬?gure 3.9). More precisely, cross-border flows came to an abrupt stop, but did not go into reverse as in Asia in 1997–98. The one exception is the EU eastern partnership (driven by developments in Ukraine), where foreign banks had a less dominant position and short-term wholesale funding sources, mostly delinked from ownership structures, were not renewed.15 142 CHAPTER 3 Box 3.1: Economic adjustment in three small European economies Iceland, Ireland, and Latvia, with populations covered banks’ losses with taxpayers’ money. in construction. of 0.3 million, 4.4 million, and 2.3 million, In Latvia, about two-thirds of bank assets · Precrisis gross government debt was 40 respectively, got into trouble during the global were held by foreign (mostly Scandinavian) percent of GDP or less in all three countries. crisis as a result of rapid growth in credit and banks, which assumed most of the losses. The But the fall in output, the large budget other banking activities ï¬?nanced by precrisis exception was the domestically owned Parex deï¬?cits accumulated during the crisis, and international borrowing. Credit booms led to Bank, which was nationalized. Total bank banking sector support—about 40 percent of property price booms, peaking in 2006 or 2007 losses in 2009 and 2010 were 9 percent of GDP. GDP in Ireland, and 20 percent in Iceland—all (box ï¬?gure 1). The construction sector was Financial support from ofï¬?cial sources helped contributed to sharp increases in public slightly over 10 percent of GDP in each of these stem the risk of a run on deposits. debt. Despite similar public debt-to-GDP countries. During the crisis, property prices collapsed. All three countries had to turn to the Capital controls. Only Iceland applied capital ratios, in the summer of 2011, 5-year credit IMF and their European partners for help. controls—and only Iceland could. This had a default swaps on sovereign debt were high lock-in effect on nonresident deposits; it also (above 1,000 basis points) in Ireland, but Fiscal austerity programs coupled with had fallen to a moderate level (around 250 locked out krona assets outside the country. structural reforms were central to these basis points) in Iceland and Latvia. The IMF (2011) estimates that offshore krona countries’ economic adjustments. Although holdings imply a high spread between onshore saving–investment imbalances in the high- The moral and offshore exchange rates. Capital controls growth years were largely of a private origin, Although similar before the crisis, the have so far been effective. public spending kept up with the revenue economic recovery of each country is overperformance, but it had to be clawed back Economic outcomes proceeding at a different pace. (more so in Latvia than the other countries). Precrisis vulnerabilities shaped these The three countries also faced banking · Latvia suffered a sharper decline in GDP outcomes. Both Latvia and Iceland had problems (over half of bank assets were (and thus incomes) than Iceland and Ireland. unusually large current account deï¬?cits of over foreign-owned in Latvia, but domestic owners It has stabilized its public ï¬?nances, returned 20 percent of GDP. Ireland’s deï¬?cit was more dominated in Iceland and Ireland). Such moderate, at 5 percent. The improvements in to growth, and tapped international bond differences meant that the policy responses the external accounts had knock-on effects on markets again, but will take a long time to and economic outcomes varied. all components of demand, employment, and catch up with Iceland in employment and public ï¬?nance: output recovery. Policy responses Exchange rates. Adjustments in real exchange · From peak to trough, Latvian GDP collapsed · Iceland emerged from the crisis with the rates form the clearest difference across these by 25 percent—twice as much as in Iceland smallest fall in employment and a fast countries. Ireland is a member of the euro area, (11 percent) and Ireland (13 percent). expansion of tradable production despite so changing the exchange rate was not an the largest shock to the ï¬?nancial system option. Latvia had pegged its exchange rate to · All three countries saw a comparable and a collapse of the exchange rate. Yet it the euro, and chose not to devalue. For Iceland collapse in investment. Private consumption will have to lift capital controls (Gylfason devaluation was the only option given the went into free fall in Iceland and Latvia (the 2011; IMF 2011). size of the country’s obligations and available adjustment in Ireland was smaller). · Ireland did not have the option of devaluing ï¬?nancing. Accordingly, the krona fell by about · Public consumption fell furthest in Latvia its currency nor of introducing capital 50 percent and the country introduced capital (20 percent), in line with reliance on internal controls. But the external imbalance was controls to limit further depreciation. While devaluation, and the onus on clawing back the smallest and the tradable sector was the depreciation-induced inflation eroded public spending. some of the competitiveness gain, the krona competitive (Darvas, Pisani-Ferry, and Sapir is still weaker by about a third relative to its · In Iceland, export growth fostered the 2011). Ireland’s problem was its banks, precrisis level in real terms. Ireland and Latvia massive adjustment of the current account. whose losses were largely charged to Irish have seen small declines in their real effective Exports of goods and services rose by 7 taxpayers. exchange rates, but Latvia’s is still well above percent in 2009, against an average fall of One main lesson from the crisis is that when its precrisis value (box ï¬?gure 2). 12 percent in the European Union. debts are commercially held, the state should Lender of last resort. In Iceland, with · Imports collapsed by about 40 percent in avoid loading itself with debts to save the obligations exceeding the country’s GDP Iceland and Latvia, in line with the fall in ï¬?nancial system. The costs to Ireland are several times over, the central bank could not investment and private consumption, while clear: public debt exploded, necessitating a fulï¬?ll this role. It had no choice but to let the the Irish import decline (14 percent) was sharp ï¬?scal adjustment that has hampered banks default. Domestic deposits were fully similar to the EU average. conï¬?dence and recovery. guaranteed, but foreign creditors of Icelandic The other main lesson is that a sharp banks faced a €47 billion loss in 2007—three · Iceland experienced a modest (6 percent) adjustment in the real exchange rate times Iceland’s precrisis GDP (Benediktsdottir, fall in employment from 2007 to 2010. The labor market impact was sharper in Latvia through nominal devaluations comes about Danielsson, and Zoega 2011). The central (17 percent) and Ireland (13 percent). more rapidly and thus is helpful when the bank suffered losses because of the liquidity saving-investment balance needs a drastic support it provided to banks. · The differences in output and employment improvement. Iceland did much better than Irish banks’ balance sheets reached eight times between Iceland and Latvia are likely Latvia in this regard. However, domestic GDP. The Eurosystem and the central bank due to real exchange rate developments. borrowers also suffered heavily from the provided liquidity (Buiter, Michels, and Rahbari Less clear is why Ireland’s employment collapse of the exchange rate. 2011a and 2011b). The Irish government contracted more than Iceland’s, given the guaranteed all liabilities of Irish banks and similar GDP developments and a similar fall Source: Darvas (2011). 143 GOLDEN GROWTH Box ï¬?gure 1: Real housing prices (2007=100) Box ï¬?gure 2: Real effective exchange rates (CPI-based, 2007=100) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on data collected by the Global Property Guide; and IMF IFS. That foreign ownership could have been a source of stability is somewhat perplexing. Cross-border flows are supposed to protect countries from domestic shocks and exacerbate exogenous shocks. Several factors might explain this, including the moral suasion role of international ï¬?nancial institutions through the Vienna Initiative and the provision of liquidity and public ï¬?nancial support in Western Europe to parent banks at the peak of the crisis.16 But the “lock- inâ€? of resources in banks’ subsidiaries due to the long-term nature of their loan portfolio must be remembered.17 Deleveraging is likely to be limited and gradual. However, downside risks remain high and originate in the problems faced by the EU cohesion countries and their impact on Europe’s economic outlook; indeed, the overall balance sheet strength of Western European banks that are active in emerging Europe is being challenged by the exposures to sovereign debts within the eurozone. This is a risk that could have spillover effects on emerging Europe. The experience described points to heterogeneity in the regional buildup of external and domestic vulnerabilities. Some countries sustained high growth rates without growing imbalances, while others experienced growth with increasing vulnerabilities. But what deï¬?nes a high-reward, low-risk outcome? Research since the crisis highlights some of the economic characteristics and policies that would strengthen Europe’s ï¬?nancial integration model. Ghosh, Sugawara, and Zalduendo (2011b) identify some drivers of the tradeoff between growth and vulnerability (box 3.2). The main policy conclusion for emerging Europe is to manage external imbalances,18 which requires boom-prooï¬?ng public ï¬?nance and crisis-prooï¬?ng private ï¬?nance. Boom-prooï¬?ng public ï¬?nance How policymakers boom-proof public ï¬?nance is critical. Fiscal deï¬?cits were not the cause of the saving-investment imbalances in emerging Europe (nor of the resulting boom-bust cycles these countries experienced). But a distinction has 144 CHAPTER 3 to be drawn between the cause of these imbalances and the policy stance that should be put in place in their presence. There was a shift toward a procyclical ï¬?scal stance across emerging Europe from 2004 to 2008 (ï¬?gure 3.10). More precisely, the difference between ï¬?scal balances and cyclically adjusted ï¬?scal balances shifted from negative (countercyclical) to positive (procyclical) territory for many countries, and in some countries the shift was quite marked. This implies that countries entered the crisis with weakening ï¬?scal positions. Other developing regions experienced less ï¬?scal deterioration. The explanation for this ï¬?scal deterioration is simple. As noted by Bakker and Gulde (2010) and Islam (2010), real expenditures rose sharply in the decade before the crisis, especially after 2004. While ï¬?scal deï¬?cits for the most part did not deteriorate, the revenue overperformance before the crisis masks actual developments in public ï¬?nances. In Latvia, for example, additional budget allocations were authorized in the middle of every ï¬?scal year after 2005 (Ã…slund and Dombrovskis 2011). Also, some countries (such as Latvia and Serbia) approved wage and pension increases, as well as new capital spending, just a few months before the crisis broke. How should integrating countries boom-proof public ï¬?nances? For some economies, following an acyclical ï¬?scal policy might sufï¬?ce; if economic growth leads to revenue overperformance, these resources should be saved. The ï¬?scal policies of Bulgaria and Estonia in the precrisis period were, with hindsight, enlightened (ï¬?gure 3.11). But even there ï¬?scal positions were excessively procyclical.19 In fact, a more determined countercyclical ï¬?scal policy stance— using both revenue and spending measures—would have been needed in many countries to counterbalance private behavior. The unusually large size of private sector imbalances in some countries could not (and should not) have been fully matched by ï¬?scal surpluses, but many authorities shied away from the signaling that was required by the overheating that was apparent even then. Figure 3.10: Fiscal positions became procyclical in 2004–08 (difference between unadjusted and cyclically adjusted ï¬?scal balances) Note: The ï¬?gure depicts the difference between ï¬?scal balances and cyclically adjusted ï¬?scal balances. Arrows begin in 2004 and end in 2008. Group median values are presented for EU12, candidate countries (EU cand.), and eastern partnership countries (E. prtn.). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. 145 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.11: Revenues lost to the Great Recession, 2009 Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on IMF WEO. Crisis-prooï¬?ng private ï¬?nance Financial integration has beneï¬?ts and risks. De Larosière (2009, p72) puts it well: “Integration increases contagion risks, and thereby jeopardises ï¬?nancial stability; integration makes it more difï¬?cult to ensure a level playing ï¬?eld if rules and supervisory practices differ; integration means the development of large cross-border groups, which will require more streamlined and cost- effective supervisory organisation.â€? The global crisis also revealed weaknesses in ï¬?nancial architectures. The emerging market countries in Europe were hit hard, but few experienced a collapse of their banking system. By contrast, in Ireland, the banking crisis became a sovereign debt crisis, in turn revealing weaknesses in the European Union and euro area precrisis economic policy and regulatory frameworks, surveillance arrangements, and governance mechanisms. Financial developments in Europe highlight the difï¬?culties of concurrently pursuing ï¬?nancial integration, ï¬?nancial stability, and national sovereignty. Typically, only two of these objectives can be attained concurrently (Allen and others 2011). Just as the precrisis experience showed that ï¬?nancial integration is key to Europe’s income convergence, the ï¬?nancial crisis showed the importance of ï¬?nancial stability. To some degree, sovereignty appears to be the casualty of an integrated world. Yet, countries will always need to tailor their policy responses to country-speciï¬?c developments. At a national level, macroprudential policies play a useful role, and will have to be tailored to a country’s initial conditions and, in particular, to cyclical developments that might differ across Europe. And of course supranational approaches are also needed. Policy coordination is paramount in such a context to achieve the correct balance between sovereignty and country speciï¬?city. The alternative, not worth pursuing, is to give up on ï¬?nancial integration, a big part of what fuels Europe’s redoubtable convergence machine. Nor should ï¬?nancial stability be compromised. 146 CHAPTER 3 Box 3.2: Understanding the growth–vulnerability tradeoff Ghosh, Sugawara, and Zalduendo (2011b) case, governments should not shy away from countries in emerging Europe. analyze economic policies and other conditions signaling their concerns with private behavior. • Monetary policies should have played a that are favorable for countries to achieve Fourth, capital account openness appears to counter-credit role. Countries in emerging growth without building macroeconomic increase vulnerability. However, given the many Europe had loose monetary conditions vulnerability, using data for countries in the beneï¬?ts that have been derived from foreign at the outset of the credit boom in 2004. World Bank’s Europe and Central Asia region. capital in parts of emerging Europe, the correct Monetary conditions were tightening by What are their main conclusions from? First, lesson is to manage external imbalances more 2008, but credit growth rates suggest trade supports growth, but could also lead to proactively. that monetary policy should have been vulnerability. Vulnerability is less likely to occur, What was the policy stance of countries in tightened further. however, if a dynamic export sector is part of emerging Europe in the years preceding the • Capital controls may play a role in the the equation. Second, the type of capital coming global crisis? A snapshot of policy stances for future. Measures of capital account into a country matters. Financial openness 2004 and 2008 offers lessons on what countries openness changed little between 2004 and might support growth, but also contributes could have done differently. 2008 (right panel), but the Chinn-Ito index to vulnerability. As this chapter argues, • Fiscal policy did not play enough of a (Chinn and Ito 2006 and 2008) suggests foreign capital is an enviable development countercyclical role. It is well known that that emerging Europe’s capital account was opportunity with tail risks. However, if FDI public imbalances were limited in much more open than that in other emerging (and to a degree this must also apply to of emerging Europe, and they were not markets. Work by the IMF suggests that ï¬?nancial FDI) is one of the elements of the the drivers of external imbalances. Fiscal capital controls may have a role under capital flowing into the country, then it is less policy, however, became looser before the certain conditions (Ostry and others 2010). likely to increase a country’s vulnerability and crisis—the opposite of what was advisable For EU members the options are limited more likely to support its growth. Third, ï¬?scal for overheating economies. Also, countries (that is, capital controls can be against the policy is a key element in the toolkit to reduce freedom of capital movement), but others vulnerability. It might slow down economic with ï¬?xed exchange rate regimes had, in Europe could consider such measures. activity, but it also shifts countries into a less on average, looser ï¬?scal policies than Alternatively, these results could suggest vulnerable development path when risks are other emerging European countries, that there is room to develop policies that mounting. In this regard, when private ï¬?nance contrary to what was expected given the might affect capital inflows, for example is the engine of growth—but also of growing exchange rate regime of these countries. macroprudential policies. vulnerabilities—ï¬?scal policy can play a signaling In conclusion, the revenue windfalls of high role on the need to avoid excesses. In such a growth were spent, not saved, in most Source: Ghosh, Sugawara, and Zalduendo (2011b). Macroprudential policies Prudential regulations are traditionally used to mitigate risks in individual institutions. But they are also central to strengthening ï¬?nancial system stability, particularly against the systemic risks that arise from the externalities associated with individual institutions’ actions. In this context, macroprudential policies are those that are adjusted to turns in the economic cycle. Examples of macroprudential regulations include policies that increase buffers, contain credit growth, and directly improve individual credit quality during good times. Some traditional prudential policies, such as capital-adequacy ratios for banks, may be intended to hedge risks by creating buffers or slowing credit growth (or both). But they become macroprudential only when adjusted in response to macroeconomic developments. Ratios may, for example, be increased when credit growth is high—either for the whole ï¬?nancial system or for systemic banks―or may include larger capital buffers for certain types of lending, such as changing risk weights on mortgage loans.20 Liquidity-related regulations are intended to curtail (or promote) credit growth by increasing the cost of extending credit without using (or in addition to) monetary policy instruments. These measures can be targeted to all or to speciï¬?c business lines. For example, Croatia applied additional liquidity requirements that increased the cost of credit across all business lines. By contrast, FYR Macedonia targeted credit card and consumer loans. Quantitative 147 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.12: Countries showed varying experiences with credit growth and asset prices Note: The exchange rate classiï¬?cation follows the description in table 3.1. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on data collected by the Global Property Guide; Bloomberg; IMF 2010; IMF IFS. 148 CHAPTER 3 restrictions or direct credit controls (sectoral or aggregate) are also possible, but it should be noted that acting through quantity-based measures rather than price-based measures potentially has more severe distortionary effects. Regulations to improve the quality of new loans take the form of more stringent eligibility requirements on certain types of lending and may be viewed as reducing systemwide ï¬?nancial risks one transaction at a time. Polgár and Zdzienicka (2010) classify these regulations into “hardâ€? and “softâ€? restrictions. The ï¬?rst includes tighter loan-to-value ratios and debt service-to-income ratios. The second refers to qualiï¬?cation requirements, such as a checklist of requirements that household borrowers must meet in order to borrow in foreign currency.21 What, then, was the experience with macroprudential policies in emerging Europe before the crisis? For Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, FYR Macedonia, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Turkey this report asked for written accounts from staffs at the central bank or ï¬?nancial supervision agencies of these countries. It is worth noting that ï¬?nancial sector developments in the run- up to the crisis differed substantially in these eight countries (ï¬?gure 3.12). This influenced both the type of and scope for macroprudential tools. These eight countries had varied experiences with macroprudential policies before the crisis (table 3.2 and box 3.3), but many are deploying these policies more proactively during the recovery. A range of factors affected policymakers’ choices, including the monetary policy and exchange rate regime in place, the historical context of ï¬?nancial sector development (such as the convergence process and the presence of foreign banks), the distributional implications of various policies, the legal implications of policies (such as whether the authorities were legally permitted to vary regulations according to the size of the institution), and the ability of regulated entities to circumvent regulations. External factors also played a role. Countries that adopted these policies had to adapt them as agents changed their economic behavior, loopholes emerged, and side effects became more apparent. Overall, the impact of macroprudential policies had the intended effect though sometimes only a transitory one. The ï¬?rst lesson is that policymakers need to consider the implications of prudential regulation across all ï¬?nancial intermediaries. They should be aware, for instance, that tightening regulation might not always be effective because it could encourage a shift to less regulated institutions or countries, such as through direct cross-border lending to corporations by parent banks with subsidiary operations. Second, the macroprudential toolkit deployed emphasized creating buffers and slowing credit growth, but few countries introduced measures to strengthen credit quality before the crisis, an area deserving greater attention going forward.22 Third, even if the effect of these policies might at times be transitory, supervisory authorities should assess what works and aim to adjust these policies when undesired developments take place or loopholes emerge in the macroprudential toolkit. A wait-and-see strategy is too costly, as the 2008 crisis has shown. 149 GOLDEN GROWTH Table 3.2: Precrisis use of macroprudential policies in eight emerging European countries CZE EST HRV HUN MKD POL ROM TUR Buffers and credit growth containment Capital-adequacy ratios • • • • • Risk weights • • • • • Liquidity requirements • • • • • Constraints on total credit growth • • Regulations on lending in foreign currency • • • Other • • • • Credit quality Loan-to-value ratios • Debt service-to-income ratios • Eligibility criteria • Other • • • Note: The table reflects changes during 2004-08. Source: Background papers prepared by country ofï¬?cials for this report. Supranational policies Financial system frameworks before the crisis let market discipline and ofï¬?cial oversight work in tandem to provide checks and balances to prevent systemic threats to ï¬?nancial stability.23 The global crisis revealed that this approach was wrong. Neither market discipline nor ofï¬?cial oversight performed their functions as envisaged. The strategy tilted too heavily toward allowing the market to discipline itself, which proved to be elusive until it was too late—at which point market-disciplining behavior led to widespread uncertainty and severe market dysfunctions. Too little ofï¬?cial oversight—the corollary—failed to spot the buildup of systemic weaknesses. Similar to other advanced economies, the European Union introduced on January 1, 2011, a new architecture for safeguarding ï¬?nancial stability, collectively referred to as the European System of Financial Supervision. It includes three new microprudential European Supervisory Authorities (ESAs) and a new macroprudential body—the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB).24 The goals are to improve the microprudential supervision of ï¬?nancial institutions and the regulation of capital markets at national and supranational levels, assess systemic risks, and recommend risk- mitigation measures. This is complemented by changes still being introduced in the role and mandate of the European Financial Stability Facility and its programmed successor to be introduced later in this decade. Even if used as envisaged, these reforms have limitations (box 3.4). The ESAs are more than a group of coordinating mechanisms in “crisisâ€? situations, but they must defer to national authorities. Similarly, although the ESRB can identify countries that pose systemic risks and make recommendations, it has 150 CHAPTER 3 Box 3.3: Country experiences with macroprudential policies Classifying countries into four groups serves to-income ratios. compliance with what legally were only to represent these experiences: countries that recommendations), but they became stricter Limited macroprudential action were proactive in the use of macroprudential after the crisis (Kruszka and Kowalczyk 2011). policies, countries that relied somewhat on Turkey experienced a more gradual credit They now include quantitative standards to macroprudential policies, countries that relied boom cycle in the precrisis period. Perhaps for evaluate creditworthiness (Recommendation on moral suasion, and countries that did not this reason the authorities acted in a limited T) and more speciï¬?c loan-to-value and use these policies. fashion on the macroprudential front, with debt service-to-income ratios (in a revised the most visible intervention related to higher Recommendation S, scheduled to come into Proactive use of macroprudential policies capital-adequacy ratios for banks that wished effect in December 2011). FYR Macedonia, Croatia, and Romania were to expand (measured by authorizations for perhaps the most proactive in applying opening new branches). Turkey did not allow No use of macroprudential policies macroprudential tools before the crisis. FYR foreign currency lending to households before Hungary and the Czech Republic did not Macedonia introduced regulations to limit the the crisis. Since witnessing a rapid pickup in take any macroprudential steps before the growth of lending in foreign currency and in credit in late 2009, the authorities have ï¬? rmly crisis. In Hungary, the authorities deemed household lending in early 2008. In the view applied macroprudential policies, including fast credit growth to be sustainable given of Celeska, Gligorova, and Krstevska (2011), the measures to improve credit quality (such as regulations were beginning to have an impact lower loan-to-value ratios) and to preclude the country’s convergence to EU incomes. when the crisis hit. This partly reflected FYR Although they had some concerns over lending in lira indexed to the exchange rate Macedonia’s late exposure to the process of foreign currency lending and fast growth (Kenc, Turhan, and Yildirim 2011). These high credit growth that characterized emerging policies’ success remains to be seen. in mortgage loans, they did not impose Europe, and it is unclear how much the crisis restrictions for political and social reasons. slowed credit growth. Moral suasion The banking authorities have recently In Croatia, the authorities adopted various In Estonia and Poland much of the initial imposed several lending restrictions to prudential measures to limit credit growth and intervention centered on moral suasion efforts reduce systemwide risks in household to safeguard the ï¬?nancial system against an (Sutt, Korju, and Siibak 2011). Only a few policy lending (Banai, Király, and Nagy 2011). Since accumulation of systemic risks, particularly actions were taken as credit booms emerged. late 2010, for example, mortgages may from lending in foreign currency. They In Estonia, the initial policy response was not be denominated in foreign currency, introduced the new regulations relatively to reduce the tax deductibility of mortgage and tight loan-to-value limits have been early, in 2003. Because banks attempted to interest payments; it was reduced by half adopted. circumvent the new regulations, they were in 2004. This move was followed in 2005 improved simply through “trial and error.â€? with changes to risk weights on mortgage Judicious macroeconomic policy with a flexible A combination of prudential regulations lending. Capital buffers were maintained at exchange rate helped the Czech ï¬?nancial and complementary monetary policies higher levels than in advanced economies and system avoid some of the pitfalls of other reduced credit growth, though the tools were accompanied by high reserve requirements. countries. Although credit growth, especially sometimes circumvented by direct cross- household credit, was high in some years, the Poland applied stricter rules on capital- border lending by parent banks (Kraft and authorities for the most part viewed it to be in adequacy ratios for new banks and used Galac 2011). line with the country’s convergence process moral suasion to build capital buffers through (Frait, GerÅ¡l, and Seidler 2011). What makes Romania is a case of proactive monetary policy retained earnings. It also increased the the Czech banking system special is that it did and prudential tools aimed not only at securing emphasis on credit eligibility criteria. Until not accumulate lending in foreign currency. a low inflationary environment, but also at the crisis, its prudential toolkit took the form Perhaps because the country had established strengthening ï¬?nancial stability (Popa 2011). of recommendations. Recommendation S, macroeconomic management credibility well Although monetary authorities were proactive for example, sets guidelines on mortgage before high global liquidity emerged, and thus in the use of policy rates, their approach was loans, ranging from rules for evaluating had low inflation and interest rates, carry-trade accompanied by a large set of administrative creditworthiness in foreign currency loans opportunities that fueled foreign currency and prudential measures, including differential to standards for disclosing information to lending elsewhere were simply nonexistent reserve requirements on domestic and foreign customers on exchange rate risks. These (Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo 2010). currency liabilities, changes to risk weights in recommendations led to some action in some business lines, and adjustments over the banking sector before the crisis (by all Source: Background papers prepared by time to the level and coverage of debt service- accounts, supervisory authorities emphasized country ofï¬?cials for this report. no authority other than moral suasion. Looking ahead, three challenges are important for emerging European countries: regulatory requirements, a large foreign presence, and liquidity management during a crisis. · Regulatory requirements for capital, liquidity, and leverage. The crisis showed that microprudential regulations for ensuring the safety and soundness of individual ï¬?nancial institutions were inadequate. Many aspects contributed to the buildup of risks, such as misunderstood management of 151 GOLDEN GROWTH liquidity risks, inadequate and unbinding leverage limits, and a flawed Basel framework for determining capital requirements for on- and off-balance sheet credit exposures. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision and the Financial Stability Board—each with European leadership and representation—are considering reforms to tackle these weaknesses, which will be phased in over time. As discussed in Ghosh, Sugawara, and Zalduendo (2011a), emerging Europe is the region most likely to be negatively affected Box 3.4: The new European architecture for ï¬?nancial stability The precrisis EU architecture for ï¬?nancial Plus Pact, to strengthen the economic and a lack of attention to systemwide risks. stability evolved into an institutional pillar of the euro area; a strengthened The ESRB will assess and prioritize sources framework with three characteristics that the economic surveillance framework; and the of systemic ï¬?nancial risks and vulnerabilities crisis revealed needed to be strengthened: European Semester, an integrated annual and will make recommendations for change. surveillance cycle. To achieve its objectives, the ESRB will collect • Decentralization. Before the crisis, and analyze relevant information; identify ï¬?nancial stability functions were The new microprudential framework and prioritize systemic risks; issue warnings decentralized, based on the exercise Three microprudential supervisory authorities where risks are signiï¬?cant and make those of national responsibilities by banking (ESAs) were created: the European Banking warnings public; issue recommendations supervisors, central banks, treasuries, and Authority, the European Insurance and for remedial action and, where appropriate, deposit insurance schemes (despite the Occupational Pensions Authority, and the make those recommendations public; integration of European ï¬?nance). European Securities and Markets Authority. issue conï¬?dential warnings of emergency • Segmentation. Precrisis ï¬?nancial stability The ESAs should be seen as the next step situations to the Council and provide the functions were segmented across sectors in the evolution of effective cooperation Council with an assessment of the situation; and countries; for example, supervision between national authorities rather than monitor the follow-up to warnings and of banks and ï¬?nancial conglomerates was as a centralization of power. Each of the recommendations; and cooperate closely with conducted separately by the supervisors ESAs has the following responsibilities in all the other parties to the European System that licensed each entity. their respective competencies: establishing of Financial Supervision, providing the ESAs a single set of harmonized rules; ensuring with information on systemic risks that is • Cooperation. Voluntary cooperation consistent application of EU rules; managing required for the performance of their tasks, structures were relied on to bridge the disagreements between national supervisors; and developing in collaboration with the ESAs gaps between national responsibilities. These structures ranged from legal making recommendations if there is a manifest a common set of indicators to identify and provisions (for example, consolidated breach of Community law; creating a common measure systemic risk. supervision) to voluntary memorandums supervisory culture as well as supervisory The decisionmaking body of the ESRB, the of understanding. practices; having full supervisory powers for General Board, will have voting members some entities; ensuring a coordinated response who are also top-level policymakers: the Since the crisis, the European Union has during crises; and collecting microprudential governors of the 27 EU national central undertaken institutional reforms aimed at data. banks, the president and vice president of enhancing the effectiveness of economic, the European Central Bank, a member of the ï¬?nancial, and ï¬?nancial sector policymaking and The three new authorities are responsible European Commission, and the chairpersons policy coordination. The two elements of the in these areas for coordinating with the of the three ESAs. There are also nonvoting response are: respective national supervisory or regulatory members. But there is uncertainty about authorities. But the legal and regulatory • The creation on January 1, 2011, of whether this decisionmaking structure is authority for conducting everyday supervision the European System of Financial sufï¬?ciently empowered and independent. remains with national authorities. The Supervision, a framework for coordination First, because of the size and composition mandates of the new ESAs therefore do not of microprudential supervision and of the board, it will be difï¬?cult to reach provide much scope beyond an enhanced for a macroprudential organization for consensus on risks and mitigation response. coordination role. An important part of the assessing Europe-wide systemic ï¬?nancial Second, the ESRB’s recommendations are legislation is a safeguard clause specifying that nonbinding and subject to influence. National risks. no decision by the ESAs may impinge on the authorities are responsible for taking action, • The creation of a new—and still evolving— ï¬?scal responsibilities of member states. but are not obliged to do so. Although the sovereign crisis resolution and European ESRB does have the authority to follow up on The new macroprudential supervisor economic surveillance mechanism its recommendations, its only recourse is to comprising the European Stability The European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) go public. Third, the board is constrained in Mechanism, a permanent crisis resolution is the European Union’s coordinating assessing risks and making recommendations tool, to replace in July 2013 the European organization to monitor and assess Europe- because it does not have uninhibited access Financial Stabilization Mechanism in EU wide systemic risks and vulnerabilities. or independent authority for obtaining member states and the European Financial One of the shortcomings of the precrisis information on ï¬?nancial institutions. Stability Facility in euro area countries architecture was an overemphasis on facing sovereign debt problems; the Euro supervising individual ï¬?nancial institutions Source: Schinasi (2011). 152 CHAPTER 3 by the capital requirements proposed in Basel III. Yet these effects are still manageable, and the beneï¬?ts of greater ï¬?nancial stability are likely to outweigh transitional costs. One possible area of disagreement between EU members relates to the discussions on capital, liquidity, and leverage regulations. The source of conflict is whether these requirements should be viewed as a minimum standard or as a target to be applied equally by all countries. Bulgaria, Estonia, Lithuania, the Slovak Republic, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom recently argued that EU member states should be allowed to apply more stringent regulations.25 Given that countries in the European Union might face different initial conditions and different economic cycles, it would seem sensible to allow for differential practices as long as these are not discriminatory and meet the agreed minimum standards. This approach is further supported by the fact that the ï¬?scal implications of bank resolution remain in the purview of national ï¬?scal authorities. · Dealing with a large foreign presence: the home and host challenge. Despite ï¬?nancial integration and the emergence of pan-European ï¬?nancial institutions, supervision of EU groups remains segmented. Where cross- border groups have set up subsidiaries under local host country laws, these subsidiaries are subject to host country supervision and regulation. By contrast, where cross-border branches have been set up, these are supervised by home country authorities. EU laws provide safeguards for the host country supervisors to act only under certain conditions (for example, to protect depositors in emergencies). Moreover, these supervisors retain control of liquidity even in branches (as is the case with domestic institutions, be these domestically owned or subsidiary operations from other countries), and are entitled to being informed by home authorities of relevant information on the whole group. But this supervision structure, largely unchanged from before the crisis, is complex, with multiple lines of reporting between home and host country supervisors. Nor does it address the misaligned incentive structures of cross-border supervision: it creates supervisory gaps, especially in emerging Europe, and has been associated with a level of mistrust that does not encourage effective cooperation. Host country supervisors depend heavily on the effectiveness of home country supervisors. Problems to be addressed include: · Host country supervisors do not have comprehensive means to challenge the home state supervision of a group with branches in its territory. Home state supervisors tend to protect their own domestic banking system, not the host country’s. · There is no binding mediation mechanism arbitrating between home and host supervisors. If a national supervisor fails to take a necessary step, no quick mechanism allows for a collaborative decision on the liquidity or solvency of a group. · Effective cross-border crisis-management arrangements are lacking. 153 GOLDEN GROWTH · There are no mechanisms to facilitate sharing the costs of liquidity support between home and host country authorities, or the costs of recapitalizing or winding down an institution in the host country. Unless Europe deals with this policy failure on cooperation between home and host supervisors, emerging Europe will continue to struggle in managing the ï¬?nancial implications of foreign banks’ operations as their activities ebb and flow with economic and credit cycles. · Managing liquidity during a crisis. A sudden restriction of access to euro and dollar liquidity hurt emerging Europe. Prior to the crisis, domestic and foreign banks in the European Union (but outside the eurozone) relied heavily on the pan-European money markets for managing liquidity. These markets work through a hub-and-spoke system in which large (or money center) institutions gather liquidity at European Central Bank (ECB) auctions and then act as conduits to provide and gather liquidity from small and medium European banks engaged in retail ï¬?nance. During the repeated bouts of liquidity crisis since late 2007 and until late 2009, large money center banks became risk-averse and curtailed their lending to what they viewed as higher-risk countries and banks. This lending “triageâ€? led to severe euro liquidity shortages in emerging Europe. While some parent banks of dominant foreign branches and subsidiaries operating in the EU12 provided liquidity, the subsidiaries operating there did not have direct access to ECB liquidity facilities because of the ECB’s collateral arrangements and policies. The ECB relaxed its collateral requirements during the crisis, but it did not expand eligibility to securities denominated in non- euro currencies (other than a handful of reserve currencies), though it should also be said that the ECB did support non-euro area countries indirectly by providing liquidity to parent banks in the euro area. Developments since mid-2011 are once again threatening the liquidity needs in Europe’s banking system, though central banks are also showing signs of being better prepared to intervene swiftly to address liquidity problems as they arise. Because of these liquidity problems, IMF-supported programs (in some cases with European Commission and World Bank support) became necessary. Although recent reforms to IMF facilities are likely to help by providing precautionary liquidity to eligible countries through flexible credit lines, the sovereign debt crises in the euro area suggest that no amount of funding can resolve economic and ï¬?nancial stability challenges when the policy environment itself produces indecision and uncertainty. Perhaps the ECB could take on this responsibility in the future; for instance, it could extend swap lines to central banks of noneuro countries in the European Union, akin to what the U.S. Federal Reserve did with Brazil, Korea, and Mexico at the peak of the 2008–09 crisis. Manage external imbalances, don’t eliminate them Europe’s ï¬?nancial integration represents an enviable development opportunity but with large tail risks. While there is no doubt that unusually liquid global markets during the precrisis period would have strained the toolkit of any government authority (Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo 2010), policymakers 154 CHAPTER 3 across emerging Europe often did not use all the tools at their disposal. The presumption that a convergence-driven “new Europeâ€? was at hand led to complacency among bankers and bureaucrats. In several countries, deep output falls and a slow climb to recovery are the result. What lessons can be learned? First, ï¬?scal policy should have done more to counterbalance private sector behavior, even though it was not the source of the imbalances across emerging Europe. To this end, boom-prooï¬?ng public ï¬?nance will require more determined action going forward, ranging from the discipline to save the revenue over- performance of boom cycles to, in some cases, a more deliberate effort to counterbalance private sector behavior—if not one-to-one, at least as a signaling device to avoid a buildup of vulnerabilities. Second, private ï¬?nance has to be crisis-proofed. Macroprudential tools must play a greater role in the future, and nationally, they should be deployed to limit the buildup of vulnerabilities (even though the experience of countries that used these policies suggests that their effects are transitory, and thus might require frequent modiï¬?cations). For example, many countries are now taking steps to improve credit quality, an area in which most countries did little in the years preceding the global crisis. In addition, at a supranational level, countries that are less ï¬?nancially and institutionally developed must have recourse to measures that could require special treatment within the single market―and still in conformity with the single market principles. The newer elements of the European ï¬?nancial architecture are, as a result of the current sovereign debt crises, likely to strengthen ï¬?nancial stability. But the initial conditions in the small, open economies at income levels much below the EU average may occasionally call for more proactive interventions. This remains an area for further discussion among EU members. Helping markets deal with overindebtedness The debt challenges faced by Eastern Europe are different from those in the EU cohesion countries, yet the future of these countries is interconnected. Indeed, while at the time of writing the center of gravity has shifted toward Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, spillover effects could still reach east given the interlinkages in Europe’s ï¬?nancial system. It is against this background that policymakers in emerging Europe have to assess whether a debt overhang threatens the recovery. This requires assessing how widespread the use of debt is, in particular among ï¬?rms and households. It is worth noting that a debt overhang does not necessarily mean that governments should take over this debt. Removing institutional and structural bottlenecks that act as a disincentive to private debt restructuring efforts is the logical ï¬?rst step (even with no debt overhang). But in extreme cases, debt relief with public resources might be needed to strengthen coordination between debtors and creditors.26 These public actions, however, are not costless. By intervening, the public sector internalizes the economic implications of default that, in turn, could eventually weaken growth prospects.27 Moreover, just the hint of a debt relief intervention could lead to a lack of payment discipline (“debtor moral hazardâ€?) or excessive risk-taking (“creditor moral hazardâ€?; box 3.5). 155 GOLDEN GROWTH How can one assess if a debt overhang exists? The ï¬?rst step is to carry out what can be viewed as a macroeconomic analysis of balance sheets. This involves both an assessment of external solvency and liquidity indicators, as well as an examination of domestic public and private aggregate exposures.28 Two questions need answers: Is the country solvent or illiquid? Do the debt overhang risks originate in public or private balance sheets? As a benchmark against which to compare developments in emerging Europe, this chapter uses aggregate external and domestic indicators from emerging markets in East Asia, Latin America, and the EU cohesion countries.29 In doing so, one must keep in mind a number of factors that impact debt sustainability. For example, countries with better institutions can sustainably accommodate higher debt levels. In addition, underlying debt dynamics depend closely on growth and interest rates. Thus, the aggregate assessment of debt levels that follows should be looked at as a ï¬?rst approximation, not least because the uncertain economic outlook in the eurozone and the global economy make debt sustainability across emerging Europe more challenging. But aggregate balance sheets can only take you so far, as they provide no more than a general idea of debt risks. As argued by Albacete and Fessler (2010, p89), “macrodata is of limited use in the analysis of the risks to ï¬?nancial stability … as it is neither possible to differentiate between households that hold debt and those that do not, nor is it possible to combine data on … debt with data on … assets.â€? The same applies to ï¬?rms. In this regard, data originating in surveys of ï¬?rms and households provide a fuller picture of the debt risks faced by a country. What is novel about this chapter is that it also looks at the microeconomic dimensions of debt in emerging Europe: ï¬?rst, by examining the debt incidence among ï¬?rms and households, as well as the characteristics of those with debt; second, by assessing the combination of risk and shock factors to which ï¬?rms and households with debt have been exposed during the crisis; and third, by stress-testing the resilience of households’ balance sheets to economic shocks. This section concludes that much of emerging Europe is different from the worst-off among the EU cohesion countries. At a macroeconomic level, external and domestic public and private balance sheets seem manageable, although a prolonged economic downturn in the European Union and a lagging recovery of the global economy could have signiï¬?cant negative spillover effects. At a microeconomic level, indebted ï¬?rms and households are a small share of all ï¬?rms and households, so direct effects on aggregate consumption and investment are likely to be small. This does not mean that the ï¬?rms and households that borrowed heavily and the banks that lent them money will not face ï¬?nancial distress. (They might.) But the aggregate direct effect on economic activity is unlikely to be large. This conclusion, sanguine at ï¬?rst sight, must be qualiï¬?ed due to developments in the banking sector. Ratios of nonperforming loans to total lending in the range of 10–20 percent are a serious concern, and the need to husband resources back home could force some foreign banks to retrench their operations in emerging Europe. So far this has not happened, and foreign bank ownership has been a source of stability in emerging Europe in contrast to previous crisis episodes in emerging markets. Since emerging Europe has debt 156 CHAPTER 3 Box 3.5: The pros and cons of debt-relief interventions Macroeconomic nominal exchange rate changes is needed). decisions should not be taken in haste. A debt overhang affects growth through Microeconomic First, it is important to assess if a debt multiple channels. If the debtor is the public overhang actually exists and that, absent Evaluating whether there is a debt overhang sector, the overhang could require higher taxes public ï¬?nancial support, social welfare will requires balance sheets to be assessed. Myers to service these debts, which in turn would decline. In emerging Europe, the case for such (1977) argued that a link exists between weaken economic incentives and undermine debt relief does not appear to be compelling. debt levels and ï¬?rms’ decisions: if proï¬?ts growth prospects (Sachs 1989). It might also from new investments are likely to be used Even in the countries most at risk, market- turn funding markets more fragile. Speciï¬?cally, to pay existing creditors, shareholders might based approaches appear adequate to address if rollover risks increase, creditors might want choose to pass up what would otherwise be the borderline debt-overhang cases discussed to limit their exposure, concerned that liquidityproï¬?table investment opportunities. Similar in this chapter. Also, although the strength problems may generate market disruptions. arguments apply to household investment in of banks’ balance sheets in emerging Europe Further, when the debts are external, the home improvement (Melzer 2010), reduced is uncertain, these banks depend heavily on ï¬?nancial integration process that created these labor supply owing to the wedge imposed on their Western European parent institutions’ obligations might also alter the economic incomes by debt-service obligations (Mulligan strength. The provision of public money by adjustment process. Large external obligations 2008), and limited consumption (Olney 1999). emerging Europe’s governments is not easy require trade surpluses that are more easily Equally, banks that have overleveraged to justify. achieved with exchange rate depreciations, balance sheets and are facing losses might Second, the debtor and creditor moral hazard but while depreciations help to bring in the limit new lending. In sum, balance sheet risks need to be gauged. From a borrower necessary foreign exchange, they also have factors might become a drag on banks’ ability perspective, just talk of debt relief weakens valuation effects. Import compression might to restore credit and support the recovery. payment discipline. From a lender perspective, generate the necessary foreign exchange The extent to which the balance sheets of bailouts might encourage excessive risk- resources, but at the expense of limiting ï¬?rms, households, and banks undermine taking. Debt-relief interventions also risk domestic demand and deepening a recession. economic activity also relates to their creating opportunities for politicization and Thus the resulting social and economic costs aggregate impact on the economy. Other capture by special interest groups on a matter might require either a debt restructuring or ï¬?rms, households, and banks might pursue that, so far, remains a largely private affair in increased access to ofï¬?cial ï¬?nancial assistance investment, consumption, and lending much of emerging Europe. to mitigate the economic adjustment. opportunities that economic agents with Third, the premise that households should be The positive aspect of ï¬?nancial integration, overleveraged balance sheets cannot. But as compensated for an increase in debt-service seen, debt incidence in emerging Europe is not as in Europe, is that it allows countries to burden due to external economic shocks is not widespread and thus unlikely to become a drag spread the adjustment across borders. Foreign easily justiï¬?ed given the distribution of debt on economic activity. investors, for instance, see a decline in proï¬?ts across income quintiles. The analysis suggests on their equity holdings. Another feature of Given that the public sector in emerging that most households have room to tackle emerging Europe is that the foreign ï¬?nancing, Europe is not highly leveraged, it is often economic shocks. If, for political reasons, it is which enabled high credit growth, is also the argued that governments can share the necessary to introduce such programs, it would main source of external account adjustment burden imposed by existing debts on ï¬?rms seem sensible to target scarce public resources (that is, no change in relative prices through and households. For several reasons, such by loan size and household income. concentrated in few ï¬?rms and households, there is at least the potential for other actors (that is, new banks) to consider entering the ï¬?nancial sector. Given the challenges faced by Europe as a whole, however, there is no question that downside risks remain unusually high. Deleveraging has so far been limited and orderly, but in large measure because growth prospects in emerging Europe remained strong. The challenges within the eurozone are calling into question this assessment and could force parent banks to retrench in noncore markets. Economies—solvent and liquid Several studies have recently analyzed the level of external indebtedness beyond which a country is likely to suffer slower growth and sustainability risks (Reinhardt and Rogoff 2010; Imbs and Rancière 2007). They point to a gross external debt-to-GDP ratio above 60 percent as a vulnerability threshold, although this varies with a country’s level of ï¬?nancial development and 157 GOLDEN GROWTH institutional strength. For emerging Europe, and in particular new EU members, the sustainable threshold is likely to be above that for a typical developing country. Moreover, it may be more appropriate to look at net external liabilities than at gross external debt as an indicator for a country’s external solvency, explicitly taking a country’s foreign assets as well as the structure of its liabilities (debt or equity) into account. As noted, any assessment of underlying debt dynamics depends closely on growth and interest rates, all of which currently face high degrees of uncertainty. Against this background, and compared with emerging markets in past crises that had average net foreign asset positions of –36 percent of GDP, equivalent group positions in 2009 of the EU12 (–70 percent), EU candidates (–57 percent), and EU eastern partnership countries (–62 percent) were weaker (ï¬?gure 3.13, left panel; these have changed only marginally since 2009). But they compare favorably with EU cohesion countries (–99 percent of GDP). Countries vary of course: net foreign asset positions were –129 percent of GDP in Hungary and –87 percent of GDP in Latvia, but less than –50 percent of GDP in the Czech Republic and Turkey. While overall external liabilities seem large, net debt positions are not too weak in emerging Europe. With one exception, such positions are better than –60 percent of GDP, reflecting the substantial FDI inflows that characterize emerging Europe (ï¬?gure 3.13, right panel). Net equity positions decline much more than net debt positions between 2002 and 2009 (ï¬?gure 3.14). By contrast, net debt positions are the sole source of increase in external obligations among EU cohesion countries. The same is true for Estonia, Lithuania, Slovenia, and, to a lesser extent, Latvia and Hungary, though their net debt positions are not as large as those of EU cohesion countries. Why is the distinction between net debt and net equity positions important? The distinction matters because different types of liabilities have different burden- sharing features. In good times, the upside from growth accrues to foreign investors (Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2007). Conversely, the value of equity liabilities falls as the economic performance of capital-recipient countries weakens. Emerging Europe has another unique feature: a large share of its net debt positions originate in parent banks and ï¬?rms extending credit lines to their subsidiary operations, due to the tax and regulatory advantages of such credit lines. When subsidiaries in emerging Europe are confronted with ï¬?nancial difï¬?culties, however, not only is the capital base of their subsidiaries able to provide a buffer against negative shocks, but also parent banks and ï¬?rms have been willing to convert these credit lines into capital. This is, for instance, the experience of banks in the Baltic countries. In sum, support by parent institutions to their subsidiaries in emerging Europe is a long-term strategic decision that depends on the European Union’s growth outlook; thus, an integrated region where foreign ownership structures are important cannot be looked at through the metric used in other emerging markets.30 What about external liquidity positions? Emerging Europe has large foreign exchange positions that should serve to cushion the risks of external shocks.31 Apart from the Baltic states, most countries have a ratio of total gross debt liabilities to foreign exchange assets of 3.5 or less—a sizable buffer. Countries 158 CHAPTER 3 that suffered capital account crises in the past had weaker foreign exchange liquidity positions a year before such crises (ï¬?gure 3.15). On this metric, the countries most at risk are the Baltic states (though Estonia must now be excluded as it joined the euro in January 2011), but their dependence on one country for most of their foreign exchange liquidity needs (Swedish banks dominate their banking sectors) likely lessens these risks because such concentration facilitates debtor and creditor coordination. In sum, emerging Europe’s external solvency and liquidity positions are in some respects stronger than those of emerging markets that suffered balance of payments or debt crises in the past, particularly taking into account the strength of parent bank support, the particular role of FDI, and the sizable foreign exchange reserves many of these countries have. Institutional developments in Net foreign assets (percentage of GDP) Net debt (percentage of GDP) Figure 3.13: Emerging Europe is solvent, the EU cohesion countries less so (net foreign assets and net debt, percentage of GDP, 2009) Note: The right panel reports net debt, which is international debt assets plus foreign exchange reserves minus international debt liabilities as a percentage of GDP. Ireland is excluded from the right panel as its data are distorted because international mutual funds hosted by Ireland are recorded as positive net debt, even though these resources are not related to the domestic economy. The light blue columns in both panels represent the EU cohesion countries. Similarly, the dark green columns are capital account crises countries in East Asia and LAC (Latin America and the Caribbean) regions in the 1990s and 2000s as well as Turkey in 2000. The light green columns are the 2009 regional averages for East Asia and LAC. Source: Updated and extended version of dataset constructed by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2007. Figure 3.14: Greater debt exposure in Southern Europe, more equity exposure in the east (aggregate external net equity and net debt exposures, percentage of GDP, 2002–09) Note: Arrows begin in 2002 and end in 2009. The arrows for each region are median values. The dots are the median values for the reference groups. Ireland is excluded from net debt position (see note for ï¬?gure 3.13). Source: Updated and extended version of dataset constructed by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2007. 159 GOLDEN GROWTH emerging Europe are also a positive aspect of their integration experience. This does not make emerging Europe immune to potential spillovers from troubles in the eurozone (such as a deleveraging on the part of parent banks), but the countries in the east and southeast of Europe would appear to be in more robust external health than their more advanced peers in Europe’s south. Still, concerns remain and debt dynamics are worrying given the lack of growth in the region and the many uncertainties that still affect the recovery of the global economy; in other words, downside risks remain high. Governments—largely solvent High public debts can adversely affect capital accumulation and growth by raising inflation, distortionary taxes, long-term interest rates, and policy uncertainty. Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) ï¬?nd that differences in median growth rates of GDP between low-debt countries (less than 30 percent) and high-debt countries (above 90 percent) amount to 2–3 percentage points a year. Kumar and Woo (2010) ï¬?nd that a 10 percentage point increase in public debt ratios is linked to a slowdown in annual real per capita GDP growth ranging from 0.15 in advanced economies to 0.25 in emerging markets. They argue that this difference might reflect less developed ï¬?nancial markets or fragile access to international markets. Emerging Europe is likely to be better off on both counts. By these criteria, countries in emerging Europe are not generally at risk of a public debt overhang. Many have public debt levels only slightly above the lower threshold of 30 percent: the regional average was 37 percent of GDP at end-2009. Emerging Europe’s public debt ratios are, in most cases, lower than in Western Europe, EU cohesion countries, and countries that suffered economic crises in the recent past (ï¬?gure 3.16, vertical axis). The one risk country is Hungary, where public debt ratios reached 78 percent of GDP at end-2009. While smaller than those observed among EU cohesion countries (the median Figure 3.15: Most economies in emerging Europe are liquid (ratio of gross liabilities to foreign exchange holdings, 2009) Note: Higher columns indicate greater risk of suffering foreign exchange liquidity problems. The dark green columns are capital account crises countries in East Asia and LAC (Latin America and the Caribbean) regions in the 1990s and 2000s as well as Russia in 1998 and Turkey in 2000. The data for capital account crises countries reflect liquidity ratios a year before the crisis. The light green columns are the 2009 regional median values for East Asia and LAC. Source: Brown and Lane 2011. 160 CHAPTER 3 value of public debt among this latter group rose to 95 percent of GDP by end-2010), it remains too high for comfort. Albania and Poland also have borderline high levels of public debt. In conclusion, even though very few countries are a concern, the capacity to add debt on public balance sheets is limited across most emerging European countries—and perhaps more so given the uncertain outlook for the global economic recovery. Most countries have accumulated debt since the crisis erupted, and a few already have to adopt debt-reducing policies. Fiscal prudence will thus need to be maintained and potentially even strengthened (see also chapter 7). Private aggregate debt—mostly manageable Private sector credit developments reveal the growing ï¬?nancial depth of emerging Europe as it integrated with Western Europe, greater dependence on direct cross-border loans, and the dominant role of relationship-based ï¬?nancing that characterizes Continental Europe. Speciï¬?cally, the private debt obligations of emerging Europe’s countries—as credit through the domestic banking system and direct cross-border loans to the nonï¬?nancial sector—are in some cases larger than in other emerging markets (ï¬?gure 3.16, horizontal axis). Private sector debt in, for instance, the Baltic states, Bulgaria, Croatia, and Slovenia is higher than in East Asia, though lower than in the EU cohesion countries and other countries in Western Europe. The high credit growth between 2004 and 2009 stems mainly from growing credit to ï¬?rms (ï¬?gure 3.17, vertical axis). The countries with the most rapid increase in ï¬?rm credit are Albania, Bulgaria, Slovenia, and Ukraine. Total household debt in emerging Europe is below the EU15 average (ï¬?gure 3.18). At 25–30 percent, the ratios correspond to those in the United States when this country had similar incomes per capita (in real purchasing power parity terms).32 Overleveraged households are a potential risk, but only in a handful of countries: Croatia, Estonia, and Latvia, and perhaps also in Bosnia Figure 3.16: EU cohesion countries have higher levels of public and private debt than emerging European countries (aggregate exposure of the public and private sectors, percentage of GDP, 2004–09) Note: Arrows begin in 2004 and end in 2009. The exception is the EU cohesion countries where the data for public debt corresponds to end-2010. The arrows for each region are median values. The dots are the median values for the reference groups. Total private sector credit is the combination of credit through the domestic banking system and credit through direct cross-border flows. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Abbas and others 2011; Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine 2000 and 2010; BIS Locational Banking Statistics; European Commission 2011; and IMF WEO. 161 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.17: Credit to ï¬?rms grew faster than to households in most emerging European countries (change in aggregate exposure of ï¬?rms and households, percentage of GDP, 2004–09) Note: Arrows begin in 2004 and end in 2009. The arrows for each region are median values. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on EBRD Structural Change Indicators; and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine 2000 and 2010. and Herzegovina, Montenegro, and Ukraine (these three countries on account of their lower income levels). Still, margins for additional private debt accumulation are more limited than in the early 2000s. To conclude, even though emerging Europe’s countries have high aggregate private debt exposures, benchmarking ï¬?nancial sector development shows that only a handful have private sector credit-to-GDP ratios above what corresponds to countries at similar levels of economic development.33 More important, they have much less developed stock and bond markets. This suggests that emerging Europe’s experience with high credit-to-GDP ratios might partly reflect the relationship-based ï¬?nancing features of Continental Europe (Wolf 2011). In this context, examining the debt features at the level of ï¬?rms, households, and banks using microeconomic level data (surveys) can provide useful insights. Firms—the stressed are sophisticated The Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey (BEEPS), conducted by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) and the World Bank every three years, can be used to assess potential debt overhang among ï¬?rms. The 2008–09 BEEPS was carried out at the onset of the crisis, and provides data on a representative sample of 9,098 ï¬?rms in emerging Europe.34 The survey deï¬?nes use of bank credit as ï¬?rms that have loans or overdraft facilities.35 The survey offers several ï¬?ndings. First, the ï¬?rms that are most indebted are also more likely to be ï¬?nancially sophisticated. Speciï¬?cally, in line with the evidence on information asymmetries and credit access (for example, Brown, Jappelli, and Pagano 2009), large ï¬?rms (with more than 50 employees), ï¬?rms with audited ï¬?nancial statements, and ï¬?rms with an export orientation are more likely to use bank credit (table 3.3). The difference is also economically important: about 60 percent of large, audited, and exporting ï¬?rms rely on bank credit, while only about 40 percent of small, nonaudited, and nonexporting ï¬?rms do. Also, old and manufacturing ï¬?rms are more likely to use bank credit, but the difference relative to ï¬?rms with the opposite characteristics is not large. 162 CHAPTER 3 Figure 3.18: Household indebtedness rose in emerging Europe, but remains below EU15 levels (total household debt, percentage of GDP, 2000–09) Note: All types of household debt are included. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on data from the European Credit Research Institute (Lending to Households in Europe, 1995-2010); and EBRD Transition Indicators. Table 3.3: Firm characteristics and use of bank credit in emerging Europe Note: The sample tests report the results of linear independent tests that examine whether credit incidence differs for ï¬?rms with and without each ï¬?rm characteristic. ***, **, and * denote signiï¬?cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Share of firms Bank loan (share of firms within Overdraft (share of firms within (percent) category) category) yes 74 0.40 0.44 Small firm no 26 0.60 *** 0.61 *** yes 62 0.42 0.47 Young firm no 38 0.48 *** 0.52 *** yes 44 0.55 0.55 Audited no 56 0.38 *** 0.43 *** yes 34 0.49 0.45 Manufacturing no 66 0.42 *** 0.53 *** yes 26 0.58 0.60 Exporter no 74 0.41 *** 0.44 *** yes 5 0.47 0.49 State-owned no 95 0.44 0.47 yes 1 0.40 0.64 Foreign-owned no 99 0.44 0.47 * Source: Brown and Lane 2011. Second, emerging Europe’s ï¬?rms still rely heavily on internal ï¬?nancing or retained earnings. The share of ï¬?xed investment ï¬?nanced by bank credit during 2007 is small (table 3.3). Seventy-four percent did not rely on debt, either because they did not invest (40 percent) or because they ï¬?nanced their investments without use of bank credit (34 percent). Among the ï¬?rms that use external ï¬?nancing for investment, the amount of ï¬?nancing (that is the amount of “leverageâ€?) increases as ï¬?rms get more sophisticated. Leverage is moderate to high (meaning that more than 34 percent of investments are externally ï¬?nanced) in large (25 percent), audited (24 percent), and exporting (26 percent) ï¬?rms. Other characteristics also matter (for example, age and ownership), but 163 GOLDEN GROWTH the differences are not as important economically. With this as background, two approaches assess the existence of a debt overhang among ï¬?rms: a level approach and a risk-shock approach. The level approach relies on the ï¬?ndings of the literature on aggregate leverage. Coricelli and others (2009) examine balance sheets and income statements for 8,000 manufacturing ï¬?rms in emerging Europe and establish a leverage threshold—40 percent—above which debt reduces ï¬?rm productivity.36 They ï¬?nd that the share of ï¬?rms with leverage exceeding this threshold is higher in Bulgaria, Latvia, and the Russian Federation (15 percent of all ï¬?rms in these countries). Taking this threshold as given, the BEEPS data suggest that the share of ï¬?rms with excessive leverage (moderate to high leverage ratios) has, at about 19 percent, increased only marginally from the Coricelli and others sample (table 3.4).37 Even among the larger ï¬?rms, only one in four had either large or moderate leverage, and these ï¬?rms are more likely to withstand economic shocks. The level approach thus presents a largely reassuring picture: debt incidence among ï¬?rms is a limited phenomenon and is unlikely to be important in limiting economic activity.38 Table 3.4: Firm debt is held by the ï¬?nancially sophisticated in emerging Europe Note: The table reports the distribution of the variable investment loan for subsamples of ï¬?rms that have and do not have a speciï¬?c ï¬?rm characteristic. Chi-square tests report whether the distribution is signiï¬?cantly different for ï¬?rms with and without each ï¬?rm characteristic. ***, **, and * denote signiï¬?cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. No Investment share financed by loan (percent) investment 0 1 - 33 34 - 67 67 - 100 Chi2 test All firms 40 34 7 8 11 yes 48 32 5 6 10 Small firm no 28 38 9 11 14 *** yes 42 34 6 7 11 Young firm no 36 35 8 8 12 *** yes 32 36 8 10 14 Audited no 46 34 6 5 9 *** yes 40 34 7 7 11 Manufacturing no 40 35 7 8 11 yes 30 36 8 11 15 Exporter no 45 34 6 6 10 *** yes 27 49 6 8 10 State-owned no 41 33 7 8 11 *** yes 42 35 8 8 8 Foreign-owned no 40 34 7 8 11 Source: Brown and Lane 2011. 164 CHAPTER 3 Combining risk and shock factors augments the level approach. High debt affects future operations and investment if ï¬?rms are hit by a shock. Whether highly leveraged ï¬?rms are at risk depends also on the macroeconomic environment in which they operate. Three sources of macroeconomic shocks and their potential impact on the balance sheets of ï¬?rms are explored: a decline in GDP, a decline in exports, and a rise in exchange rates (which affects unhedged ï¬?rms with foreign currency loans). The main conclusion is that ï¬?nancial distress owing to these risk–shock combinations is limited in emerging Europe. Figure 3.19 plots the outcome of all three economic shocks.39 The ï¬?gure helps to identify endangered countries that face high risks (due to a large proportion of relatively highly leveraged ï¬?rms or a large proportion of foreign currency loans) and suffer large macroshocks: · The top-left panel shows the share of ï¬?rms with moderate to high leverage ratios (the risk factor) and declines in real GDP in 2009 (the shock factor). The risk region is the upper left corner of the panel: countries that have a large share of overleveraged ï¬?rms and face a sharp decline in real GDP. By this measure, only ï¬?rms in the three Baltic states are likely to face ï¬?nancial distress. Firms in Croatia and Slovenia might face ï¬?nancial distress as well, though the income shock they experienced was not as large. As a counterexample, FYR Macedonia is a high-risk country on account of its high leverage levels, but ï¬?nancial distress is unlikely because this economy did not suffer a sharp GDP contraction. · The top-right panel plots the share of unhedged foreign currency loans (the risk factor) against the depreciation (the shock factor) experienced by each country: the cumulative exchange rate change in 2007–09.40 The debt overhang zone is at the upper-center and upper-right corner of the panel, showing countries that have a large share of unhedged ï¬?rms and face a sharp depreciation. Albania seems to be the country most at risk, with a depreciation of more than 15 percent and more than 30 percent of all loans unhedged. Firms in Ukraine, which experienced the sharpest depreciation during the crisis (55 percent), are less likely to be affected due to the low shares of unhedged foreign currency loans. · The bottom left panel shows the share of exporting ï¬?rms with moderate to high leverage ratios (the risk factor) and declines in exports (the shock factor). The countries in the upper left corner of the panel are those most at risk, with a large share of overleveraged ï¬?rms and a sharp decline in exports. Firms in Estonia, FYR Macedonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and Slovenia are the most likely to be experiencing ï¬?nancial distress. In each of these countries about a third of the exporting ï¬?rms are moderately to highly leveraged, and the decline in exports is pronounced. But ï¬?nancial distress in the tradable sector affects a broader set of countries. For example, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Serbia, the Slovak Republic, and Turkey had a quarter of their export-oriented ï¬?rms moderately to highly leveraged and faced export declines of about 20 percent of GDP. The speed with which export markets recover will be critical in determining the impact of these trade shocks. Developments in 2010 and 2011 (at least until July) are, in terms of export recovery, encouraging (ï¬?gure 3.19, bottom right panel). 165 GOLDEN GROWTH Households—few indebted and often wealthy The 2010 EBRD-World Bank Life in Transition survey (LITS), which provides information on 23,525 households for the 21 emerging European countries examined in this chapter, is used to assess the extent of debt overhang among households.41 This survey includes information on expenditures, household composition, current and past economic activity of respondents, and the incidence and type of bank debt held. Households that own the dwelling they inhabit are asked whether they have a mortgage and, if so, whether it is denominated in local or foreign currency. Households are also asked whether any member has a debit or credit card, and how they responded to the crisis, whether through cuts in consumption and investment or the sale of assets. As with ï¬?rms, debt incidence among households is limited. Just 6 percent of households living in a dwelling they own have a mortgage (table 3.5), and only a third of all mortgages are in foreign currency—that is, just 2 percent of the owner-occupied dwellings in the region have a foreign currency mortgage. By contrast, credit cards are used by a quarter of the population. This contrasts with around 40 percent of households in France, Germany, Italy, Sweden, and Figure 3.19: A few ï¬?rms in a few countries are at risk in emerging Europe Note: Error bands (95 percent conï¬?dence intervals) are depicted with dashed lines. The shaded countries denote varying degrees of risk. Also, in Estonia’s case, the adoption of the euro eliminates the exchange rate risk in euro-denominated loans. Source: Brown and Lane 2011; and IMF WEO. 166 CHAPTER 3 the United Kingdom who have a mortgage, and 53 percent who have a credit card. The countries naturally have differences. In the EU12 countries, 9 percent of all households have a mortgage compared with 4 percent in EU candidate and 2 percent in EU eastern partnership countries. Credit card use is less frequent in EU eastern partnership countries (10 percent) than in either the EU12 (31 percent) or EU candidate countries (30 percent). Even the EU12 countries reveal large differences in household use of credit. In Hungary, for example, 16 percent of households in owner-occupied dwellings have a mortgage and 55 percent of all households have a credit card. In Lithuania, the corresponding shares are 6 percent and 12 percent.42 Although household debt is limited to few households, it is still useful to ask how much they have been affected by the crisis. To answer this, two aspects of household vulnerability can be examined: how debt affects a household’s consumption and investment (the level approach), and whether household debt is more prevalent in countries severely hit by the crisis (the risk-shock approach). The 2010 LITS survey allows an assessment of household vulnerability by examining the impact of household debt on consumption and investment during the crisis (the level approach). The results of the econometric work carried out (Brown and Lane 2011) suggest that households with mortgage debt are more likely to reduce consumption and investment than households without mortgages. Speciï¬?cally, households with mortgage debt were 3 percent more likely to reduce their consumption, 8 percent more likely to cut the use of services, and 2 percent more likely to sell assets. Interestingly, the impact of mortgage debt is comparable to a loss of income (job loss). Thus the impact of mortgage debt is economically relevant. But, as already noted, the incidence of debt is limited. By contrast, there is no impact of credit card use on consumption or investment, suggesting that credit cards are not used extensively for ï¬?nancing.43 When the risk-shock approach presented earlier for ï¬?rms is applied to households with mortgage debts, the ï¬?rst conclusion is that mortgage debt does not appear to be much of a risk for economic activity (ï¬?gure 3.20, left panel). Estonia is the only country that experienced a sharp contraction in GDP and has a high incidence of mortgages. But, at 17 percent of all households, even Estonia’s debt incidence is low and unlikely to become a drag on aggregate household consumption and investment. Another endangered country is Hungary, but here too mortgage debt is limited (16 percent of all households), and the income shock has not been as sharp. Latvia, the Czech Republic, and the Slovak Republic are also moderately at risk. The second conclusion is that for countries that experienced exchange rate depreciation, the use of foreign currency mortgages is limited (ï¬?gure 3.20, right panel).44 Countries that face a large depreciation and have a large share of households with foreign currency loans are at risk. This includes Ukraine, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Serbia, although only Hungary has a large share of households with foreign currency mortgages (9 percent). 167 GOLDEN GROWTH These conclusions hold even when a broader range of household debt (that is, not only mortgage debt) and economic shocks are considered. As in previous World Bank reports (for example, Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo 2010; Sugawara and Zalduendo 2009; Tiongson and others 2010), the vulnerability of indebted households is assessed by stress-testing individual household balance sheets using economic shocks similar to the worst shocks that these countries experienced from 2007 to 2010. Using household budget surveys, households are tagged as vulnerable if they have to spend more than 30 percent of disposable income on debt service. This is done before subjecting these households to economic shocks. Speciï¬?cally, the darker shaded areas in the columns represent households that are vulnerable in each income quintile Table 3.5: Few households in emerging Europe have debt Percentage of Households with o/w FX Mortgage- Credit Card Mortgage Holder (percent) Bulgaria 14.9 3.7 30 Czech Republic 41.4 11.1 0 Estonia 31.0 16.9 50 Hungary 55.4 16.3 56 Latvia 33.6 9.2 80 Lithuania 12.4 5.6 41 Poland 19.0 4.5 37 Romania 12.9 4.8 73 Slovak Republic 40.5 12.8 0 Slovenia 46.9 3.9 19 EU12 30.8 8.9 39 Albania 17.8 2.4 39 Bosnia and Herzegovina 14.9 3.9 16 Croatia 37.5 7.0 85 Macedonia, FYR 33.1 1.7 11 Serbia 21.2 3.5 75 Turkey 57.6 3.2 6 EU candidates 30.3 3.6 39 Armenia 8.6 3.8 23 Georgia 6.7 1.7 58 Moldova 2.4 0.5 0 Ukraine 20.9 1.1 47 Eastern partnership 9.6 1.8 32 Average 26.4 5.9 37 Note: Observations are weighted to account for the varying size of the sampling units within countries. A household is said to have a mortgage if the household owns the dwelling in which it lives. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Brown and Lane 2011. 168 CHAPTER 3 Figure 3.20: Only few households in few emerging European countries are excessively indebted Note: Error bands (95 percent conï¬?dence intervals) are depicted with dashed lines. Relevant foreign currency refers to the dominant currency in which household debt seems to be denominated. For all countries it is the euro, except the Swiss franc for Hungary, Poland, and Slovenia; and the U.S. dollar for Armenia, Belarus, Georgia, Moldova, and Ukraine. Also, in Estonia’s case, the adoption of the euro eliminates the risk in all euro-denominated loans. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Brown and Lane 2011. before a household is subjected to an economic shock simulation (ï¬?gure 3.21).45 The median debt service is the lower dotted line in the ï¬?gure. Across all indebted Estonian households, for example, median debt service is 17 percent of income and only 4 percent of all households (or about 15 percent of households with debt) are vulnerable before an economic shock takes place. Two ï¬?ndings stand out. First, debt service is concentrated in upper-income households. Second, few households have debt. In Estonia, for instance, about 30 percent of all households have some type of debt (the last column in ï¬?gure 3.21). In other words, debt is not as widespread as it is in Western Europe and the United States. Next, two shock combinations are introduced.46 First, the effects of a simultaneous increase in interest rates and a depreciation of the local currency are examined (ï¬?gure 3.21, top panel). The size of these shocks is based on the highest increase in interest rates together with the largest depreciation in each country over the four-year period from January 2007 through December 2010. Implicitly, countries with ï¬?xed exchange rates would not have such a shock (and, in addition, in Estonia’s case the adoption of the euro eliminates this risk in euro-denominated loans). Second, the implications of unemployment are estimated by randomly selecting household members who become unemployed (ï¬?gure 3.21, bottom panel). The conclusion from these stress-testing scenarios is that households are affected by the shocks, but that debt burden remains manageable. For example, while 4 percent of all households were vulnerable in Estonia before an economic shock is applied, this increases to about 8 percent of all households after the shock. This represents 20–25 percent of all loans to households. Although this is not a ï¬?gure to be dismissed lightly, the shocks affect only one in every 13 households. In short, this low frequency suggests that household debt is unlikely to become a drag on aggregate economic activity in emerging 169 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 3.21: Households in emerging Europe can withstand economic shocks Note: A country-speciï¬?c shock means the magnitude of the shock varies by country and depends on the historical development in each country. For example, the unemployment shock in Estonia amounts to a 12 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate while, in Hungary, the increase is only 3 percentage points. The roman numerals refer to income quintiles in each country with “Iâ€? referring to households in the poorest quintile. Source: World Bank staff calculation, based on household budget surveys of respective countries. Europe. And the number of additional households at risk as a result of economic shocks does not appear to be particularly high, suggesting households are quite resilient to the economic shocks being modeled. Banks—some troubled, most of them foreign Even though the previous analysis concludes that debt distress affects only a small proportion of ï¬?rms and households, for some banks even this fraction can represent a sizable share of their loan portfolio. Nonperforming loans (NPLs) have increased throughout emerging Europe. Thus there may be a temporary drag on credit to the private sector as banks repair their balance sheets.47 The health of banks’ balance sheets reflects how well they can cope with the credit losses they accumulated during the crisis, an ability that depends on their proï¬?t potential. NPLs climbed sharply during 2008–09, rising by over 40 percentage points in Ukraine, for example, and 20 percentage points in Georgia, Latvia, Lithuania, and Moldova (ï¬?gure 3.22, left panel).48 In Georgia, Lithuania, 170 CHAPTER 3 Figure 3.22: Some banks in some emerging European countries are at risk (nonperforming loans and proï¬?tability) Note: Error bands (95 percent conï¬?dence intervals) are depicted with dashed lines. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Brown and Lane 2011; and Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine 2000 and 2010. Latvia, and Ukraine the increases in NPLs to precrisis (2005–07) average returns on assets were 1–2 percent—not high, but higher than in most advanced economies (about 1.5 percent in the United States, and 0.5 percent in the United Kingdom and Germany; ï¬?gure 3.22, right panel). The ratio of change in NPLs during a crisis relative to precrisis returns on assets provides an indication of a debt overhang affecting postcrisis credit growth.49 This indicator exceeds 30 for Ukraine, is between 10 and 20 for Lithuania, Hungary, and Georgia, and is just below 10 for Albania and Latvia. In other words, banks in Ukraine will require more than 30 years of precrisis proï¬?ts to cover the loan losses incurred during the crisis. By contrast, banks in Estonia or Turkey could cover the increase in NPLs with 1 or 2 years of precrisis proï¬?ts. These calculations do not include recovery rates on NPLs, which are likely to be high; indeed, real estate is the most common collateral used in emerging Europe and such collateral has high rates of recovery (Sveriges Riksbank 2009; PiÄ…tkowski and Zalduendo 2010).50 Sugawara and Zalduendo (2011) describe the case of economic shocks on household debt and the impact of ï¬?nancial stability; while it is not negligible, emerging Europe’s well-capitalized banks provide some comfort. So will banks’ problems become a drag on economic activity? Repairing their balance sheets might lead to a slowdown in credit growth. Such a deceleration is needed to a degree, given the unsustainably high credit growth rates seen before the crisis. Because many ï¬?rms and households have no debt, there is at least the potential for further expansion in banking activities. Therefore, if existing banks have difï¬?culties in mending their balance sheets (for example, Greek banks involved in the Balkans), then it is possible that new banks might enter these markets, helping to lessen credit constraints. This depends on the ability and willingness of new investors to exploit these market opportunities. In the end, the economic outlook for Europe as a whole is likely to be the key determinant of the rate at which bank lending in emerging Europe recovers—and, as noted throughout this chapter, current downside risks are particularly high. 171 GOLDEN GROWTH Moral suasion instead of public resources Even though the evidence presented so far suggests that aggregate debt distress risks are manageable, and governments, ï¬?rms, and households are for the most part not facing ï¬?nancial distress, those that are could potentially impact the balance sheets of the banking system. Therefore, avoiding the emergence of “zombie banksâ€? remains the challenge going forward. To ensure this does not hamper economic recovery, countries should remove impediments for banks to clean up their balance sheets themselves and continue to use moral suasion to lower NPL stocks (box 3.6). So far ofï¬?cial bailouts in emerging Europe have been limited to domestically owned banks (as in Latvia and Ukraine). The large share of foreign ownership of the banking system has meant that parent institutions (for which emerging Europe still represents a small share of their asset portfolio) have carried out recapitalizations when needed—and as opposed to Western Europe, many banks in emerging Europe are already well-capitalized. Moral suasion may have played a role in parent banks’ willingness to support their subsidiaries. But these foreign-owned banks seem also to have recognized the long-term nature of their investments in the region and its importance as a proï¬?t center. In sum, foreign ownership has been a blessing so far, and banking flows in the emerging Europe region are more stable (see ï¬?gure 3.9, and Ghosh, Sugawara, and Zalduendo 2011a). If a debt overhang is unlikely, what explains the slow recovery of domestic demand and credit in emerging Europe? First, uncertainty regarding sovereign debts in the EU cohesion countries acts as a disincentive for investment across Europe. Second, the health of parent banks’ balance sheets is unknown as developments in Western Europe’s sovereign debt crises evolve, leading to more cautious credit decisions and a rebalancing of balance sheets. Third, exchange rate regime choices might have contributed to a lower reduction in cross-border flows than in earlier crises in other emerging market regions—an overshooting of the exchange rate has not taken place. But these regimes have also resulted in sharper output adjustment and corresponding income shocks on individual economic actors. Fourth, the recovery of the global economy remains challenged. Fifth, unemployment remains high and remittance flows are still lower than before the crisis, further limiting the recovery of regional domestic demand. In conclusion, some deleveraging of balance sheets in emerging Europe is to be expected. For the most part, the decline in outstanding credit envisaged in some sectors is unlikely to become a stumbling block to economic recovery. (One exception is the possible retrenchment of the real estate sector in some countries.) Therefore, it follows that the case for debt relief interventions with public ï¬?nancial support is not compelling as ï¬?scal space is limited; the social considerations for such interventions, funded with scarce public resources, are not obvious; and the moral hazard risks are signiï¬?cant and likely to have large distortionary effects. For instance, countries like Hungary—as well as Albania and Poland—already have high public debt ratios, and other countries have entered high-risk zones (public debt ratios of at least 40 percent of GDP). However, a more permanent solution to Western Europe’s public debt problems through sensible write-downs and comprehensive structural reforms is essential for the growth outlook of Europe— and thus emerging Europe—to improve. 172 CHAPTER 3 Box 3.6: Facilitating private debt resolution without public resources Public involvement in resolving debt overhangs which would force them to recognize their advanced economies is the United Kingdom’s should be limited to regulatory measures losses. Regulations will rightly require preforeclosure protocol. Its goal is to that facilitate debt restructuring and ensure provisioning against restructured loans, encourage negotiations between creditors that an effective institutional framework for given that such loans are riskier than normal and debtors by setting options on how to debt resolution is in place. Although countries loans, though unduly strict post-restructuring restructure loans, such as extending the typically have insolvency frameworks capable classiï¬?cations may impede debt resolution. term of the mortgage, changing the type of of dealing with reorganization, bankruptcy, mortgage, deferring payment on interest, or Two areas of action may be considered and liquidation, judicial systems can become capitalizing arrears. Banks are better suited to for institutional arrangements: overwhelmed when, for example, NPLs are judge the loan’s long-term viability, and this high. In such cases, out-of-court voluntary Out-of-court corporate restructuring. The decision should remain their responsibility, workouts have been effective. And there out-of-court “London approach,â€? which with an independent authority ensuring that might be strong disincentives in the regulatory was developed in the 1970s, has led to proper and fair steps are followed. A particular regime for pursuing debt-restructuring efforts. what is known as the INSOL (International concern with mortgage restructurings is that Action on both the regulatory and institutional Association of Restructuring, Insolvency they might not involve enough of a reduction fronts is needed. and Bankruptcy Professionals) principles as in net present value terms. Thus the protocol guidance for multi-creditor workouts. Three Regulatory action includes: of these principles are at the center of these should set out minimum requirements for Eliminating tax impediments to debt restructuring efforts: minimizing losses to restructuring loans, deï¬?ne which restructuring restructuring. Tax laws are designed to curb creditors from unavoidable company failures; methods should not be pursued (such as tax evasion, frequently leading to undue avoiding unnecessary liquidation through the long grace periods for insolvent borrowers), impediments to debt workouts. Whereas preservation of employment and productive and provide guidelines for the regulatory appropriate provisions created for NPLs are capacity while the ï¬?rm is restructured; and treatment of restructured mortgage loans. generally tax deductible, the deductions seeking ways to provide ï¬?nancial support to Latvia has recently developed guidelines for may have to be reversed, generating a tax companies deemed viable as the workout is restructuring mortgage loans (see Erbenova, cost after certain actions associated with concluded. These out-of-court efforts are not Liu, and Saxegaard 2011, for a discussion of problem loan resolution. Examples include a substitute for a well-functioning in-court current developments in Latvia’s mortgage debt forgiveness that is not tax deductible system; they are a necessary complement. debt restructuring efforts), and Romania (particularly when it is not part of a court- The threat of a court-imposed loss under a has developed consumer debt restructuring supervised restructuring); losses in debt-to- country’s insolvency laws is needed to create guidelines. equity swaps that might not be tax deductible the incentive for debtors to agree to measures Do these out-of-court frameworks work? As when the face value of the debt exceeds the such as asset sales, the dilution of equity, and already suggested, the success of an out-of- value of the equity; and losses when selling reduction of management control (Laryea court system of voluntary workouts depends a loan below its face value (for example, to 2010). As examples, authorities in Latvia and on the ability of creditors to impose losses a company specializing in distressed asset Romania have recently introduced reforms to on debtors. Without the threat of a court- management) that are not tax deductible. remove obstacles to out-of-court corporate Changes to tax treatment might thus be restructuring, allowing “prepackagedâ€? imposed loss under a country’s insolvency necessary to expedite debt resolution. recovery and settlement agreements between laws, debtors have little incentive to agree to debtors and creditors, and introducing asset sales, dilution of equity, and reduction of Ensuring loss recognition by lenders through management control. Indeed, a requirement flexibility to insolvency proceedings. supervision and fair regulatory treatment of for an out-of-court process is a credible threat restructured loans. Problem loans may be Out-of-court mortgage restructuring. A of seizure of assets and liquidation under provisioned inadequately, in particular at similar set of principles can be developed a normal insolvency or bankruptcy regime. weakly capitalized banks fearing regulatory for mortgage debt. The aim is to establish Creditors cannot otherwise force debtors to actions, and in these instances supervisory trust between the lender and the borrower take part in good faith. vigilance on asset classiï¬?cation is essential. and facilitate loan restructuring, rather Otherwise, lenders will avoid debt resolution, than foreclosure. A model applied in many Box contributed by Steen Byskov. An enviable development opportunity with tail risks In the late 1990s, emerging Europe embraced economic integration with Western Europe through the flow of capital, labor, and goods and services. Integration also had a deeper dimension: full membership of the European Union and then entry into a common currency area. Financial integration took place through all types of capital. FDI played a more important role than in other parts of the world, as did banking flows. Abundant global liquidity aided ï¬?nancial deepening as emerging Europe received large ï¬?nancial flows from 173 GOLDEN GROWTH richer countries. Given their dependence on Western European capital, it is unsurprising that these economies were hurt by the crisis. As external ï¬?nance dried up, the resulting income declines and job losses were bigger than in other developing regions. Financial integration contributed to the transmission of a crisis that did not originate in local economic conditions. So it is sensible to ask: Has ï¬?nancial integration in Europe happened too fast, and has it made economies in emerging Europe more vulnerable instead of vibrant? There is no doubt that gains in incomes and jobs over the two or three years prior to 2008–09 were rapidly lost during the crisis in countries such as Latvia and Ukraine. But a longer view provides a more encouraging assessment. Indeed, even after taking into account the impact of the crisis in the region, convergence in per capita incomes (in purchasing power parity terms) remains impressive. Latvia’s real GDP at end-2010 was 22 percent below the peak level reached in 2007, but this country still ranks 24th of 184 countries in terms of convergence to EU15 average incomes since 2000. So, although ï¬?nancial integration led to easy access to foreign funding and overborrowing by ï¬?rms and households in some countries, it also supported income convergence. In short, Western European savings helped Eastern European growth. Why is emerging Europe different from other regions such as East Asia and Latin America? The evidence presented in this chapter points to institutional anchoring as the unique strength of the European model of ï¬?nance for countries that begin their entry into this club. This is related to the European Union. The expectation that institutions will converge to the structures that can already be seen in Western Europe appears to be enough to spur growth. This link between foreign savings and growth has been found to be weak in other parts of the world—it has been difï¬?cult to prosper with someone else’s money. But emerging Europe is for the most part different. Foreign savings have made possible the pursuit of investment opportunities. What helped some European economies get more out of such large international ï¬?nancial flows than other countries in the region? The crisis shows that this convergence is an opportunity, not a guarantee. As noted throughout this chapter, excesses and resource misallocation also took place. Thus, to beneï¬?t from the institutional-anchoring aspects of EU membership, structural reforms are needed to persuade markets that the vision will become a reality. The right balance between growth and vulnerability has to be found, and bankers and bureaucrats need to show less complacency toward large external imbalances. The ï¬?rst area of action relates to the need to boom-proof public ï¬?nances. When economic growth leads to government coffers overflowing, this money should be saved, not spent. In some cases, countercyclical ï¬?scal policies have to offset the vulnerabilities that the closeness to big capital markets inevitably implies. The second area of action concerns the need to crisis-proof private ï¬?nance. Nationally, this requires greater reliance on macroprudential policies. As seen in the experiences of central bankers and bank supervisors in eight countries of emerging Europe, the effectiveness of such policies may at times be transitory, and regulators have to constantly play catch-up with the eagerness of ï¬?nancial intermediaries to ï¬?nd loopholes in existing prudential 174 CHAPTER 3 regulations. Also, to be fair, this policy toolkit was not always deployed; for instance, policies to improve credit quality had not been applied until recently. A ï¬?nal question: In the countries that did not manage capital inflows as well, or where these could be viewed as excessive, is there a debt overhang—a level of indebtedness that risks becoming a drag on investment and economic activity? At a macroeconomic level, the evidence for much of emerging Europe suggests not. Although countries in the region have negative foreign asset positions, their liability structure points to reliance on equity ï¬?nancing that has useful burden- sharing features. Net debt liabilities are in most cases manageable, and some have burden-sharing features given their links to ownership structures. Foreign exchange liquidity also remains, with few exceptions, comfortable. Where this is not the case, the dependence on one Western European economy for funding—for example, Sweden for the Baltic countries—helps to facilitate policy coordination between debtors and creditors. Among emerging Europe’s peers, however, some EU cohesion countries look particularly vulnerable, and this could have spillover effects on emerging Europe. At a microeconomic level, few ï¬?rms and few households have high debt. This limits the risk of a debt overhang. Most ï¬?rms and households with debt appear able to withstand severe negative shocks. Government balance sheets are quite healthy. Still, ï¬?scal space is limited. Therefore, at least for now, there is no good justiï¬?cation for using scarce public money to reduce the debt of ï¬?rms and households. Nor is there a need to bail out banks at this time. Emerging Europe has many well-capitalized banks that could once again become proï¬?t centers for Western European parents. Foreign ownership of the banking system isolated emerging Europe’s governments from the ï¬?nancial sector bailouts that were necessary in Western Europe and the United States during the crisis. In fact, foreign banks in emerging Europe took upon themselves the recapitalization of banks that were needed. This is a virtue that should be preserved. In conclusion, whether European ï¬?nance is unique should not be debated. Nor should it be deplored, and the attributes that make it unique should be preserved. Capital in Europe flows downhill—from richer to poorer countries. It also flows to higher-growth countries. Financial integration is a principal component of Europe’s economic convergence engine. Capital inflows have contributed to economic growth and made the host countries in emerging Europe richer—a conclusion that remains valid even after the recent recession. In and near the European Union, investment projects have been ï¬?nanced that would not have been otherwise. Why Europe is different can be debated, but ï¬?nancial development is not the reason. More likely, the expectations of improvements in institutional quality are the crucial element in the foreign savings–growth link—and EU membership serves as an anchor for these expectations. But this positive assessment should not distract from the risks faced by countries at different stages of development and integration. Indeed, there are lessons to be drawn from the diverse experiences of emerging Europe and the EU cohesion countries: excesses are possible and countries must remain vigilant to avoid a buildup of 175 GOLDEN GROWTH vulnerabilities. To keep up with the speed of income convergence facilitated by the extraordinary trade and ï¬?nancial integration, and to avoid Southern Europe’s current challenges, new and future members of the European Union should pay more attention to the policies and institutions that govern enterprise, innovation, work, and public service. These are the issues examined in the rest of the report. Answers to questions on page 131 The prospect of membership in the European Union exerts a powerful policy and institutional pull, making Europe unique and strengthening the link between foreign savings and economic growth. European economies that managed to “boom-proofâ€? public ï¬?nances and “crisis-proofâ€? private ï¬?nancing without resorting to the costly self-insurance seen in Asia beneï¬?ted from foreign ï¬?nancial flows. In emerging Europe, treasuries, enterprises, and households do not face a debt overhang, but in the eurozone’s periphery this problem is acute, posing a danger for banks everywhere. 176 CHAPTER 3 Chapter 3: Annexes Table A3.1: Foreign savings and growth—EU12 and EU candidate countries are different (testing the role of EU proximity and investment-driven versus savings-substitutions effects) Is it investment or savings EU proximity Dependent variable is growth in GDP per substitution? Mostly investment! capita (PPP terms) 3 emerging 2 emerging 3 emerging 2 emerging Europe groups Europe groups Europe groups Europe groups Current account balance (CAB) 0.044 0.047 0.079 -0.107 0.053 0.053 0.061 0.071 EU12 x CAB -0.245** 0.101 EU candidates x CAB -0.124** 0.062 EU 12 and EU candidates x CAB -0.165** -0.085 -0.141** 0.077 0.059 0.062 EU eastern partnership x CAB 0.485*** 0.471*** 0.495*** 0.445*** 0.135 0.130 0.178 0.129 Investment 0.318*** 0.068 Savings 0.228*** 0.066 Observations 584 584 584 584 Number of countries 88 88 88 88 p value of Hansen statistic 0.204 0.204 0.188 0.062 Number of instruments 45 40 49 49 Note: Other growth determinants included (but not reported) are population growth, educational attainment, trade openness, and the relative price of investment goods. Robust standard errors are reported below each point estimate. ***, **, * denote signiï¬?cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Source: Stojkov and Zalduendo 2011, table 5. 177 GOLDEN GROWTH Table A3.2: EU membership as an anchor for institutional development (testing the role of EU proximity and investment-driven versus savings-substitutions effects) Dependent variable is growth in GDP per Financial Financial frictions capita (PPP terms) development (institutional development) Current account balance (CAB) 0.032 0.028 0.029 0.019 0.031 0.016 0.034 0.039 0.040 0.038 0.057 0.041 EU 12 and EU candidates x CAB -0.164*** -0.169*** -0.169*** -0.674** -0.735*** -0.505* 0.051 0.057 0.060 0.255 0.260 0.264 EU eastern partnership x CAB 0.488*** 0.477*** 0.476*** 0.498*** 0.429*** 0.499*** 0.082 0.101 0.107 0.086 0.095 0.074 CAB x dummy for financial development 0.006 in top two quartiles 0.049 CAB x dummy for financial development -0.025 in top quartile 0.077 CAB x dummy for institutional 0.027 development in top two quartiles 0.075 CAB x dummy for institutional -0.037 development in top quartile 0.055 Observations 329 329 329 208 208 208 Number of countries 88 88 88 59 59 59 p value of Hansen statistic 0.305 0.567 0.269 0.511 0.598 0.720 Number of instruments 37 46 46 37 46 46 Note: Other growth determinants included (but not reported) are population growth, educational attainment, trade openness, and the relative price of investment goods. Robust standard errors are reported below each point estimate. ***, **, and * denote signiï¬?cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. Source: Stojkov and Zalduendo 2011, table 6. 178 CHAPTER 3 Notes 1 Emerging Europe includes all the countries 5 The country acronyms for ï¬?gure 3.4 and 11 Two approaches yield similar results. The integrating into the European Union, all subsequent ï¬?gures and tables are: ALB, ï¬?rst excludes countries with growth rates politically or economically: the 2004 and Albania; ARM, Armenia; AZE, Azerbaijan; that are one standard deviation above 2007 entrants to the EU (the “newâ€? member BGR, Bulgaria; BIH, Bosnia and Herzegovina; the precrisis average in each of the three states or the EU12), the EU candidate BLR, Belarus; CAN, Canada; CZE, Czech four-year periods in our sample. This countries, and the EU eastern partnership Republic; DEU, Germany; ESP, Spain; EST, excludes one or two periods for countries countries in the former Soviet Union. Estonia; GBR, Great Britain; GEO, Georgia; that experienced sharp reversals in real The EU12 comprises Bulgaria, Cyprus, the GRC, Greece; HRV, Croatia; HUN, Hungary; GDP in 2009 and eliminates (somewhat Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, IRL, Ireland; ITA, Italy; JPN, Japan; KSV, mechanically) what could be referred to Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Romania, the Kosovo; LTU, Lithuania; LVA, Latvia; MDA, as the unsustainable effects of foreign Slovak Republic, and Slovenia; data for Moldova; MKD, FYR Macedonia; MNE, savings on growth. The countries excluded Cyprus and Malta are not always available. Montenegro; POL, Poland; PRT, Portugal; are Albania, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, The candidates are the Balkans (Albania, ROM, Romania; SRB, Serbia; SVK, Slovak Montenegro, and Romania. The second Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, Kosovo, Republic; SVN, Slovenia; TUR, Turkey; UKR, approach excludes countries that have FYR Macedonia, Montenegro, and Serbia) Ukraine; and USA, United States. external imbalances that are one standard plus Turkey. The EU eastern partnership deviation above the average; many of the covers Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, 6 A similar argument is made by Prasad, same countries are excluded. Georgia, Moldova, and Ukraine. This chapter Rajan, and Subramanian (2007a and 2007b), refers to Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Abiad, Leigh, and Mody (2009), and EBRD 12 See Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo (2010) Spain as the “oldâ€? EU cohesion countries, (2009) for all transition countries. for a discussion of the challenges faced and the EU15 comprise Austria, Belgium, by the monobank systems of transition 7 A few caveats before outlining the ï¬?ndings. countries in the 1990s. Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, The countries of emerging Europe have Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, a limited economic history as market 13 The IMF’s AREAER (IMF 2010) is aggregated Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United economies since central planning. In into three groups of countries: group Kingdom. addition, transformational recessions 1 (flexible or independent floating): 2 There are differences within each country dominated the early years of transition. As Albania, Armenia, the Czech Republic, group. Estonia and Latvia, for example, a result, empirical work on these countries Moldova, Poland, and Turkey; group 2 relied heavily on Nordic banks, but at the is difï¬?cult, and for the growth analysis (intermediate, including basket, peg within peak of the crisis in Latvia these banks reported here, emerging Europe covers only bands, crawling peg, crawling band, and accounted for a smaller share of banking three four-year periods between 1997 and managed floating): Azerbaijan, Belarus, system assets: 90 percent in Estonia and 60 2008. Moreover, the global crisis interrupted Croatia, Georgia, Hungary, FYR Macedonia, percent in Latvia. While Nordic banks have the progress of these countries over the Romania, Serbia, the Slovak Republic, and maintained their exposures, banks in Latvia past decade and this needs to be captured Ukraine; and group 3 (ï¬?xed, which includes that relied on wholesale funding sources in the analysis. Finally, the verdict on countries with no legal tender, currency (delinked from parent-bank ownership ï¬?nancial integration would be less sanguine boards, and conventional pegs): Bosnia structures) and on nonresident deposits in relation to the EU cohesion countries, in and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, were more vulnerable during the crisis. See particular countries such as Greece, where Lithuania, Montenegro, and Slovenia. Both Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo (2010) for a structural and ï¬?scal weaknesses were de jure and de facto classiï¬?cations of these full discussion. papered over with foreign borrowing in choices are used, but the conclusions are the aftermath of the euro’s introduction. similar. To make the presentation simpler, 3 Private capital might flow downhill, but it These qualiï¬?cations notwithstanding, the only the de jure classiï¬?cation results are is redirected to the accumulation of foreign evidence provides an encouraging story on discussed. Following Tsangarides (2010), exchange reserves, which in effect is the merits of Europe’s ï¬?nancial integration, alternative deï¬?nitions of periods of interest equivalent to capital flowing uphill; it is not but provides a warning that its tail risks are used. The regime in place at end-2007 absorbed. Absorption would take place only are ignored only at considerable peril. The is assumed to remain valid in the two years if imports expand or the domestic resources empirical work for this section can be found reported in the ï¬?gures. devoted to producing exports are reduced, in Stojkov and Zalduendo (2011). in other words, if net capital flows match 14 This arises from faster productivity current account deï¬?cits. 8 For most emerging markets the usual growth in the tradable goods sector than explanation is that the absorptive capacity in nontradables. Wages are determined 4 This is known as the allocation puzzle, of these countries remains limited despite in the tradable goods sector in line with posed by Gourinchas and Jeanne (2007). the availability of ï¬?nancing and, as a result, productivity, and hence unit labor costs in foreign savings trigger a real overvaluation the economy as a whole increase, causing a of the currency. In turn, this weakens the real appreciation. proï¬?tability of investment and results in consumption booms. 15 The literature on the impact on credit is more mixed; De Haas and others (2011) ï¬?nd 9 See Stojkov and Zalduendo (2011). that foreign banks constrained credit more than domestic banks while Barba Navaretti 10 In the ï¬?ctional television saga Star Trek, and others (2010) ï¬?nd the opposite. The smaller spaceships cede control to large distinction between supply and demand spaceships or space stations upon approach, factors remains a challenge and, as and are pulled into docking stations by a suggested by ï¬?gure 3.9, heterogeneity powerful “tractor beam.â€? across emerging European countries will likely complicate a deï¬?nitive assessment. 179 GOLDEN GROWTH 16 In early 2009, several international 24 Similarly, euro area and EU leaders 33 Chapter 5 reports the results of a organizations and the European Commission have introduced reforms to establish benchmarking exercise similar to Cottarelli, created what became known as the Vienna permanent sovereign debt crisis- Dell’Ariccia, and Vladkova-Hollar (2005). It process: a forum for countries with IMF- resolution and ï¬?nancing mechanisms, also carries out such benchmarking for the supported programs to exchange views as well as a pact aimed at improving level of stock market development. The on economic conditions with the primary European macroeconomic performance, main conclusion is that in a few emerging banking groups involved in their countries as competitiveness, and governance. In the European countries (after controlling for well as with banking supervision authorities meantime, the sovereign debt crises are structural features), private sector credit is of both the host and home countries. being managed with temporary EU and euro above the levels of other countries at similar This process included legally nonbinding area ï¬?nancing facilities and the resources of stages of development. By contrast, stock agreements in which banks committed to the IMF. markets are extremely underdeveloped. maintain their exposures in the countries The extent to which this might simply be a involved. While it can be argued that banks 25 See Tait, Masters, and Braithwaite (2011). reflection of differences in the importance already had strong incentives to remain in 26 Creditors might, for example, have no of relationship-based ï¬?nancing is a subject the countries concerned as a result of the incentive to take part in debt-restructuring for further research. long-term nature of their investments in efforts because they would prefer to be the region, the forum facilitated exchange 34 As noted in Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo repaid on existing lending terms; in doing (2010), concerns that the survey might of views and instilled conï¬?dence in the so, however, they negatively impact the economic programs being implemented be contaminated by the early effects of region’s recovery. the crisis are not supported by the data. with international ï¬?nancial support. 27 Recent government interventions—in Ireland Although the average complaint level across 17 Allen and others (2011) highlight this most prominently—have greatly raised all dimensions of the business environment feature—what Mitra, Selowsky, and public debt, burdening economic activity. rises in 2008 relative to 2005, it is close to Zalduendo (2010) refer to as golden the 1999–2005 average and to the level handcuffs. 28 The section draws on Brown and Lane observed in nontransition economies. (2011), which provides a framework for By contrast, the 2008 complaint level 18 A similar argument is put forward by Lane assessing debt overhang, and Sugawara and for problems related to ï¬?nance remains (2010). Zalduendo (2009 and 2011), which examines similar to that in the 2002 and 2005 BEEPS 19 Purï¬?eld and Rosenberg (2010) put forward a the stress-testing of household balance surveys. This evidence would suggest that similar argument for the Baltic states. sheets. the responses from the last BEEPS survey 29 In this section East Asia comprises should be interpreted as on the eve of the 20 Some countries have experimented with crisis rather than in its early stages. dynamic provisioning rules. Spain, for Indonesia; the Republic of Korea, Malaysia; example, requires a buildup of capital the Philippines; Taiwan, China; and Thailand. 35 The BEEPS survey does not include sampling buffers when credit growth exceeds The LAC region comprises Argentina, Brazil, weights, but as the surveyed sample size certain thresholds. Note, however, that Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, and across countries accounts for country size, these policies succeed in increasing buffers Uruguay. and industry and size quotas were set so but appear to have a less clear impact in 30 No doubt this positive aspect has its own as to get a representative sample within containing credit growth itself. risks, and what will happen as a result of countries. 21 The use of high rates of reserve ongoing developments in the eurozone 36 Some perception surveys highlight that requirements is not discussed because, is a concern (such as risks of added respondents say they have more difï¬?culties although quite common in some Balkan deleveraging). But so far the behavior of servicing their debts, but this does not really countries, it represents a monetary policy parent institutions has been a plus. mean that they are facing a debt overhang tool. 31 The bulk of external debt liabilities in euro that would require debt restructuring or area countries is denominated in euro, debt-relief interventions. 22 It is difï¬?cult to estimate the impact of these measures on the health of the ï¬?nancial and these countries have access to ECB 37 Roughly 9,000 ï¬?rms are covered in the system and the degree to which they liquidity facilities. Thus, high gross debt and BEEPS 2008–09 round. Of these, 4,667 ï¬?rms mitigated the negative impacts of the low foreign exchange reserves are more report that they have a loan (roughly 50 subsequent ï¬?nancial collapse. One attempt viable options than in countries outside a percent). Among these ï¬?rms, 3,364 report in this direction is a recent paper by Polgár monetary union. positive leverage due to 2007 investment and Zdzienicka (2010) where the authors 32 Historical comparisons have limitations. For and 1,303 do not. Thus at most an additional attempt to assess the impact of different instance, ï¬?nancial innovation might enable 1,303 of the 9,000 ï¬?rms in the sample could macroprudential policies on subsequent agents to carry greater debt burdens. This is also be overleveraged. credit growth or lending in foreign why we complement the analysis by stress- exchange. testing the balance sheets of households in 23 This subsection draws on Schinasi (2011). emerging Europe. 180 CHAPTER 3 38 More detailed information for the 24 42 The table suggests very low levels of debt 44 Unlike Brown and Lane (2011), we use the countries in emerging Europe examined in among households in the region. But how depreciation relative to the foreign currency this section is simply not available—thus the good are these surveys? We explored that is most common in each country. reliance on survey information. However, central bank information and three different the analysis is consistent with earlier World sources of household budget surveys: 45 Given the concentration of debt in upper- Bank work (Mitra, Selowsky, and Zalduendo ofï¬?cial household budget surveys, the income quintiles, this vulnerability threshold 2010) using data from both Datastream European Union Statistics on Income and overestimates households at risk. Another and Bloomberg on nonï¬?nancial corporate Living Conditions, and the LITS. Overall, metric, used in Sugawara and Zalduendo leverage and on debt service coverage the data seem to be consistent though (2011), is known in the literature as the ratios. Speciï¬?cally, debt and debt service some indicators are unclear. For instance, ï¬?nancial margin (are households unable to ratios among nonï¬?nancial corporates are what is understood by a foreign currency maintain subsistence consumption levels?). not high when compared with the levels mortgage now that Slovenia and the Slovak It also suggests that household over- observed in past capital account crises Republic have adopted the euro remains an indebtedness is not widespread. events (see tables 3.3 through 3.6 in the open question. We also carried out some 46 A detailed discussion of the shocks referenced report). The drawback of such back-of-the-envelope calculations. For methodology can be found in Sugawara and data is that they only cover large, listed example, private sector credit to households Zalduendo (2011) for the case of Croatia. ï¬?rms (and in a handful of countries) in the in Ukraine amounts to some $40 billion (or This paper also includes an assessment of emerging Europe region. 25 percent of GDP), of which mortgage debt arbitrary exchange rate shocks. amounts to 14 percent of GDP. Because only 39 The regression lines and corresponding about 250,000 of 13 million households have 47 The analysis depends crucially on the conï¬?dence bands only depict the mortgage debt (2 percent of all households quality of the ofï¬?cial NPL statistics. For relationship between the indicators on living in a dwelling that they own), this example, one concern could be that Albania each axis. Identifying endangered countries would imply an average mortgage loan has seen only a small increase in NPLs requires matching high-risk and high-shock size of about $90,000 at most. These despite having about a third of foreign countries. surveys do not include consumer credits. currency loans and experiencing a sharp 40 Of course, some countries have experienced In sum, even though there are some depreciation. no adverse depreciation shock given their discrepancies between different household 48 Excesses have occurred, as noted. Thus the choice of exchange rate regime. This is a budget surveys and the LITS, they do not sectors to which resources are channeled potential source of risk in some countries. appear to be large enough to eliminate the will be quite important in the strength and For the case of households, Sugawara conclusions presented in this chapter. sustainability of the recovery. and Zalduendo (2009 and 2011) carry out 43 Respondents are asked whether during the stress-testing exercises that assume sharp 49 This is the approach followed by Brown and crisis they reduced consumption of goods Lane (2011). changes in exchange rates even in countries (food, luxury goods, alcoholic beverages), that have ï¬?xed exchange rate regimes. Even cut the use of services (phone, utilities, 50 Although real estate prices have declined, in such cases the impact remains for the health insurance), or sold assets. Such recovery rates are higher than for movable most part manageable. behavior is then linked to the household’s collateral. 41 The LITS dataset includes sampling weights use of bank debt (credit card, mortgage to account for differences in the ratio of debt) after controlling for other household sample to population size across countries characteristics (income, education level, and for sampling biases within countries. employment type) and a range of economic The data enable a representative analysis of shocks (job loss, income reduction, closing debt incidence. of a family business, reduction in remittance flows). 181 GOLDEN GROWTH References Background papers Contributions from staff at commissioned for central banks and banking this chapter supervision agencies Brown, M., and P. Lane. 2011. “Debt Banai, Ã?., J. Király, and M. Nagy. 2011. Overhang in Emerging Europe?â€? Policy “Home High Above and Home Deep Research Working Paper 5784, World Bank, Down Below—Lending in Hungary.â€? Policy Washington, DC. Background paper for this Research Working Paper 5836, World Bank, report. Washington, DC. Background paper for this Darvas, Z. 2011. “A Tale of Three Countries: report. Recovery after Banking Crises.â€? Bruegel Celeska, F., V. Gligorova, and A. Krstevska. Policy Contribution 2011/19, Bruegel, 2011. “Macroprudential Regulation of Brussels. Background paper for this report. Credit Booms and Busts: The Experience Ghosh, S., N. Sugawara, and J. Zalduendo. of the National Bank of the Republic of 2011a. “Banking Flows and Financial Macedonia.â€? Policy Research Working Crisis—Financial Interconnectedness and Paper 5770, World Bank, Washington, DC. Basel III Effects.â€? Policy Research Working Background paper for this report. Paper 5769, World Bank, Washington, DC. Frait, J., A. GerÅ¡l, and J. Seidler. 2011. “Credit Background paper for this report. Growth and Financial Stability in the Ghosh, S., N. Sugawara, and J. Zalduendo. Czech Republic.â€? Policy Research Working 2011b. “Finding a Balance between Growth Paper 5771, World Bank, Washington, DC. and Vulnerability Trade-Offs: Lessons Background paper for this report. from Emerging Europe and the CIS.â€? Policy Kenc, T., M. Turhan, and O. Yildirim. 2011. Research Working Paper 5592, World Bank, “The Experience with Macro-Prudential Washington, DC. Background paper for this Policies of the Central Bank of the Republic report. of Turkey in Response to the Global Schinasi, G. 2011. “Financial-Stability Financial Crisis.â€? Policy Research Working Challenges in European Emerging-Market Paper 5834, World Bank, Washington, DC. Countries.â€? Policy Research Working Background paper for this report. Paper 5773, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kraft, E., and T. Galac. 2011. Background paper for this report. “Macroprudential Regulation of Credit Stojkov, A., and J. Zalduendo. 2011. “Europe Booms and Busts—The Case of Croatia.â€? as a Convergence Engine: Heterogeneity Policy Research Working Paper 5772, World and Investment Opportunities in Emerging Bank, Washington, DC. Background paper Europe.â€? Policy Research Working Paper for this report. 5837, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kruszka, M. and M. Kowalczyk. 2011. Background paper for this report. “Macro-Prudential Regulation of Credit Sugawara, N., and J. Zalduendo. 2011. Booms and Busts—The Case of Poland.â€? “Stress-Testing Croatian Households with Policy Research Working Paper 5832, World Debt—Implications for Financial Stability.â€? Bank, Washington, DC. Background paper Policy Research Working Paper 5906, World for this report. Bank, Washington, DC. Background paper Popa, C. 2011. “Growth of Non-Government for this report. Credit and Macroeconomic Developments: Wolf, H. 2011. “Relationship-Based and The Case of Romania.â€? Mimeo, World Bank, Arms-Length Financial Systems—A Washington, DC. Background paper for this European Perspective.â€? Policy Research report. Working Paper 5833, World Bank, Sutt, A., H. Korju, and K. Siibak. 2011. “The Washington, DC. Background paper for this Role of Macro-Prudential Policies in the report. Boom and Adjustment Phase of the Credit Cycle in Estonia.â€? Policy Research Working Paper 5835, World Bank, Washington, DC. Background paper for this report. 182 CHAPTER 3 Other references Brown, M., T. Jappelli, and M. Pagano. 2009. Erbenova, M., Y. Liu, and M. Saxegaard. “Information Sharing and Credit: Firm-Level 2011. “Corporate and Household Debt Abbas, S., N. Belhocine, A. El-Ganainy, and Evidence from Transition Countries.â€? Journal Distress in Latvia: Strengthening the M. Horton. 2011. “Historical Patterns and of Financial Intermediation 18 (2): 151–172. Incentives for a Market-Based Approach to Dynamics of Public Debt—Evidence from a Buiter, W., J. Michels, and E. Rahbari. 2011a. Debt Resolution.â€? IMF Working Paper 11/85, New Database.â€? IMF Economic Review 59 “ELA: An Emperor without Clothes?â€? Citi IMF, Washington, DC. (4): 717–742. Economics, Global Economics View, January European Commission. 2011. “European Abiad, A., D. Leigh, and A. Mody. 2009. 21, Citi Investment Research and Analysis, Economic Forecast – Spring 2011.â€? “Financial Integration, Capital Mobility, and London. Commission Staff Working Document, Income Convergence.â€? Economic Policy 24 Buiter, W., J. Michels, and E. Rahbari. European Economy 1/2011, Directorate- (58): 241–305. 2011b. “ELA Revisited: A Clariï¬?cation.â€? General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Aizenman, J., B. Pinto, and A. Radziwill. Citi Economics, Global Economics View, European Commission, Brussels. 2007. “Sources for Financing Domestic February 11, Citi Investment Research and Gourinchas, P-O., and O. Jeanne. 2007. Capital – Is Foreign Saving a Viable Option Analysis, London. “Capital Flows to Developing Countries: for Developing Countries?â€? Journal of Chinn, M., and H. Ito. 2006. “What Matters The Allocation Puzzle.â€? NBER Working International Money and Finance 26 (5): for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Paper 13602, National Bureau of Economic 682–702. Institutions, and Interactions.â€? Journal of Research, Cambridge, MA. Albacete, N., and P. Fessler. 2010. “Stress Development Economics 81 (1): 163–192. Gylfason, T. 2011. “Houston, We Have a Testing Austrian Households.â€? Financial Chinn, M., and H. Ito. 2008. “A New Problem: Iceland’s Capital Controls.â€? VoxEU. Stability Report 19, June, Oesterreichische Measure of Financial Openness.â€? Journal of org, June 1. Available at www.voxeu. Nationalbank, Vienna. Comparative Policy Analysis 10 (3): 309–322. org/index.php?q=node/6597. Accessed Allen, F., T. Beck, E. Carletti, P. Lane, D. December 12, 2011. Claessens, S., and N. van Horen. 2012. Schoenmaker, and W. Wagner. 2011. Cross- “Foreign Banks: Trends, Impact and Hansen, F. 2010. “Raiffeisen Bank Border Banking in Europe: Implications Financial Stability.â€? IMF Working Paper International CEO: E-Europe Will Be EU for Financial Stability and Macroeconomic 12/10, IMF, Washington, DC. Growth Engine Ahead.â€? Dow Jones Business Policies. London: Centre for Economic Policy News, November 29. Research. Coricelli, F., N. Drifï¬?eld, S. Pal, and I. Roland. 2009. “Excess Leverage and Productivity Imbs, J., and R. Rancière. 2007. “The Ã…slund, A., and V. Dombrovskis. 2011. How Growth in Emerging Economies: Is There a Overhang Hangover.â€? Update of 2005 Latvia Came through the Financial Crisis. Threshold Effect?â€? CEPR Discussion Paper version, Policy Research Working Paper Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for 7617, Centre for Economic Policy Research, 3673, World Bank, Washington, DC. International Economics. London. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2010. Bakker, B., and A.-M. Gulde. 2010. “The Cottarelli, C., G. Dell’Ariccia, and I. Vladkova- Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements Credit Boom in the EU New Member States: Hollar. 2005. “Early Birds, Late Risers, and and Exchange Restrictions 2010. Bad Luck or Bad Policies?â€? IMF Working Sleeping Beauties: Bank Credit Growth to Washington, DC: IMF. Paper 10/130, IMF, Washington, DC. the Private Sector in Central and Eastern IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2011. Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and R. Levine. Europe and in the Balkans.â€? Journal of “Iceland: Fifth Review Under the Stand-By 2000. “A New Database on the Structure Banking and Finance 29 (1): 83–104. Arrangement, and Request for Modiï¬?cation and Development of the Financial Sector.â€? Darvas, Z., J. Pisani-Ferry, and A. Sapir. of Performance Criteria and Rephasing of The World Bank Economic Review 14 (3): 2011. “A Comprehensive Approach to the Access.â€? IMF Country Report 11/125, IMF, 597–605. Euro-Area Debt Crisis.â€? Bruegel Policy Brief Washington, DC. Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and R. Levine. 2011/02, Bruegel, Brussels. Islam, R. 2010. “To Spend or Not to Spend: 2010. “Financial Institutions and Markets De Haas, R., Y. Korniyenko, E. Loukoianova, Fiscal Choices for ECA in the Crisis and across Countries and over Time: The and A. Pivovarsky. 2011. “Foreign Banks Its Aftermath.â€? Mimeo, World Bank, Updated Financial Development and During the Crisis: Sinners or Saints?â€? Mimeo, Washington, DC. Structure Database.â€? The World Bank EBRD, London. Kumar, M., and J. Woo. 2010. “Public Debt Economic Review 24 (1): 77–92. de Larosière, J. 2009. “The High-Level Group and Growth.â€? IMF Working Paper 10/174, Benediktsdottir, S., J. Danielsson, and G. on Financial Supervision in the EU: Report.â€? IMF, Washington, DC. Zoega. 2011. “Lessons from a Collapse of a Report prepared by the de Larosière Group Lane, P. 2010. “A European Perspective on Financial System.â€? Economic Policy 26 (66): for the European Commission, European External Imbalances.â€? SIEPS 2010:5, Swedish 183–235. Commission, Brussels. Institute for European Policy Studies, Blanchard, O., and F. Giavazzi. 2002. “Current EBRD (European Bank for Reconstruction Stockholm. Account Deï¬?cits in the Euro Area: The End and Development). 2009. Transition Report of the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle?â€? Brookings 2009: Transition in Crisis? London: ERBD. Papers on Economic Activity 2002 (2): 147–186. 183 GOLDEN GROWTH Lane, P., and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2007. “The Prasad, E., R. Rajan, and A. Subramanian. External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised 2007a. “Foreign Capital and Economic and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets Growth.â€? Brookings Papers on Economic and Liabilities, 1970–2004.â€? Journal of Activity 2007 (1): 153–209. International Economics 73 (2): 223–250. Prasad, E., R. Rajan, and A. Subramanian. Laryea, T. 2010. “Approaches to Corporate 2007b. “The Paradox of Capital.â€? Finance Debt Restructuring in the Wake of Financial and Development 44 (1): 16–19. Crises.â€? IMF Staff Position Note 10/02, IMF, Purï¬?eld, C., and C. Rosenberg. 2010. Washington, DC. “Adjustment under a Currency Peg: Estonia, Lucas, R. 1990. “Why Doesn’t Capital Flow Latvia and Lithuania during the Global from Rich to Poor Countries?â€? The American Financial Crisis 2008-09.â€? IMF Working Economic Review 80 (2): 92–96. Paper 10/213, IMF, Washington, DC. Melzer, B. 2010. “Mortgage Debt Overhang: Reinhart, C., and K. Rogoff. 2010. “Growth Reduced Investment by Homeowners with in a Time of Debt.â€? The American Economic Negative Equity.â€? Mimeo, Kellogg School Review 100 (2): 573–578. of Management, Northwestern University, Sachs, J. 1989. “Conditionality, Debt Relief, Evanston, IL. and the Developing Country Debt Crisis.â€? Mitra, P., M. Selowsky, and J. Zalduendo. In Developing Country Debt and the World 2010. Turmoil at Twenty: Recession, Economy, ed. J. Sachs: 275–284. Chicago, IL: Recovery, and Reform in Central and University of Chicago Press. Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Sugawara, N., and J. Zalduendo. Union. Washington, DC: World Bank. 2009. “Public Monies and Mortgage Mulligan, C. 2008. “A Depressing Scenario: Restructuring—The Need for Targeted Mortgage Debt Becomes Unemployment Interventions.â€? ECAnomics Note 09/3, Ofï¬?ce Insurance.â€? NBER Working Paper 14514, of the Chief Economist, Europe and Central National Bureau of Economic Research, Asia Region, World Bank, Washington, DC. Washington, DC. Sveriges Riksbank. 2009. “Financial Stability Myers, S. 1977. “Determinants of Corporate Report 2009:1.â€? June, Sveriges Riksbank, Borrowing.â€? Journal of Financial Economics Stockholm. 5 (2): 147–175. Tait, N., B. Masters, and T. Braithwaite. 2011. Barba Navaretti, G., G. Calzolari, A. Pozzolo, “IMF Supports UK Push on Bank Rules.â€? and M. Levi. 2010. “Multinational Banking in Financial Times, June 6. Europe – Financial Stability and Regulatory Tiongson, E., N. Sugawara, V. Sulla, A. Taylor, Implications: Lessons from the Financial A. Gueorguieva, V. Levin, and K. Subbarao. Crisis.â€? Economic Policy 25 (64): 703–753. 2010. The Crisis Hits Home: Stress-Testing Olney, M. 1999. “Avoiding Default: The Role Households in Europe and Central Asia. of Credit in the Consumption Collapse of Washington, DC: World Bank. 1930.â€? The Quarterly Journal of Economics Tsangarides, C. 2010. “Crisis and Recovery: 114 (1): 319–335. Role of the Exchange Rate Regime in Ostry, J., A. Ghosh, K. Habermeier, M. Emerging Market Economies.â€? IMF Working Chamon, M. Qureshi, and D. Reinhardt. 2010. Paper 10/242, IMF, Washington, DC. “Capital Inflows: The Role of Controls.â€? IMF Staff Position Note 10/04, IMF, Washington, DC. PiÄ…tkowski, M., and J. Zalduendo. 2010. “Assessing EU-10 Banking Sectors’ Resilience to Credit Losses.â€? Kwartalnik Nauk o PrzedsiÄ™biorstwie 2010/1 (14): 62–69. Polgár, É., and A. Zdzienicka. 2010. “The Effectiveness of Policy Measures to Control Credit Growth in Emerging Europe.â€? Mimeo, ECB, Frankfurt. 184 CHAPTER 4 Enterprise and Innovation The chapters on trade and ï¬?nance analyzed how the 26 countries in emerging Europe have balanced the demands and dividends of integrating economically with advanced Europe. Chapters 4 and 5 now widen the analysis to include developed Europe. What binds these two chapters is productivity, a favorite subject of economists interested in economic growth. The chapters show that some parts of Europe are doing as well as North America, while others are falling behind. Much is expected of Europe’s enterprises. Workers look to them for jobs. Owners expect them to create value and generate proï¬?ts. Governments want them to become export “champions.â€? Chapter 4 documents that between 1995 and 2008, remarkably, European enterprises delivered all three—jobs, value added, and exports. But over the last decade, Europe’s southern periphery has been falling behind Continental and Northern Europe, while Eastern Europe has been catching up. The timing—100 million people in the new member states became part of the European Union as another 100 million living in Greece, southern Italy, Portugal, and Spain reached high income levels—may not be a coincidence. The chapter discusses whether the industrial structures in Eastern Europe—despite the communist past—are better suited for an integrated continent than those in the south, and suggests that they are. These differences are manifest in productivity growth differentials between countries in six internationally contestable sectors (manufacturing, construction, transport and telecommunications, wholesale and retail trade, hotels and restaurants, and real estate and professional services). Two gaps in productivity motivate chapter 5—the widening gap between Southern and Northern Europe, and a persistent gap between advanced Europe and the United States. Europe’s “innovation deï¬?citâ€? is assessed, trying not to ï¬?xate on shortfalls in research and development (R&D) spending but seeing them instead as the most readily available measures of innovation performance. The chapter also tries to assess demand shortfalls and the weaknesses in linkages between demand and supply in European innovation systems. A big part of Europe’s R&D deï¬?cit is due to the lack of “young and largeâ€? companies such as Amazon, Apple, Google, and Microsoft. This in turn may be due to regulations that inhibit labor turnover and mechanisms for funding research, and that discourage proï¬?table collaboration between business and research institutes. Because the information needed to carry out serious study of productivity growth is mostly available for the European Union, the 27 member states are the focus of chapters 4 and 5. Wherever possible, the analysis is extended to the other 18 countries in Europe: the four countries of the European Free Trade Association, the eight EU candidate and potential candidate countries, and the six eastern partners. 185 GOLDEN GROWTH 186 CHAPTER 4 Chapter 4 Enterprise Mr. Rossi (not his real name) owns a small mechanical ï¬?rm in Northern Italy. The company repairs valves and other components for manufacturing plants, serving mostly the agro-processing businesses in the region. Mr. Rossi’s father started the company more than 40 years ago and it remains a family-run enterprise with ï¬?ve or six employees and some family workers. The business is proï¬?table. But it has not grown since its ï¬?rst few years. When asked why, Mr. Rossi answers: “Do you know what I would have to deal with if my business employs 40 people? To start with, my workforce would be unionized by law. I would have to employ ‘a socially useful worker.’ The tax police and other government agencies like the labor safety agency would enforce stricter controls. I pay most of my taxes and I try to be current with the health and safety norms, but how much would this additional scrutiny cost? I would have to spend days running after the inspectors and I am sure that they would ï¬?nd something wrong. And to be frank, in family-run companies like mine, it is common to pay overtime in cash. We are happy because this costs 50 percent less than paying through the ofï¬?cial payroll, and our workers are happy to get some extra cash.â€? In Italy one out of two workers is employed by a company with fewer than 10 employees. In Greece the number is six out of ten. When the cost of dealing with the government is high, many businesses choose to stay small. Firms tend to be small in countries such as Sweden too but, as this chapter shows, for different reasons and with starkly different economic consequences. What does Europe expect from its enterprises? How have European ï¬?rms done in an enlarged Europe? Why did some parts of Europe do better than others? Which government policies help enterprises do better? 187 GOLDEN GROWTH This chapter assesses the performance of European enterprises over the past decade, asking and answering four questions: · What does Europe expect from its enterprises and do they fulï¬?ll these expectations? Enterprises in Europe are expected to generate new employment, make jobs more productive, and export a large share of their output. European enterprises have generally delivered on these expectations, though recently there have been signs that in some parts of Europe—notably the south—enterprises are failing to deliver two or more of these three goals. · How have European ï¬?rms done in an enlarged Europe? While regional discrepancies exist, European ï¬?rms beneï¬?t from a bigger and more diversiï¬?ed market. Enterprises in the new member states have become part of the pan- European supply chain, helping them restructure their production systems and increase their exports. Many Western European enterprises responded well to the growing competition in global markets (especially from East Asia) by investing in emerging countries in Europe and moving parts of their business eastward. However, Southern Europe has neither attracted investment nor taken advantage of the offshoring opportunities presented by cheaper eastern economies. · Why did some parts of Europe do better than others? This question is answered along two perspectives: geographic (a three-speed Europe); and the beneï¬?ts and drawbacks of foreign direct investment (FDI), offshoring, and lower quality of regulations. Countries with more efï¬?cient regulatory systems did best in increasing productivity. This helped them become internationally competitive, raise exports, and sustain job creation. These countries had entrepreneurial proï¬?les that were better suited for ever more integrated European markets. In particular, they had a critical mass of large enterprises. Regulatory arrangements that made complying with laws easy and did not penalize enterprises that grew, as well as supporting policies that attracted foreign investors, were most important in helping enterprises balance social responsibility at home and competitiveness abroad. · What is the relationship between business regulation and enterprise growth? The answer is a little different looking east (emerging Europe) or west (Continental and Northern Europe, and Southern Europe). In advanced Europe, reducing the regulatory burden on ï¬?rms increases their productivity and brings about a size and sector distribution of enterprises that is most conducive for a single European market. An efï¬?cient—not necessarily lighter—regulatory framework is needed for ï¬?rms to reach the minimum size required to operate internationally, especially to attract FDI. In emerging Europe governments can also support enterprise through improved infrastructure and better access to credit to ï¬?nance investments, which are common features of the best-performing countries. In short, an economic model that requires enterprises to be socially responsible can be compatible with a vibrant private sector if it is supported by a simple and efï¬?cient regulatory framework. Not all countries in Europe have managed to strike this balance. Regulations still impede enterprises in some countries, preventing businesses from taking advantage of a more integrated Europe. Nevertheless, this chapter concludes that outside the EU15 southern states, 188 CHAPTER 4 Europe’s enterprises have largely delivered what was expected of them by their workers, owners, and governments. What does Europe expect from enterprise? Jobs, value added, and exports Firms may be more integrated with the social fabric in Europe than in any other part of the world. Private enterprises are not only held accountable by shareholders for proï¬?ts, but also held responsible by society for the social and environmental consequences of their actions. This is reflected in regulations that stress such consequences more than in other regions: labor regulations that protect the rights of workers;1 a taxation system that supports generous welfare policies;2 and licensing and permitting regimes that control access to speciï¬?c activities and verify adherence to strict codes and norms. In sum, ï¬?rms are expected by societies to create jobs and protect the environment, by shareholders to generate proï¬?ts, and by governments to pay taxes and—if they are sizable—to generate exports. Accordingly, this chapter assesses the performance of European enterprises using three criteria: · Jobs. Enterprises contribute to economic growth by generating employment. About three of four jobs in Europe are created by enterprises,3 and ï¬?rms are given a speciï¬?c social role: reducing unemployment. · Productivity (value added). Enterprises contribute to growth by adding value. An enterprise’s contribution to aggregate growth is most easily measured by labor productivity growth: increases in value added per employee. Productivity is not a bad proxy of proï¬?tability.4 · Exports. The third performance indicator of an enterprise is its export propensity (the likelihood a ï¬?rm will export), which proxies its capacity to identify foreign markets where it can successfully place its products. Export propensity measures a ï¬?rm’s ability to compete on an international scale and, taken in aggregate, measures the competitiveness of an open economy. While pursuing these objectives, ï¬?rms in Europe must comply with regulations that, while reflecting society’s expectations, affect their performance by generating direct costs—for example, through tax or labor contributions and payments for licenses and permits. Regulations also affect performance by influencing investment decisions. Similar regulations can have different impacts, depending on the way they are enforced. Many well-designed regulations have a negative impact due to poor implementation. The quality of the design and implementation of regulations across Europe can be assessed with the World Bank Doing Business indicators as proxies. These indicators measure the quality of regulations (such as the burden of tax systems, rigidity of labor laws, regulations affecting entry and exit, ease of access to ï¬?nance, and enforcement of contracts), based on the experience of users. They allow comparisons across countries and over time. In particular, the “time and motionâ€? indicators measure the steps that enterprises must take to comply with business regulations—in number of procedures, time, and money spent.5 189 GOLDEN GROWTH Europe overall has heavier regulations than other regions, but intercountry variance is considerable. Northern and Continental European countries have better regulatory frameworks than Southern or Eastern European countries. Sweden, Finland, and Norway do better than the rest of Europe in balancing the quantity and quality of business regulations and are in line with the most advanced countries in the world thanks to the efï¬?ciency of their administrative systems, which makes compliance less burdensome. This chapter assesses the likely impact of the regulatory framework on how enterprises perform, measured by employment, productivity, and exports. It looks deeper than the aggregate indicators of an economy’s performance, employment growth, productivity growth, and total share of exports in GDP and looks into more disaggregate elements of successful ï¬?rm performance, such as ï¬?rm size and ownership. The investigation ï¬?nds that performance depends on the characteristics of a ï¬?rm such as its size, ownership structure, and age, as well as country-speciï¬?c factors related to the environment in which it operates. It focuses on the regulatory framework among the country factors, but also considers the amount of credit available to the private sector, the quality of infrastructure, workforce skills, and FDI inflows and outflows.6 When one disentangles the impact of ï¬?rm and country characteristics, the Figure 4.1: European question arises whether seemingly similar companies perform equally well in enterprises did well different countries. If companies with similar characteristics do equally well in 1995–2009 in different countries, differences in “typesâ€? of companies would explain the Note: “Peripheryâ€? includes Greece, difference in country aggregates. By contrast, if the performance of companies Ireland, Portugal, and Spain. Source: World Bank staff calculations, with similar characteristics is different, the differences can be explained by based on ILO 2010; and WDI. factors that vary across countries. Periphery 190 CHAPTER 4 This distinction has policy implications. Government policies and regulations, and the institutions that enforce them, affect ï¬?rm performance by influencing the enterprise’s cost structure. If ï¬?rm performance differs across countries, measuring the effect of policies on performance would be illuminating. The impact of regulations on ï¬?rm performance could be viewed as the “staticâ€? impact of regulations. Government policies might also affect market dynamics by influencing ï¬?rms’ entry and exit decisions and growth patterns. The type of ï¬?rms that survive and succeed in different environments depends on the policies in different countries. If the mix of enterprises operating in each country differs, the link between market structure and the regulatory framework must be understood. The impact of regulations on enterprise growth—the “dynamicâ€? impact of regulations—is as important in explaining how ï¬?rms produce jobs, value added, and exports. Both ï¬?rm- and country-speciï¬?c elements affect performance, but their relative importance differs in ways relevant to policy reforms. How have enterprises done? Quite well Over the past two decades, the competitive landscape for European enterprises has changed. The globalization of markets and enlargement of the European Union have altered the way European ï¬?rms do business. European ï¬?rms have generally coped well with these changes: during 1995–2009, they managed to deliver against the three objectives set out above and remained globally competitive (ï¬?gure 4.1 and table 4.1).7 A comparison of the performance of European subregions shows the following: · In 1995, enterprises in Europe employed a larger share of the working-age population than in the rest of the world, but lower than other most advanced economies. Since then, Europe has produced jobs faster than the United States but more slowly than the rest of the world. In fact, emerging market countries, notably China, saw a massive reallocation of labor from agriculture to industry, which Europe experienced soon after World War II. · Value added per worker has increased in much of Europe. While European productivity8 grew in line with its competitors (but from a higher base), Europe did not close the productivity gap with the United States. However, the EU15 grew at a rate comparable with Japan, the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand taken together, while many European countries performed as well as the United States. · European enterprises have maintained a favorable position in global trade. In 1995, Europe exported goods and services worth more than 40 percent of its GDP, a much higher share than the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) average. Since then, Europe has increased exports in value terms, although less quickly than emerging countries. Average trends mask differences in performance among countries and ï¬?rms in Europe. Disparities are evident not only between advanced and emerging Europe, but also between countries in each group. 191 GOLDEN GROWTH Table 4.1: European enterprises, benchmarked quantitatively and globally (GDP, labor participation (industry and services), productivity, and exports, 1995–2009) Exports of goods and Employment participation, Productivity, '000, constant Real GDP GDP per services, BOP, percentage percentage of working-age population 2005 US$ growth, capita, PPP, of GDP percent, '000, current Growth, Growth, Level Level Level CAGR int'l$, Latest percent, percent, Initial Latest CAGR Latest CAGR Initial Latest Norway 2.4 55.7 68.4 75.5 0.7 111.9 0.4 37.6 40.9 Switzerland 1.7 45,1 76.4 72.7 -0.4 96.9 1.2 39.0 57.0 Iceland 3.6 36.7 73.9 79.9 0.6 84.7 2.5 35.5 52.8 Liechtenstein 3.7 - - - - - - Ireland 5.3 39.6 48.6 60.3 1.6 98.1 2.1 73.7 90.9 Denmark 1.3 37.7 70.7 74.4 0.4 78.9 0.7 36.1 47.7 Sweden 2.3 37.2 68.7 72.1 0.3 74.1 1.4 37.7 47.9 Finland 2.8 35.3 57.2 65.7 1.0 71.8 1.4 36.7 38.2 United Kingdom 2.1 35.1 67.5 69.3 0.2 71.8 1.4 27.8 27.4 Luxembourg 4.1 84.8 53.4 58.1 0.6 188.2 2.0 132.7 142.0 Netherlands 2.3 40.8 59.8 69.2 1.0 76.5 0.9 57.6 65.2 Austria 2.0 38.8 65.1 68.0 0.3 73.7 1.4 37.7 49.9 Germany 1.1 36.3 62.0 70.3 0.9 67.0 0.5 23.8 41.8 Belgium 1.8 36.3 54.6 60.7 0.8 80.2 0.7 67.1 70.8 France 1.7 33.3 53.6 59.2 0.7 77.2 0.4 23.1 23.6 Italy 0.8 32.4 48.0 56.0 1.1 68.2 -0.5 26.3 23.8 Spain 2.9 32.3 42.5 57.7 2.2 56.9 -0.5 22.4 24.0 Greece 3.3 29.3 42.1 52.5 1.6 56.4 1.4 11.8 18.1 Portugal 1.9 25.1 57.9 62.9 0.6 36.7 1.0 27.7 28.8 Slovenia 3.4 27.6 57.2 63.0 0.7 40.2 3.5 49.9 58.2 Czech Republic 2.6 25.6 65.9 64.9 -0.1 27.1 3.0 51.0 67.2 Slovak Republic 4.4 22.9 54.8 57.9 0.4 26.7 2.8 43.5 70.5 Hungary 2.7 20.3 48.4 53.6 0.8 25.7 2.8 44.3 77.8 Poland 4.4 18.9 44.9 50.4 0.8 22.7 3.0 25.7 39.7 Estonia 4.8 19.7 60.2 69.2 1.1 21.7 5.7 59.1 71.2 Lithuania 4.6 17.1 49.9 55.8 0.8 18.1 4.3 40.4 54.8 Latvia 4.7 16.2 48.3 57.7 1.3 15.3 4.2 39.9 43.4 Cyprus 3.3 30.7 58.1 65.7 0.9 34.0 0.5 49.8 48.3 Malta 2.6 24.8 50.1 56.3 1.0 33.1 0.1 83.8 79.0 Romania 2.5 14.2 43.4 43.6 0.0 15.6 3.4 26.5 31.3 Bulgaria 3.0 13.8 44.0 57.7 2.1 8.8 2.5 51.9 47.9 Croatia 3.2 20.0 47.7 51.9 0.7 25.2 2.8 31.6 35.7 Turkey 3.6 14.2 30.9 33.9 0.7 24.8 1.2 21.6 23.3 Montenegro 2.6 12.9 31.9 36.2 1.8 13.3 3.8 - - Serbia 3.6 11.5 44.6 42.5 -1.2 10.9 8.4 30.1 28.4 Macedonia, FYR 2.5 11.1 30.9 34.0 1.6 10.3 1.9 29.4 38.2 Albania 5.4 8.6 16.4 21.6 2.8 12.5 4.2 12.5 29.3 Bosnia and Herzegovina 12.2 8.5 49.4 52.7 0.8 6.5 3.4 27.3 32.4 Kosovo 6.4 - - - - - - - - 192 CHAPTER 4 Exports of goods and Employment participation, Productivity, '000, constant Real GDP GDP per services, BOP, percentage percentage of working-age population 2005 US$ growth, capita, PPP, of GDP percent, '000, current Level Growth, Level Growth, Level CAGR int'l$, Latest percent, percent, Initial Latest CAGR Latest CAGR Initial Latest Belarus 7.1 13.0 52.8 61.3 1.1 7.8 6.9 37.7 50.5 Azerbaijan 12.8 9.4 32.2 40.1 1.7 8.7 9.2 25.7 53.1 Ukraine 2.0 6.3 29.3 54.5 4.9 4.7 -1.2 35.4 46.3 Armenia 7.3 5.3 46.4 29.1 -3.3 6.3 10.6 20.4 15.7 Georgia 6.1 4.7 34.1 31.1 -1.0 6.6 9.5 16.4 29.8 Moldova 2.3 2.9 38.3 37.6 -0.1 2.7 4.4 50.4 36.7 United States 2.5 45.7 69.6 70.1 0.1 84.6 1.6 10.8 11.2 Australia 3.5 39.4 65.0 71.4 0.7 64.1 1.5 18.8 21.2 Canada 2.6 37.8 64.2 71.0 0.9 66.2 1.1 37.2 28.8 New Zealand 2.7 29.3 63.7 70.3 0.9 50.7 0.9 28.5 26.2 Singapore 5.1 50.7 67.4 67.3 0.0 58.1 2.4 183.2 200.6 Japan 0.6 32.0 69.5 72.8 0.4 76.3 1.2 9.4 13.4 Taiwan, China 4.3 31.0 - - - - - - - Korea, Rep. 4.1 27.1 55.8 62.4 0.9 38.1 2.9 28.8 51.8 Malaysia 4.5 13.7 48.7 52.2 0.5 15.3 1.9 93.8 96.5 Thailand 2.7 7.8 39.1 46.3 1.2 7.8 0.1 41.8 68.5 China 9.8 6.8 40.7 49.2 1.5 6.1 7.8 20.2 26.7 Indonesia 3.5 4.0 36.2 39.7 0.7 4.7 0.8 26.2 24.6 Philippines 4.1 3.7 36.3 40.9 0.8 4.7 0.9 36.2 28.9 Vietnam 7.2 3.0 24.6 40.4 5.1 2.0 0.1 38.5 64.7 Argentina 3.4 14.5 54.0 67.9 1.7 11.1 0.3 9.7 21.7 Chile 3.8 14.3 46.1 50.5 0.6 20.0 1.1 27.1 38.9 Mexico 2.8 13.8 45.1 52.2 1.1 21.5 -0.1 31.2 27.8 Uruguay 2.7 13.1 61.9 63.2 0.2 11.5 0.4 18.2 27.3 Venezuela, RB 2.5 12.3 50.2 56.7 1.2 13.4 -3.2 27.7 18.3 Brazil 2.7 10.3 50.8 59.1 1.1 10.6 0.0 6.8 11.3 Columbia 3.0 9.0 50.9 45.5 -0.8 11.0 1.9 13.3 16.2 Peru 4.3 8.7 62.8 62.7 0.0 7.7 2.7 12.3 24.1 South Africa 3.3 10.2 37.1 39.0 0.6 18.5 1.0 22.8 27.8 Tunisia 5.0 8.2 35.2 36.1 0.6 12.1 2.8 44.3 45.8 Algeria 3.5 8.1 34.1 39.4 5.0 10.1 -2.5 47.7 34.3 Egypt, Arab Rep. 5.1 6.0 31.1 32.1 0.3 5.7 2.4 22.0 23.6 Morocco 4.6 4.5 47.6 30.2 -3.4 8.5 5.9 27.4 28.9 Russian Federation 3.7 18.9 56.5 59.0 0.3 11.8 3.3 23.5 28.2 India 6.9 3.3 24.0 26.2 1.7 3.5 4.2 10.7 18.9 Note: CAGR refers to compound annual growth rate. Although for most countries the initial and latest years are 1995 and 2009, the period varies by country and data series: for real GDP growth, Kosovo (2000 -09) and Montenegro (1997 -2009); for GDP per capita, Taiwan, China (2008); for exports, Luxembourg (2002 -09), Bosnia and Herzegovina (1998 -2009), Macedonia, FYR (1996 -2009), Serbia (2007 -09), Georgia (1997 -2009), Vietnam (1996 -2009), and Algeria (2005 -09). Selected Indicators table A4 (Enterprise) at the end of the report gives the periods for productivity data. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on ILO 2010; WDI; UNdata; and data from country sources. 193 GOLDEN GROWTH In the EU15, different development patterns can be discerned by geography, according to the three criteria. Performance differs among Northern Europe (Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Norway, Sweden, and the United Kingdom), Continental Europe (Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands), and Southern Europe (Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain): · Job creation. Southern countries have done better than others though they started with a lower participation rate. Spain generated 6.8 million jobs in 1995–2009. Northern, particularly Continental, Europe has lagged in employment generation, but has increased employment, and the average share of the working-age population employed remains higher overall. Ireland is the best performer in the EU15, increasing its workforce by 3.4 percent a year. (The global economic and ï¬?nancial crisis, however, highlighted that employment resilience is as critical as employment generation. In some countries, the crisis reversed some of the earlier gains: from end-2008 to the second quarter of 2011, Spain lost 1.5 million jobs, Ireland 200,000.) · Productivity. Northern European countries have outperformed the rest, with productivity growing by 1.4 percent a year. However, productivity declines from north to south. Italy and Spain show a fall in productivity, while Greece and Portugal narrowed the gap dividing them from the rest of the EU15. · Exports. Trade performance reveals a “winners-take-allâ€? pattern. Continental Europe, already more outward-oriented than the rest of Europe, became even more open, while Southern Europe shows only a modest increase of its export share. In Continental Europe, France’s stagnant exports resemble those of its southern neighbors. Emerging Europe (the EU12)9 can be categorized in three groups: Central Europe (the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia); the Baltic countries (Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania); and the south (Bulgaria and Romania). The EU12 demonstrates a pattern similar to the EU15, with two groups (the Baltic countries and Central Europe) dominating exports and the south lagging behind: · Job creation. The economies that proceeded fastest in enterprise restructuring generated new jobs. Romania appears to be the only country still grappling with its restructuring. · Productivity. With an average annual growth in value added above 5 percent—realized mainly through vigorous restructuring starting from low productivity levels—the Baltic economies outperformed the rest of the EU12. Central and Southern Europe also did well, with intercountry variations. · Exports. Emerging Europe maintained a high share of exports in GDP. Central Europe responded to European integration by increasing its share of exports, while the Baltic countries remained highly open economies. Bulgaria and Romania beneï¬?ted less from close relationships with the rest of Europe, but have maintained their export shares. The EU candidates and eastern partnership countries are different from EU member states: 194 CHAPTER 4 · Job creation. The share of the working-age population employed in industry and services is about 60–70 percent of the share in the European Union, reflecting lower participation rates in the labor force following transition and greater reliance on traditional sectors (such as agriculture) and on the government. However, employment growth in enterprises is consistently higher than in the European Union. · Productivity. Countries outside the European Union recovered from the transition with high growth rates, but the development patterns remain different. While some EU candidate countries show productivity in line with or higher than that of the EU12, the gap between Europe and the eastern partnership countries remains, as productivity in the latter is about one-tenth that in Western Europe. Catch-up accounts for a large share of productivity improvements. · Exports. The EU eastern partnership countries’ exports/GDP ratio is close to Europe’s and more than double that of the EU candidate countries. The ratio is increasing, testifying to increased integration with Europe and global markets. Why did some parts of Europe do better than others? A three-speed union Prato was one of the most famous Italian industrial districts. Its specialization in textile production dates to the seventh century, when clothes production was regulated by the Arte della Lana craft guild. By the 1980s Prato had the biggest concentration of textile ï¬?rms in Europe specializing in yarns for weaving and knitwear, woven and knitted fabrics for the apparel industry, and special fabrics. Changes in global textile production patterns altered Prato’s fortunes. From 1991 to 2010 about 1,600 of the 7,600 textile ï¬?rms in Prato closed or relocated. Between 2002 and 2009 Prato’s total textile exports fell from $2.2 billion to $1.5 billion.10 The loss of market share is not the only result of globalization. Prato’s surviving clothing industry now has a different business model. More than half of Prato textile businesses are reportedly owned by the Chinese, who import fabric from China and produce cheap “fast fashionâ€? clothes for sale in the single market. Siemens, the electronics and engineering conglomerate, is increasingly less German and more global. Founded in 1847 by the inventor of the pointer telegraph, Siemens was already operating in countries such as Estonia, Turkey, and Ukraine in its ï¬?rst 10 years. Its introduction of the ï¬?rst direct transatlantic telegraph cable in 1874 signaled the company’s global goals. After World War II, Siemens maintained a global presence through foreign investments, acquisitions, and partnerships. With the fall of the Berlin Wall, the company started to operate again in Eastern European countries. Between 1996 and 2008 Siemens’ overall employment increased from 380,000 to 430,000 and the company became more international. More than 20,000 jobs were created in production and service facilities in the Czech Republic, Poland, the Slovak Republic, Hungary, and Romania while Germany’s employment share decreased from 54 to 31 percent. Siemens reached new product markets and by 2008, just 17 percent of its revenues were generated in Germany, compared to 39 percent in 1996. A German economist described Siemens as “a global value chain with its R&D and engineering activities located in Europe and the United States, procurement and logistics located in south 195 GOLDEN GROWTH east Asia, its assembly activities located in eastern Europe, and its marketing activity organised at local level or via the Internet.â€?11 Å koda Auto, the automaker from the former Czechoslovakia discussed in chapter 2, began as a bicycle manufacturer. The collapse of communism left Å koda in a difï¬?cult position. Its products were based on obsolete Soviet-era technologies and faced a wide technological, design, and quality gap with Western competitors. Lada-AutoVaz, an automaker in the Russian Federation, was in a similar state. Å koda was acquired by the Volkswagen Group, which revamped its product range. Å koda is now the entry brand of a global group. It produces ï¬?ve times as many cars as in 1990, generating proï¬?ts for its parent, and employs nearly 25,000 workers. Lada, on the other hand, still produces cars that are not competitive in the bigger European market. These three examples—Prato, Siemens, and Å koda—come from the south, north, and east, respectively. They illustrate three different responses to a new economic landscape (box 4.1). This section analyzes these differences, the changes in the European economy, and their consequences for jobs, productivity, and exports. A period of structural change In the early 2000s, economists in Europe debated which pressures the European model would face as the European Union enlarged. Enterprises in the EU12 were emerging from a decade of restructuring and had large productivity gaps with older EU member states. The prognosis was unclear: The accession of 10 more countries also adds a dimension of complexity and heterogeneity that was not present in the previous round. … Because of the gap in income, convergence between the new member states and the current EU members is more than ever the key to successful enlargement. Neither theory nor the experience of earlier enlargement convincingly supports a hypothesis of automatic convergence. … On the one hand the new member states have relatively high levels of human capital. On the other hand, they have a legacy of old industrial investment, environmental damage and poor public administration to remedy (Sapir and others 2004, рр. 4-5). Policymakers sought to integrate these diverse entities into a single market without creating imbalances and compromising competitiveness. In hindsight, European ï¬?rms mostly did well. The 2004 and 2007 enlargements—along with integration efforts since the mid-1990s—appear successful so far. Enterprises in the new member states experienced vigorous productivity improvements and generated new jobs, contributing to economic growth in all parts of Europe. European enterprises fought off the increasing competition from emerging markets and maintained a signiï¬?cant share of global trade. In 2002–08, in aggregate, enterprises in the European Union increased value added by 16 percent. In 2008, the European Union exported the equivalent of 40 percent of its GDP.12 Discontinuity in Europe’s competitive landscape challenged the way ï¬?rms did business and created winners and losers. Winners captured the opportunities to expand sales and production into new markets. Siemens and Volkswagen- 196 CHAPTER 4 Å koda expanded networks in the bigger European market to grow outside Europe as well. Firms with traditional business models whose markets were disrupted by the competition from emerging economies were the losers. Italian industrial districts like Prato are among the entities that depended on the flexibility offered by local networks of small companies and are struggling in a world where a minimum scale is critical to success. As a result of these and other changes (box 4.1), and despite decent performance overall, the expanded single European market did not beneï¬?t incumbents equally. A decomposition of overall performance depicts a European Union13 where convergence of emerging Europe toward advanced Europe coexists with a divergence within advanced Europe. The result is a Europe growing at different speeds (ï¬?gure 4.2): · The leaders. Continental and Northern Europe saw value added grow in 2002–08 at an average of 3 percent a year, due in equal part to productivity gains and employment creation. The average export share in GDP in these countries was more than 40 percent. · The chasers. Emerging Europe reduced part of the gap with the rest of the European Union, generating value added at more than twice the rate of the EU15, mostly because of increased productivity. These economies became increasingly connected to the rest of Europe and the world: on average, exports now stand at more than 50 percent of their GDP. · The laggards. Southern Europe (EU15 South) shows the slowest value-added growth (1.3 percent) in the same period, coming exclusively from employment generation. Southern countries did not register productivity improvements and showed little growth in export intensity (the share of foreign sales in total turnover) which, at 28 percent of GDP, is well below the EU average. Figure 4.2: The east giving chase, the south falling behind (employment, productivity, and exports, 2002–08) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat and WDI. 197 GOLDEN GROWTH These changes also had implications for product and factor markets in Europe. In the product market, the reduction in the cost of accessing foreign and other European markets implies that the competition in the local market increases. This effect can be offset by the opportunity to compete in other product markets. In factor markets, the forces at play are less obvious: while access to international markets opens new opportunities for companies to reduce their cost base, the impact on the local market can be negative or positive, depending on local conditions.14 A strategy to protect a market niche can only be pursued in the short term: over time most markets open, so the best strategy for a ï¬?rm is to be prepared. For ï¬?rms to fully beneï¬?t from the single market, they need to engage in foreign operations in the form of sales, sourcing, or both. Companies that do not can ï¬?nd themselves in a “lose-loseâ€? world in which competition increases in the local product markets, but there are no beneï¬?ts in international markets. Not all ï¬?rms can access international markets—the costs are often simply too high to justify the investment. In particular, the costs of entry—especially access to information and management of subsidiaries abroad or a decentralized sales network—are often too high for small ï¬?rms. Hence minimum scale is becoming more important. In other words, although falling barriers to entry to new markets imply that the minimum scale for international operations is now lower, reaching that scale becomes critical to success (box 4.2). To address current imbalances and learn lessons to make future EU enlargement even more effective, it is necessary to understand the determinants of Europe’s varied performance. More immediately, policymakers need to understand Box 4.1: Is staying local now riskier? When measuring the performance of European new technologies, managerial know-how, offshore. This fragmented the production enterprises, one should keep in mind some and cooperative links with ï¬?rms from process and supply chain, rewarding ï¬?rms structural changes: advanced Europe and other mature market that could better manage the complex economies. It also presented a unique structures involved. • Transition in emerging Europe. For opportunity for thousands of start-ups and emerging Europe, the transition from spin-offs to emerge, bringing the diversity • EU enlargement and the creation of the the socialist to market system involved of Western Europe to the broader group of single market. EU enlargement—built on the privatizing on a large scale, restructuring countries. principle of a common market for goods, production and distribution systems, and services, capital, and labor—strengthened • Globalization of markets. Trade and a global trend. In Europe, due in part to shedding surplus labor. Transition affected production became more globalized, with the macroeconomic stability provided by small and medium enterprises, with developed and emerging economies around (prospective) membership, geographic and slower and still incomplete privatization the world becoming more integrated. and restructuring of larger state-owned market borders became thinner, allowing This is evidenced by the growth in trade enterprises. At the macro level, the biggest increased mobility for products and factors volumes, which almost tripled in 2000–10. challenge was an efï¬?cient reallocation of production. The EU expansion process (Trade also improved timing and reliability of the enterprise workforce that was opened new markets to enterprises of shipments, allowing ï¬?rms to better made redundant during rationalization. control the decentralized supply chain, in advanced Europe. It also expanded For ï¬?rms, the changes went beyond the since, along with costs, they are key factors opportunities for offshoring parts of the pure shift in the ownership structure and in ï¬?rms’ outsourcing decisions.) European production process, while providing an encompassed technological and managerial enterprises, operating in one of the largest opportunity for ï¬?rms in emerging Europe to modernization to align production and markets in the world with about 500 million enter niche markets and take over parts of commercial processes with those in the high- and middle-income consumers, the value chains. For example, the Slovak rest of the world. FDI inflows were essential were increasingly exposed to international Republic, with virtually no tradition of car to the transition’s success: in 1990–2009, competition. On the cost side, the reduction manufacturing, became one of Europe’s $814 billion was invested in emerging of transaction costs introduced additional largest car manufacturers, and many Polish Europe, according to UNCTAD (at current opportunities to maximize proï¬?ts as ï¬?rms enterprises are becoming suppliers to prices and exchange rates). It brought attempted to move labor-intensive activities German companies. 198 CHAPTER 4 how to help lagging countries catch up or at least to ensure that the gaps grow no wider. Enterprise productivity growth in the south is needed most of all. Policymakers will also need to ensure that the countries now catching up will continue to grow in an enlarged Europe, where new entrants will vie for potential investors. Finally, internal sources have driven enterprise growth in Europe to date. The sources of growth once the EU12 catches up remain unclear (chapter 5). Jobs—some are more durable than others Contrary to common perceptions, enterprises created employment across Europe in 2002–08: enterprises outside ï¬?nancial and extractive sectors, for example, created more than 12 million jobs.15 Of these, 25 percent were made in the new member states, 31 percent in Southern Europe, and 44 percent in the rest of the European Union. Employment generation in emerging Europe was almost double that in the EU15. Following the large reallocation of labor resulting from the transition, private enterprises became net job creators. The domestic service sector, which is underdeveloped in emerging Europe relative to advanced Europe, drives employment growth across all countries (ï¬?gure 4.3). Construction, fueled by the precrisis real estate boom in the Baltic states, but also in Bulgaria and Romania, explained much of the difference between Central European countries and the rest of New Europe. Manufacturing jobs fell slightly in emerging Europe overall, Box 4.2: Firms in Europe are becoming more similar—in size Regional integration and globalization are their minimum efï¬?cient scale. According to the international competition– manufacturing, making ï¬?rms increasingly similar. As barriers theory of contestable markets, in an industry transport and telecoms, real estate, and other to entry to new markets have fallen, so have with no ï¬?xed costs, extra proï¬?ts would be services—both trends are visible, especially differences among ï¬?rms operating across eliminated through entry and ï¬?rms should in transport and telecommunications (box countries. A critical and observable ï¬?rm converge to the efï¬?cient minimum scale. In ï¬?gure 1). The forces described above affect the characteristic is size, where European ï¬?rms this way, dispersion of ï¬?rm sizes is explained appear to be increasingly similar. This is in day-to-day operations of companies in Europe by barriers to entry in the form of ï¬?xed costs. and around the globe. Some companies have line with economic theory: thanks to reduced barriers to entry, markets become more When observing the evolution in size of the managed to successfully adapt and beneï¬?t— competitive and industries converge toward European ï¬?rms in sectors most exposed to but not all. Box ï¬?gure 1: Average ï¬?rm size by sector in EU countries: 2002 and 2007 Note: Nonparametric estimations of the density function of EU average ï¬?rm size (10 employees and above) for 2002 and 2007. Empirical densities were estimated using Epanechnikov kernel techniques. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 199 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.3: In the EU12, most jobs created were in services and construction (employment growth, by size of ï¬?rms and sector, 2002–07) Note: Data for 2008 are not included as sector classiï¬?cation changed from 2007 to 2008. The period of time considered varies by country: Estonia and Lithuania (2004–07), Latvia and Poland (2003–07), and the Slovak Republic (2002–05). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. reflecting two opposite forces: growth in some parts due to delocalization of labor-intensive tasks from advanced to emerging Europe to leverage the lower labor costs of the skilled workforce; and decline in the EU entrants’ larger enterprises, especially the Baltic economies, as they restructured their industries from the legacy of the Soviet system. In advanced Europe, the southern countries outperformed the rest in job creation, with an average yearly growth of 1.9 percent in 2002–08 (compared with 1.5 percent and 1.1 percent in Continental and Northern Europe, respectively). The sector distribution of employment creation followed a path similar to emerging Europe’s. Manufacturing declined overall, emphasizing the shift toward services (ï¬?gure 4.4). The type of companies generating service jobs varied. In Southern Europe, microenterprises (mostly family-owned ï¬?rms with fewer than 10 employees) and small and medium enterprises generated most jobs. Construction contributed to employment in the south, accounting for a large share of the growth: in Spain alone, it accounted for one out of ï¬?ve jobs in 2007. Yet a simple comparison of growth rates misses the fact that jobs do not all contribute equally to growth. Decomposing job creation by sector and size brings out two main trends: · Some jobs are more stable than others. Domestic, consumer-driven retail services16 accounted for the largest share of the difference in job-growth rates across countries. More than half the growth in the EU15 South (1.8 percent of 2.9 percent) was concentrated in these sectors, which are cyclical and credit-dependent: in Southern Europe alone more than 1.4 million jobs created in 2000–08 (about half the total) disappeared by end-2010. Similarly, jobs created in microï¬?rms (those with fewer than 10 employees) 200 CHAPTER 4 are less resilient than those in larger companies, as they are less likely to survive—bad news for the EU15’s south, where half the new jobs were in microenterprises.17 · Some jobs add more value than others. Jobs in microenterprises often have low productivity. This is evident in Southern Europe where one job in a large ï¬?rm produces on average the same value added as two jobs in a small family-run business with up to nine employees (ï¬?gure 4.5). The additional jobs created in microï¬?rms and in labor-intensive nontradable sectors in the EU15 South have only a small impact on value addition. The size of enterprises generating jobs in Southern Europe—mostly smaller ï¬?rms with fewer than 10 employees—is also relevant to explain the high unemployment rates, especially among young people, despite reasonably rapid job creation. This could signal a mismatch between what is demanded by such ï¬?rms—essentially unskilled labor—and the skilled labor available in the market. A worker in a microï¬?rm generates output valued at about $40,000 annually, including the gross salary, gross proï¬?ts, and depreciation. With this low value added per worker, microï¬?rms cannot afford to hire educated Europeans, who form a sizable fraction of job seekers. Besides, they may only require unskilled or semiskilled workers. When the durability and value added of the new jobs is taken into account, the gap between the apparently sluggish north and faster south in creating jobs narrows. Value added—closing one productivity gap, opening another Intercountry differences are most telling in productivity indicators (ï¬?gure 4.6). These differences are instrumental in understanding ï¬?rm performance. Over time, in a single integrated market like Europe, ï¬?rms in low-productivity countries are expected to upgrade their technology, adopt new management Figure 4.4: In the EU15, a loss of manufacturing jobs, replaced by small service enterprises (employment growth, by size of ï¬?rms and sector, 2002–07) Note: Data for 2008 are not included as sector classiï¬?cation changed from 2007 to 2008. For Belgium, France, and Greece, the period considered is 2003–07. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 201 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.5: Microenterprises in the EU15 South cannot pay for skilled workers (productivity level, by ï¬?rm size and sector, 2007) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. Figure 4.6: Productivity levels were lower in the south and lower still in the east (average productivity in 2002, thousand 2005 US$) Note: For Belgium and Greece, productivity levels refer to 2003. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. Figure 4.7: The east has been catching up, the south has been falling behind (average productivity growth in EU27, annual percentage rates, 2002–08) Note: The period of time considered varies by country: Belgium (2003–08), Greece (2003–07), and Great Britain, France, Czech Republic, Latvia, and Romania (2002–07). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 202 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.8: In the EU12, manufacturing and services are more productive, construction less (productivity growth, by size of ï¬?rms and sector, 2002–07) Note: Data for 2008 are not included as sector classiï¬?cation changed from 2007 to 2008. For Estonia and Lithuania, the period considered is 2004–07; for Poland and Latvia, 2003–07. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. processes, and learn from the more productive ones through the flow of knowledge, capital, labor, and goods, moving toward the efï¬?ciency frontier (Acemoglu, Zilibotti, and Aghion 2006). Productivity growth should be inversely correlated with initial productivity levels. The data for Europe show a different story.18 As expected given the low initial level, from 2002 to 2008 EU12 productivity growth was strong, three to four times as high as in the average EU15 country. However, while the productivity divide between advanced and emerging Europe was closing, another gap was growing—that between the EU15 South and the rest of Western Europe (ï¬?gure 4.7). North and Continental Europe improved productivity, while the EU15 South showed a decline. A breakdown of the productivity contribution from 2002 to 2007 according to the different mix of sectors and size of enterprises helps explain in particular why Southern Europe was lagging. The catch-up of productivity in emerging Europe was vigorous, with annualized growth rates above 6 percent for almost all countries, from all types of ï¬?rms (ï¬?gure 4.8). The sectors more exposed to foreign trade (manufacturing and other services) accounted for a similar productivity gain across countries, while differential productivity growth in the remaining sectors (construction, wholesale and retail trade, hotel and restaurants, and transport and telecommunications) accounted for most of the difference, particularly the higher growth in the Baltic economies and the EU12 South (Bulgaria and Romania). In Central Europe, where larger enterprises shed excess labor, and drove productivity levels close to Portugal’s, smaller enterprises have increased productivity. In Romania and Bulgaria, ï¬?rms of different sizes show similar growth patterns, although in Bulgaria—where the average ï¬?rm size is larger— the productivity gains by large enterprises account for half of overall growth. 203 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.9: Manufacturing drives productivity growth in the EU15 center, services in the north (productivity growth, by size of ï¬?rms and sector, 2002–07) Note: Data for 2008 are not included as sector classiï¬?cation changed from 2007 to 2008. For Belgium, France, and Greece, the period considered is 2003–07. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. In the EU15, the construction sector shows limited or no productivity growth. Excluding construction, the gap between the EU15 South and the other countries is seen in all type of enterprises and sectors. On average, productivity growth for micro, small and medium, and large enterprises in all sectors is 0.5–1 percent lower than in the rest of Europe, pointing to a structural issue rather than ï¬?rm-speciï¬?c patterns. The mix of ï¬?rms may also explain part of the gap. Productivity growth in Southern Europe particularly lagged in services and in microenterprises. Microenterprises showed less productivity growth than larger enterprises across the continent and revealed a productivity decline in some southern countries. Given the relative importance of the microenterprises in these economies, this has a clear implication for overall growth. Likewise, while services increased productivity over the period in Northern Europe, the South (and to some extent Continental Europe) showed a different pattern. In Portugal and Greece, services made a negative contribution to productivity growth (ï¬?gure 4.9). The combined effect of these two patterns explains why the gap in productivity growth between Southern Europe and the rest is concentrated in real estate and other services, where microï¬?rms have the largest productivity gap versus their peers elsewhere. Exports—a winner-take-all reality? Generally speaking, European countries with higher export shares are pulling ahead and countries that are less open to trade are losing ground. Continental Europe and the new member states in the center are the export winners. Not only are they more export-oriented than the rest of Europe, their performance over the period is superior, with exports equivalent to more than half GDP. These export results are a function of the pan-European value chains 204 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.10: Exporting— Central Europe’s specialty (exports as share of GDP, 2002 and 2008) Source: WDI. developed by ï¬?rms across countries. Although overall exports relative to GDP increased across Europe, level and growth remain consistently lower in EU15 South (ï¬?gure 4.10). The presence of exporters in an economy is not only relevant from a macroeconomic perspective, but also at ï¬?rm level. Research shows that although the number of ï¬?rms that export is small, these ï¬?rms make a big contribution to economic growth and welfare. Higher-productivity ï¬?rms tend to export more.19 When looking at the EU15 and EU12 countries separately to account for differences in initial conditions, one ï¬?nds a strong correlation between country productivity and export performance (ï¬?gure 4.11). A recent study of manufacturing in six major European countries shows that exporting ï¬?rms in Europe tend to be larger, more productive, more innovative, and faster-growing than nonexporters in the same industry (box 4.3). Why did some parts of Europe do better than others? —FDI, offshoring, and heavy regulation Volkswagen, on the edge of bankruptcy in 1993 with €1 billion in losses, achieved a turnaround by consolidating platforms among its brands (Volkswagen, Å koda, Audi, and Seat); cutting development time and cost; and relocating production to Hungary, the Slovak Republic, and elsewhere. Å koda’s Mlada Boleslav plant became Volkswagen’s leader for supplier integration, offering jobs in several on-site suppliers to deliver carpets, seats, exhaust systems, rear axles, dashboards, and instrument panels. By 2010, Volkswagen Group had increased non-German employment from 41 percent in 1993 to 53 percent (Kubes and Radler 2002) and had 22 percent of the car markets in Central and Eastern Europe.20 The reconï¬?guration of the value chain transformed both the parent and the subsidiary. Benetton Group, an apparel manufacturer and retailer, has around 6,000 stores in 120 countries and annual sales of about €2 billion. Distinct from its smaller peers in Prato, Benetton is an Italian “globalizer.â€? Its supply and distribution chains are characterized by the combination of upstream vertical integration, outsourcing of labor-intensive downstream production, and retail outlets 205 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.11: The size and productivity of ï¬?rms influence a country’s exports, late 2000s (export share as a function of aggregate size and productivity) Note: The variables on the y-axis in each panel are for 2009, while those on the x-axis are for 2007. For the Slovak Republic, data refer to 2005. WAP is working age population. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat, UNCOMTRADE, and WDI. managed by third parties—balancing quality control, cost competitiveness, and responsiveness to market shifts (Camuffo, Romano, and Vinelli 2001). Benetton has production facilities in Croatia, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Romania, Serbia, and Ukraine. Å koda and Benetton exemplify the successful companies in Europe: those that attracted investors, expanded, and accessed new markets, often by setting up foreign subsidiaries. The success of a country in generating jobs, value, and exports depends on its enterprises. Over the past decade in Europe, this meant having export-oriented, sizable companies. But not all European ï¬?rms like to grow. Mr. Rossi’s ï¬?rm in Northern Italy, referred to in the opening paragraphs of this chapter, remains a family-run enterprise and has not grown in size since its early years. Mr. Rossi’s experience is unfortunately all too common in Italy, Greece, and some other countries. When the cost of dealing with the government is high, many businesses prefer to stay small. Together, these examples help answer three questions: · Why did countries in emerging Europe manage to successfully start catching up to the EU15? Being open to foreign investments, like Å koda was, helped countries begin to catch up. Lada, which until 2008 was owned by the Russian government, did not perform nearly as well. Investment flows from advanced to catch-up economies beneï¬?ted host countries by generating employment, transferring technological and managerial knowledge that raised productivity, and linking the companies to global networks, which increased exports. · How did EU15 North and Continental countries manage to keep doing well? These countries had the right type of ï¬?rms to take advantage of enlargement. These ï¬?rms could offshore and enter new markets. Volkswagen is just one of many companies that decentralized its production chain in Eastern Europe. 206 CHAPTER 4 · What makes the EU15 South a laggard? Southern Europe had few global companies. If the south had more Benettons, or attracted more foreign investment, it would have been a different story. Mr. Rossi’s company is typical of many in the south. A complex business environment—especially poor design and enforcement of regulations—stifles enterprises’ growth, making them unsuited for increasingly competitive European and global markets. The northeastern achievement: attracting FDI In 1990–2009, Poland took in more than $180 billion in FDI,21 equivalent to 39 percent of its GDP. Estimations based on a representative sample of ï¬?rms from Eastern Europe show that in 2008, one of six Polish companies with 10 employees or more was foreign-owned. The same foreign companies employ a third of Polish workers and generate close to half its value added. In 2003–08, foreign enterprises were responsible for creating one of four new jobs in Poland.22 This trend is not unique to Poland. Since 1990, other countries in Central and Eastern Europe have also received large volumes of FDI—for emerging Europe, equivalent to one-quarter of its GDP (ï¬?gures 4.12 and 4.13).23 FDI flows have accelerated since enlargement in the 2000s, when about 20 percent of FDI flows in Europe were directed toward former Soviet bloc countries. FDI through new subsidiaries and the acquisition of existing enterprises—most often due to privatization of former state-owned enterprises—affects the performance of the economy. Box 4.3: What do successful exporters look like? An extensive economic literature analyzes ownership, and age. than country characteristics in explaining the relationship between ï¬?rm characteristics export behavior. The export performance of Some common patterns in advanced and and export propensity. Barba Navaretti and Eastern European ï¬?rms is largely explained others (2011) analyze the export activity of emerging Europe emerge, indicating that ï¬?rm by ï¬?rm-speciï¬?c characteristics. When trying ï¬?rms in Austria, France, Germany, Hungary, characteristics are what matter more than to measure the extent to which differentials Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom. Using country conditions. in export behavior in emerging Europe are data collected by the World Bank’s Enterprise • Extensive margin: larger, foreign, more correlated with business regulations, and Surveys in 2009, this report extends the productive, and more innovative ï¬?rms are particularly trade-related regulations, the analysis to 20 emerging Europe and eastern more likely to export; differences in age results show that: partnership/EU candidate countries (Armenia, between exporters and nonexporters do Azerbaijan, Belarus, Bosnia and Herzegovina, • Extensive margin is positively correlated not appear to be signiï¬?cant. Bulgaria, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, with business regulation (measured by the Georgia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, the former • Intensive margin: the share of exports principal components analysis indicator Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Moldova, is higher for larger, young, and foreign- of the Business Operations Index). A Poland, Romania, Serbia, the Slovak Republic, owned ï¬?rms. similar result holds for the speciï¬?c trade Slovenia, Turkey, and Ukraine). indicator (one component of the Business Some differences indicate peculiarities of Following Barba Navaretti and others (2011), Operations Index). emerging Europe: size and foreign ownership this report uses a cross-country linear have a much higher impact on exports in • Intensive margin appears correlated with probability model for the extensive margins emerging Europe than in the EU15 (Hungary the Business Operations Index, but not (the share of exporting ï¬?rms) and a linear is the exception). Age does not appear speciï¬?cally with trade regulations. regression model for the intensive margins relevant, conï¬?rming that in emerging Europe (the share of the export value over total sales, These results indicate that better trade young ï¬?rms are often more dynamic. And in restricting the sample to exporters) to identify regulations facilitate exports by reducing emerging Europe, research and development is the features that characterize exporters barriers to new market. For ï¬?rms that reach relevant to explain the propensity of a ï¬?rm to and nonexporters. The empirical estimation new sale destinations and overcome the export, but not its export intensity. considers a number of ï¬?rm characteristics: size entry costs, export intensity is affected by the (measured in number of full-time employees), Barba Navaretti and others (2011) show overall regulatory environment rather than by labor productivity, domestic versus foreign that ï¬?rm characteristics are more relevant regulations governing foreign trade. 207 GOLDEN GROWTH As Poland’s example shows, foreign-owned ï¬?rms in the EU12 are more productive and tend to grow faster than domestic ones. This is the result of parent company investments in plants and people, which materialized in new technology and processes, but also in management skills, access to better inputs, and connection to international markets. This is the case for most countries in the sample (ï¬?gure 4.14).24 FDI does not beneï¬?t only the receiving company (Javorick 2004). It has broader sector and economywide beneï¬?ts, producing spillover effects as productivity improvements and employment effects are captured not only by the receiving ï¬?rm, but other enterprises in the country. Other members of the value chain, which receive knowledge from international best practices (vertical spillovers, as through quality certiï¬?cation systems), and competitors which learn from the products brought to the market by the foreign-owned ï¬?rms (horizontal spillovers), also beneï¬?t from FDI. FDI was positively correlated with growth in jobs and productivity in the EU12, and contributed to value-added growth (ï¬?gure 4.15). The export performance of ï¬?rms in Eastern Europe conï¬?rms that foreign ownership—along with size—is one of the most important explanations for the enterprise’s export propensity and export intensity. Figure 4.12: The south has become less attractive to foreign investors, the east more so (FDI flows into Europe, all sectors, 1985-2009) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on UNCTAD (2010). Figure 4.13: Not all countries in emerging Europe are equally attractive for foreign investors (EU12 FDI stock, 2008, percentage of GDP) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 208 CHAPTER 4 Beyond FDI, what are the factors behind the productivity performance of the new member states? A panel of surviving ï¬?rms (with 10 employees or more) from the Amadeus dataset in EU12 countries25 helps illuminate the drivers of productivity growth in different sectors of the real economy in 2003–08. The analysis disentangles ï¬?rm-speciï¬?c characteristics from country-level attributes. · Do country characteristics explain enterprise performance in the EU12? Yes. Considering ï¬?rm productivity growth as a function of the ï¬?rm’s initial productivity level, ï¬?rm characteristics (size, age, ownership, and sector of activity), and country dummies, country dummies are statistically signiï¬?cant and differ greatly, indicating that similar companies perform differently in different countries (table A4.2).26, 27 For example, the productivity of a manufacturing Figure 4.14: Foreign ï¬?rm are more productive and have faster productivity growth Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus. Figure 4.15: In the EU12, FDI is positively associated with productivity and jobs (growth in employment, productivity, and value added, 2002–08) Note: For the Czech Republic, Latvia, and Romania, data on the y-axis refer to 2002–07. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 209 GOLDEN GROWTH company in Poland grows 2.1 percentage points slower than that of a similar manufacturer in Slovenia. The results are similar for manufacturing and services—a country that does well in facilitating business in one sector tends to do well in the other. · Are country characteristics more important than ï¬?rm characteristics in explaining enterprise performance in the EU12? They appear to be. The exclusion of ï¬?rm characteristics from the regression of productivity growth for manufacturing ï¬?rms reduces the explanatory power of the model by 8 percent. However, when country dummies are excluded, the model loses about four times as much of its predictive power, or 33 percent. For services, a similar pattern emerges: the explanatory power of the model is reduced more when dropping country-ï¬?xed effects (23 percent) than when excluding variables of ï¬?rm characteristics (8 percent). The conclusion is that cross-country differences are more relevant for ï¬?rm performance than ï¬?rm characteristics in the new member states. · What are the most important country characteristics for ï¬?rm performance in the EU12? The “fundamentals.â€? This response emerges from a correlation of estimated country dummies with country characteristics such as the regulatory environment, quality of hard infrastructure, skills of the workforce, share of credit to GDP, and FDI inflows and outflows.28 The quality of infrastructure, FDI inflows, availability of credit, and ease of conducting business operations appear to drive country productivity improvements (ï¬?gure 4.16). That most variables are similarly correlated with ï¬?rms’ performance in both manufacturing and services points to the importance of fundamentals. To infer causality, an extended version of the model is used in which ï¬?rm productivity growth (in 2003–08) is explained by the same ï¬?rm controls, sector dummies, country ï¬?xed effects, and changes of country characteristics in the same period. By including both country characteristics and country dummies, the unobservable country-speciï¬?c influences are controlled for, allowing a more reliable understanding of what causes what. For both manufacturing and services, productivity gains in the EU12 are indeed linked to increases in inward FDI and, relatedly, to better business regulations, especially for taxes, foreign trade, and employment.29 · What are the most important ï¬?rm characteristics for explaining ï¬?rm performance in the EU12? In one word—ownership. This question was answered in two ways. First, a counterfactual exercise compared how the estimated country dummies change when adding each control (baseline productivity, sector, ownership, size, and age) in the model that explains productivity growth. A Czech manufacturing ï¬?rm is a good illustration. The average productivity gap between a Slovenian and a Czech ï¬?rm in manufacturing is 6.7 percent. When considering two ï¬?rms with the same baseline productivity, this gap falls to 4.7 percent, indicating greater productivity for the average Czech ï¬?rm. Limiting the observation to two ï¬?rms with the same sector specialization would not change the result (4.6 percent). Finally, if the two ï¬?rms had the same ownership, size, and age composition, the gap narrows further, to 3.8 percent, indicating that the Czech Republic 210 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.16: In the EU12, infrastructure, credit, FDI, and regulations are correlated with productivity (correlation between country dummies and policy variables in EU12 countries, 2002–08) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus, Doing Business, WEF's Global Competitiveness Reports, and WDI . has a negative mix of ï¬?rm characteristics (table A4.2).30 The remaining effect is country-speciï¬?c. A complementary way to explore the role of ï¬?rm features in ï¬?rm performance is to look at the coefï¬?cients of the ï¬?rms’ characteristics in the regression model. Results show that ownership is especially important for productivity growth in the EU12 (table A4.2). Being part of an international group pays: foreign-owned ï¬?rms grow faster than purely domestic ones, in manufacturing and services. Home-based companies with an international presence31 also grow faster than domestic-owned companies: by 6.7 percent in manufacturing and by 3.1 percent in services. Size seems to matter less: both in manufacturing and services, size is negatively correlated with productivity growth. Lower productivity growth for larger enterprises can be part of the legacy of the Soviet system; newer, smaller enterprises are more likely to have efï¬?cient production processes and less cumbersome employment structures. The age of the ï¬?rm does not seem to matter for productivity growth in the EU12. Together, the productivity performance of foreign-owned ï¬?rms and the positive correlation of inward FDI at the country level with productivity growth at the level of the ï¬?rm conï¬?rm a prominent role for FDI in emerging Europe.32 Inward FDI can be attracted and stimulated. Good infrastructure and favorable business regulations help the most, even when adjusting for market size and skills of the workforce (box 4.4). Among the business regulations that matter most, three stand out: trade, labor, and taxation (the burden of which is calculated as the total tax rate and compliance costs). Why Northern Europe thrived: flexibility in offshoring About 10 percent of Swedish ï¬?rms belong to Sweden-based enterprise groups with at least one subsidiary in Europe.33 By contrast, fewer than 3 percent of Italian or Spanish ï¬?rms are part of a domestic group with an international presence. As a result, more Swedish ï¬?rms operate on a European scale and have taken advantage of an enlarged Europe. Such offshoring introduces substantial beneï¬?ts. Domestic companies in Europe with an international presence involved in manufacturing and 211 GOLDEN GROWTH services are at least 30 percent more productive, and their value added grows much faster, than domestically owned companies (ï¬?gure 4.17). Investment in new member states—facilitated by the enlargement process—is not only beneï¬?cial for FDI-receiving companies. FDI-providing ï¬?rms in tradable sectors—largely in manufacturing but also in services—leveraged vertical FDI to establish production facilities in foreign markets, reducing labor costs and maintaining competitive advantage. German Mittelstand companies are the best example of this successful integration (ï¬?gure 4.18). Successful countries in Northern and Continental Europe not only nurtured domestic ï¬?rms that invested abroad, but also attracted foreign ï¬?rms, as reflected in their FDI. In 2000–09, $4,400 billion came into the EU15 economies, 49 percent of which went to the United Kingdom, Germany, and France (ï¬?gure 4.19).34 The result is a widely internationalized enterprise sector. As with the EU12 above, the drivers of productivity growth in different sectors of the real economy in 2003–08 may be analyzed for the EU15, as follows. Despite similarities, the different stages of enterprise development in advanced and emerging Europe stand out. · Do country characteristics explain enterprise performance in the EU15? Yes. Based on the panel of surviving ï¬?rms from the Amadeus dataset, a regression model is applied to explain ï¬?rm productivity growth in the EU15 countries as a function of the ï¬?rms’ initial productivity level, characteristics (size, age, ownership, and sector), and country dummies.35 Country dummies Box 4.4: What attracts FDI?—Decent infrastructure and good regulations Regardless of geographic focus, most studies The Amadeus database can also be used to Across Borders database. of the drivers of FDI point to market size (and shed light on the relationship between the The analysis for Europe conï¬?rms what Mukim its growth potential) and factor endowments business environment and FDI. By considering (2011) and Waglé (2011) found for the rest of (infrastructure, human capital) as signiï¬?cant a list of top-performing manufacturing ï¬?rms the world: the quality of FDI-related institutions factors in attracting FDI.1 in Europe—the 150 international groups that (measured by the ease of accessing industrial contributed the most to value added in 2003– The policy environment also matters, land), regulation of business operations, and 08—and analyzing their asset allocation across however. According to Demekas and others infrastructure quality in a speciï¬?c country are countries, we can measure the country-speciï¬?c (2005 and 2007), even though market size positively associated with the share of total factors in a location choice. These 150 groups explains a large part of FDI inflows in Central investment made by the top global groups in made manufacturing investment (for example, and Eastern Europe, including Southeastern Europe, even when controlling for market size car parts and assembly factories) as well as Europe, the investment climate is another and workforce skills. A one standard deviation retail, wholesale (car dealers, for example), and determinant. Expropriation risks, lack of increase in the Doing Business indicator raises other services (car leasing) subsidiaries. contract enforcement, poor provision of public the country share by 2.1 percent. For the goods, overregulation, and unreasonable costs To calculate the factors, we use the value Investment across Borders index on access to of doing business are likely to deter private of the assets of these companies’ foreign land, a one standard deviation increase would activity. Mukim (2011), using worldwide data, subsidiaries as proxies for the FDI in a speciï¬?c augment the country share by 0.7 percent. ï¬?nds that better access to and availability country in given sectors. Exogenous factors And a one standard deviation increase of of land information increases the chances of affecting FDI decisions about where to locate, the infrastructure quality would increase the new investment. Also using worldwide data, such as the country’s market size, labor skills, country share by 2.8 percent. Waglé (2011) ï¬?nds a statistically signiï¬?cant infrastructure, and business regulations, we relationship between FDI regulations and the also consider. GDP (in US$ billions) is used as a 1 Mukim and Nunnenkamp 2010 offer an value of inward FDI, after controlling for market proxy for the market size of the host country, overview of the literature; World Bank 2010b size and quality of infrastructure logistics. while the proxy for FDI-relevant institutions gives a compilation of recent studies on this comes from the World Bank’s Investment subject. 212 CHAPTER 4 are statistically signiï¬?cant and large, indicating that cross-country differences are a relevant correlate of the performances of similar companies across the EU15. Locating in one country or another can mean up to 7 percentage points of productivity variation in manufacturing and 5 percentage points in services (table A4.3).36 Country performances differ widely among sectors: Norway leads in productivity in services, but is the laggard in manufacturing. · Are country characteristics more important than a ï¬?rm’s features in explaining its performance in the EU15? Generally no. The ï¬?rm’s type matters most. The exclusion of country dummies from the regression of productivity growth in manufacturing reduces the explanatory power of the model by 19 percent. For services, the model loses 11 percent. With the same exercise but excluding ï¬?rm characteristics—size, ownership, sector of activity,37 and age—the model loses about 25 percent of its explanatory power, in both manufacturing and services. Overall, these results suggest that the ï¬?rm size, age, ownership, and sector composition explain a large share of cross-country disparities. · What are the most important country characteristics for ï¬?rm performance in the EU15? The factors for advanced Europe appear to be different from those for emerging Europe. Different variables explain productivity growth in manufacturing and services, with one element in common: entry and employment regulations are positively correlated with productivity growth. But while manufacturing productivity is largely correlated with FDI inflows and outflows, services appear to be most affected by regulations (ï¬?gure 4.20). As with emerging Europe, an extended version of the model including variation in country characteristics as explanatory variables was used to understand causes and effects. Results show that for manufacturing in EU15, changes in supply of outward FDI increase productivity growth. Similarly, improvements in business regulation appear to increase productivity growth in both manufacturing and services. Figure 4.17: In the EU15, ï¬?rms with a foreign presence are more productive and grow faster (productivity levels, 2008, and growth of value added, 2002–08) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus. 213 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.18: Investing abroad is related to higher productivity growth (correlation between economywide productivity and investments abroad) Note: Both productivity and FDI ï¬?gures refer only to manufacturing industry. For France and United Kingdom, the period of time considered to calculate the productivity growth is 2002–07. For Greece, data over the period of 2003–07 are used to compute the growth rate. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. · What ï¬?rm features explain ï¬?rm performance most in the EU15? Italian manufacturing is illustrative. The average productivity growth gap between an Italian and a Finnish ï¬?rm in manufacturing is 2.9 percent. However, considering companies with the same sector specialization, the gap declines to 2.4 percent. If ï¬?rms in these two countries were similar in size, age, and ownership composition, the gap would be just 1.7 percent (table A4.3).38 These results suggest that ownership, size, and sector are important. Estimated coefï¬?cients of the ï¬?rm characteristics in the regression model reveal other points. For EU15, ownership, size, and age are important ï¬?rm features for productivity growth (table A4.3). Foreign-owned ï¬?rms and afï¬?liates of an international group grow more. Unlike within the EU12, scale is important in EU15 countries in both manufacturing and services: larger ï¬?rms’ productivity rises faster. Firms that have 50–499 employees grow faster than ï¬?rms with 10–49 employees. Older ï¬?rms in services expand faster than the youngest. In manufacturing, however, age does not seem to matter. In the EU27 as a whole, workforce skills do not appear to be an important country characteristic to explain productivity growth at ï¬?rm level. Using the Amadeus sample of ï¬?rms, the correlation between estimated country dummies and workforce skills—measured as the proportion of the workforce with tertiary education—showed a positive but small effect for EU12 ï¬?rms: 0.16 for manufacturing and 0.07 for services. For the EU15, the estimate was negative (but also small): –0.08 for manufacturing and –0.11 for services. 214 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.19: Northern and Continental Europe get the bulk of FDI (EU15 FDI stock, percentage of GDP, 2008) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. The results are somewhat surprising, because much evidence shows that human capital is an essential factor in economic growth. One possible reason for this result might be the indicator used to proxy skills. The outcome of education is composed of quantity and quality of educational capital. While quantity can be measured by the proportion of the workforce with a certain level of instruction, or even by the number of graduates, it is hard to accurately measure the quality of educational capital. Conceptually, quality is reflected in the performance of students and graduates, but it can be also measured by the perceptions about the quality of the educational system. Using the quality of education systems reported by the World Economic Forum and performing the same exercise with the estimated country dummies provides somewhat different results. The quality of labor force does seem to matter for ï¬?rm level productivity growth at ï¬?rm level, particularly in EU12 countries.39 It appears to matter even more among the non-EU countries of Europe (box 4.5). Figure 4.20: In the EU15, FDI and regulations are the closest correlates of productivity (correlation between country dummies and policy variables) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus, Doing Business, WEF's Global Competitiveness Reports, and WDI. 215 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 4.5: Productivity drivers are similar outside the European Union Using the sample of surviving ï¬?rms (with 10 are more important than ï¬?rm features, a and services indicate that for this group of employees or more) from the Amadeus dataset pattern that is similar for manufacturing and countries, these “fundamentalsâ€? are more it is possible to study a few non-EU European services. The exclusion of country dummies relevant for enterprise productivity. countries such as Bosnia and Herzegovina, from the regression of productivity growth in Croatia, Serbia, and Ukraine. By performing manufacturing reduces the explanatory power Third, ownership is the most important ï¬?rm- exactly the same set of exercises, a picture of the model by 20 percent. For services, speciï¬?c variable for productivity growth. Being similar to the one for EU12 countries emerges. the model loses 16 percent. Excluding ï¬?rm part of an international group pays off. Foreign- characteristics—size, ownership, sector of owned ï¬?rms grow faster than purely domestic First, country characteristics explain enterprise activity, and age—the model loses about ones, both in manufacturing and services. performance more, indicating that similar 10 percent of its explanatory power in Home-based companies with an international companies perform differently in different manufacturing, and 11 percent in services. presence grow 8 percent more than domestic- countries (table A4.4, columns 1 and 6). For example, the productivity of a manufacturing Second, the most important country owned companies, but only in manufacturing. company operating in Croatia grows 8.6 characteristics are incoming FDI, availability Older ï¬?rms grow less than young companies, percentage points higher than a similar of credit, and ease of conducting business both in manufacturing and services, while manufacturer in Bosnia and Herzegovina. The operations (particularly trade and tax size does not seem to matter for productivity results also show that country characteristics regulation). Similar results for manufacturing growth (table A4.4, columns 1 and 6). Why the south is slow: inappropriate structures and burdensome regulations Why did the southern countries in the EU15 not experience the productivity improvements that beneï¬?ted the rest of Europe? The answer lies in both ï¬?rm and country drivers of productivity. First, the mix of companies nurtured at home—skewed toward microenterprises—and the limited number of ï¬?rms attracted from abroad explain part of the productivity gap. Second, an unfavorable set of country characteristics, including a more complex regulatory framework, also creates an environment that is not conducive to productivity growth. The two elements are connected: the “mixâ€? of companies is largely driven by a country’s environment, and each requires analysis. A comparison of the EU15 South with the rest of the EU15 shows that business regulations and FDI—the country-level variables positively correlated with ï¬?rm performance in advanced Europe—consistently lag in Southern Europe (ï¬?gure 4.21). But size, too, plays an important role. The average size of ï¬?rms in Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain is a little more than half that of ï¬?rms in the rest of the European Union (according to Eurostat data). Size is a good proxy for the “typeâ€? of company and the sophistication of its operations. Microenterprises are mostly family-owned and have a limited division of tasks. Flexibility in the use of labor and limited overhead costs allow microenterprises to reach a basic level of efï¬?ciency. However, limited capital investments constrain microenterprises in scaling up operations, especially in capital-intensive sectors. Microï¬?rms play a role in the economies of Southern Europe, which is uncommon in the other developed economies of Europe. One of two workers in the EU15 South is employed by microenterprises. In addition, about a third of the entire value added of the economy is generated by these ï¬?rms. These ï¬?gures are almost double those for the rest of Europe, where large enterprises have a more prominent role. The proportion becomes even higher when small and medium enterprises are added to microï¬?rms: taken together, micro and small and 216 CHAPTER 4 medium enterprises employ four of ï¬?ve workers in Southern Europe (ï¬?gure 4.22). Microenterprises are one of the factors behind the productivity gap between the EU15 South and the rest of the EU15. If the south had a size mix similar to that of the other countries in advanced Europe, and its microenterprises had a productivity level equal to that of its comparators, Southern Europe would reduce its productivity gap by 40 percent. A smaller share of large ï¬?rms explains not only Southern Europe’s gap in productivity, but also the difference in export levels. Medium and large enterprises perform consistently better in exports than smaller enterprises, and Southern Europe is no exception. The export propensity of larger ï¬?rms in Southern Europe is similar or better—as in Italy—than in the rest of advanced Europe (ï¬?gure 4.23). Figure 4.21: Southern Europe underperforms the rest of the EU15 in all aspects but access to credit (country-level indicators, 2008-12) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Doing Business, WEF's Global Competitiveness Reports, WDI. Figure 4.22: Microï¬?rms generate half the employment and a third of the value added in the EU15 South (distribution of ï¬?rm population, employment, and value added per ï¬?rm size structure, 2008) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat. 217 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 4.6: The features of a global ï¬?rm Firm ownership is an important characteristic internationalization. Firms with more than and related productivity differences. The in the evolution of ï¬?rm performance. 1,000 employees are 35 percent more likely to probability of internationalizing is correlated Companies with international operations be the global headquarters of a company in with better business regulation (box ï¬?gure (a global headquarters of an international the EU15 (box table 1). Age is not important. 1). This might reflect the fact that ï¬?rms in group or one of its domestic afï¬?liates) have countries with better business regulation But there is country-speciï¬?c bias. For have higher productivity growth. “Global higher productivity growth than purely example, being in Italy and Spain signiï¬?cantly sourcingâ€? models (Antràs and Helpman 2004, domestic-owned ï¬?rms in the EU15, both in reduces the probability of being a global for example) suggest that as ï¬?rms increase manufacturing and services. headquarters, while being in Sweden increases productivity, they tend to access international Size is the most important correlate of this likelihood. Why? Business regulations markets by producing abroad. Box table 1: Average estimated marginal effects on Box ï¬?gure 1: Better business regulations the probability of being a global headquarters in EU15 aid successful globalization of enterprises Variable dy/dx (percent) P>|z| Size (50–249) 7.25 0.000 Size (250–499) 18.34 0.000 Size (500–999) 22.92 0.000 Size (1,000 or more) 35.04 0.000 Age –0.06 0.494 Note: Additional controls considered but not reported are sector (NACE) dummies. The omitted size category is (10–49). Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Doing Business 2008. Source: World Bank staff calculations. If Southern Europe had a higher share of larger ï¬?rms, its export gap could be ï¬?lled (see Barba Navaretti and others 2011). Similarly, larger companies are more inclined to invest in foreign markets. Larger ï¬?rms are most likely to have an international subsidiary and to beneï¬?t from offshoring (box 4.6). The industrial structure is not a given. For instance, the presence of foreign-owned ï¬?rms is influenced by policy decisions and a country’s ability to attract FDI. The business environment is a critical driver in this process (box 4.4). Lagging in regulations, Southern European economies are making themselves less attractive to foreign ï¬?rms. Additionally, microï¬?rms in Southern Europe prefer to stay small and informal as a coping strategy, to simply bypass a complicated regulatory framework. Comparing countries in advanced Europe, the correlation between a heavier regulatory framework (measured by a lower quality of regulations) and the share of employment in microenterprises becomes evident. On the one hand, microenterprises face simpliï¬?ed regulations in most countries.40 On the other, weaker enforcement mechanisms are applied to microï¬?rms,41 which allow 218 CHAPTER 4 them to more easily operate semiformally. This is corroborated by the relationship between density of microï¬?rms and the share of the informal sector in the economy.42 Both elements provide an incentive for ï¬?rms to stay small (ï¬?gure 4.24). At the same time, faced with more complicated business regulations and competition from microenterprises, small and medium enterprises and larger ï¬?rms in Southern Europe ï¬?nd it harder to grow. They are likely to survive but shrink in size. A healthy competitive process should select companies so the better ones survive and graduate toward larger classes while inefï¬?cient companies exit the market. This is not what happens in Southern Europe. Firms do not grow, they often downsize, but do not exit the market. Figure 4.23: In the EU15, size matters more than country for exports (percentage of exporting ï¬?rms and share of export per size class, 2008) Source: Barba Navaretti and others 2011; and Eurostat. Figure 4.24: In a difï¬?cult business environment, ï¬?rms stay small and operate more informally (business environment, share of informal economy and microenterprises in the EU15) Note: For Ireland, data refer to 2005. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Eurostat, Doing Business, and Schneider and others (2010). 219 GOLDEN GROWTH Figure 4.25: Firms in southern and emerging Europe are most likely to survive, but shrink (share of ï¬?rms that maintained (stay) or modiï¬?ed (down or up) their size between 2003 and 2008) Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus data. Figure 4.26: In a better business environment, ï¬?rms are less likely to shrink (marginal effect of a 10-point improvement in business regulations and the density of microï¬?rms) Note: Data refer to the estimated marginal effects of varying, separately, the key variables used in the multinomial logit model: regulation on business operations and density of microï¬?rms. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Amadeus. The matrices in ï¬?gure 4.25 show the distribution of ï¬?rm size using the initial (2003) and ï¬?nal (2008) size for a given class. For instance, in the EU15 North/ Continental, 83 percent of surviving ï¬?rms with 10–49 employees in 2003 were in the same size category in 2008, while 12.4 percent were smaller (but still in business). In the EU15 South, this latter proportion was higher: 18.5 percent of ï¬?rms of that size class had transited to a smaller size category by 2008. By estimating the probabilities of a ï¬?rm’s downsizing, staying in the same size category, or jumping to a higher size class from 2003 to 2008—based on the Amadeus panel of survival ï¬?rms and relating these probabilities to country characteristics (regulations, industrial structures, and access to credit)—one sees what helps foster competition and creative destruction.43 Regulations seem related to this Southern European phenomenon, both directly and through their impact on microï¬?rms. The industrial structure is approximated by the density of microenterprises in the country: the share of microï¬?rms per 1,000 employable people. Credit-to-GDP is used to approximate access to ï¬?nancing.44 Figure 4.26 presents the marginal effect of both business regulation (measured by each alternative indicator used in the model) and density of microï¬?rms on the probability of decreasing in size class. The probability that a ï¬?rm transits to a smaller size class from 2003 to 2008 is negatively related to business regulation in the country where it is located, suggesting that better business regulation reduces the probability 220 CHAPTER 4 of downsizing. For instance, improving regulation by 10 points decreases the probability of downsizing by 3.5 percent. When regulations are complicated, ï¬?rms survive, but stay small. The existence of microï¬?rms might even drag down ï¬?rms that are larger, hampering their growth. An increase of 10 points in the density of microï¬?rms is related to increases of about 8 percent in the probability that a ï¬?rm will downsize. The effect of credit on the probability of downsizing did not seem to be statistically signiï¬?cant. What is the relationship between regulations and enterprise growth? Parmalat, an Italian dairy and food corporation, became famous in 2003 for the biggest bankruptcy in Europe’s history.45 Parmalat was rescued, its business downsized, and the company brought back to market in 2005. In early spring 2011, Lactalis, a large French dairy group, expressed interest in acquiring Parmalat. The announcement spurred heated political discussion in Italy. After three months Lactalis was allowed to take over Parmalat, but not before politicians denounced the acquisition by foreign companies of Italy’s “family jewels.â€? In July 2011, the Italian parliament approved a law regulating book sales, crafted along the lines of similar legislation in force in France since 1981 known as the “anti-Amazon Law.â€? The law regulates the price of books (physical and digital) that can be sold in retail and wholesale outlets and over the Internet, restricting the timing and amount of discounts. The law protects small bookstores against competition from large chains and Internet sellers. Regulations such as these are a major obstacle to business in Southern Europe. Consider a truck company operating in both the United Kingdom and Italy. The payroll slip of a truck driver in the United Kingdom consists of ï¬?ve lines, and costs about €5 to ï¬?ll in. The payroll slip for a similar driver in Italy is a page long, requires the services of an accounting expert, and costs about €25–30 to ï¬?ll in. This section explores whether European enterprises are overregulated and whether these regulations are an obstacle to economic growth. The short answer is mostly not. Sweden shows how a heavily regulated country can, indeed, perform well (box 4.7). Country and ï¬?rm characteristics matter for performance, and business regulations are a signiï¬?cant part of the puzzle. On the one hand, regulations directly affect company performance in producing jobs, value added, and exports, because simplifying payroll ï¬?ling requirements is likely to reduce costs and improve ï¬?rms’ productivity. On the other, regulations can change the type of businesses that succeed. An unnecessarily complex business environment breaks the virtuous circle encompassing productivity, enterprise growth, and internationalization. Faced with complicated regulations, ï¬?rms tend to be smaller, less productive, and less inclined to operate in international markets. The relationship between business regulation and enterprise growth can be disentangled into three (interrelated) threads: regulation for graduating small and medium enterprises; that for increasing productivity; and that for internationalizing ï¬?rms (either through exports or offshoring) and attracting foreign companies. 221 GOLDEN GROWTH Box 4.7: The Swedish model Sweden has a total corporate tax rate of 50 to a minimum. According to Doing Business, enterprises about 285 hours.) A simple tax percent but achieves employment participation ï¬?rms in Sweden are only required to pay system also reduces reliance on, for example, rates above 70 percent. Swedish enterprises taxes twice a year—the fewest in the world. tax accountants. By eliminating a burden increased their productivity at 1.4 percent a The time required for Swedish ï¬?rms to fulï¬?ll on ï¬?rms, a simple tax system partially year over the last 15 years, almost up to the their tax requirements is just 122 hours compensates for a higher tax rate. level seen in the United States. a year, signiï¬?cantly lower than the OECD Sweden achieved its productivity growth by average of almost 200 hours. (Italy requires Source: World Bank staff calculation, based on keeping regulation compliance requirements 15 tax payments, taking small and medium Doing Business 2011. Small ï¬?rms are beautiful—when they are young “Small is beautifulâ€? was the industrial development slogan of the 1970s in Italy. Italian family-run enterprises were praised for their dynamism, efï¬?ciency, and flexibility, which flowed mainly from their small size. But there is a minimum scale below which size becomes a constraint to growth. Growing is an important part in nurturing productivity growth and internationalizing ï¬?rms. As seen, larger ï¬?rms beneï¬?t from economies of scale, are more productive, and are likely to engage in international operations (through export and FDI). Business regulation plays an important role in this process (ï¬?gure 4.27). A better regulatory framework affects the growth of ï¬?rm size. Hence policies concerning the operation of ï¬?rms, such as tax administration and labor regulation, can improve the ï¬?rms’ cost structure. Reforms in these areas can be especially important in graduating small and medium enterprises to larger ï¬?rms (Shiffer and Weder 2001). The instruments that help ï¬?rms grow bigger depend on the stage of development. In emerging Europe, improving access to credit and institutional development, such as greater judicial efï¬?ciency, by the late 1990s, moderates ï¬?nancial constraints and contributes to ï¬?rm growth (Kumar, Rajan, and Zingales 1999). Reducing costs to increase ï¬?rm productivity Enterprise productivity growth is largely associated with country characteristics where ï¬?rms operate. The analysis of surviving ï¬?rms showed that similar ï¬?rms (in size, age, ownership, and sector) perform differently across countries, suggesting that the country and its policy environment are relevant to productivity performance. The same analysis highlighted some of the country characteristics related to productivity performance. Business regulation was important. As highlighted by Crafts (2006), business regulation can result in resources directed toward compliance rather than the creation of productive output, and can impose constraints on the choice of production techniques (such as preventing the use of inputs) or lead to a misallocation of resources. The earlier empirical analysis shows that the size of the relationship between business regulation and productivity performance differs according to region (EU15 or EU12) and sector (manufacturing or services). In the EU12, business regulation, with infrastructure and credit, positively correlates with productivity 222 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.27: Better regulations create jobs (regulatory quality, ï¬?rm size, and employment ratios, 2007) Note: For the Slovak Republic, data refer to 2005. Source: World Bank staff calculations, based on Doing Business and Eurostat. performance (both for manufacturing and services), with the strongest correlation with trade, employment, and taxes. In the EU15, business regulation, especially for services, is an important country factor, particularly through regulations on business start-ups and labor. Ensuring that business regulation is well designed and targeted is likely to have a positive impact on the productive capacity of an economy and productivity at ï¬?rm level. These important regulatory areas—trade, employment, taxes, and business start-ups—can be illustrative of how to design regulations to improve productivity performance. For employment regulation, reducing the costs of hiring and ï¬?ring workers would increase the incentives to innovate, and hence productivity growth (Scarpetta and Tressel 2002). Reforms that simplify tax regulations and reduce the administrative costs of compliance (which tend to be proportionately higher for smaller ï¬?rms) will likely have a positive effect on productivity growth as resources are freed to create productive output. Reforms that reduce start- up cost for entrepreneurs, simplify company registration procedures and requirements, eliminate steps to register property, and streamline bankruptcy procedures (which facilitate exit of inefï¬?cient enterprises) are likely to increase 223 GOLDEN GROWTH competition and contestability of markets. Increased competition will in turn provide an incentive for ï¬?rms to adopt more advanced technologies, thereby increasing productivity (Klapper, Laeven, and Rajan 2006; Poschke 2010). Firms beyond borders A regulatory environment conducive to private sector growth closely relates to international expansion, either through exports or through production abroad. Reforms that make it easier for ï¬?rms to export and run their business operations are likely to lift the export performance of an economy and therefore overall economic growth. Recent literature provides evidence that “behind the borderâ€? policies matter for trade performance (Hoekman and Nicita 2008) and that trade facilitation measures and the prevailing business environment in the trading countries have a signiï¬?cant effect on trade development. Anderson and Marcouiller (2002) ï¬?nd that weak institutions act as signiï¬?cant barriers to international trade. Francois and Manchin (2007) measure institutional quality through the lens of economic freedom, focusing on the size of government, freedom of trade, protection of property rights, and business regulation. They ï¬?nd that strong institutions are associated with increased trade at both the intensive and extensive margins. Overall, aggregate data suggest that trade-speciï¬?c regulation helps ï¬?rms internationalize, either through exports or production abroad. Policy reforms to facilitate trade can enhance countries’ competitiveness, allowing them to trade goods and services on time and with low transaction costs. By the same token, policies that set certain requirements in some sectors for product quality—such as technical standards or safety requirements—can force ï¬?rms to be internationally competitive and promote exports when such policies are harmonized with international standards. Building a regulatory environment that is friendly to foreign investors is necessary (box 4.4). Even though enforced legal frameworks may not be the main drivers of foreign investment decisions, they can tip the balance in favor of one economy over another (World Bank 2010). Speciï¬?cally, expropriation risks, lack of enforcement of contracts, poor provision of public goods, overregulation, and unreasonable costs of doing business are likely to deter private activities, domestic or foreign. Northern Europe is a good example of an environment in which more stringent rules and regulations are compatible with a thriving private sector because they are accompanied by efï¬?cient implementation procedures that minimize the burden for enterprises. Enterprises for a growing Europe Enterprise is not a weak part of the European growth model. The overall soundness of the European enterprise model is indicated by its performance—European enterprises have largely delivered what they are expected to, with only a few qualiï¬?cations. European ï¬?rms have created jobs at roughly the same pace as other developed economies around the world. The south has been particularly successful in creating jobs, but mostly in cyclical activities such as construction. The northern 224 CHAPTER 4 and continental countries also increased labor participation rates—already among the highest in the world. In Eastern Europe, enterprises recovered from the transition and in many cases generated employment rapidly. Productivity patterns show that Western Europe has largely succeeded in keeping pace with other advanced economies. Eastern Europe impressively increased in its productivity, while the EU15 North and Continental countries also beneï¬?ted from eastward outsourcing of labor-intensive activities. Lately, however, Southern Europe has moved away from such convergence, and its productivity growth has stalled. Northern and Eastern Europe, already more outward-oriented than the south, are expanding productivity and exports faster than the south. This internal divergence will strain the economic union, especially countries using the euro. What has helped the countries that did better than others? In advanced Europe, northern and continental countries succeeded globally by developing pan-European and global businesses, both in sales and in sourcing. In emerging Europe, the winners are the countries that set aside a “fear of foreignersâ€? and created an environment favorable for FDI. Southern Europe, however, was caught in a no man’s land. With an industrial structure dominated by smaller ï¬?rms—largely because of unfriendly regulations—Southern Europe has fewer ï¬?rms equipped to beneï¬?t from the single market, either in attracting foreign capital from the north or in making use of cheaper labor in the east. These experiences offer three lessons: · More Europe, not less. Countries whose enterprises were ready to operate in the single market seem to be winning the race. When barriers to entry were eliminated and transaction costs cut, countries with industrial structures with larger and more outward-oriented enterprises did better. Enterprises in the former communist countries adjusted to this new European imperative better than those in the EU15 southern states. · Regulations can upgrade industrial structures or degrade them. The type of enterprises operating in each country—particularly their size and ownership— is a function of the design and enforcement of regulations. Good regulations provided the right incentives for ï¬?rms to grow and reach an optimal size, and were as critical as the quality of the physical infrastructure in attracting FDI. Similar companies performed better when regulations were less burdensome. Of course, other aspects played a role. In countries at an earlier stage of development of the enterprise sector—like those of the former Soviet bloc— hard infrastructure and credit were as important as regulations. In advanced Europe, regulations were a critical competitive factor, especially in services. · Better entrepreneurial structures can be built—or imported. Countries do not necessarily need to create domestic enterprises, especially when entire sectors need to be revamped, as was the case for emerging Europe. Successful countries did not enact protectionist policies, but welcomed FDI. Foreign companies modernized their subsidiaries and afï¬?liates and connected them to international markets, but they also created spillovers among suppliers and competitors. Openness to FDI also helps advanced countries like Germany. Countries that took advantage of these opportunities fared better than those that did not. 225 GOLDEN GROWTH If they continue to improve their regulations, ï¬?nancial sectors, and infrastructure, countries in emerging Europe will keep beneï¬?ting from the successful European convergence machine. Southern Europe must also deal with its entrepreneurial deï¬?cit. Greater openness to the rest of Europe seems to be the solution for the laggards: importing ï¬?rms, capital, regulations, and institutions from the most advanced countries would help Southern Europe grow in line with its peers. Northern and continental countries should ï¬?x their sights on enterprises in North America and East Asia. Maintaining their position at the frontier requires efï¬?ciency and an outward orientation. Future growth will require reestablishing the momentum for regulatory reform last seen in the mid-1990s and early 2000s, this time aimed at services. And it will require improving Europe’s innovation performance, addressed in chapter 5. For now, the answer to the main question asked at the beginning—are regulations an obstacle for enterprise in Europe?—is a qualiï¬?ed no. Outside the EU15 southern states, European enterprises have created jobs, added value, and generated exports over the last decade. Answers to questions on page 187 Workers expect enterprises in Europe to create jobs, shareholders to generate value added, and governments to bring in sizable export earnings. In most parts of Europe, ï¬?rms have taken advantage of greater regional integration to decentralize production, attract foreign investment, and expand the markets for their products. In Western and Eastern Europe, industrial structures I W t dE t E i d ti l t t were better suited for a single market; Southern European enterprises have been slower to offshore activities and to attract foreign investors. In advanced European economies, many governments have to streamline regulations to make doing business easier; in emerging Europe, most have to improve infrastructure and credit as well. 226 CHAPTER 4 Chapter 4: Annexes Annex 4.1: Using the Amadeus dataset Amadeus is a comprehensive, pan-European, ï¬?rm-level database of ï¬?nancial information for more than 11 million public and private companies throughout Europe, provided by Bureau van Dijk. A 2010 version of the Amadeus database is used for the ï¬?rm-level analysis in this chapter. Although rich and detailed in balance sheet information, the Amadeus database does not necessarily reflect the underlying population. In most countries Amadeus did not have a satisfactory coverage of microï¬?rms. For this reason we focused our research on companies with 10 or more employees, small and medium enterprises, and large ï¬?rms. Another limitation of the Amadeus database is that ï¬?rms are not removed from the database unless they fail to report ï¬?nancial information for at least ï¬?ve years. Companies that exit the market or stop reporting their ï¬?nancial statements are represented as “not available/missingâ€? for four years following their last ï¬?ling. Amadeus does not distinguish ï¬?rms that close their activities from those that exit the sample because they either fall below a size threshold or were reorganized through a merger, for example. This limitation drove our choice to focus our analysis on a (balanced) sample of surviving ï¬?rms that were present in the database for the entire period of observation. In addition, ï¬?rms that were involved in merger and acquisitions operations during 2003–08 were excluded in order to eliminate meaningless growth measures. To ensure that the sample is representative of the ï¬?rm population and supports the application of inferences to the broader population, a resampling technique was applied. Population weights were computed using the Eurostat database for the year 2006 for every size, sector, and country stratum.46 Random draws were taken from each size-sector-country stratum in the sample (targeting ï¬?rms with 10 employees or more) in order for each stratum to correspond to its population weight. Once the sample was drawn, a two-step procedure was implemented to control for extreme outliers. First, observations for which the employment growth rate was larger than 300 percent (if the ï¬?rm had fewer than 50 employees) or 50 percent (if the ï¬?rm had more than 50 employees) were excluded from the analysis. Second, companies with annual productivity growth more than three standard deviations away from the average value in each country were excluded. The Amadeus dataset was used to collect information on the following: · Company characteristics: The main sector of activity and year of registration and ownership were collected to verify differential performance. For ownership, information on the global ultimate owner contained in the Amadeus database was used to distinguish companies that are purely domestic, part of a domestic group operating on a European or global scale, or foreign-owned. · Company performance indicators: Value-added data47 and total number of employees included in the company’s payroll48 were collected to perform calculations of productivity and employment growth over time. 227 GOLDEN GROWTH Table A4.1 shows the composition of the ï¬?nal sample of surviving ï¬?rms adopted in the empirical analysis. Table A4.1: Sample composition Country Number of ï¬?rms per year Bosnia and Herzegovina 590 Belgium 2,485 Czech Republic 2,410 Estonia 561 Spain 16,850 Finland 1,035 France 15,029 Croatia 1,211 Italy 17,143 Norway 1,523 Poland 3,811 Romania 4,249 Serbia 1,465 Sweden 2,436 Slovenia 526 Ukraine 6,782 Econometric results To analyze productivity growth in Europe, while disentangling the impact of ï¬?rm level from country-level characteristics, we start from estimating the following ï¬?rm-level equation: Δln(Prodi)03-08 = α + β2ln(Prodi)03 + β2 Agei,03 + β3 Sizei,03 + β4OwnTypei,03 + ∑φSector